Value at Risk - Notes
Value at Risk - Notes
Value at Risk (VAR) – “for a given portfolio, time horizon, and probability p,
the p VaR is defined as a threshold loss value, such that the probability that
the loss on the portfolio over the given time horizon exceeds this value is p”
– Wikipedia definition
2. Price Risk
Rt+1 = μt + σt εt+1
Where
μt is the expectation of the return Rt+1 conditional on information
available at day t
σt is the standard deviation of Rt+1 conditional on information
available at day t
εt+1 is a “shock” with a conditional mean of zero and a conditional
standard deviation of one
Generally speaking, actual price models are used for risk management
2.4. Jump-Diffusions
Our Model:
Note:
1.) This formulation for volatility rules out any sort of
structured dependence of the distribution of changes in
volatility on other variables such as the volatility in
related markets and overarching macro-economic factors, which
in real world application may be very relevant
2.) This model does allow the possibility of correlation between
the volatility shock z and the return shock ε. Negative correlation
implied a negatively skewed distribution of daily returns, and thus the VaR estimate
for a short position would be less than that of a long position of equal value
Two-State Example:
Consider a situation where there are two possible volatilities, νa and νb.
Let the following matrix represent the transitional probabilities of σt between
νa and νb :
The following figure illustrates an example using estimates inferred from oil
pricing (Duffie & Gray 1995):
Where alpha, gamma & kappa are constants, and gamma indicates the level of
volatility persistence. The closer gamma is to 1, the higher the level of
persistence. Except in cases of “explosive volatility,” we assume that
-1<gamma<1. If the shocks are independent to returns and volatility, the term
structure of conditional volatility is the following:
If the shocks are not independent to returns and volatility, the term structure
of conditional volatility can be calculated but that is beyond the scope of
this overview. Nonetheless, allowing this correlation is often necessary in
practical application.
2.5.3 Garch
Where alpha, beta, & gamma are positive constants. The gamma here is a stronger
persistence indicator than in the autoregressive model of 2.5.2 due to the
quadratic nature of the volatility term. Returning to crude oil, Duffie & Gray
(1995) estimated the following parameters (T-statistics in parenthesis):
Assuming the “non-explosivity condition,” i.e. delta = Beta + gamma < 1, the
steady-state volatility is the following:
It can be shown that the term structure of volatility for the GARCH model is
One major drawback of this model is related to the impact of persistence.
Because the term involving returns Rt is quadratic any sudden large loss or gain
coupled with a reasonably high persistence factor gamma will cause a
persistently high volatility forecast.
2.5.4 EGARCH
exponential GARCH:
With Beta & Gamma assumed to be diagonal, Duffy & Gray (1995) get the following
estimates for (a) heating oil & (b) crude oil using maximum likelihood
estimation over a bivariate GARCH model (T-statistics in parenthesis):
Note that the t-statistics in this model show great improvement upon the
estimates in the univariate GARCH model of section 2.5.3
For the plain-vanilla model, tail-fatness & volatility exhibit a flat term
structure. The term structure generally exhibited by tail-fatness & volatility
are dependent on the source of tail fatness.
1. Jumps
We can see that the term structure of kurtosis for these 3 jump-diffusion
models is continuously declining to that of a Normal Distribution, i.e. K
= 3. This follows from the central limit theorem.
Unlike Kurtosis, whose term structure is steadily decreasing, the standard
deviations to 0.01 critical values of the 3 jump-diffusion models first
increase and then slowly decrease to the standard 2.326 of a Normal
variable. This is due to the fact that since the “jump” is expected to occur
no more than 3 times a year in any of the models, the standard deviations
are relatively low for a time horizon of one day. However, as the time
horizon increases, the effect of the “jumps” become more poignant and reach
their respective peak for each model somewhere between 1 day & 100 days.
However, over larger time horizons, the effect of the “jumps” become more
and more negligible and the 3 jump-diffusion models tend toward normal.
2. Stochastic Volatility
For this section we will let the mean returns be constant, the “shocks” be
i.i.d., and the volatility stochastic. Due to the stochastic nature of the
volatility, it is theoretically possible for the term structure to take any
form.
The above figure represents the term structure of volatility for an
autoregressive model of stochastic volatility for the Hang Seng Index fitted
by Heynen & Kat (1993). The maximum-likelihood estimates in this model are
alpha = -5.4, gamma = 0.38, & kappa = 1.82. Line B represents the term
structure of stochastic volatility for an initial volatility at the mean of
the steady-state distribution. Line A & Line C represent the term structure
for an initial volatility of one standard deviation above & below the mean,
respectively. One can easily see how in this model, the term structure will
approach a common asymptote despite the different starting values.
Line A shows the complications that can arise when the initial volatility is
allowed a level of randomness. This, combined with the allowance for “jumps”
in the model, can cause problems related to bias & misspecification.
Nonetheless, it is a complication that can be necessary considering that
Jorion[1989] finds evidence for both jumps and stochastic volatility modeled
in GARCH form.
3. Mean Reversion
Let the volatility in our daily Returns model be constant to go along with
i.i.d. shocks and introduce mean reversion into the model. One possible way
is to let μt = α(R*-R-t-1) with alpha > 0 serves as a dampener in order to
center the return model around an asymptotic mean R*. In this model the term
structure of volatility is decreasing asymptotically to a positive value,
and the term structure of volatility is constant.
Where
Due to the fact that this formula is monotone increasing on σ, with the option
price Ct one can obtain a value for the volatility σ using the Black-Scholes
Implied Volatility Function:
Although the stochastic complexity of the Black Scholes formula prevents the
existence of an explicit formula for the above, an implied volatility can be
calculated to any desired accuracy using numerical techniques. In most markets,
option-implied volatility is more reliably accurate than any method utilizing
historic data.
2.7.3 Option-Implied Stochastic Volatility
Assume our model’s shocks are independent with respect to returns and
volatility. One can use the following slightly modified version of Black
Scholes to obtain the price of an option:
In certain cases, the day of the week, the season, or other seasonal
effects can influence the volatility. In the realm of energy products, the
demand for heating oil and gasoline depend upon winter and summer weather
patterns, respectively. Thus, their pricing models exhibit greater volatility
in the summer and winter months, respectively.
2.8 Skewness
skewness – “a measure of the degree to which positive deviations from the mean
are larger than negative deviations from the mean, as measured by the expected
third power of these deviations”
2.9 Correlations
One component not discussed in any further detail in this article but critical
to the real-world accurate estimation of price risk is the modeling of cross-
market correlations between the shocks of multiple markets.
Works Cited:
Duffie, D., & Pan, J. (1997). An Overview of Value at Risk. The Journal of
GIOVANNINI, A., & JORION, P. (1989). The Time Variation of Risk and Return in the
Foreign Exchange and Stock Markets. The Journal of Finance, 44(2), 307-325.
doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1989.tb05059.x
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Value_at_risk
Energy Price Risk, edited by Lou Pai and Peter Field, Risk Publications,
Note: the compiler of these notes claims no intellectual ownership of the ideas
presented here. All intellectual rights are relinquished to the original
authors. All images belong to the original authors Duffie & Pan.