0% found this document useful (0 votes)
55 views27 pages

Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model: Ben Mcclure

The dividend discount model (DDM) values stocks based on expected future dividend payments, discounted by a risk-adjusted rate. However, the DDM requires many assumptions about long-term dividend growth that are difficult to predict accurately. Multi-stage models attempt to account for changing growth rates but still rely on uncertain long-term forecasts. Additionally, the DDM does not value high-growth stocks that reinvest profits rather than pay dividends, and has difficulty incorporating companies with fluctuating or no dividend payments. While imperfect, the DDM framework encourages evaluating assumptions about a company's future prospects.

Uploaded by

PrashantK
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
55 views27 pages

Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model: Ben Mcclure

The dividend discount model (DDM) values stocks based on expected future dividend payments, discounted by a risk-adjusted rate. However, the DDM requires many assumptions about long-term dividend growth that are difficult to predict accurately. Multi-stage models attempt to account for changing growth rates but still rely on uncertain long-term forecasts. Additionally, the DDM does not value high-growth stocks that reinvest profits rather than pay dividends, and has difficulty incorporating companies with fluctuating or no dividend payments. While imperfect, the DDM framework encourages evaluating assumptions about a company's future prospects.

Uploaded by

PrashantK
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 27

Digging Into The Dividend

Discount Model
By Ben McClure | September 16, 2014 4:00 AM EDT

It's time to dust off one of the oldest, most conservative methods of valuing
stocks - the dividend discount model (DDM). It's one of the basic applications of a
financial theory that students in any introductory finance class must learn.
Unfortunately, the theory is the easy part. The model requires loads of
assumptions about companies' dividend payments and growth patterns, as well
as future interest rates. Difficulties spring up in the search for sensible numbers
to fold into the equation. Here we'll examine this model and show you how to
calculate it. (Will the dividend discount model work for you? Find out more in How
To Choose The Best Stock Valuation Method.)
Tutorial: Top Stock-Picking Strategies
The Dividend Discount Model
Here is the basic idea: any stock is ultimately worth no more than what it will
provide investors in current and future dividends. Financial theory says that the
value of a stock is worth all of the future cash flows expected to be generated by

the firm, discounted by an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. According to the DDM,


dividends are the cash flows that are returned to the shareholder. (We're going to
assume you understand the concepts of time value of money and discounting.
You can learn more about these subjects in Understanding The Time Value Of
Money.)
To value a company using the DDM, you calculate the value of dividend
payments that you think a stock will throw-off in the years ahead. Here is what the
model says:

Where:
P= the price at time 0
r= discount rate
For simplicity's sake, consider a company with a $1 annual dividend. If you figure
the company will pay that dividend indefinitely, you must ask yourself what you
are willing to pay for that company. Assume expected return, or, more
appropriately in academic parlance, the required rate of return, is 5%. According
to the dividend discount model, the company should be worth $20 ($1.00 / .05).
How do we get to the formula above? It's actually just an application of the
formula for a perpetuity:

The obvious shortcoming of the model above is that you'd expect most
companies to grow over time. If you think this is the case, then the denominator
equals the expected return less the dividend growth rate. This is known as the
constant growth DDM or the Gordon model after its creator, Myron Gordon. Let's
say you think the company's dividend will grow by 3% annually. The company's

value should then be $1 / (.05 - .03) = $50. Here is the formula for valuing a
company with a constantly growing dividend, as well as the proof of the formula:

The classic dividend discount model works best when valuing a mature company
that pays a hefty portion of its earnings as dividends, such as a utility company.
The Problem of Forecasting
Proponents of the dividend discount model say that only future cash
dividends can give you a reliable estimate of a company's intrinsic value. Buying
a stock for any other reason - say, paying 20 times the company's earnings today
because somebody will pay 30 times tomorrow - is mere speculation.
In truth, the dividend discount model requires an enormous amount of
speculation in trying to forecast future dividends. Even when you apply it to
steady, reliable, dividend-paying companies, you still need to make plenty of
assumptions about their future. The model is subject to the axiom "garbage in,
garbage out", meaning that a model is only as good as the assumptions it is
based upon. Furthermore, the inputs that produce valuations are always
changing and susceptible to error.
The first big assumption that the DDM makes is that dividends are steady, or
grow at a constant rate indefinitely. But even for steady, reliable, utility-type
stocks, it can be tricky to forecast exactly what the dividend payment will be next
year, never mind a dozen years from now. (Find out some of the reasons why
companies cut dividends in Your Dividend Payout: Can You Count On It?)

Multi-Stage Dividend Discount Models


To get around the problem posed by unsteady dividends, multi-stage models take

the DDM a step closer to reality by assuming that the company will experience
differing growth phases. Stock analysts build complex forecast models with many
phases of differing growth to better reflect real prospects. For example, a multistage DDM may predict that a company will have a dividend that grows at 5% for
seven years, 3% for the following three years and then at 2% in perpetuity.
However, such an approach brings even more assumptions into the model although it doesn't assume that a dividend will grow at a constant rate, it must
guess when and by how much a dividend will change over time.
What Should Be Expected?
Another sticking point with the DDM is that no one really knows for certain the
appropriate expected rate of return to use. It's not always wise simply to use the
long-term interest rate because the appropriateness of this can change.
The High-Growth Problem
No fancy DDM model is able to solve the problem of high-growth stocks. If the
company's dividend growth rate exceeds the expected return rate, you cannot
calculate a value because you get a negative denominator in the formula. Stocks
don't have a negative value. Consider a company with a dividend growing at 20%
while the expected return rate is only 5%: in the denominator (r-g) you would
have -15% (5%-20%)!
In fact, even if the growth rate does not exceed the expected return rate, growth
stocks, which don't pay dividends, are even tougher to value using this model. If
you hope to value a growth stock with the dividend discount model, your valuation
will be based on nothing more than guesses about the company's future profits
and dividend policy decisions. Most growth stocks don't pay out dividends.
Rather, they re-invest earnings into the company with the hope of providing
shareholders with returns by means of a higher share price .
Consider Microsoft, which didn't pay a dividend for decades. Given this fact, the
model might suggest the company was worthless at that time - which is
completely absurd. Remember, only about one-third of all public companies pay

dividends. Furthermore, even companies that do offer payouts are allocating less
and less of their earnings to shareholders.
Conclusion
The dividend discount model is by no means the be-all and end-all for valuation.
That being said, learning about the dividend discount model does encourage
thinking. It forces investors to evaluate different assumptions about growth and
future prospects. If nothing else, the DDM demonstrates the underlying principle
that a company is worth the sum of its discounted future cash flows. (Whether or
not dividends are the correct measure of cash flow is another question.) The
challenge is to make the model as applicable to reality as possible, which means
using the most reliable assumptions available.

Read more: Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model |


Investopedia http://www.investopedia.com/articles/fundamental/04/041404.asp#ixzz4TTHL2
x83
Follow us: Investopedia on Facebook

Digging Into The Dividend


Discount Model
By Ben McClure | September 16, 2014 4:00 AM EDT

It's time to dust off one of the oldest, most conservative methods of valuing
stocks - the dividend discount model (DDM). It's one of the basic applications of a
financial theory that students in any introductory finance class must learn.

Unfortunately, the theory is the easy part. The model requires loads of
assumptions about companies' dividend payments and growth patterns, as well
as future interest rates. Difficulties spring up in the search for sensible numbers
to fold into the equation. Here we'll examine this model and show you how to
calculate it. (Will the dividend discount model work for you? Find out more in How
To Choose The Best Stock Valuation Method.)
Tutorial: Top Stock-Picking Strategies
The Dividend Discount Model
Here is the basic idea: any stock is ultimately worth no more than what it will
provide investors in current and future dividends. Financial theory says that the
value of a stock is worth all of the future cash flows expected to be generated by
the firm, discounted by an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. According to the DDM,
dividends are the cash flows that are returned to the shareholder. (We're going to
assume you understand the concepts of time value of money and discounting.
You can learn more about these subjects in Understanding The Time Value Of
Money.)
To value a company using the DDM, you calculate the value of dividend
payments that you think a stock will throw-off in the years ahead. Here is what the
model says:

Where:
P= the price at time 0
r= discount rate
For simplicity's sake, consider a company with a $1 annual dividend. If you figure
the company will pay that dividend indefinitely, you must ask yourself what you
are willing to pay for that company. Assume expected return, or, more
appropriately in academic parlance, the required rate of return, is 5%. According
to the dividend discount model, the company should be worth $20 ($1.00 / .05).

How do we get to the formula above? It's actually just an application of the
formula for a perpetuity:

The obvious shortcoming of the model above is that you'd expect most
companies to grow over time. If you think this is the case, then the denominator
equals the expected return less the dividend growth rate. This is known as the
constant growth DDM or the Gordon model after its creator, Myron Gordon. Let's
say you think the company's dividend will grow by 3% annually. The company's
value should then be $1 / (.05 - .03) = $50. Here is the formula for valuing a
company with a constantly growing dividend, as well as the proof of the formula:

The classic dividend discount model works best when valuing a mature company
that pays a hefty portion of its earnings as dividends, such as a utility company.
The Problem of Forecasting
Proponents of the dividend discount model say that only future cash
dividends can give you a reliable estimate of a company's intrinsic value. Buying
a stock for any other reason - say, paying 20 times the company's earnings today
because somebody will pay 30 times tomorrow - is mere speculation.
In truth, the dividend discount model requires an enormous amount of
speculation in trying to forecast future dividends. Even when you apply it to
steady, reliable, dividend-paying companies, you still need to make plenty of
assumptions about their future. The model is subject to the axiom "garbage in,
garbage out", meaning that a model is only as good as the assumptions it is
based upon. Furthermore, the inputs that produce valuations are always
changing and susceptible to error.

The first big assumption that the DDM makes is that dividends are steady, or
grow at a constant rate indefinitely. But even for steady, reliable, utility-type
stocks, it can be tricky to forecast exactly what the dividend payment will be next
year, never mind a dozen years from now. (Find out some of the reasons why
companies cut dividends in Your Dividend Payout: Can You Count On It?)

Multi-Stage Dividend Discount Models


To get around the problem posed by unsteady dividends, multi-stage models take
the DDM a step closer to reality by assuming that the company will experience
differing growth phases. Stock analysts build complex forecast models with many
phases of differing growth to better reflect real prospects. For example, a multistage DDM may predict that a company will have a dividend that grows at 5% for
seven years, 3% for the following three years and then at 2% in perpetuity.
However, such an approach brings even more assumptions into the model although it doesn't assume that a dividend will grow at a constant rate, it must
guess when and by how much a dividend will change over time.
What Should Be Expected?
Another sticking point with the DDM is that no one really knows for certain the
appropriate expected rate of return to use. It's not always wise simply to use the
long-term interest rate because the appropriateness of this can change.
The High-Growth Problem
No fancy DDM model is able to solve the problem of high-growth stocks. If the
company's dividend growth rate exceeds the expected return rate, you cannot
calculate a value because you get a negative denominator in the formula. Stocks
don't have a negative value. Consider a company with a dividend growing at 20%
while the expected return rate is only 5%: in the denominator (r-g) you would
have -15% (5%-20%)!
In fact, even if the growth rate does not exceed the expected return rate, growth
stocks, which don't pay dividends, are even tougher to value using this model. If
you hope to value a growth stock with the dividend discount model, your valuation
will be based on nothing more than guesses about the company's future profits

and dividend policy decisions. Most growth stocks don't pay out dividends.
Rather, they re-invest earnings into the company with the hope of providing
shareholders with returns by means of a higher share price .
Consider Microsoft, which didn't pay a dividend for decades. Given this fact, the
model might suggest the company was worthless at that time - which is
completely absurd. Remember, only about one-third of all public companies pay
dividends. Furthermore, even companies that do offer payouts are allocating less
and less of their earnings to shareholders.
Conclusion
The dividend discount model is by no means the be-all and end-all for valuation.
That being said, learning about the dividend discount model does encourage
thinking. It forces investors to evaluate different assumptions about growth and
future prospects. If nothing else, the DDM demonstrates the underlying principle
that a company is worth the sum of its discounted future cash flows. (Whether or
not dividends are the correct measure of cash flow is another question.) The
challenge is to make the model as applicable to reality as possible, which means
using the most reliable assumptions available.

Read more: Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model |


Investopedia http://www.investopedia.com/articles/fundamental/04/041404.asp#ixzz4TTHL2
x83
Follow us: Investopedia on Facebook

Digging Into The Dividend


Discount Model
By Ben McClure | September 16, 2014 4:00 AM EDT

It's time to dust off one of the oldest, most conservative methods of valuing
stocks - the dividend discount model (DDM). It's one of the basic applications of a
financial theory that students in any introductory finance class must learn.
Unfortunately, the theory is the easy part. The model requires loads of
assumptions about companies' dividend payments and growth patterns, as well
as future interest rates. Difficulties spring up in the search for sensible numbers
to fold into the equation. Here we'll examine this model and show you how to
calculate it. (Will the dividend discount model work for you? Find out more in How
To Choose The Best Stock Valuation Method.)
Tutorial: Top Stock-Picking Strategies
The Dividend Discount Model
Here is the basic idea: any stock is ultimately worth no more than what it will
provide investors in current and future dividends. Financial theory says that the
value of a stock is worth all of the future cash flows expected to be generated by
the firm, discounted by an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. According to the DDM,
dividends are the cash flows that are returned to the shareholder. (We're going to
assume you understand the concepts of time value of money and discounting.
You can learn more about these subjects in Understanding The Time Value Of
Money.)
To value a company using the DDM, you calculate the value of dividend
payments that you think a stock will throw-off in the years ahead. Here is what the
model says:

