0% found this document useful (0 votes)
44 views9 pages

Notes On Monopoly Pricing

1) The document discusses monopoly pricing and profit maximization. It notes that traditionally a monopolist chooses a constant per-unit price, but allows for more general pricing schedules where different consumers pay different prices. 2) It introduces incentive compatibility constraints, which require that the pricing schedule is designed such that consumers report their private information truthfully. 3) The optimal pricing schedule can be found by formulating the profit maximization problem subject to the incentive compatibility constraints. This leads to an optimal control problem that can be solved using techniques like the envelope theorem.

Uploaded by

WazzupWorld
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
44 views9 pages

Notes On Monopoly Pricing

1) The document discusses monopoly pricing and profit maximization. It notes that traditionally a monopolist chooses a constant per-unit price, but allows for more general pricing schedules where different consumers pay different prices. 2) It introduces incentive compatibility constraints, which require that the pricing schedule is designed such that consumers report their private information truthfully. 3) The optimal pricing schedule can be found by formulating the profit maximization problem subject to the incentive compatibility constraints. This leads to an optimal control problem that can be solved using techniques like the envelope theorem.

Uploaded by

WazzupWorld
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 9

Notes on Monopoly Pricing

The Basic Monopoly Problem

• Recall the basic monopoly profit-maximization problem:

max pD(p) − C (D(p))


p

• Here, D(p) is the market demand the monopolist faces, C(q) is the cost

function

– Assume C(0) = 0; C 0 (q) > 0; C 00 (q) > 0


q2
∗ Example: C(q) = 2

• We assume in the basic setup that the monopolist can only choose a con-

stant per-unit price p for all consumers

– This causes inefficiently low quantity supplied, and inefficiently high

price

• If the monopolist can choose different prices to different consumers, how

does that change the outcome?

From Utility to Demand

• Let’s take a closer look at where the demand D(p) comes from

1
• One convenient way is to say there are consumers with different “tastes”,

denoted by θ, for the monopolist’s product

• So, the consumer with taste θ gets the following utility from consuming q

units of the monopolist’s product:

V (q, θ) = θq

• Suppose, for convenience, that each consumer can eat at most 1 unit.

• This means, given p, all consumers with taste θ > p will buy 1 unit of the

good.

• Suppose the taste parameter θ is distributed over the interval [θ, θ̄], where

θ ≥ 0, according to the distribution F (·)

– Here, F (θ) tells you what fraction of consumers has taste below θ

– For convenience, let’s just say the total mass of consumers is 1, so

F (·) is a cdf, and f (·) is the pdf

• F (θ) = 0; F (θ̄) = 1

• By setting any price p = θ ∈ [θ, θ̄], the monopolist sells 1 − F (θ) units.

(why?)

• So D(p) = 1 − F (p)

Assumptions

• We make the following assumptions on the distribution F (·)

• F (θ) is continuous and differentiable for all θ ∈ [θ, θ̄]; (no atoms)

• f (θ) > 0 for all θ ∈ [θ, θ̄]

2
f (θ)
• The hazard rate, 1−F (θ) , is increasing in θ.

– This is a widely used and well-known assumption on probability dis-

tributions.

– Many of the commonly known distributions satisfy this property.

General Pricing Schedule

• Now let’s consider a case where the monopolist does not have to choose a

constant per-unit price

• We allow for any payment schedule T (q)

• The constant per-unit p is called linear pricing: T (q) = pq

• So now, the consumer’s net payoff is U (q, θ) = θq − T (q)

• However, the consumer can decide not to buy anything, and get a payoff

of 0

• We also use a slightly different concept of cost of production here.

• Denote now the monopolist’s cost of producing q units for one consumer

as c(q)

• c(q) is not the total cost function, but rather the cost of producing a

product of q size meant for a single consumer

– Think 8 oz. coffee cup vs. 12 oz. coffee cup

– Alternatively you can think of q as measuring quality. The idea is to

abstract away from things like increasing returns to scale that adds

more complexity

• We still assume that c0 > 0, c00 > 0

3
• With a non-linear pricing schedule T (q), the market demand D(p) isn’t

the monopolist’s constraint anymore

– The monopolist is no longer choosing a threshold level of consumer

to sell to

– Can design a pricing schedule T (q) where different consumers will

buy different quantities

– Still possible to set T (q) in such a way that excludes certain types

– But also possible to sell to all types and still make profits

• Crucial assumption: the monopolist only knows the distribution F (θ)

• Does not know the taste θ for any given consumer

• How should the monopolist make use of her information (knowledge of

F (θ))?

• How do we find the optimal (profit-maximizing) pricing schedule?

Revelation Principle

• The following result helps us find the optimal pricing schedule for the

monopolist:

– For any schedule T (·), which results in consumer with type θ max-

imizing his net payoffs by choosing quantity q and making pay-

ment T (q), there is an equivalent menu of quantity-payment pairs

(q(θ), T (θ)) that results in the same outcome.

• Think of this as the monopolist committing to sell quantity q(θ) and charge

T (θ), if a consumer goes and tells the monopolist that his taste parameter

is θ.

