0% found this document useful (0 votes)
28 views13 pages

MPRA Paper 75241

This document summarizes a research paper that examines the effects of the black market exchange rate on demand for money in Algeria. It begins with an introduction that provides background on money demand functions and the inclusion of exchange rates as a determinant. It notes that in developing countries with foreign exchange controls, there are often both official and black market exchange rates. The document then reviews literature on the role of black market exchange rates in money demand. Finally, it previews the methodology and empirical results of examining the impact of Algeria's black market exchange rate on money demand.

Uploaded by

Karthik Keyan
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
28 views13 pages

MPRA Paper 75241

This document summarizes a research paper that examines the effects of the black market exchange rate on demand for money in Algeria. It begins with an introduction that provides background on money demand functions and the inclusion of exchange rates as a determinant. It notes that in developing countries with foreign exchange controls, there are often both official and black market exchange rates. The document then reviews literature on the role of black market exchange rates in money demand. Finally, it previews the methodology and empirical results of examining the impact of Algeria's black market exchange rate on money demand.

Uploaded by

Karthik Keyan
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 13

M PRA

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

The Black Market Exchange Rate and


Demand for Money in Algeria

Abdelnacer Bouteldja and Abdelhak Benamar and Samir


Maliki

University of Tlemcen

November 2013

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/75280/
MPRA Paper No. 75280, posted 29 November 2016 13:23 UTC
International Journal of Arts and Commerce Vol. 2 No. 10 November, 2013

The Black Market Exchange Rate and Demand for Money in Algeria

Bouteldja Abdelnacer1,
Faculty of Economic Sciences,
University of Tlemcen,
Email : bouteldja_nacer@yahoo.fr

Benameur Abdelhak
Faculty of Economic Sciences,
University of Tlemcen,
Email : benamarabdelhak@yahoo.fr

Samir Maliki
Faculty of Economic Sciences,
University of Tlemcen,
Email: maliki.samir@gmail.com

Abstract:
The aim of this paper is to examine empirically the effects of black market exchange rate on the demand for
money in Algeria where due to government restrictions and controls on foreign exchange, two exchange
rates (official and black) coexist and operate simultaneously. The discrepancy between the two rates has
intensified since the adoption of the (S.A.P) in 1994. Using quarterly data for the 1974-2005 and an ARDL
approach combined with CUSUM and CUSUMSQ, our results provide further evidence in favor to the
inclusion of black market exchange rate rather than official rate issue.

Keywords: Money demand; Black market exchange rate; ARDL Bounds testing approach

1. Introduction
The demand for money is one of the hot topics that have attracted the most attention in the literature both for
developed and developing countries. According to Goldfeld (1994), a well-specified money demand
function is very crucial for the conduct of a successful monetary policy. The idea of including the exchange
rate in the demand for money function as another important determinant, though not tested empirically, was
first introduced by Robert mundell (1963). Subsequently, many studies attempted to examine such link
empirically, ( see, for example, Arrango and Nadiri, 1981 ; Domowitz and Elbadawi,1987 ; Arize, 1989 ;

1 Corresponding author : Bouteldja Abdelnace, Faculty of Economic Sciences,University of Tlemcen,

email : bouteldja_nacer@yahoo.fr
71
International Journal of Arts and Commerce ISSN 1929-7106 www.ijac.org.uk

Bahmani-Oskooee and Pourheydrian, 1990 ; McNown and Wallace, 1992 ; Hassan, 1992 ; Arize and
shwiff, 1993 ; Chowdhury, 1997 ; and Pozo and Wheeler, 2000 ).
The general consensus in the literature is that in developed countries, nominal exchange rate represents a
suitable cost of holding money where as in developing countries, due to lack of well developed financial
markets, the cost of holding money is often proxied by the expected rate of inflation. Therefore, the choices
available for asset holders in developing countries are limited to mostly money and goods. Also, investors
in these Countries, are constrained to invest in bank deposits and bank bonds, the interest on which are not
market determined, they are fixed by the countries’ monetary authorities for extended time period (
wong,1977 ; Hassan, 1992 ).
In addition, some of the above mentioned authors investigated the impact of foreign interest rates and
expected domestic currency depreciation on the domestic demand for money in developing countries. They
conclude that, since many of these countries are small, open economies, the most likely alternatives to
holding domestic money for individuals are domestic goods and foreign currencies. Thus, the official
exchange rates in small open economies are more of an exception than a rule. The inclusion of exchange rate
in the demand for money equation issue in developing countries was not well supported by empirical
evidence. Different studies yielded mixed and country – specific results. Such differences in findings may
thus be due to either a misspecification of the money demand equation; the improper use of a proxy for the
foreign exchange rate, the estimation method, or both. Little attention has been paid to analyze the impact
of the black market exchange rate on the long-run demand for money in developing countries that have
black market activities for their currencies (for an exception, see Hassan et al., 1995; Bahmani-Oskooee,
1996; Arize and Shwiff, 1998, Tabesh, 2000, Hafez and Afzal (2003) and Bahmani- Oskooee and Altin
Tanku 2006).
A unique feature of the exchange rate regimes in any developing country with foreign exchange controls is
the coexistence of a parallel or black market along with the official market for foreign exchange. The official
exchange rate is fixed by the monetary authorities, whereas the black market exchange rate is a market
determined rate. The two rates operate simultaneously, often with substantial discrepancies between them.
Thus, individuals in these countries tend to alter their wealth portfolios by substituting foreign money for
domestic money whenever they expect foreign exchange rate depreciation. This adjustment takes place
mostly in the black market.
The main purpose of this work is to test empirically the effects of the black market exchange rate on the
demand for money in Algeria thereby contributing to the existing literature on the role of black market
exchange rate.
The impact of the black market exchange rate on the demand for money in Algeria is worth investigating for
several reasons: First, compared with other countries, literature on the demand for money in Algeria is rather
scarce. Second, the area of the black market exchange rate in Algeria is unexplored, so, no study on the
effects of the black market exchange rate on the demand for money in Algeria has published yet. Third,
there is a growing need to a well-specified money demand equation in Algeria; particularly in its transition
from a central-planning economy to a market- based one. The choice of the appropriate rate to fit the
demand for money function is extremely important to avoid parameter estimates biasdness for the demand
for money. As far as policy makers are concerned, a well defined money demand function will help in
designing appropriate monetary policy actions and researchers in carrying out further research. Finally, the
statistics about black market exchange rate in Algeria bring out an active black market for currencies. The
gap between the official exchange rate of the Algerian dinar against the euro and that observed on the black
market has widened. The difference amounts today to 40% or even 45%. The foregoing discussion reveals
the importance of black market exchange rate as an important determinant of the demand for money in
Algeria. Given this introduction, the rest of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the
72
International Journal of Arts and Commerce Vol. 2 No. 10 November, 2013

literature on black market exchange rate. Section 3 describes the data, methodology and presents the
empirical results. Section 4 summarises the main findings, provides an economic interpretation and some
policy recommendations.

2. Literature Review
This section reviews the pertinent literature that deals with the black market exchange rate and the demand
for money in developing countries. Studies that have considered the effects of black market exchange rate
issue though are few; most of them reveal the importance of black market exchange rate as an essential
determinant for the demand for money.
Blejer (1978 ) examined the effects of the black market exchange rate and its expectations on the domestic
demand for money in three Latin- American countries namely Brazil, Chile, and Colombia in which foreign-
exchange control where in force during the 1950- 1973 period. His research suggested that a depreciation in
the black market exchange rate led to a decrease in the domestic money demand. He attributed these results
to portfolio rebalancing by individuals. According to Blejer’s results, an omission of the proxy for expected
currency depreciation from the demand for money, leads to overestimation of the variations in the demand
for money because of changes in the expected rate of domestic inflation. He concluded that in nations where
a substantial discrepancy develops between the official and the black market exchange rate, the expected
black market rate could be the major determinant of domestic demand for money.
Hassan (1992) examined the role of the credit constraint, foreign interest rates, currency depreciation, the
domestic inflation rate, and domestic income in the demand for money in Bangladesh. Using quarterly data
from 1974:1 to 1989:4, he found, as is the case in many countries, that real income and expected rate of
inflation are significant determinants of the demand for money in Bangladesh. As concerns foreign interest
rates and currency depreciation, they did not play any major role in explaining the demand for money in
Bangladesh. The complete absence of any relationship between money demand and currency depreciation
may be attributed to the way exchange rate depreciation was measured (calculation of currency depreciation
would rather be made from black market currency rates instead of official exchange rate).
Hassan and Suryadi (1993) investigated empirically the impact of foreign interest rates, domestic rate of
depreciation, and the credit constraint on the demand for money in Indonesia. Significance was found only
for expected currency depreciation.
Following Blejer (1978), Hassan (1995) studied the demand for money in Nigeria using quarterly data for
the period 1976-1988. Using conventional regression analysis like Blejer, Hassan’s findings confirmed
Blejer’s results that an expected black market exchange rate depreciation has a significant negative effect on
domestic demand for money ( a depreciation in the in the black market exchange rate leads to a decrease in
demand for money). He suggested that the black market exchange rate must be taken into account as an
important element by monetary policy.
Bahmani- Oskooee (1996) investigated the determinants of the demand for money in Iran using annual data
over the period 1959-1990. He estimated demand for broad money (M2) by applying the Johansen and
Juselius technique of cointegration and exclusion tests. According to him, the long-run demand for money
(M2) in Iran includes real income, the inflation rate, and the black market exchange rate. Two versions of
(M2) were estimated in Bahmani- Oskooee (1996), one with official exchange rate and another with black
market exchange rate. His results showed better performance with the black than the official rate. Bahmani-
Oskooee’s conclusion was that “in the countries where there is a black market for currencies, it is the black
market exchange rate and not the official exchange rate that should enter into the money demand equation”.
The relevance of the black market exchange rate in the money demand function in a developing countries
has also been stressed by the study of Arize and Shwiff (1998). Undertaking a similar analysis to that of
Bahmani- Oskooee (1996), they used annual data for the period 1951-1990 to estimate a money demand
73
International Journal of Arts and Commerce ISSN 1929-7106 www.ijac.org.uk

function for 25 developing countries namely India, Korea, Malaysia, Myanmar, Pakistan, the Philippines,
Taiwan, Thailand, Egypt, Ghana, Morocco, Tunisia, Argentina, Brazil, Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Costa
Rica, Ecuador, El Salvador, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela. Their results provide
evidence that the elasticities for real income and the official rate in the second function are generally larger
than those of the first function (which includes black market exchange rate). They interpreted this result as
evidence against the use of the official exchange rate variable as the relevant exchange rate variable in the
money demand function of these countries.
Tabesh (2000) explored the impact of the black market exchange rate expectations on the demand for money
in Iran using annual data for the period 1959-1994. In the post-revolution era, Iran has imposed a great deal
of restriction on the exchange market. The restrictions were so severe that in the period 1979-89, the nation
was basically a closed economy. However, as the exchange market restrictions intensified, an active
underground exchange market emerged in which key currencies in general and the U.S. dollar in particular,
was exchanged several-fold higher than the official rate. The findings suggested that in the sample period
1959-94, demand for real cash balances had been significantly affected by the expected black market
exchange rate. Further, the results of a cointegration test provided ample evidence that the expected
appreciation/depreciation in the black market exchange rate, real income, and the rate of inflation jointly
determine the demand for real (M2) money in Iran.
Following Bahmani- Oskooee (1996 ), Hafez and Afzal ( 2003) examined empirically the impact of black
market exchange rate on the demand for money in Pakistan .Using quarterly data over the period 1972-2000,
the same money demand equation proposed by Bahmani- Oskooee (1996 ) was estimated. Hafez and Afzal (
2003) however, employed an ARDL approach combined with CUSUM and CUSUMQ tests. Their results
showed that M2 was cointegrated with income, inflation rate and the black market exchange rate, moreover,
the estimation relation was also stable.
Bahmani- Oskooee and Altin Tanku (2006) estimated a money demand equation similar to Bahmani-
Oskooee (1996 ) for 25 LDC, namely, Algeria, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Costa Rica, Egypt, Ethiopia, India,
Indonesia, Jordan, Kenya, Malaysia, Malawi, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Paraguay,
Philippine, S-Africa, Sri Lanka , Suriname ,Syria ,Thailand and Turkey. Using an ARDL approach, they
were unable to generalize the conclusion that the black market exchange rate and not the official rate
belongs to the demand for money.

3. Data, Methodology and Results


The demand for money is of a paramount importance in macroeconomic analysis. Thus, a well defined
money demand equation is very crucial for conducting an appropriate monetary policy. The general
consensus in the literature on the demand for money is that a demand for money equation should contain a
scale variable to the level of transactions in the economy and a variable representing the opportunity cost of
holding money. Furthermore, to account for economic openness, another variable reflecting the relative
returns of foreign money vis-à-vis domestic money should be included in the demand for money equation.
This reflects the impact of currency depreciation on domestic money demand. Also as it is well accepted in
the literature, in developing countries, due to lack of well developed financial markets, interest rate is not a
suitable opportunity cost variable of holding money. This rate has often been proxied by the rate of inflation.
In a country like Algeria, inflation rate is an appropriate measure for opportunity cost for the following
reasons: First, financial markets are not well developed. Second, the interest rate is set by the monetary
authority and remains fixed for long periods. Finally, real assets are more attractive than financial assets.
Indeed most Algerians speculate in land, housing or even in durable commodities markets.

74
International Journal of Arts and Commerce Vol. 2 No. 10 November, 2013

3.1 A profile of black market for currencies in Algeria


In less developed countries, government regulation and controls, particularly on foreign exchange, lead to
black markets for currencies. Exchange controls in Algeria, though substantially reduced through the
adoption of the structural adjustment program (S.A.P), still have their effects. This can be seen clearly from
the volume of transactions carried out through the black market.
Supply of funds in this market generally comes from emigrants in France, retirement pensions and other
pensions paid in foreign currency and tourist industry while demand originates mainly from individuals
wishing to open bank accounts in foreign currency for visas purposes. As a result, a large part of foreign
currency liquidity flowing through the black market is regularly held with banks in foreign currency
accounts form. This is a positive aspect because it gives the banking system the opportunity to channel some
Algerian foreign currency resources available from emigrants, who for obvious reasons prefer the informal
market channel rather than the formal sector.
Another significant portion of the currency however, flows on the parallel market, and is difficult to assess,
goes to the benefit of importers of goods and services. These are a fringe engaged in importing prohibited
goods or counterfeit, which generally strengthens the informal sector.
Finally, the last part of the foreign exchange resources available to the informal sector, takes the form of
capital flight. Indeed, many Algerians invest heavily in activities such as restaurants, hotels, services, or
property outright in some countries such as France, Spain and Tunisia.
Two main phases can be distinguished in the history of black market for foreign currency in Algeria. The
first one dates back to the seventies and a large part of the eighties, characterized by a strict exchange
controls, shortages of all kinds and a total absence of effective and efficient banking system. The second and
most crucial stage began with the adoption of the structural adjustment program in Algeria in 1994. The new
procedures such as the liberalization of the national economy, the significant change in the liberalization of
the convertibility of the dinar that Algeria has undertaken since then were justified as essential for economic
development, trade facilitation and foreign investment encouragement. Given the above realities, the black
market for currencies in Algeria has taken new dimensions, and therefore deserves more attention.

3.2 The Model:


Following Bahmani- Oskooee (1996), the money demand equation which will be tested in this paper takes
the following form:
(1)
Where;
Mt is the desired holdings of real money balances (M1 and M2); M1 consists of currency in circulation and
demand deposits in scheduled banks. M2 consists of M1 plus quasi money.
Yt is the real GDP; Pt is the consumer price index; EXt is the exchange rate defined as the number of
Algerian dinars per U.S dollar; is the stochastic disturbance term. The inflation rate is measured by
= - .
Two alternatives versions of equation (1) are subject to empirical tests; one with official exchange rate and
the other with black market exchange rate.
According to macroeconomic theory, the money demand is assumed to be an increasing function of real
income (i.e., real GDP), thus, an estimate of is expected to be positive. Estimate of the inflation rate is
expected to be negative. As regards the estimate of it could be positive or negative depending on the
prevailing effect (the substitution effect or the wealth effect)