Where:
P= the price at time 0
r= discount rate
For simplicity's sake, consider a company with a $1 annual dividend. If you figure
the company will pay that dividend indefinitely, you must ask yourself what you
are willing to pay for that company. Assume expected return, or, more
appropriately in academic parlance, the required rate of return, is 5%. According
to the dividend discount model, the company should be worth $20 ($1.00 / .05).
How do we get to the formula above? It's actually just an application of the
formula for a perpetuity:

The obvious shortcoming of the model above is that you'd expect most
companies to grow over time. If you think this is the case, then the denominator
equals the expected return less the dividend growth rate. This is known as the
constant growth DDM or the Gordon model after its creator, Myron Gordon. Let's
say you think the company's dividend will grow by 3% annually. The company's
value should then be $1 / (.05 - .03) = $50. Here is the formula for valuing a
company with a constantly growing dividend, as well as the proof of the formula:

The classic dividend discount model works best when valuing a mature company
that pays a hefty portion of its earnings as dividends, such as a utility company.
The Problem of Forecasting
Proponents of the dividend discount model say that only future cash
dividends can give you a reliable estimate of a company's intrinsic value. Buying

a stock for any other reason - say, paying 20 times the company's earnings today
because somebody will pay 30 times tomorrow - is mere speculation.
In truth, the dividend discount model requires an enormous amount of
speculation in trying to forecast future dividends. Even when you apply it to
steady, reliable, dividend-paying companies, you still need to make plenty of
assumptions about their future. The model is subject to the axiom "garbage in,
garbage out", meaning that a model is only as good as the assumptions it is
based upon. Furthermore, the inputs that produce valuations are always
changing and susceptible to error.
The first big assumption that the DDM makes is that dividends are steady, or
grow at a constant rate indefinitely. But even for steady, reliable, utility-type
stocks, it can be tricky to forecast exactly what the dividend payment will be next
year, never mind a dozen years from now. (Find out some of the reasons why
companies cut dividends in Your Dividend Payout: Can You Count On It?)

Multi-Stage Dividend Discount Models


To get around the problem posed by unsteady dividends, multi-stage models take
the DDM a step closer to reality by assuming that the company will experience
differing growth phases. Stock analysts build complex forecast models with many
phases of differing growth to better reflect real prospects. For example, a multistage DDM may predict that a company will have a dividend that grows at 5% for
seven years, 3% for the following three years and then at 2% in perpetuity.
However, such an approach brings even more assumptions into the model although it doesn't assume that a dividend will grow at a constant rate, it must
guess when and by how much a dividend will change over time.
What Should Be Expected?
Another sticking point with the DDM is that no one really knows for certain the
appropriate expected rate of return to use. It's not always wise simply to use the
long-term interest rate because the appropriateness of this can change.

The High-Growth Problem


No fancy DDM model is able to solve the problem of high-growth stocks. If the
company's dividend growth rate exceeds the expected return rate, you cannot
calculate a value because you get a negative denominator in the formula. Stocks
don't have a negative value. Consider a company with a dividend growing at 20%
while the expected return rate is only 5%: in the denominator (r-g) you would
have -15% (5%-20%)!
In fact, even if the growth rate does not exceed the expected return rate, growth
stocks, which don't pay dividends, are even tougher to value using this model. If
you hope to value a growth stock with the dividend discount model, your valuation
will be based on nothing more than guesses about the company's future profits
and dividend policy decisions. Most growth stocks don't pay out dividends.
Rather, they re-invest earnings into the company with the hope of providing
shareholders with returns by means of a higher share price .
Consider Microsoft, which didn't pay a dividend for decades. Given this fact, the
model might suggest the company was worthless at that time - which is
completely absurd. Remember, only about one-third of all public companies pay
dividends. Furthermore, even companies that do offer payouts are allocating less
and less of their earnings to shareholders.
Conclusion
The dividend discount model is by no means the be-all and end-all for valuation.
That being said, learning about the dividend discount model does encourage
thinking. It forces investors to evaluate different assumptions about growth and
future prospects. If nothing else, the DDM demonstrates the underlying principle
that a company is worth the sum of its discounted future cash flows. (Whether or
not dividends are the correct measure of cash flow is another question.) The
challenge is to make the model as applicable to reality as possible, which means
using the most reliable assumptions available.

Read more: Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model |


Investopedia http://www.investopedia.com/articles/fundamental/04/041404.asp#ixzz4TTHL2

x83
Follow us: Investopedia on Facebook

Digging Into The Dividend


Discount Model
By Ben McClure | September 16, 2014 4:00 AM EDT

It's time to dust off one of the oldest, most conservative methods of valuing
stocks - the dividend discount model (DDM). It's one of the basic applications of a
financial theory that students in any introductory finance class must learn.
Unfortunately, the theory is the easy part. The model requires loads of
assumptions about companies' dividend payments and growth patterns, as well
as future interest rates. Difficulties spring up in the search for sensible numbers
to fold into the equation. Here we'll examine this model and show you how to
calculate it. (Will the dividend discount model work for you? Find out more in How
To Choose The Best Stock Valuation Method.)

Tutorial: Top Stock-Picking Strategies


The Dividend Discount Model
Here is the basic idea: any stock is ultimately worth no more than what it will
provide investors in current and future dividends. Financial theory says that the
value of a stock is worth all of the future cash flows expected to be generated by
the firm, discounted by an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. According to the DDM,
dividends are the cash flows that are returned to the shareholder. (We're going to
assume you understand the concepts of time value of money and discounting.
You can learn more about these subjects in Understanding The Time Value Of
Money.)
To value a company using the DDM, you calculate the value of dividend
payments that you think a stock will throw-off in the years ahead. Here is what the
model says:

Where:
P= the price at time 0
r= discount rate
For simplicity's sake, consider a company with a $1 annual dividend. If you figure
the company will pay that dividend indefinitely, you must ask yourself what you
are willing to pay for that company. Assume expected return, or, more
appropriately in academic parlance, the required rate of return, is 5%. According
to the dividend discount model, the company should be worth $20 ($1.00 / .05).
How do we get to the formula above? It's actually just an application of the
formula for a perpetuity:

The obvious shortcoming of the model above is that you'd expect most
companies to grow over time. If you think this is the case, then the denominator
equals the expected return less the dividend growth rate. This is known as the
constant growth DDM or the Gordon model after its creator, Myron Gordon. Let's
say you think the company's dividend will grow by 3% annually. The company's
value should then be $1 / (.05 - .03) = $50. Here is the formula for valuing a
company with a constantly growing dividend, as well as the proof of the formula:

The classic dividend discount model works best when valuing a mature company
that pays a hefty portion of its earnings as dividends, such as a utility company.
The Problem of Forecasting
Proponents of the dividend discount model say that only future cash
dividends can give you a reliable estimate of a company's intrinsic value. Buying
a stock for any other reason - say, paying 20 times the company's earnings today
because somebody will pay 30 times tomorrow - is mere speculation.
In truth, the dividend discount model requires an enormous amount of
speculation in trying to forecast future dividends. Even when you apply it to
steady, reliable, dividend-paying companies, you still need to make plenty of
assumptions about their future. The model is subject to the axiom "garbage in,
garbage out", meaning that a model is only as good as the assumptions it is
based upon. Furthermore, the inputs that produce valuations are always
changing and susceptible to error.

The first big assumption that the DDM makes is that dividends are steady, or
grow at a constant rate indefinitely. But even for steady, reliable, utility-type
stocks, it can be tricky to forecast exactly what the dividend payment will be next
year, never mind a dozen years from now. (Find out some of the reasons why
companies cut dividends in Your Dividend Payout: Can You Count On It?)

Multi-Stage Dividend Discount Models


To get around the problem posed by unsteady dividends, multi-stage models take
the DDM a step closer to reality by assuming that the company will experience
differing growth phases. Stock analysts build complex forecast models with many
phases of differing growth to better reflect real prospects. For example, a multistage DDM may predict that a company will have a dividend that grows at 5% for
seven years, 3% for the following three years and then at 2% in perpetuity.
However, such an approach brings even more assumptions into the model although it doesn't assume that a dividend will grow at a constant rate, it must
guess when and by how much a dividend will change over time.
What Should Be Expected?
Another sticking point with the DDM is that no one really knows for certain the
appropriate expected rate of return to use. It's not always wise simply to use the
long-term interest rate because the appropriateness of this can change.
The High-Growth Problem
No fancy DDM model is able to solve the problem of high-growth stocks. If the
company's dividend growth rate exceeds the expected return rate, you cannot
calculate a value because you get a negative denominator in the formula. Stocks
don't have a negative value. Consider a company with a dividend growing at 20%
while the expected return rate is only 5%: in the denominator (r-g) you would
have -15% (5%-20%)!
In fact, even if the growth rate does not exceed the expected return rate, growth
stocks, which don't pay dividends, are even tougher to value using this model. If
you hope to value a growth stock with the dividend discount model, your valuation
will be based on nothing more than guesses about the company's future profits

and dividend policy decisions. Most growth stocks don't pay out dividends.
Rather, they re-invest earnings into the company with the hope of providing
shareholders with returns by means of a higher share price .
Consider Microsoft, which didn't pay a dividend for decades. Given this fact, the
model might suggest the company was worthless at that time - which is
completely absurd. Remember, only about one-third of all public companies pay
dividends. Furthermore, even companies that do offer payouts are allocating less
and less of their earnings to shareholders.
Conclusion
The dividend discount model is by no means the be-all and end-all for valuation.
That being said, learning about the dividend discount model does encourage
thinking. It forces investors to evaluate different assumptions about growth and
future prospects. If nothing else, the DDM demonstrates the underlying principle
that a company is worth the sum of its discounted future cash flows. (Whether or
not dividends are the correct measure of cash flow is another question.) The
challenge is to make the model as applicable to reality as possible, which means
using the most reliable assumptions available.

Read more: Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model |


Investopedia http://www.investopedia.com/articles/fundamental/04/041404.asp#ixzz4TTHL2
x83
Follow us: Investopedia on Facebook

Digging Into The Dividend


Discount Model
By Ben McClure | September 16, 2014 4:00 AM EDT

It's time to dust off one of the oldest, most conservative methods of valuing
stocks - the dividend discount model (DDM). It's one of the basic applications of a
financial theory that students in any introductory finance class must learn.
Unfortunately, the theory is the easy part. The model requires loads of
assumptions about companies' dividend payments and growth patterns, as well
as future interest rates. Difficulties spring up in the search for sensible numbers
to fold into the equation. Here we'll examine this model and show you how to
calculate it. (Will the dividend discount model work for you? Find out more in How
To Choose The Best Stock Valuation Method.)
Tutorial: Top Stock-Picking Strategies
The Dividend Discount Model
Here is the basic idea: any stock is ultimately worth no more than what it will
provide investors in current and future dividends. Financial theory says that the
value of a stock is worth all of the future cash flows expected to be generated by
the firm, discounted by an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. According to the DDM,
dividends are the cash flows that are returned to the shareholder. (We're going to
assume you understand the concepts of time value of money and discounting.
You can learn more about these subjects in Understanding The Time Value Of
Money.)
To value a company using the DDM, you calculate the value of dividend
payments that you think a stock will throw-off in the years ahead. Here is what the
model says:

Where:
P= the price at time 0
r= discount rate

For simplicity's sake, consider a company with a $1 annual dividend. If you figure
the company will pay that dividend indefinitely, you must ask yourself what you
are willing to pay for that company. Assume expected return, or, more
appropriately in academic parlance, the required rate of return, is 5%. According
to the dividend discount model, the company should be worth $20 ($1.00 / .05).
How do we get to the formula above? It's actually just an application of the
formula for a perpetuity:

The obvious shortcoming of the model above is that you'd expect most
companies to grow over time. If you think this is the case, then the denominator
equals the expected return less the dividend growth rate. This is known as the
constant growth DDM or the Gordon model after its creator, Myron Gordon. Let's
say you think the company's dividend will grow by 3% annually. The company's
value should then be $1 / (.05 - .03) = $50. Here is the formula for valuing a
company with a constantly growing dividend, as well as the proof of the formula:

The classic dividend discount model works best when valuing a mature company
that pays a hefty portion of its earnings as dividends, such as a utility company.
The Problem of Forecasting
Proponents of the dividend discount model say that only future cash
dividends can give you a reliable estimate of a company's intrinsic value. Buying
a stock for any other reason - say, paying 20 times the company's earnings today
because somebody will pay 30 times tomorrow - is mere speculation.
In truth, the dividend discount model requires an enormous amount of
speculation in trying to forecast future dividends. Even when you apply it to

steady, reliable, dividend-paying companies, you still need to make plenty of


assumptions about their future. The model is subject to the axiom "garbage in,
garbage out", meaning that a model is only as good as the assumptions it is
based upon. Furthermore, the inputs that produce valuations are always
changing and susceptible to error.
The first big assumption that the DDM makes is that dividends are steady, or
grow at a constant rate indefinitely. But even for steady, reliable, utility-type
stocks, it can be tricky to forecast exactly what the dividend payment will be next
year, never mind a dozen years from now. (Find out some of the reasons why
companies cut dividends in Your Dividend Payout: Can You Count On It?)

Multi-Stage Dividend Discount Models


To get around the problem posed by unsteady dividends, multi-stage models take
the DDM a step closer to reality by assuming that the company will experience
differing growth phases. Stock analysts build complex forecast models with many
phases of differing growth to better reflect real prospects. For example, a multistage DDM may predict that a company will have a dividend that grows at 5% for
seven years, 3% for the following three years and then at 2% in perpetuity.
However, such an approach brings even more assumptions into the model although it doesn't assume that a dividend will grow at a constant rate, it must
guess when and by how much a dividend will change over time.
What Should Be Expected?
Another sticking point with the DDM is that no one really knows for certain the
appropriate expected rate of return to use. It's not always wise simply to use the
long-term interest rate because the appropriateness of this can change.
The High-Growth Problem
No fancy DDM model is able to solve the problem of high-growth stocks. If the
company's dividend growth rate exceeds the expected return rate, you cannot
calculate a value because you get a negative denominator in the formula. Stocks
don't have a negative value. Consider a company with a dividend growing at 20%

while the expected return rate is only 5%: in the denominator (r-g) you would
have -15% (5%-20%)!
In fact, even if the growth rate does not exceed the expected return rate, growth
stocks, which don't pay dividends, are even tougher to value using this model. If
you hope to value a growth stock with the dividend discount model, your valuation
will be based on nothing more than guesses about the company's future profits
and dividend policy decisions. Most growth stocks don't pay out dividends.
Rather, they re-invest earnings into the company with the hope of providing
shareholders with returns by means of a higher share price .
Consider Microsoft, which didn't pay a dividend for decades. Given this fact, the
model might suggest the company was worthless at that time - which is
completely absurd. Remember, only about one-third of all public companies pay
dividends. Furthermore, even companies that do offer payouts are allocating less
and less of their earnings to shareholders.
Conclusion
The dividend discount model is by no means the be-all and end-all for valuation.
That being said, learning about the dividend discount model does encourage
thinking. It forces investors to evaluate different assumptions about growth and
future prospects. If nothing else, the DDM demonstrates the underlying principle
that a company is worth the sum of its discounted future cash flows. (Whether or
not dividends are the correct measure of cash flow is another question.) The
challenge is to make the model as applicable to reality as possible, which means
using the most reliable assumptions available.

Read more: Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model |


Investopedia http://www.investopedia.com/articles/fundamental/04/041404.asp#ixzz4TTHL2
x83
Follow us: Investopedia on Facebook

Digging Into The Dividend


Discount Model
By Ben McClure | September 16, 2014 4:00 AM EDT

It's time to dust off one of the oldest, most conservative methods of valuing
stocks - the dividend discount model (DDM). It's one of the basic applications of a
financial theory that students in any introductory finance class must learn.
Unfortunately, the theory is the easy part. The model requires loads of
assumptions about companies' dividend payments and growth patterns, as well
as future interest rates. Difficulties spring up in the search for sensible numbers
to fold into the equation. Here we'll examine this model and show you how to
calculate it. (Will the dividend discount model work for you? Find out more in How
To Choose The Best Stock Valuation Method.)
Tutorial: Top Stock-Picking Strategies
The Dividend Discount Model
Here is the basic idea: any stock is ultimately worth no more than what it will
provide investors in current and future dividends. Financial theory says that the
value of a stock is worth all of the future cash flows expected to be generated by
the firm, discounted by an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. According to the DDM,
dividends are the cash flows that are returned to the shareholder. (We're going to
assume you understand the concepts of time value of money and discounting.
You can learn more about these subjects in Understanding The Time Value Of
Money.)

To value a company using the DDM, you calculate the value of dividend
payments that you think a stock will throw-off in the years ahead. Here is what the
model says:

Where:
P= the price at time 0
r= discount rate
For simplicity's sake, consider a company with a $1 annual dividend. If you figure
the company will pay that dividend indefinitely, you must ask yourself what you
are willing to pay for that company. Assume expected return, or, more
appropriately in academic parlance, the required rate of return, is 5%. According
to the dividend discount model, the company should be worth $20 ($1.00 / .05).
How do we get to the formula above? It's actually just an application of the
formula for a perpetuity:

The obvious shortcoming of the model above is that you'd expect most
companies to grow over time. If you think this is the case, then the denominator
equals the expected return less the dividend growth rate. This is known as the
constant growth DDM or the Gordon model after its creator, Myron Gordon. Let's
say you think the company's dividend will grow by 3% annually. The company's
value should then be $1 / (.05 - .03) = $50. Here is the formula for valuing a
company with a constantly growing dividend, as well as the proof of the formula:

The classic dividend discount model works best when valuing a mature company
that pays a hefty portion of its earnings as dividends, such as a utility company.
The Problem of Forecasting
Proponents of the dividend discount model say that only future cash
dividends can give you a reliable estimate of a company's intrinsic value. Buying
a stock for any other reason - say, paying 20 times the company's earnings today
because somebody will pay 30 times tomorrow - is mere speculation.
In truth, the dividend discount model requires an enormous amount of
speculation in trying to forecast future dividends. Even when you apply it to
steady, reliable, dividend-paying companies, you still need to make plenty of
assumptions about their future. The model is subject to the axiom "garbage in,
garbage out", meaning that a model is only as good as the assumptions it is
based upon. Furthermore, the inputs that produce valuations are always
changing and susceptible to error.
The first big assumption that the DDM makes is that dividends are steady, or
grow at a constant rate indefinitely. But even for steady, reliable, utility-type
stocks, it can be tricky to forecast exactly what the dividend payment will be next
year, never mind a dozen years from now. (Find out some of the reasons why
companies cut dividends in Your Dividend Payout: Can You Count On It?)

Multi-Stage Dividend Discount Models


To get around the problem posed by unsteady dividends, multi-stage models take
the DDM a step closer to reality by assuming that the company will experience
differing growth phases. Stock analysts build complex forecast models with many
phases of differing growth to better reflect real prospects. For example, a multistage DDM may predict that a company will have a dividend that grows at 5% for
seven years, 3% for the following three years and then at 2% in perpetuity.
However, such an approach brings even more assumptions into the model although it doesn't assume that a dividend will grow at a constant rate, it must
guess when and by how much a dividend will change over time.

What Should Be Expected?


Another sticking point with the DDM is that no one really knows for certain the
appropriate expected rate of return to use. It's not always wise simply to use the
long-term interest rate because the appropriateness of this can change.
The High-Growth Problem
No fancy DDM model is able to solve the problem of high-growth stocks. If the
company's dividend growth rate exceeds the expected return rate, you cannot
calculate a value because you get a negative denominator in the formula. Stocks
don't have a negative value. Consider a company with a dividend growing at 20%
while the expected return rate is only 5%: in the denominator (r-g) you would
have -15% (5%-20%)!
In fact, even if the growth rate does not exceed the expected return rate, growth
stocks, which don't pay dividends, are even tougher to value using this model. If
you hope to value a growth stock with the dividend discount model, your valuation
will be based on nothing more than guesses about the company's future profits
and dividend policy decisions. Most growth stocks don't pay out dividends.
Rather, they re-invest earnings into the company with the hope of providing
shareholders with returns by means of a higher share price .
Consider Microsoft, which didn't pay a dividend for decades. Given this fact, the
model might suggest the company was worthless at that time - which is
completely absurd. Remember, only about one-third of all public companies pay
dividends. Furthermore, even companies that do offer payouts are allocating less
and less of their earnings to shareholders.
Conclusion
The dividend discount model is by no means the be-all and end-all for valuation.
That being said, learning about the dividend discount model does encourage
thinking. It forces investors to evaluate different assumptions about growth and
future prospects. If nothing else, the DDM demonstrates the underlying principle
that a company is worth the sum of its discounted future cash flows. (Whether or
not dividends are the correct measure of cash flow is another question.) The

challenge is to make the model as applicable to reality as possible, which means


using the most reliable assumptions available.

Read more: Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model |


Investopedia http://www.investopedia.com/articles/fundamental/04/041404.asp#ixzz4TTHL2
x83
Follow us: Investopedia on Facebook

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy