Long Run and Short Run Cost Functions: Example of A Production Function in Which The Inputs Are Perfect Substitutes
Long Run and Short Run Cost Functions: Example of A Production Function in Which The Inputs Are Perfect Substitutes
In the long run, the firm can vary all its inputs. In the short run, some of these inputs are
fixed. Since the firm is constrained in the short run, and not constrained in the long run, the
long run cost TC(y) of producing any given output y is no greater than the short run cost
STC(y) of producing that output:
TC(y) STC(y) for all y.
Now consider the case in which in the short run exactly one of the firm's inputs is fixed. For
concreteness, suppose that the firm uses two inputs, and the amount of input 2 is fixed at k.
For many (but not all) production functions, there is some level of output, say y , such that the
0
firm would choose to use k units of input 2 to produce y , even if it were free to choose any
0
amount it wanted. In such a case, for this level of output the short run total cost when the firm
is constrained to use k units of input 2 is equal to the long run total cost: STC (y ) = TC(y ).
k 0 0
We generally assume that for any level at which input 2 is fixed, there is some level of output
for which that amount of input 2 is appropriate, so that for any value of k,
(There are production functions for which this relation is not true, however: see the example
of a production function in which the inputs are perfect substitutes.)
perfect substitutes. The long run total cost function for this production function is
given by
w 1
if w < w
1 2
y
TC(y,w ,w
1 if w =
2 1
wy
)= w =w 2
w 2
if w > w
1 2
y
Its short run total cost of production when the amount of input 2 is fixed at k is
STC (y)
k if y
wk 2
= k
w (y
1 k) + if y >
wk
2 k.
Note that in this case if w < w then there is no level of output for which short
1 2
run total cost is equal to the long run total cost. In this case the firm would like to
use only input 1 to produce any output, so if k > 0 there is no output for which
the short run total cost is equal to the long run total cost. The short and long run
cost functions in this case are shown in the following figure.
Example: a Cobb-Douglas production function
Consider the production function F (z , z ) = z z . The long run total cost
1 2 1
1/2
2
1/2
TC(y,w ,w ) = 2y(w w ) .
1 2 1 2
1/2
Its short run total cost of production when the amount of input 2 is fixed at k is
STC (y) =w y /k + w k.
k 1
2
2
figure.
For a total cost function with the typical shape, the following figure shows the relations
between STC and TC.
Examples of long run and short run cost functions
worker and one machine produce one unit of output). The long run total cost
function for this production function is given by
TC(y,w ,w ) = w y + w y = (w + w )y.
1 2 1 2 1 2
Its short run total cost of production when the amount of input 2 is fixed at k is
STC (y) w y +
k 1 if y
= wk 2 k
if y >
k.
perfect substitutes. The long run total cost function for this production function is
given by
w 1
if w < w
1 2
y
TC(y,w ,w
1 2if w = 1
wy
)= w =w 2
w 2
if w > w
1 2
y
Its short run total cost of production when the amount of input 2 is fixed at k is
STC (y)
k if y
wk 2
= k
w (y
1 k) + if y >
wk
2 k.
Note that in this case if w < w then there is no level of output for which short
1 2
run total cost is equal to the long run total cost. In this case the firm would like to
use only input 1 to produce any output, so if k > 0 there is no output for which
the short run total cost is equal to the long run total cost. The short and long run
cost functions in this case are shown in the following figure.
TC(y,w ,w ) = 2y(w w ) .
1 2 1 2
1/2
Its short run total cost of production when the amount of input 2 is fixed at k is
STC (y) =w y /k + w k.
k 1
2
2
figure.
Note:
• The SMC goes through the minimum of the SAC and the LMC goes through
the minimum of the LAC.
• When SAC = LAC we must have SMC = LMC (since slopes of total cost
functions are the same there).
In the case that the production function has CRTS, the LAC is horizontal, as in the
following figure.
The long run and the short run do not refer to a specific period of time such as 3 months or 5
years. The difference between the short run and the long run is the flexibility decision makers
have. The 2nd edition of Parkin and Bade's "Economics" gives an excellent distinction between the
two:
"The short run is a period of time in which the quantity of at least one input is fixed and the
quantities of the other inputs can be varied. The long run is a period of time in which the
quantities of all inputs can be varied.
There is no fixed time that can be marked on the calendar to separate the short run from the long
run. The short run and long run distinction varies from one industry to another." (239)
I find examples helpful, so we'll consider a hockey stick manufacturer. A company in that industry
will need the following to manufacture sticks:
Suppose the demand for hockey sticks has greatly increased, prompting our company to produce
more sticks. We should be able to order more raw materials with little delay, so we consider raw
materials to be a variable input. We'll need extra labor, but we can likely increase our labor supply
by running an extra shift and getting existing workers to work overtime, so this is also a variable
input. The equipment on the other hand, may not be a variable input. It may be time consuming
to implement the use of additional equipment. It depends how long it would take us to buy and
install the equipment and how long it would take us to train the workers to use it. Adding an extra
factory is certainly not something we could do in a short period of time, so this would be the fixed
input.
Using the definitions given at the beginning of the article, we see that the short run is the period in
which we can increase production by adding more raw materials and more labor. In the short run
we cannot add another factory, but in the long run all of our inputs are variable, including our
factory space.
The increase in demand for hockey sticks will have different implications in the short run and the
long run at the industry level. In the short run each of the firms will increase their labor supply and
raw materials to meet the added demand for hockey sticks. At first only existing firms will be likely
to capitalize on the increased demand as they will be the only ones who will have access to the
four inputs needed to make the sticks. However we know that in the long run the factor input is
variable as well. This means that existing firms can change the size and number of factories they
own and new firms can build or buy factories to produce hockey sticks. In the long run we will see
new firms enter the hockey stick market, while we will not in the short run because firms will not
be able to acquire all of the inputs they need.
Short Run: Some inputs variable, some fixed. New firms do not enter the industry, and existing
firms do not exit.
Long Run: All inputs variable, firms can enter and exit the market place.
Long-run is strictly defined as the time period long enough for the
firm to be able to vary the quantities of all its factors of production,
rather than just some of them. For example, suppose that a firm
uses labour, raw materials and machinery to make a particular
product. Labour is hired on a weekly contract; raw materials take
one month to arrive, from date of order, while plant and machinery
takes two years to design, order, construct and install. The long-run
for this firm is therefore two years, since over this time the firm can
vary all its factors of production. The implication of the definition is
that the long –run is not a fixed period of time for all the firms in all
industries, but rather varies with the characteristics of an industry’s
technology.