75
International Journal of Arts and Commerce ISSN 1929-7106 www.ijac.org.uk

3.3 The data


Quarterly data over the period 1974Q1 – 2003Q3 are collected from the international Financial Statistics
(IFS) by the IMF. Data on black market exchange rate are collected from other source2.
3.4 The ARDL Estimation Technique
Equation (1) above, will be estimated using a cointegration ARDL bounds testing approach developed by
Pesaran (1997), Pesaran and Shin (1999) and Pesaran et al. (2001). This method has several advantages over
conventional methods such as cointegration of Engle and Granger (1987), Johansen (1988) and Johansen
and Juselius (1990). First, the ARDL procedure does not require that the series should be integrated of the
same order3 (it can be used for stationary variables and / or integrated of order 1 and / or fractional
integration). We note in this context that this procedure cannot be applied to variables with order of
integration superior or equal two. Secondly, this procedure has good small sample properties as compared to
alternative approaches. In this context, we note that Narayan (2005) has provided critical values for sample
sizes ranging from 30 to 80 observations. Third, this procedure allows variables to have different numbers of
delay, and provide unbiased long- run estimates with a valid t-statistic even in the case of endogeneity of
regressors (Harris and Sollis, 2003). Fourth, unlike conventional methods of cointegration that use a system
of equations for estimating long-term relationships, this procedure uses a single equation in the reduced
form.
The main objective of this study is to estimate the long –run income, inflation, and exchange rates (black or
official) elasticities of M1 and M2 monetary agregates and examine their stability. However, this will not be
sufficient. Laidler (1993) as well as many other authors, point out the importance of the short-run adjustment
process. According to them, the short-run modeling of money demand could be a potential source of
instability. Thus, incorporating the short –run dynamics into equation (1) leads to an error correction model
of the ARDL form following Pesaran et al. (2001):

(2)
With the operator ∆ the first difference and εt is a white noise representing the error term. The number of
delay for each variable is determined using criteria such as Ackaik (AIC), and SCHWARZ (SBC).
The cointegration bounds testing approach is based on the F statistic or Wald statistic. According to Pesaran
et al. (2001), the asymptotic distribution of F is non-standard under the null hypothesis of the absence of
long-term relationships between variables, and this regardless of their order of integration if it is (I (0) or I
(1)). Based on equation (2), the null hypothesis is , while the alternative
hypothesis (existence of cointegration relations) is . To perform the test,
Pesaran et al. (2001) provide two sets of critical values, upper and lower. The first (upper) when all variables
are integrated of order one (I (1)) and second (lower) when all variables are stationary (I (0)). These two sets
of critical values provide a band covering all possible classifications of variables, whether purely I (0),
purely I (1) or mutually cointegrated. If the F statistic exceeds the upper band, then the null hypothesis is
rejected, then there are cointegration relationships between variables. In case the F-statistic lies between the
two bands, while the cointegration test is conclusive (in this case it is necessary to know the order of
integration of each variable). And in the case when the F statistic is less than at the bottom band, the null
hypothesis can be rejected; therefore there is no cointegration relationship.

2
Data on black market exchange rate for the same period are collected from http://www.globalfinancialdata.com
3
This advantage is very important when testing variables with different order of integration.
76
International Journal of Arts and Commerce Vol. 2 No. 10 November, 2013

3.5 The Results


The cointegration ARDL Bounds testing approach requires that the series should have an integration order
less than two. Therefore, it is essential to ensure that the order of integration of the variables in the work in
hand is less than two. The results of PP test of stationarity are
presented in Table (1).
Table (1): Stationarity test results

Log(GDP) Log(M1) Log(M2) Log(CPI) Log(OEX) Log(BEX)


2.7055 -3.0458 -2.0767 -0.8723 -1.8749 -1.2463
Level
[0.9983] [0.1242] [0.5533] [0.9550] [0.6616] [0.8959]
-22.5723* -10.6560* -9.9522* -11.6035* -8.0279* -9.9348*
1st
[0.0000] [0.0000] [0.0000] [0.0000] [0.0000] [0.0000]
difference

*denotes rejection of null hypothesis. Values between brackets are probabilities

According to these results, all variables are integrated of order one (I (1)). As far as the long-term
relationship between monetary aggregates (M1 and M2), income, inflation rate and exchange rates (official
and black) is concerned, the Akaike and Schwarz criterion is used to determine the number of delays for
each variable, which will allow us to estimate the optimal ARDL. We then calculate the F statistic and
compare it with the critical values of Pesaran et al. (2001). The results of cointegration test are presented in
Table (2).
Table (2): Results of F-test for cointegration
OEX BEX
M1 7.9698 8.534
M2 0.7027 0.8034

At 10% level of significance. Peasaran et al (2001)


critical values are : upper bound 3.73, lower bound 2.62
From Table2, it appears that there is no cointegration relationship between M2 and other variables.
However, when the monetary aggregate M1 is used, a cointegration relationship exists regardless of which
exchange rate is used. Such results indicate that M1 is a better monetary aggregate in terms of formulating
monetary policy in Algeria.
Table 3 and Table 4 below represent short and long run estimation results respectively. Table 3 represents
the coefficients estimates of lagged first differenced variables in the ARDL model.
Table 3: Short- run coefficient estimates
OEX BEX
∆ Ln M1 -0.710821 (0.03851) -0.675014 (0.04108)
∆ Ln M1(-1) 0.303854 (0.037069) 0.3384 (0.04034)
∆ Ln GDP 0.0119629 (0.003456) 0.014957 (0.003498)
∆ Ln CPI -0.184606 (0.039247) -0.210622 (0.0415)
∆ LnEX 0.005011 (0.02479) -0.065 (0.01615)
∆ Ln EX(-1) 0.011360 (0.024286) -0.125 (0.01604)

The short run coefficients show the dynamic adjustment of all variables. Results in Table 3 indicate that in
the short-run, both exchange rates have a significant effect on the demand for money in Algeria.

77
International Journal of Arts and Commerce ISSN 1929-7106 www.ijac.org.uk

Table 4: Long- run coefficients:


OEX BEX
Constant 0.08119 (0.0227) 0.1125 (0.022904)
Ln GDP 0.008449 (0.009061) 0.014361 (0.008517)
Ln CPI -0.038427 (0.021768) -0.039044 (0.01800)
LN EX 0.02962 (0.01256) -0.03904 (0.0126674)
EC (-1) -0.2623 (0.01225) -0.1831 (0.009544)
R squared 0.999392 0.99939
Adjusted R squared 0.999371 0.99938

According to the results in table 4, when the official exchange rate is used, we have an insignificant income
elasticity of 0.008. The inflation rate elasticity is negative (- 0.04) and it is significant. The official exchange
rate coefficient is positive and insignificant. Table 4 shows also that with the black market exchange rate,
the income elasticity becomes significant. The inflation rate elasticity is negative and significant which is in
line with the theory. The black market exchange rate is negative and significant. These results, confirm the
inclusion of the black market exchange rate as another determinant of the demand for money in country like
Algeria where the black market for foreign currencies is very active.
Finally, we perform CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests. From the plots, it clear that the demand for money
equation is more stable when the black market exchange rate is used.

Figure1: CUSUM Test (official exchange rate)

40

30

20

10

-10

-20

-30

-40
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

CUSUM 5% Significance

78
International Journal of Arts and Commerce Vol. 2 No. 10 November, 2013

Figure 2: CUSUMSQ Test (official exchange rate)

1.2

1.0

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0.0

-0.2
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

CUSUM of Squares 5% Significance

Figure 3: CUSUM Test (black market exchange rate)

40

30

20

10

-10

-20

-30

-40
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

CUSUM 5% Significance

79
International Journal of Arts and Commerce ISSN 1929-7106 www.ijac.org.uk

Figure 4: CUSUMSQ Test (black market exchange rate)

1.2

1.0

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0.0

-0.2
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

CUSUM of Squares 5% Significance

From the plots of CUSUMSQ , it is clear that the demand for money equation is more stable when the black
market exchange rate is used.

4. Conclusion:
Our study provides further evidence on the relevance of the black market exchange rate as another
determinant of the demand for money in less developed countries.
According to the above results, M1 is the right monetary aggregate to be considered for effective policy
formulation. Furthermore, our analysis shed some light on the importance of black market exchange rate,
which has a strong impact on the money demand function in Algeria.

References
Arango, S., Nadiri, Ishaq M., 1981. Demand for money in open economies. J. Monetary Econ. 7, 69–83.
Arize, A. (1989). An econometric investigation of money demand behaviour in four
Arize, A. C. and Shwiff, S. S. ( 1993). Cointegration, Real Exchange Rate and Modelling the Demand
for Broad Money in Japan, Applied Economics 25 (6): 717-726.
Arize, Augustine C., and Steven S. Shwiff. 1998. “The Appropriate Exchange-rate Variable in the Money
Demand of 25 Countries: An Empirical Investigation.” The North American Journal of Economics and
Finance 9 (2): 169–185.
Asian developing countries, International Economic Journal, 3(4): 79-93.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., 1996. The black market exchange rate and demand for money in Iran. J. Macroecon.
18, 171–176.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., Malixi, M., 1991. Exchange rate sensitivity of the demand for money in developing
countries. Appl. Econ. 23, 1377–1384.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., Pourheydarian, M., 1990. Exchange rate sensitivity of the demand for money and
effectiveness of fiscal and monetary policies. Appl. Econ. 22, 917–925.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., Rehman, H., 2005. Stability of the demand for money function in Asian developing
countries. Appl. Econ. 37, 773–792.
80
International Journal of Arts and Commerce Vol. 2 No. 10 November, 2013

Bahmani-Oskooee, Mohsen, and Altin Tanku. 2006. “Black Market Exchange Rate, Currency Substitution
and the Demand for Money in LDCs.” Economic Systems 30 (3): 249–263.
Blejer, Mario I. 1978. “Exchange Restrictions and the Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate.” The
Economics of Exchange Rates: Selected Studies, Edited by JA Frankel and HG Johnson. London:
Addison-Wesley: 117–28.
Case of Sudan' Journal of Development Economics 26(1987)257-275.
Chowdhury, A.R., 1997. The financial structure and the demand for money in Thailand. Appl. Econ. 29,
401–409.
Domowitz, I. and I. Elbadawi, 'An Error Correction Approach to Money Demand: The
Engle, R.F., and C.W.J. Granger. 1987. “Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation,
and Testing.” Econometrica 55: 251–276.
Goldfeld, S.M. 1994. “Demand for money: empirical studies“, in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money &
Finance, Edited by P. Newman, M. Milgrate and J. Eatwell. London: Macmillan Press.
Hafez, UR, Muhammad Afzal, 2003. The Black Market Exchange Rate and Demand for Money in Pakistan:
A cointegration analysis. Pakistan Economic and Social Review XLI, N°. 1&2, 13-28
Harris, Richard ID, and Robert Sollis. 2003. Applied Time Series Modelling and Forecasting. J. Wiley.
http://www.lavoisier.fr/livre/notice.asp?id=OKLWOSAKKK2OWI.
Hassan, M. Kabir, and Tatak Suryadi. 1993. “An Econometric Investigation of the Determinants of the
Demand for Money in Indonesia.” The Singapore Economic Review 38 (1).
Hassan, M. Kabir, K. Choudhury, and M. Waheeduzzaman. 1995. “On Black Market Exchange Rate and
Demand for Money in Developing Countries: The Case of Nigeria.” Atlantic Economic Journal 23 (1):
35–44.
Hassan, M. Kabir. 1992. “An Econometric Analysis of Credit Constraint, Foreign Interest Rates and
Currency Depreciation in the Demand for Money in Bangladesh.” The Bangladesh Development
Studies: 25–45.
Johansen, S., 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 12, 231–254.
Johansen, S., Juselius, K., 1990. Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration with
applications to the demand for money. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. 52, 169–210.
Laidler, E.W.D., 1993. The Demand for Money: Theories, Evidence and Problems, 4th ed. Harper
Collins College Publishers, New York.
Lee, T.H., Chung, K.J., 1995. Further results on the long-run demand for money in Korea: a cointegration
analysis. Int. Econ. J. 9, 103–113.
McNown, R., Wallace, M.S., 1992. Cointegration tests of a long-run relationship between money
demand and the effective exchange rate. J. Int. Money Finance 11, 107–114.
Mundell, R.A., 1963. Capital mobility and stabilization policy under fixed and flexible exchange rates. Can.
J. Econ. Pol. Sci. 29, 475–485.
Narayan, Paresh Kumar. 2005. “The Saving and Investment Nexus for China: Evidence from Cointegration
Tests.” Applied Economics 37 (17): 1979–1990.
Odedokun, M.O., 1996. Black market exchange behaviour in African countries: evidence from an eclectic
model. Afr. Dev. Rev. 8, 1–19.
Pesaran, M. Hashem, Yongcheol Shin, and Ron P. Smith. 1999. “Pooled Mean Group Estimation of
Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 94 (446): 621–634.
Pesaran, M.H. 1997. “The Role of Economic Theory in Modelling the Long Run.” The Economic Journal
107: 198–191.
Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., Smith, R.J., 2001. Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships.
J. Appl. Econometrics 16, 289–326.
81
International Journal of Arts and Commerce ISSN 1929-7106 www.ijac.org.uk

Pozo, Susan and Mark Wheeler (2000), Exchange-rate uncertainty and dollarization: A structural vector
error correction approach to estimating money demand. Applied Financial Economics, Volume 10,pp.
685-692.
Tabesh, Hamid. 2000. “Demand for Money and the Black Market Exchange Rate Expectations: Further
Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Economics 26 (2): 1–9.
Wong, Chorng-huey. 1977. “Demand for Money in Developing Countries: Some Theoretical and Empirical
Results.” Journal of Monetary Economics 3 (1): 59–86.

82

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy