Eurozone Crisis
Eurozone Crisis
recession that struck these countries. The focus of the article will be on the spread of financial contagion onto the peripheral Eurozone economies, namely Greece, Portugal, Ireland, Italy and Spain. The problems that occurred for the peripheral Eurozone economies can be described through three features they all shared: domestic preconditions and instabilities, current account deficits and the euro, and outside contagion from the US. The first are local instabilities and the way these countries ran their economies in the wake of the crisis. This doesnt in all cases imply budget deficits and debt accumulation, rather each country was characterized by specific conditions which endangered the sustainability of their economies. Ireland and Spain experienced a housing and construction boom and suffered an immediate impact of deteriorating housing prices and loss of construction jobs. Before the crisis, their fiscal position was fine, with decreasing debt and a balanced budget, but after bank bailouts (Ireland) and bankruptcies of the largest construction companies (Spain), decreasing revenues and increasing expenditures increased their budget deficit and public debt beyond sustainable. Portugal had over-expenditures into large public projects (including building stadiums for the Euro 2004), mismanagement in public services and investment bubbles which all led to a rising public debt and an unsustainable fiscal position. Greece and Italy, both on very sensitive high public debt levels before the crisis (see Figure 2) had an additional constraint corrupt politicians who cared more of self-preservation than the well-being of their country. Their politicians used expensive populist policies to remain in power. They used cheep borrowing on the international market to fund their electoral victories by broadening its welfare states and offering concessions to particular electoral groups. They bought votes by increasing pensions, hiring more public sector workers and increasing their wages in order to create a perception of high employment. Their governments were perfect examples of how the inflow of foreign capital was used inefficiently to finance consumption and maintain political power. The second characteristic was the introduction of the euro. Due to a common currency it became cheaper for the peripheral economies to borrow on the international market which induced large current account deficits. This was the point of a single currency to ease the movement of capital across borders. But what it created was a dependency on credit from abroad. Once this credit flow stopped the stage was set for the spread of the crisis. They found themselves in a typical sudden credit stop (as explained in Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009), usually a characteristic of emerging economies that pegged their currencies. And third, what brought to the sudden stop of credit, worsening their fiscal balances, was the spread of outside contagion, particularly from the US. The financial crisis that started in the US quickly spread worldwide through decreasing trade and a loss of investor and consumer confidence causing a credit squeeze. All this made it harder for the peripheral economies to borrow on international markets, and since their economies became dependent on cheap capital from abroad to finance their consumption and government expenditures, the credit squeeze proved to be particularly painful. Outside
contagion brought the domestic instabilities of the Eurozone economies onto the surface, and created the final trigger for the sovereign debt crisis.
Figure 1. Peripheral eurozone output gap. Source: IMF Economic Outlook, September 2011 (note: data for 2012 are predictions)
Some of them grew well beyond their potential levels of GDP, implying a clear sign of an overheating economy. For example, Greece managed to grow 8% above its potential GDP, a growth mostly fuelled by its rising debt and large capital inflows. Ireland and Spain experienced a similar output gap well beyond their potential level, but unlike Greece, the driving forces of their high growth were the asset price booms in housing and construction. Portugal and Italy grew within their potential levels, and weren't overheating as much, but have nevertheless found themselves in similar structural problems. So if high, above potential GDP growth wasnt a common characteristic, something else was. The usual implication is domestic imbalances and fiscal profligacy. They were borrowing cheep and used this money to live above their means. The inflow of foreign capital fuelled the economies beyond what they were capable of. Only part of that story is true. Figure 2 looks at each country's CA deficit (left axis) compared with gross government debt (right axis), both in percentage of nominal GDP
Figure 2. CA balance (left axis, blue) compared with gross government debt (right axis, red), both in percentage of nominal GDP. Source of data: IMF World Economic Outlook, September 2011. Note: All data for 2012 are estimates.
Observing Figure 2, a common feature is obvious: right before the start of the crisis, and mostly since the introduction of the euro, all peripheral economies experienced rising current account deficits, while the same period saw a large CA surplus in Germany. Even though Greece didn't have a CA surplus for over 30 years, Portugal, Spain, Ireland and Italy all experienced CA surpluses at some point prior to the introduction of the euro, only to see them decrease rapidly from the beginning of the decade. Government debt increase, on the other hand, fails to give such strong implications. Spain, Italy and Ireland were actually decreasing their government debts and improving their fiscal positions, while Greece kept it steady. It wasnt until the actual start of the crisis that the debt levels started rising in every country. Therefore, fiscal profligacy isnt as crucial as often made to believe. Some instabilities certainly did exist, but they couldn't have caused a crisis so severe and so widespread. It is more likely that outside contagion combined with dependence on foreign capital inflows exacerbated the systemic risk of each country. Domestic imbalances became more visible once the foreign inflow of credit stopped. They are now the cause of problems of structural adjustments, but they werent the cause of the contagion itself.
I.2. Instabilities from abroad I.2.1. Problems with a CA deficit and the common currency
When one country runs a current account deficit, this implies it runs a surplus in its capital account. A capital account surplus means an inflow of foreign capital into a country (foreigners buying more domestic assets) which is essentially a good thing since money will always flow to where it expects the highest and safest returns. However, the question is where is the money from abroad being transferred to domestically? If it is used to finance investment (into manufacturing, productivity increase or any other wealth creating activity) instead of consumption, then the deficit can carry on rising as the country is using the inflow of capital to boost its production
facilities and increase growth. If it is used to finance consumption and government expenditures focused on politically popular policies, then the outcome might be an asset price boom or an unsustainable fiscal position of the government who is becoming dependent on foreign capital to finance its exaggerated expenditures. Ireland, Spain and to some extent the US suffered from the first, while Greece, Portugal and Italy suffered from the former. Before the euro Greece had a history of debt defaults, financial contagion, inflation crises and banking crises (see Reinhart and Roggof, 2009). This was usually reflected in its higher bond yields a risk premium for investing in its debt. The spread between Greek and German bonds was historically always high. However, once the euro was introduced, its yields and the spread started decreasing making the Greek debt as safe an investment (financially) as the German debt. The reasoning behind it was that the ECB would make sure inflation and currency instability will never again be the problem of Greece or any other peripheral country. Soon enough, every peripheral Eurozone bond on the market traded as the German Bund thespreads were smaller (see graph below) and the risks were perceived as non-existent (Basel II recognized their debt as zero risk-weighted assets).
Figure 3. Yield spreads over the German Bund, 1991-2011. Source: FT Aplhaville
This meant one thing; all these countries could borrow at cheap rates, while its politicians had no need to be fiscally responsible and could resort to populist policies that would keep them in power. Borrowing cheaply meant that credit from abroad was used to fuel domestic consumption which led to a rapid increase in GDP above its potential levels, either through high government spending (Greece, Portugal) or housing market booms (Ireland, Spain). Figure 4 observes how the inflow of capital was used in peripheral Eurozone. It compares levels of consumption, government expenditures and gross fixed capital formation (fixed investments) for each nation observed to evaluate the sustainability of the CA deficit.
Figure 4. Government expenditure (blue), fixed capital formation (red) and consumption (right axis, green) are all taken as log variables. Source of data: St. Louis Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), February 2012.
From the graphs it can be inferred that in all these countries, except Italy, consumption was growing much faster and more stable than fixed capital formation. In Italy and Ireland they grew simultaneously right about two years before the crisis until the housing prices started to fall - the same effect can be noticed in Spain. Greece and Portugal saw steadily increasing consumption, with investments being more cyclical and volatile. In Germany, fixed investments have deteriorated immediately since the introduction of the euro, when a lot of German capital flew across borders. Government expenditures also show a rising trend for each country (represented by the blue line). For all the countries government expenditures were closing the gap between investments. In Spain they grew simultaneously with investments, while in Ireland they grew simultaneously with consumption. In Greece, they grew rapidly, doubling in absolute terms over the past decade, while Portugal experienced a significant decrease of the gap between investments and government expenditures after the introduction of the euro.
Figure 5 serves as a good reminder on importance of debt levels and the sustainability of these debt levels on investor confidence and country bond yields. Greece, Italy, Portugal and Ireland (4 out of 5 countries analyzed) are countries with the highest debt burdens in the eurozone and are the countries most exposed to the threat of default. In addition to this I would like to stress out the mechanism of outside contagion described excelently by Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) (I summarize their main findings on the spread of contagion throughout the world financial system):
"Banking crises in advanced economies decrease growth of these economies. This slowing of growth and economic activity will hit exports thus eliminating availability of hard currency to emerging market countries, making it more difficult for them to service their debts. Weakening global growth will decrease commodity prices which will reduce export earnings to primary commodity producers the emerging market countries, making it even more difficult for them to service their debt Banking crises in global financial centers will yield a credit squeeze on the international lending market. Since it will become harder for the emerging market economies to obtain credit, their economic activity will contract and the burden of the debt will be harder to service Banking crises will decrease investor confidence and make them withdraw from risk taking and move their money into safe assets (such as low-yield government
securities). Again, emerging markets will find it much harder to borrow on the international market as the yields on their bonds will rise and they will become less attractive to investors." Reinhart, Rogoff (2009): "This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly" Princeton University Press There are striking similarities with the case of the eurozone economies. The only difference is that they didn't depend on commodity prices to drive their exports, but the credit squeeze and the dependence on credit from net lenders forced them into a situation where they were unable to service their debts anymore, and their economies contracted. Now, due to a severe decrease in confidence they find it hard to borrow on international markets and are entering into an even higher dependency on foreign aid from either Germany, the ECB or eventually the IMF (in the emerging markets case, it's usually only the IMF who comes to the rescue).
private Greek debt holders are EU banks. It is their bancrupcy and/or nationalization, not the default itself that may prove to be the trigger for another depression. What was the end outcome of an artificially created demand for peripheral debt? It made it easy for the governments of these countries to borrow to fund their populist, electoral winning policies. It worsened domestic fiscal balances of these countries and worked towards increasing their debt levels. Higher debts in Italy and Greece were evident even before the crisis. The Basel accords only further endangered the fiscal positions of these countries and havent worked at all towards decreasing the systemic risks for their banks.
Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook, September 2011. The data for 2012 are estimates. The sudden credit stop was a result of a recession spreading from the US. As was describedpreviously, a banking crisis in the centres of world finance (New York, London) yields a credit squeeze on the international market, and a severe decrease of investor confidence. As a result emerging market economies and economies dependent on foreign lending to finance its consumption find it much harder to borrow on the international market and see their bond yields rise and their debt harder and harder to service. This was an inevitable scenario for the eurozone peripheral countries. A stop of borrowing from the core eurozone countries such as Germany, triggered by the US financial crisis, exposed the depended peripheral countries to the threat of default. Fiscal deficits and rising public debts acted as a signal to investors to exit from eurozone peripheral debt and the yields started rising. Even though the current account deficit proved to be the leading reason behind the countries respective bubbles, investors usually make the decision to buy government bonds based on whether the government will be capable to service its debt obligations and pay out interest, i.e. to stay solvent in the future. As soon as they see a rising fiscal deficit and more and more debt pilling up the probability of staying solvent decreases and the country's debt becomes a more risky investment. However, the cases of Ireland and Spain were somewhat different. As stated previously they were running a real estate boom, much like the one in the US, and suffered an immediate impact of deteriorating housing prices and loss of construction jobs. The construction and housing industries carried a lot of employment so when the building boom stopped and turned into a bust, employment soared down in both countries (see the second figure and observe the rapid increase of unemployment for both these countries in particular). In his text in the New York Times in January 2010, Paul Krugman recognizes the start of troubles for Spain and Ireland through a large fiscal deficit that arose due to a severe decrease of revenues since tax receipts were mostly depended on real estate transactions. As wasshown previously, the government debt levels of Spain and Ireland rose particularly high after the bubble burst on their housing markets. Furthermore, as unemployment rose, so did the costs of unemployment benefits, which led both Ireland and Spain from a budget surplus into a huge budget deficit. In addition, Krugman adds, guarantee on bank debts by the Irish government increased the Irish debt substantially and brought its own solvency into question. All this worked further in decreasing investor confidence regarding the eurozone situation and the result was even more short-selling of peripheral government debt and higher yields and spreads over the German Bund.
Loss of confidence further crippled any Keynesian solution of spurring big money into the economy. No matter how much liquidity was being pumped in the system, no one would use it to increase lending and businesses lost support. As opposed to American companies eurozone companies are much more dependent on bank loans to fund their business (80% of EU companies compared to only 30% of US, according to the FT). It is obvious how a lending freeze and reluctance of banks to lend further due to their increased contagion from enforced exposure to peripheral debt resulted in severe consequences for the real eurozone economy.
Figure 8. Source: Financial Times, Martin Wolf: "Thinking through the unthinkable"
sustainable wealth. It can only lead to an inevitable disaster and higher social injustice which can trigger social turmoil. The political economy implication in the eurozone debt crisis is huge. The causes lie within several factors; large CA deficits due to the introduction of the euro and a misguided idea on how it was supposed to work, internal instabilities that used cheap borrowing to fund populist policies, a US crisis that lead to a sudden credit stop which emphasised the domestic instabilities, and finally a regulatory system that steered banks' investments into sovereign debt which caused the threat of default to be far greater than it usually is. Two solutions are available; either the ECB enters the market a lender of last resort and monetizes debt, which might lead to hyperinflation a strategy Germany strongly opposes, and rightly so, or we might see serial defaults of certain eurozone countries. This was obvious three months ago and it is obvious now. However, during all this time no credible solution was proposed and the position of all these countries and the eurozone itself became unbearable. Unlike the recession in 2008 triggered by Lehman, this one will be triggered by the severe loss of confidence in the bond markets caused by political incompetence.
4 comments:
1. sajin29 November 2011 23:41 excellent stuff! thank you very much for such an in-depth analysis! it is really helpful Reply 2. Michael Foster2 December 2011 14:33 nice sum-up, but what do you think will happen to the eurozone next? Is there a way out? I'm thinking that suborn politicians and the ECB will ultimately fail to provide any solution, and I think this is what Germany really wants- to bring back its deutsche mark, and get out of the whole "nation bailout" situation.. Reply
3. Vuk Vukovic2 December 2011 15:59 I'm not in a position to make credible predictions, but I was, I would say the next step is a fiscal union. Merkel is calling for it for quite some time and she is reluctant to accept any solution (eurobonds, printing money) other than a fiscal union where she might impose strict controls on reckless countries. On one hand I'm glad she's not caving into the pressure for calls on money printing (the idea for ECB as the lender of last resort to governments) and I'm glad she's eliminating the threat of hyperinflation, but on the other hand I'm not sure how this new fiscal union is supposed to look like. If it at all resembles the European Commission, I would be against it, which I'm sure it will. It will call on European collectivism and similar nonsense. But at this point, I think we are ready to accept just about anything to keep the world out of another painful depression. Reply 4. John Turpin12 February 2012 14:38 Your analysis is spot on! the CA deficit financing is the whole point - if it went to investment that led to a sustainable growth for the economy, one shouldn't worry about it, but if it went to overconsumption and overspending from the governments to finance political goals, than we should worry about the sustainability of their balance of payments position. And I agree, the credit crunch from the US only exposed this weak BoP position in peripheral Europe. Reply Home Subscribe to: Posts (Atom) MY VIEW ON LIBERTY
Any individual is free to interact in any social endeavour he or she finds desirable, up to the point when his or her actions constrain or limit the freedom of another individual.
SEARCH THIS BLOG
Search
FOLLOW BY EMAIL
Submit
ABOUT ME
Vuk Vukovic As I claim in the title, I'm an economist. But I'm also a lecturer and a researcher trying to find my space among the stars of the economics blogosphere. See more View my complete profile
LINKS
Adam Smith Institute AEA Becker-Posner blog Bloomberg Cafe Hayek Cato Institute Causes of the crisis Center for Economic Liberty CEPR Dan Mitchell blog DeLong blog EconAcademics - RePEc Econbrowser EconLog Economic Freedom Economics One - Taylor Economist's View Economix Financial Times Fraser Institute - Economic Freedom Free exchange FT A-list FT Alphaville Greg Mankiw's blog Grumpy Economist Heritage Foundation - Freedom Index Institute for Humane Studies Institute of Economic Affairs Library of Economics and Liberty Marginal Revolution Mises Institute
NBER Nobel Prize NY Times Project Syndicate Public Choice Society Real Clear Markets Real Time Economics - WSJ blog Ronald Coase Institue The Conscience of a Liberal The Economist The Money Illusion Vox EU Wall Street Journal Why Nations Fail
POPULAR POSTS
The Eastern approach I stumbled upon a great blog post today from a Hungarian business owner on the prospects of starting a business in Hungary. He entitles it p...
NGDP targeting a licence for inflation Last week saw a new idea sprung into economic discussion focused on restoring economic growth it was proposed that the US Fed should adop...
Percentages and inequality: where is the middle class? In the last post I brought to attention the inequality issue and have presented a different approach on the 1% debate. Todays post will be...
The stimulus debate revisited The debate on stimulus vs. austerity keeps covering new grounds. The former debate originated (mostly) between Krugman , DeLong , Thoma on...
Imported instability: examining the causes of eurozone contagion Note: this article is an update and summary of the sovereign eurozone debt crisis page . I've added a few things and broadened the analysi...
Graph of the week: Big Mac Wages You've surely heard of the Big Mac Index its an interesting way to measure the plausibility of the law of one price, or to be more preci...
Eurozone crisis - Intermezzo Here's something to keep it interesting while waiting for the next few posts on consequences and the remedies of the eurozone crisis. I 'b...
Understanding unemployment Today's reports on the decrease of US unemployment to 8.5% and an increase in nonfarm payroll s by 200,000 in December 2011, resulted in an...
Percentages and inequality: who is the top 1%? This week the focus of the blog will be on the rising issue of inequality. Firstly I aim to demystify the rant over the 1% of the rich and...
Modern consumption theory - temporary vs permanent income One of the main arguments in favour of a fiscal stimulus include the idea that tax rebates will work towards encouraging consumption, and h...
NEW YORK TIMES NEWS FEED
Monti Fights to Reshape Italy in Shadow of Euro Crisis Family Net Worth Drops to Level of Early 90s, Fed Says
Sidebar: In Citizens United II, How Justices Rule May Be an Issue Itself TIMESCAST: TimesCast | June 11, 2012 Syrian Conflict Cracks Carefully Polished Image of Assad
Spain to press on with debt auctions Market rally over Spain bailout fades Tesco chief defends plan for recovery Brown challenges Murdochs sworn evidence Twitter turns to TV ads to drive traffic
OIL PRICE
GOLD PRICE
Gold Price
FOLLOWERS SUBSCRIBE TO
LABELS
Cycle (5)CA
o o
57) deficit (5) China(2)Confidence(29) Credit Easing(4) Crony 2011 ( Capitalism (7)Debt (13)Devaluation (3)Economic Freedom (7)Economies of 31) Scale(1) Education (4)Eurozone(32) FED (5)Financial Crisis (42)Fiscal Decem Stimulus(12) Germany (1)Graph of the ber(8) Week (20)Greece (15)Housing (3) Humor(2) Hungary (1)Inequality (6)Inflation (2)Instit Nove utions (8)Ireland (5) Italy (9)Migration (1)Monetary Policy (3)NGDP mber(12) targeting (1)Philosophy (3)Political economy (19)Portugal (5) Private equity (1) Public Subsidizin Choice (1)Quantitative g youth hiring is Easing(2) Recovery(36)Regulation (12)Religion (1) Risk (3)Russia (2) Social wasteful Spending (4) Spain(7) Taxing (12)Technocrats (1) Tobin and will tax (2) UK (25)Unemployment (6)USA (25) Welfare State (5) yiel... Long live the technocrat s!? Reusing chewed-up ideas on the housing market Eurozone crisis analysis of causes and consequen ... Eurozone crisis Intermezz o (2) Eurozone crisis analysis of causes and consequen ... Eurozone crisis Intermezz o Eurozone
crisis analysis of causes and consequen ... Eurozone crisis analysis of causes and consequen ... NGDP targeting a licence for inflation Political economy of eurozone crisis Currency devaluatio n why is it useless in some c... Octob er (11)
Copyright: Vuk Vukovic. Simple template. Powered by Blogger.