4
• Here, q : [θ, θ̄] → [0, 1] and T : [θ, θ̄] → R

• We can then begin to formulate the monopolist’s problem:

wθ̄
max {T (θ) − c(q(θ))} f (θ)dθ
q(·),T (·)
θ

s. to θq(θ) − T (θ) ≥ θq(θ̂) − T (θ̂); ∀θ, ∀θ̂ (IC)

θq(θ) − T (θ) ≥ 0; ∀θ (IR)

Incentive-Compatibility Constraints

• Given a schedule of quantity-payment pairs (q(·), T (·)), the incentive-

compatibility constraints are equivalent to the following two conditions:

1. Monotonicity: q(·) is non-decreasing



2. Envelope Condition: For all θ ∈ [θ, θ̄], U (θ) = U (θ) + q(t)dt; where
θ
U (θ) := θq(θ) − T (θ)

Proof

• For any pair θ and θ̂,

U (θ) = θq(θ) − T (θ)

U (θ̂) = θ̂q(θ̂) − T (θ̂)

5
• Incentive compatibility means,

U (θ) ≥ θq(θ̂) − T (θ̂)


   
U (θ) − U (θ̂) ≥ θq(θ̂) − T (θ̂) − θ̂q(θ̂) − T (θ̂)
 
U (θ) − U (θ̂) ≥ θ − θ̂ q(θ̂)

• With roles reversed, we must also have

 
U (θ̂) − U (θ) ≥ θ̂ − θ q(θ)

• But this means


 
U (θ) − U (θ̂) ≤ θ − θ̂ q(θ)

• So,
   
θ − θ̂ q(θ̂) ≤ U (θ) − U (θ̂) ≤ θ − θ̂ q(θ)

U (θ) − U (θ̂)
q(θ̂) ≤ ≤ q(θ) ; assuming θ > θ̂
θ − θ̂

• There’s the monotonicity condition

• Now for any θ̂ > θ and any θ̂ < θ,

   
θ − θ̂ q(θ̂) ≤ U (θ) − U (θ̂) ≤ θ − θ̂ q(θ)

• So, taking the limit as θ̂ → θ, we get

U (θ) − U (θ̂)
U 0 (θ) = lim = q(θ)
θ̂→θ θ − θ̂

• So U 0 (θ) = q(θ), using the fundamental theorem of calculus, we get the

6
envelope condition:

U (θ) = U (θ) + q(t)dt
θ

Payments

• Notice that

T (θ) = θq(θ) − U (θ)



T (θ) = θq(θ) − U (θ) − q(t)dt
θ

• This means that T (·) is uniquely pinned down, up to the constant U (θ),

by the choice of q(·)



• Also notice that given q(θ) ≥ 0, U (θ) = U (θ) + q(t)dt means satisfying
θ
the IR constraint for θ is enough to satisfy all IR constraints.

• What should be the monopolist’s choice for U (θ)?

Back to the PMP

• Using what we have learnt, we can rewrite the profit-maximization prob-

lem:
 
wθ̄  wθ 
max θq(θ) − c(q(θ)) − q(t)dt f (θ)dθ
q(·)  
θ θ

s. to q(·) non-decreasing (Monotonicity)

• The traditional way to solve this problem is to ignore the monotonicty

constraint, find the optimal q(·), and then check that monotonicity is

7
satisfied.

• The maximization problem at hand is an optimal control problem.

• There is a neat short-cut that allows us to solve it without using optimal

control.

• Notice that the maximand is:


 
wθ̄  wθ 
θq(θ) − c(q(θ)) − q(t)dt dF (θ)
 
θ θ

• Using integration by parts, this can be rewritten as:

wθ̄  1 − F (θ)

θq(θ) − c(q(θ)) − q(θ) f (θ)dθ
f (θ)
θ

wθ̄  1 − F (θ)
 
= θ− q(θ) − c(q(θ)) f (θ)dθ
f (θ)
θ

• Notice now that we can just pointwise maximize the term inside the second

bracket, choosing q.

• The pointwise maximization problem is:

 
1 − F (θ)
max θ − q − c(q)
q f (θ)

1−F (θ)
• FOC: θ − f (θ) − c0 (q) = 0

• So the profit maximizing solution(assuming interior solution) is to choose


1−F (θ)
q(θ) such that marginal cost, c0 (q(θ)) = θ − f (θ)

f (θ)
• Remember the monotone hazard rate condition: 1−F (θ) is increasing in θ

1−F (θ)
• This means θ − f (θ) is strictly increasing in θ

8
1 − F (θ)
c0 (q(θ)) = θ −
f (θ)

• The RHS is increasing for higher types, so the solution involves setting

higher marginal costs for higher θ

• Given c00 > 0, this means optimal q(θ) is increasing in θ. So monotonicity

is satisfied.

• Food for thought: think what the optimal q(θ) would be with constant

marginal cost.

• Is the monopolist’s quantity choice efficient (first-best) for any of the

types?

• Efficient allocation would maximize total surplus:

wθ̄
max {(θq(θ) − T (θ)) + (T (θ) − c(q(θ)))} f (θ)dθ
q(·)
θ

wθ̄
max {θq(θ) − c(q(θ))} f (θ)dθ
q(·)
θ

• Easy to see that this is achieved by setting c0 (q(θ)) = θ

1−F (θ)
• Monopolist chooses to set c0 (q(θ)) = θ − f (θ)

• Chooses less than the first-best quantity for all types θ < θ̄

• Chooses first-best quantity for θ̄ (no distortion at the top)

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy