Tdrbpconf8d3 en
Tdrbpconf8d3 en
8/3
United Nations Conference Distr.: General
27 April 2015
on Trade and Development
Original: English
Executive summary
Competition policy aims to make markets work for consumers through its core
elements: enforcement and advocacy. Nevertheless, when pursuing better access to
products, measures against anticompetitive behaviour in the pharmaceutical sector may not
be the best starting point, in comparison with other areas of law. As a relatively
underdeveloped yet promising mechanism for doing so, competition policy should be given
greater prominence for its potential to complement efforts in this area. This report
addresses some of the main competition problems in the pharmaceutical industry today.
It gives examples from various jurisdictions on the benefits of competition enforcement for
consumers and recommends some measures to enhance competition advocacy in the
pharmaceutical industry.
GE.15-
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
Contents
Page
Introduction ................................................................................................................................... 3
I. Competition problems ................................................................................................................... 4
A. Competition concerns in the public sector ............................................................................ 4
B. Competition concerns in the private sector ........................................................................... 6
II. Case examples: How Competition enforcement benefits consumers ............................................ 8
A. Competition enforcement against horizontal agreements ..................................................... 9
B. Competition enforcement against vertical agreements ......................................................... 11
C. Competition enforcement against unilateral conduct ............................................................ 12
D. Merger review ....................................................................................................................... 13
III. The role of competition policy ...................................................................................................... 14
A. Striking a balance between the rights of inventors and consumers ....................................... 14
B. Cooperating with anti-corruption policies for good governance of public health
resources ............................................................................................................................... 16
C. Coherence between competition, consumer, and regulatory policies ................................... 17
IV. Issues for discussion ...................................................................................................................... 18
2
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
Introduction
1. The pharmaceutical industry plays an important role in improving global health care.
Three of the eight Millennium Development Goals call for specific health care
improvements by 2015. However, around two billion people worldwide have inadequate
access to essential medicines and vaccines, or none at all.
2. Disease and poverty are interdependent. People are often sick because they are poor.
They may become poorer because they are sick and sicker because they are poorer. Yet,
many of the illnesses affecting people living in poverty can be prevented, alleviated or
cured with a relatively small number of essential medicines if they are available at
affordable prices.
3. Limited public health services budgets and steadily increasing expenses slow
economic growth.1 Meanwhile, drug expenditures keep rising. In 2011, the total
pharmaceutical bill across countries of the Organization of Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD) was about $800 billion. In 2013, global pharmaceutical sales
reached an all-time high of approximately $980 billion and are expected to rise beyond
one trillion dollars by 2015.2
4. Competition is important because it compels industry to provide higher quality
goods and services at lower prices. In the pharmaceutical industry, competition can
motivate brand companies to create new and improved medicines and encourage generic
companies to offer less expensive alternatives.
5. On average, pharmaceutical spending accounted for 1.5 per cent of gross domestic
product (GDP), with about 0.8 per cent of GDP publicly financed, and the remainder, from
private sources.3 Competition policy can improve both consumer and government access to
affordable pharmaceuticals through two core elements: enforcement and advocacy.
6. Throughout much of the world, however, administrative regulation, rather than
competition policy, dominates efforts to afford consumers and governments adequate
access to affordable drugs.
7. Although strict administrative regulation has stabilized prices for certain drugs, it
has also deepened competition enforcement challenges in the private sector. Also,
competition advocacy contributes towards a more transparent, efficient and consumer-
friendly administrative regulation environment. Competition policy is important in both the
public and private sectors and should be given greater prominence to complement other
efforts in this area.
1
Federal Antimonopoly Service of Russia [the Russian Federation], 2013, Results of the Assessment
of Pharmaceuticals Affordability on Basis of the Analysis of Consumer Prices and Price Setting for
Pharmaceuticals in the Russian Federation (Federal subjects included) and on Comparable Markets of
other Countries, Comprising the CIS [Commonwealth of Independent States], European Union and
BRICS [Brazil, the Russian Federation, India, China and South Africa]. Available at
http://en.fas.gov.ru/netcat_files/
560/719/h_1687770528011495271836c96cbf82ec, accessed 29 September 2014.
2
Thomson Reuters, 2014, Thomson Reuters Annual Pharmaceutical Factbook projects industry’s sales
will reach $1 trillion in 2014, available at http://thomsonreuters.com/en/press-releases/2014/thomson-
reuters-annual-pharmaceutical-factbook-projects-industrys-sales-will-reach-1-trillion-in-2014.html,
accessed 27 April 2015.
3
OECD, 2013, Health at a Glance 2013: OECD Indicators, OECD Publishing, available at
http://www.oecd.org/els/health-systems/Health-at-a-Glance-2013.pdf, accessed 28 October 2014.
3
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
I. Competition problems
10. In general, the low elasticity of demand associated with in the pharmaceutical
industry can be attributed to the must-have nature of many drugs, owing to the lack of
alternatives and regulatory requirements on the range of the products that providers must
offer and insurers must cover. The supply of brand drugs is characterized by considerable
market power because of the presence of patents to reward the high investment in research
and development that brand drug companies maintain is necessary to bring new drugs to
market. Notwithstanding the rise of generic companies in emerging countries leading to
more robust competition, there has been no significant change in the ranking of the leading
pharmaceutical companies. This creates competition concerns, and prices continue to rise
owing to these market features.
Table 1
Top 10 pharmaceutical companies by revenue
4
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
pricing practices and controls vary across countries. Where the products in a therapeutic
class are close substitutes, the prices of the drugs in that class are often set equal to the
lowest price in that class. Where a drug has few close substitutes, it is also common to set
prices based on international price comparisons of equivalent drugs. Where a drug is
covered by the list of vital and essential drugs, 4 procedures for the establishment of
wholesale and retail trade markups and their maximum rate are strictly regulated. Some
countries also regulate the prices and services of pharmaceutical wholesalers to keep a
check on possible market manipulations. However, administrative regulation also can
create competition concerns.
12. First, rigid price regulation has stabilized the prices of certain drugs, but reduced the
availability of inexpensive alternatives to brand name drugs and increased the markups on
unregulated medicines, as the wholesalers and retailers have shifted their lost profit to
expensive unregulated drugs. For example, analyst agencies data for 2011 indicate that the
average prices of drugs used for medical purposes rose by 8.8 per cent, in contrast to
10.8 per cent for drugs not covered by the model list of essential medicines, and a decrease
of 3.3 per cent, for those drugs listed for medical use.5
13. Second, governments are notoriously inefficient buyers. 6 In some countries,
government representatives entrusted with power to determine prices in negotiation with
monopoly manufacturers might abuse that power for private gain, wasting public resources.
A lack of accountability and transparency during tender and negotiation can provide a
breeding ground for corruption, creating competition concerns. Corruption in public
procurement could create an uneven playing field that affects competition.
14. Third, in some public health distribution systems, physicians influence drug sales,
and patients are misled into purchasing more expensive medicines. Since only physicians
have the right to issue prescriptions, while patients have no choice in medication, the
practices of bribe and rebate – not price and quality – may determine which drugs are
chosen. In some countries, corruption-related anticompetitive practices directly increase the
price of medicines and restrict consumers’ access to effective and affordable medicine. In
India, for example, given the anticompetitive practices common to the health delivery
system, only 35 per cent per cent of Indians have access to essential medicines.7
Stakeholders in Tajikistan and Costa Rica contend that the lack of transparency contributes
to the siphoning of public resources into a physician’s private hospital or practices.8
4
Essential drugs, as defined by WHO, are “those that satisfy the health care needs of the majority of
the population; they should therefore be available at all times in adequate amounts and in the
appropriate dosage forms, and at a price that individuals and the community can afford” (resolution
WHA31.32). They are contained in the WHO Model List of Essential Medecines (eighteenth edition)
of April 2013.
5
See note 1.
6
J Clark, 2005, Competition advocacy: Challenges for developing countries, OECD Journal of
Competition Law and Policy, 6(4): 69–80, available at http://www.oecd-
ilibrary.org/docserver/download/2404051ec003.pdf?expires=1429540476&id=id&accname=ocid570
15274&checksum=F35EC94A2EDDF8D196B24D62017BF391, accessed 24 April 2015.
7
CUTS Center for Competition, Investment and Economic Regulation, 2008, Dealing with
anticompetitive practices in the Indian pharmaceuticals and the health delivery sector, Briefing Paper
No. 5, available at http://www.cuts-international.org/pdf/CCIER-3-2008.pdf, accessed 20 April 2015.
8
United Nations Development Programme, 2014, Building transparency, accountability and anti-
corruption into the post-2015 development framework, Discussion Paper, available at
http://workspace.unpan.org/sites/Internet/Documents/UNPAN93602.pdf, accessed 20 April 2015.
5
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
9
OECD, 2014, Summary record of the Discussion on competition and generic pharmaceuticals,
DAF/COMP/M (2014)2/ANN3, 6 November, available at http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/
publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=DAF/COMP/M%282014%292/ANN3/FINAL&doclanguage=en,
accessed 24 April 2015.
10
SM Flynn, 2014, Using Competition Law to Promote Access to Medicines,
https://www.wcl.american.edu/pijip/download.cfm?downloadfile=34080B0A-C32A-6A22-
22ED8491FC3EB62B, accessed 27 April 2015.
11
European Commission, 2008, Executive Summary of the Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry Report,
available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/sectors/pharmaceuticals/inquiry/communication_en.pdf,
accessed 20 April 2015.
6
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
21. The denser the patent cluster or divisional patent, the more difficult it will be for a
generic company to bring its generic version of the original pharmaceutical product to the
market. All generic manufacturers know that very few patents in that larger group will be
valid and infringed by the product they propose to make, but it is impossible to be certain
prior to launch that their product will not infringe and thus become the subject of an interim
injunction. That is to say, although the main patent protecting the product, for example the
basic substance patent, may have expired, the generic version may still infringe one of the
multiple patents surrounding the original pharmaceutical. This kind of patent application
strategy serves to secure an optimal competitive position for originator companies’ products
in the market by creating significant legal and commercial uncertainty of viable generic
entry to block competitors. Therefore, patent clusters and divisional patents seem to be
aimed at creating legal uncertainty for generic competitors; nevertheless, they may signify
an increase of incremental innovation. As for the enforcement efforts against this type of
patent strategy, the decision of Italy’s highest administrative court in the Pfizer case,
outlined below, represents the most current development on this topic.
22. In some cases, patent clusters and divisional patents might be used as indispensable
assets for originator companies to engage in patent litigation, which will create obstacles to
market entry of generics, namely by creating costs and using injunctions preventing the sale
of the generic product. While larger generic companies may have the financial resources to
undertake long and costly litigation, smaller companies may be more substantially affected
by increasing litigation costs. Interim injunctions prevent a small generic company from
selling its product, whereas the originator company will continue to collect revenues from
its product in the name of zero tolerance to any patent infringements.
23. Product hopping or product switching generally involves branded manufacturers
introducing new formulations of patented drugs shortly before the patent protection on the
older version of the drug expires, and then withdrawing the older drug that faces imminent
generic competition. This conduct often allegedly involves the steering of physicians or
pharmacists to “hop” demand over to the new branded drug formulation, which is protected
by a long-term patent. As generic drugs tend to rely on substitution rules that allow
pharmacies to swap the generic equivalent for a branded drug, when physicians stop writing
prescriptions for the older drug, this eliminates the possibility of substitution and thus the
possibility of meaningful generic competition. 12
24. Mergers and acquisitions have been widespread in recent years. In the first half of
2014, the top 10 transactions totalled nearly $90 billion.13 Historically, investment in
research and development to generate a flow of new chemical entities has been the business
model for pharmaceutical transnational corporations with headquarters in developed
countries. However, several changes have taken place. First, many companies are facing
soon-to-expire patents, comprising up to 70 per cent of some companies’ total sales.
Second, Indian, Chinese and Brazilian generic companies are growing rapidly, leading to a
highly global competitive environment. 14 These changes lead to the demise of the research
and development investment model, and a wave of mergers and acquisitions where large
research and development-based transnational corporations are buying generic companies
with potential new drug pipelines, such as Roche and Genentech, Sanofi Aventis and
Genzyme, and Daichi Sankyo and Ranbaxy. Most developing world generic markets are
12
GN Addy and E Douglas, 2014, Canada considers hopping on board with a product-hopping case,
Competition Policy International, Antitrust Chronicle Competition Policy, Spring 2014, Vol. 3, No. 2.
13
FiercePharma, 2014, Pharma’s top 10 M&A deals of 2014’s first half, 28 October, available at
http://www.fiercepharma.com/special-reports/pharmas-top-10-ma-deals-2014s-first-half, accessed
20 April 2015.
14
UNCTAD-International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development, 2011, The structural changes
in the global pharmaceutical marketplace and their possible implications for intellectual property,
Policy Brief No. 10, July.
7
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
called branded generic markets, as the medicines carry a local brand name instead of the
scientific generic name.
25. On the demand side, a significant role assumed by physicians in influencing drug
sales in some countries has resulted in patients being misled into purchasing more
expensive medicines. Activities involving inappropriate payments to hospitals and doctors
have concerned regulators for many years. The pharmaceuticals, through rebates, unduly
turned consumer (patient) benefits into the medical institution’s proceeds.
26. In distribution chains, vertical restraints in supply and sales agreements to prevent
retailers and wholesalers from obtaining supply from competitors are also fairly
widespread. The Fair Trade Commission of the Republic of Korea found that 55 per cent of
pharmaceutical supply and sales contract terms prevented buyers from dealing with
possible rival products and imposed sales quotas in that country. Some clauses on no-rival
product requirements were structured to outlast the contract itself. To address unfairness
and improve consumer welfare, the Fair Trade Commission codified new guidelines for fair
pharmaceutical transactions, which do not allow the following:
(a) Restrictions on research and development and production, as well as
prohibitions on dealing with rival products after contract termination;
(b) Automatic contract terminations upon failure to reach a minimum purchase
or sales quota;
(c) Unconditional transfers of technological innovations developed fully by a
buyer, and allowing only exclusive raw material purchase in exceptional cases for product
quality control. Moreover, horizontal agreements at the distribution level are also possible,
as shown by recent action taken by the Brazilian competition authority. 15
15
OECD, 2014, Competition issues in the distribution of pharmaceuticals: Contribution from the United
States, DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2014) 43, 10 February.
8
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
Table 2
Examples of competition legal action in the pharmaceutical industry
Pharmaceutical
Country and date of action Description of action Impact
products
9
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
29. In May 2006, the Competition Commission of Mexico requested information from
the Mexican Institute of Social Security (IMSS), the biggest health services provider in
Latin America, regarding its bidding procedures for acquiring medicines. The material
provided evinced the presence of collusion in the IMSS public procurement process.
The investigation focused on public bidding from 2003 to 2006 for two specific products,
human insulin and electrolytic solutions, and demonstrated constant communication
between participating firms, particularly across the dates nearing the bids. Consequently,
the Commission in 2010 fined six pharmaceutical companies 151.7 million pesos, a
decision that was supported by the Mexican judiciary. Increased competition benefited
consumers by average price falls: 68.1 per cent for human insulin and 12.1 per cent for
electrolytic solutions.16
30. Another example of enforcement against horizontal anticompetitive agreements can
be found in a Spanish boycott case. In 2007, Laboratorios DAVUR (DAVUR) filed a
complaint against four pharmacy associations, claiming a collective boycott. DAVUR
decided to lower the price of 12 of its generic pharmaceuticals to below the reference prices
set by the Health Ministry. Subsequently, several pharmacy associations made
recommendations to almost all pharmacies in Spain to stop stocking DAVUR medicines.
These associations noted that, since DAVUR’s lower prices could reduce the reference
prices of generic medicines as set by the Health Ministry and thus decrease the
associations’ future revenues, those associations recommended the restriction of DAVUR’s
products. As a result, many Spanish pharmacists stopped dealing with DAVUR and
impeded the entry of its products. During the investigation, DAVUR settled with the main
claimants and withdrew its complaint. Nevertheless, the investigation continued ex officio.
In March 2009, the Spanish competition authority resolved to declare the existence of an
infringement and imposed a total fine of €1 million on the associations. 17
31. The Actavis case in the United States and the Lundbeck case in the European Union
represent the most recent enforcement trends in unconventional pay-for-delay agreements.
Box 1. Pay-for-delay cases in the United States and the European Union
In the Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Actavis, then Watson Pharmaceuticals,
filed an abbreviated new drug application, seeking approval to market a generic drug
modelled on a patented synthetic testosterone, AndroGel. The owner of the patent, Solvay
Pharmaceuticals, filed suit against Actavis and others for patent infringement. In 2006, the
parties entered into a settlement whereby Solvay (the patent owner) agreed to pay Actavis
(the alleged infringer) $19 million to $30 million a year for nine years. Additionally,
Actavis agreed to delay entry into the market until 31 August 2015, about five years before
expiration of the patent. On 17 June 2013, the the United States Supreme Court held that
the rule of reason would apply to reverse payment settlements.
Following the Actavis case, the European Commission fined the Danish
pharmaceutical company Lundbeck €93.8 million for entering into reverse payment
settlements with several generic producers (Alpharma, Arrow, Merck KGaA/Generics
(United Kingdom) and Ranbaxy), which were also fined between €9.9 million and
€21.4 million each. This was the first time the Commission had fined companies on the
grounds that reverse payment settlements contravened European Union competition law.
16
Contribution from Mexico to the UNCTAD round table on the benefits of competition policy for
consumers, Intergovernmental Group of Experts on Competition Law and Policy, fourteenth session,
Geneva, 8–10 July 2014.
17
OECD, 2014, Competition issues in the distribution of pharmaceuticals: Contribution from Spain,
DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2014) 47, 10 February.
10
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
18
Administrative Process No. 08012.004365/2010-66.
19
See note 9.
11
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
approval from both companies before selling the product to any other party, in order to
eliminate competition. In 2011, the Commission fined the companies RMB 7 million.20
20
National Development and Reform Commission of China, 2011, available in Chinese only at
http://xwzx.ndrc.gov.cn/mtfy/dfmt/201112/t20111207_449580.html, accessed 20 April 2015.
21
See note 9.
22
Ibid.
12
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
Box 2. Italy: The Administrative Supreme Court confirms the Italian competition
authority’s decision against evergreening
In 2012, the Italian competition authority sanctioned the multinational
pharmaceutical group Pfizer, imposing a fine of €10,677,706. Pfizer’s complex strategy
consisted of several types of conduct, all proved and reasonably considered punishable by
the competition authority. They included the following:
• The filing of divisional patent applications and the subsequent request of a
Supplementary Protection Certificate, in order to extend the Italian patent
protection many years after filing the main patent application, which still
contained claims related to Latanoprost, and for which there was an absence
of a commercial exploitation of a new product;
• Patent-related Court litigations hindering market entry of generic companies
(shame litigation); (c) actions aimed at preventing the Italian Medicines
Agency from granting geneticists marketing authorizations; and
(d) application for a further patent protection extension through paediatric
experimentation. All of these complex conducts, although individually and
abstractly legitimate, could correctly be defined as abuse of rights and
specifically anticompetitive. Pfizer refused to accept the penalty and brought
administrative litigation to the Regional Administrative Court of Lazio,
where the decision of the Competition Authority was annulled, as the Court
held that Pfizer only tried to protect its legitimate interests, through types of
conduct deemed lawful under patent law.
Following the Court’s decision, the Competition Authority lodged an appeal before
the Council of State, the highest administrative court on competition, against the decision
of the Regional Administrative Court. The judge finished the reasoning of abuse by holding
that such abuse of a dominant position belongs to the broader category of abuse of right.
The doctrine of the abuse of rights includes the existence of a right; the possibility to
effectively use such a right in different manners; the exercise of the right in a reprehensible
manner, although formally legitimate; and the resulting unjustifiable disproportion between
the benefit of the right’s owner and the harm caused to the counterparty.
In other words, the abuse of rights does not suppose a formal infringement of laws,
but the distorted exercise of the granted rights for purposes different from those intended by
the legislator. Therefore, besides the legitimate nature of the right, the purpose to grant such
legal right by the legislator shall be taken into account with more proportion when
weighing the pros and cons in making a decision on the abuse of intellectual property
rights. If the existence and exercise of industrial property rights are not of themselves
incompatible with competition law, they are not immune from the application of
competition law.
Source: C D’Amore, 2014, The administrative supreme court confirms the ICA’s [Italian
Competition Authority’s] decision to condemn Pfizer for abuse of dominant position aimed at
delaying the market entry of generic pharmaceutical companies, Italian Antitrust Review, 1:77–81.
D. Merger review
41. In the United States, some commentators have perceived tension between the
Affordable Care Act and the antitrust laws in merger investigations since 2014. Partly due
to the Act, which encourages provider integration, the health care sector has seen a
significant consolidation. The Federal Trade Commission considers that the antitrust laws
and the Act are compatible and that the goals of the latter are consistent with those of
13
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
competition policy. The Act seeks to promote higher quality care at lower cost through
increased coordination and clinical integration. The Commission remains committed to its
position that health care merger enforcement will continue to rely on traditional analytical
approaches. In other words, it challenges the anticompetitive consolidation of hospitals or
providers, but does not block collaborations where the evidence shows a transaction will
result in lower costs, improved care and a net benefit to consumers.
42. In the pharmaceutical sector, merger enforcement has remained largely consistent in
recent years. The Federal Trade Commission challenged the acquisition of Agila Specialties
Global PteLtd and Agila Specialties Pvt Ltd. by Mylan, Inc. on 26 September 2013. It also
adopted a final order in its challenge to the acquisition of Actavis, Inc. by Watson
Pharmaceuticals on 14 December 2012. In both cases, the Commission required divestitures
of various drugs to generic manufacturers based on its practice of defining relevant markets
based on particular drugs, as opposed to courses of treatment for particular conditions.
The Commission has been active in enforcement against 19 mergers in the branded and
generic pharmaceutical sectors in the last five fiscal years.23
23
See note 17.
24
See note 6.
25
Ibid.
14
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
opportunity to recoup investment costs and provide incentives for continued innovation. 26
This, the industry argues, makes important contributions to meeting patients’ interests.27
46. In principle, generic companies produce and market an equivalent version of the
original medicine once patent protection of that medicine has expired, inevitably resulting
in a significant decline in price and market share of the original product. In the United
States, the average price of generic drugs can be as much as 86 per cent less than that of
their brand-name counterparts. In this context, competition concerns may arise when
originator companies use their intellectual property rights to restrict or delay the market
entry of generic medications.
47. The existence of a conflict between the rights of inventors and consumers depends
on the balance between exclusiveness and public access.
48. Developed countries provide adequate protection to patent holders where domestic
medicine manufacturing industries are competitive with proven invention capability, in
order to maintain industry competitiveness in the global value chain.
49. In 2002, a decision by WTO members approved the delay of patent protection for
least developed countries until 2021. Based on the weak invention capability of local drug
makers, reverse engineering is allowed in order to encourage generic medication
production.
50. For developing countries with pharmaceutical industries that have limited ability to
make inventions, competition enforcement against generic pathway-related abuse is an
important tool in promoting free access to health technologies. Therefore, where there is a
conflict between competition and intellectual property policies, developing countries are
inclined towards competition rather than exclusiveness. However, as the invention
capability of domestic drug makers grows, a new balance will be needed.
51. Aside from the use of competition enforcement against abuse of dominance by
originator companies, a toolbox has been designed for developing countries to shape the
broad scope of exclusive rights before a patent is issued (pre-grant) and after a patent has
been granted (post-grant), and thus ensure the accessibility of generic medications, This can
be found in an UNCTAD reference guide for developing countries to use intellectual
property rights to stimulate pharmaceutical production.28
52. Pre-grant flexibilities are a proactive tool that can be used by a Government to
design and enforce intellectual property laws, such as employing a stricter standard of
patentability criteria and patentable subject matter. In this context, competition advocacy is
a useful tool for States to address competition concerns within existing patent systems and
enact reforms not covered by the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights.
53. In 2014, South Africa began taking steps to achieve patent reform that would
improve access to medicines and thereby strengthen the existing criteria for patentability.
The current system allows pharmaceutical companies to obtain multiple patents on the
same drug, even for inventions that do not fall under the country’s definition of innovation.
At present, the Competition and Consumer Policies branch of UNCTAD is assisting
developing countries in striking a balance between intellectual property and competition
26
See note 11.
27
Ibid.
28
UNCTAD, 2011, Using Intellectual Property Rights to Stimulate Pharmaceutical Production in
Developing Countries: A Reference Guide, New York and Geneva, United Nations publication,
available at http://unctad.org/en/pages/PublicationArchive.aspx?publicationid=437, accessed 20 April
2015.
15
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
policy by promoting the coordination between relevant authorities through joint capacity-
building. This work started in October 2014 with projects with the Indonesian Government.
54. In Canada, the Competition Bureau may also intervene in Federal and Superior
Court cases when it believes it is important to bring a competition perspective to
proceedings that will not be brought by the parties. In other proceedings, when the Bureau
believes that intellectual property rights could potentially be defined, strengthened or
extended inappropriately, the Bureau may intervene to make representations concerning the
scope of protection that should be accorded to intellectual property.
29
OECD, 2010, Round table on collusion and corruption in public procurement, DAF/COMP/GF
(2010) 6, 15 October.
30
OECD, 2014, Fighting corruption and promoting competition: Contribution from Mexico,
DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2014) 50, 13 February.
16
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
systems. In some countries, physicians take on a significant role in influencing drug sales;
as a result, patients are being misled into purchasing more expensive medicines. Since in
some United Nations Member States commercial bribery is prohibited by competition law,
competition policy can directly address corruption in the interest of consumers.
58. In 2011, the Fair Trade Commission of the Republic of Korea imposed corrective
orders and surcharges of 11 billion won against six drug manufacturers for offering
kickbacks. They repeatedly provided doctors, clinics and hospitals with economic
incentives, through indirect means, to increase the prescription of their drugs. Such means
included organizing seminars or conferences to offer free dinners, golf outings, and lecture
and consultancy fees, or granting cash in the form of so-called post-market surveillance.
Therefore, the pharmaceutical companies, through rebates, unduly turned consumer
(patient) benefits into the medical institution’s proceeds.
59. Similarly, in September 2014, the National Development and Reform Commission
of China fined GlaxoSmithKline $490 million for bribery towards hospitals and doctors.
Moreover, the Court issued a three-year suspended prison sentence to the former head of
the company.
60. Sound policies and laws foster high ethical standards in both public and civil
services. In addition to achievements of enforcement against specific restrictive business
practices and advocacy for more efficient public procurement systems, competition policy
can make further contributions to improved governance.
31
See note 15.
17
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
65. In Chile, an agreement signed between the National Consumer Service, the health
authority and the association of private clinics provides an example of a pro-competitive
consumer policy intervention. The competition authority observed that patients were only
provided with estimates of total costs, and price comparisons of different items included
under treatment options were not possible, thereby leading to ex-post abusive billing by
clinics. The competition authority conducted a market investigation and submitted its
findings to the health authority, which took action. To address this market failure, the
agreement requires clinics to inform patients of charges for medical services prior to
treatment and ensures that price comparisons can be made by patients for different items.
This case demonstrates the complementary nature of competition and consumer policies
and the role of cooperation between relevant authorities in identifying appropriate remedies
to address market failures in favour of consumers.32
32
TD/B/C.I/CLP/27.
18
TD/RBP/CONF.8/3
agreements? Are there concerns that these agreements may reduce inter and intra brand
competition? Are wholesalers vertically integrated with retailers and/or manufacturers? Are
there concerns that vertical integration may reduce inter and intra brand competition?
(e) How can the objective of ensuring an adequate and affordable supply of
drugs be better achieved by using competition advocacy?
19