5c6f935905e2c03b933f2737
5c6f935905e2c03b933f2737
Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .xv
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .177
Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185
This page intentionally left blank
Acknowledgments
How so? Well, let’s take a look at what happens when I ask my
undergraduate business students to undertake exactly the same
exercise.
As you’ve probably figured out by now, my day job involves
teaching undergraduate and graduate business courses at York Uni-
versity in Toronto. My favorite subject to teach is a 12-week under-
graduate course on the topic of wealth management. When I start
this course anew each semester, on the first day of class, before I dis-
cuss the syllabus, the course textbook, or the final exam schedule, I
ask each student to prepare their own personal balance sheet.
Now, their situations are probably different from yours. To start,
they’re typically only about 20 years old. But already, a large portion
of them have substantial debt obligations: Many of them have taken
out student loans in the range of $10,000 to $40,000. In this way, my
students are like college grads in the United States, in which the aver-
age student loan balance was $20,100 in 2007.1 To be sure, these stu-
dents might not need to pay back their loans for many years, and the
loans might not be accruing any interest while they are in school, but
all of them recognize their loans as liabilities with a current value.2 My
students also report having a substantial amount of credit card debt.
On average, they report slightly more than $3,100 as a revolving bal-
ance on their personal balance sheet. These numbers are broadly reflec-
tive of credit card indebtedness for that age category, according to
Sallie Mae, a U.S. student loan company.3 However, unlike their stu-
dent loans, on these liabilities the interest clock is ticking daily—and
rates can approach 20 percent, and even 30 percent, for some bank
and department store cards.
My students also often include consumer loans on their balance
sheets because many of them owe money on cars they have financed or
funds borrowed from roommates, parents, cousins, and the occasional
loan shark. In sum: Most of them have plenty of debts and liabilities.
When they get to the left side of their personal balance sheets,
they often admit to having difficulties finding any values to include.
As you might suspect, at the age of 20 many of them don’t have much
in the way of traditional financial assets. They don’t own houses. They
don’t have any stocks or bonds. They don’t own any mutual funds,
Treasury bills, or savings bonds, and they certainly don’t have any
pension accounts. Remember, some of these kids aren’t yet of legal
drinking age!
Some of my students include the little bit of money they have in a
savings account at the local bank or perhaps the value of the bicycle
they use to ride to class. In fact, sometimes a hand will go up, and a
student will ask me if he should include the newly-increased credit
limit on his MasterCard or Visa on the left side as a financial asset.
(Note: The answer is no.)
Now, you can view this exercise—either the one I posed to you at the
start of this chapter, or the one I give my new students each semester—
as a rather private, possibly intrusive, and perhaps even depressing
assignment. But as I am working through the creation of their personal
balance sheets with my students, I make it clear that I do not want them
to hand their sheets in to me at the end of class. I don’t want to make
them uncomfortable. I’m not trying to pry into their personal financial
affairs. My goal, as I’ve said, is just to get them to compute what they
think their net worth is by subtracting the value of the financial assets
they have identified from the value of their financial liabilities—but
they get to keep the resulting number to themselves, just like you do.
honest now. Reluctantly, and slowly, the vast majority of the juniors
and seniors raise their hands.
At this point, if they were a publicly traded company, with this
admission of a zero or negative net worth number, they would imme-
diately be deemed insolvent or even bankrupt. In fact, the smattering
of students—from a group of 60—who do not raise their hands are
usually exchange students (who perhaps didn’t understand the exer-
cise) or are the children of wealthy parents (maybe in Dubai?) who
don’t have any liabilities.
Now here’s the twist: I then announce to my students that based
on their responses it seems to me they did the exercise all wrong, and
they probably answered both questions incorrectly. I tell them that I
know they are relying on their previous studies of business account-
ing, using bookkeeping techniques or Financial Accounting Stan-
dards Board guidelines, to create their personal balance sheets. Much
to their surprise, I suggest they are undoubtedly missing the most
important item and most valuable asset class they own, and they are
forgetting the reason they enrolled in school and have incurred all
their student loan debt.
And now back to you—what my students have undoubtedly left
off their list of assets is the same thing that’s probably missing from
yours—the value of what economists call human capital.
But what is human capital? At the young age of 20, as I’ve said,
my students generally have little in the way of traditional financial
capital. But they do have 40 to 50 years of salary, bonus, and wage
income ahead of them. One powerful way to consider this future
income is to view it as an asset like a gold mine or oil well with 50
more years of reserves.
Think of it this way: If you own a well or mine, you probably can-
not extract more than a small fraction of the reserves in any given
year. (And it might be very costly to do so.) However, this asset has
substantial value today. I’ll say this again to make sure it’s clear: The
most valuable asset class for most people during most of their working
years is their human capital. Not just college kids in their early 20s or
graduate students in their late 20s—this applies to you in your 30s,
40s, and even 50s and 60s.
INTRODUCTION 5
TABLE I.1 Holistic Personal Balance Sheet and Net Worth Calculation
My Assets My Liabilities
4. I define Implicit Financial Capital as the present value of all defined benefit
pensions, Social Security (or Canada Pension Plan) benefits, and other illiquid
entitlements to future cash flows that you can’t sell or trade in the secondary
market but that you have earned by virtue of your past labor market participation
and are guaranteed to receive after retirement for your lifetime. My students,
generally speaking, do not have any implicit financial capital—yet.
6 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
salary growth rates and discount rates, coming from one of the better
undergraduate business schools in the country, their human capital
values are well into the seven digits.
I’ve included a human capital calculator at www.qwema.ca, so
you can try this exercise, too. What is your human capital worth?
After you estimate and include your human capital, what does your
holistic personal balance sheet look like?
5. In Canada, the median value of human capital at the age of 25 after completing
an undergraduate degree is roughly $1.3 million, assuming a discount rate of 3.5
percent. Data source: payscale.com; QWeMA Group calculations.
6. In generating these estimates, I included only income from earnings; I adjusted
for tax using average 2008 effective tax rates; and I assumed income from
employment to age 75. Lower estimates are based on 40th percentile income
(only 40 percent of people have incomes lower than this) and a discount rate of 6
percent; upper estimates are based on 90th percentile income (90 percent of
people have incomes lower than this) and a discount rate of 3.5 percent.
INTRODUCTION 7
How much money would you be willing to pay, right now, to become
20 years younger? Most of it? All of it? Many, if not most of the skep-
tics say they would be willing to pay quite a lot indeed to regain some
years of youth. Well, I reply, if you are willing to sacrifice so much
financial capital at advanced ages to regain lost human capital, then
it must be worth quite a bit at early ages!
The four bullet points might not make much sense to you at this
point, but I promise it will all click in a few chapters.
1
Is the Long-Term Value of an Education
Worth the Short-Term Cost?
13
14 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
1. University tuition fees have risen faster than inflation over the past decade in
both Canada and the United States. For U.S. data, see Baum and Ma, Trends in
College Pricing. Canadian data taken from Statistics Canada, “The Daily: University
Tuition Fees.”
1 • IS THE LONG-TERM VALUE OF AN EDUCATION WORTH THE SHORT-TERM COST? 15
Despite what I’ve already said about varying pay scales by profes-
sion, and keeping in mind I am most definitely not a guidance coun-
selor, my answer is usually as follows: First, figure out what you truly
enjoy doing. A good way to do this is by taking as many different
courses as possible. Then, when you find what you like, find out how
to make money doing that. Although the answer might not satisfy
them, this little piece of advice was given to me by my father many
years ago, and it has worked out well for me personally. Although I’ve
just spent the last few pages talking about the financial impacts of
education decisions, the bottom line, for me, is that human capital
estimates should form only part of your decision about what career to
pursue. (However, I do think they should form at least part of your
deliberations.) Somebody who truly wants to be a hairstylist but who
decides to pursue a career as an optometrist because it pays three
times as much will likely have a higher human capital value than they
otherwise would—but they are also much more likely to be miserable!
I’m sure these remarks will sound odd if you worry about your kids
who just love playing video games...or sleeping all day. Surely figuring
out what you enjoy is not the best strategy for increasing the value of
human capital, is it? Shouldn’t professors be telling students to “aim
high” and go to medical school or become engineers or lawyers?
Oddly enough, additional research—beyond what I’ve already
reported—provides some subtle reasons for the discrepancy between
the net worth of people with and without higher education. That is,
the gap in net worth between people with a college degree and those
with a high school diploma or less is attributable to more than just
educational achievement. How so? Let’s explore this question next.
First, let’s start by examining actual household balance sheet val-
ues as estimated and reported by the U.S. Federal Reserve, as
opposed to the theoretical estimates I have been giving for human
capital (see Table 1.1).
Here are some basic facts. According to 2007 data collected by
the U.S. Federal Reserve in its Survey of Consumer Finances,7 the
7. The SCF is a triennial interview survey of U.S. families sponsored by the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System with cooperation of the U.S.
Department of the Treasury. In the year 2007 survey, 4,422 families were inter-
viewed. See Bucks et al, “Changes in U.S. Family Finances from 2004 to 2007”
for more information.
1 • IS THE LONG-TERM VALUE OF AN EDUCATION WORTH THE SHORT-TERM COST? 23
average net worth of U.S. college graduates is much larger than the
net worth of individuals who don’t have a high school diploma, or who
didn’t attend college. For example, in the year 2007, the average net
worth of a family in which the head of the household has a high-school
diploma only—and did not go on to college—was $251,600, whereas
the average net worth for a college graduate was almost four times
greater at roughly one million dollars. For those without a high school
diploma, the average net worth was a mere $142,900.8 (Note that all
these numbers use the conventional accounting measures of net
worth—namely explicit financial assets minus explicit financial liabili-
ties—and don’t take into account the human capital value I previously
discussed.)
8. These patterns are seen in Canada as well. Median net worth for households
with less than a high school diploma was $92,433 in 2005; with a high school
diploma was $120,007; and with a university degree was $237,400. From Statis-
tics Canada, The Wealth of Canadians.
24 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
income. As you can see from Table 1.1, the household headed by a
college graduate had an average income of $143,800 in the year 2007
versus $51,100 for those who completed high school—and just
$31,300 for those without a high school diploma.9 (One of the first
economists to demonstrate this was Columbia University professor
Jacob Mincer in his 1974 book Schooling, Experience and Earnings.)
As you might suspect, these multiples were not just limited to the
year 2007. The gap is consistent across time. Eighteen years earlier, in
9. This finding holds true in Canada, as well: average earnings for those with less
than a high school diploma were $21,230 in 2001; those with a high school
diploma earned $25,477 annually; and those with a university degree earned
$48,648 annually. From 2001 census data as reported in Statistics Canada,
Earnings of Canadians.
1 • IS THE LONG-TERM VALUE OF AN EDUCATION WORTH THE SHORT-TERM COST? 25
What you can see is that the college graduate’s higher net worth is
allocated to a portfolio of assets that are quite different from those in
the other groups who have less education. In aggregate, college grad-
uates have more financial investments, and they own houses that are
more expensive. Now, think about what happened to the value of the
stock market, mutual funds, and housing prices during the period
1989 to 2007; they went up quite strongly. The SP500 increased by
659 percent from January 1989 to January 2007, whereas the value of
housing—as measured by the S&P/Case-Shiller Home Price
(Composite 10) index, which provides data on single-family house
prices in the United States—increased by 187 percent over the same
18 years.
So, perhaps the reason college graduates are wealthier than high
school graduates is because of what they “learned to buy” while in
college, as opposed to their earning power per se. In the words of the
author of a recent study on the same topic, “Assets more likely held
by college graduates appreciate faster than assets held by high school
graduates.”10 This insight is also echoed in a Harvard Business School
working paper in which the authors examine the impact of financial
education on financial market participation and find that cognitive
ability, which is arguably improved by attending college, increases
the odds of holding financial assets such as stocks and bonds.11 Of
course, these same assets can become a double-edged sword because
they are more volatile than other kinds of assets, and this volatility is
not under their individual owner’s control.
What you’ve seen so far is that households headed by individuals
with more education tend to have higher incomes and higher net
worth. The higher net worth comes in part because college graduates
hold different assets than those owned by households with lower levels
of education, and these components of net worth appreciate more
quickly. But you also know that the assets held by households with
higher education levels fluctuate in value more than those held by
other households. Does this mean that college graduates might become
worse off, over time, than other households with less education?
12. Brewer, Eide, and Ehrenberg, “Does it Pay to Attend an Elite Private College?”
30 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
35
36 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
“live it up” when the money is unlocked at age 50. Others respond
that it’s silly to live an impoverished life for 25 years and only enjoy
wealth in the later part of life.
Discussion then turns to the question of what happens after you
get access to the $25 million in trust. Do you spend it all then? Do
you divide the funds into yearly allotments based on how long you
expect to live and spend it year by year? The exchange is vigorous and
interesting. Occasionally, when I have the time, I have the students
form small groups and ask them to reach agreement about the best
spending plan. I tell them to ignore complications such as premature
death or ill health and assume they all will live to 75 years or 25 years
past the unlocking of the locked trust.
If this were you, how, exactly, would you plan your financial life?
Would you live cheaply for the first ten years, spend freely for the
following twenty, and then go back to consuming only $25,000 per
year? You can see the similarities between this situation and our
hypothetical inheritance, earlier in the chapter. You can also see that
the “pauper/prosper/pauper” lifestyle doesn’t make much sense.
Instead, the fundamental principle of Long Division, or income
smoothing, suggests that you live beyond your immediate (income)
means early in life and later in life, and then make it up with large
savings during the middle years.
Here’s how this would work in practice.
2 • WHAT IS THE POINT OF SAVING MONEY FOREVER? 41
1. The software was co-developed with Jagadeesh Gokhale, a senior fellow at the
Cato Institute. See www.esplanner.com for more information.
44 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
up, slowly, if things turn out well. Likewise, what if, like most peo-
ple, you can’t borrow at the zero percent interest rate I mentioned
earlier? What if you can’t get low-cost credit and must repay what
you’ve borrowed using high-cost credit cards charging 25 percent
per year, or worse? Then, yes, you would want to avoid dis-saving
(or “negative saving”) early in life. You might be concerned about
health care, or extreme longevity, or mortgage debt, and these are
all topics I discuss later.
Alternatively, you might be in an environment of abnormally low
interest rates in which you can borrow at negative real (inflation
adjusted) rates; in which case your discounted human capital value
might be actually higher, and your Long Division process leads to a
greater standard of living today.
Back to our example. To be clear, developing good financial
habits, such as saving a portion of income, while you are young will
probably help you during your entire life. But let’s be careful to dis-
tinguish between financial advice and psychological or behavioral
advice. For now, my key message is that advising the young to save,
save, save, just for the sake of it; or advising the middle age to target a
given income replacement rate at retirement, as if that point in time
matters, is inconsistent with human capital thinking. (Kotlikoff calls
these standard recommendations “rules of dumb” because they don’t
provide a reliable basis for financial planning.) Instead, the concept of
Long Division is the rational response to the conventional messages.
In the next section you see that many people have trouble behav-
ing rationally when it comes time to allocating their lifetime resources.
In the same way, the value of your human capital is higher in a low
interest rate environment. Because interest rates are not signifi-
cantly discounting the value of your future earnings as they reach
maturity (so to speak) and are cashed out by you from year to year,
each year of your future earnings is worth more today. This way of
thinking might seem a little unusual at first, but it makes sense!
among lottery winners in the State of Florida backs this up with some
sobering evidence. First, some background.
During the period from 1993 to 2002, approximately 35,000 peo-
ple were first-time winners in Florida’s popular Fantasy5 lottery
game. And, although the median sum won was somewhere between
$10,000 and $50,000; about 250 people won between $100,000 and
$150,000—and 153 were lucky enough to get more than $150,000.
So, these are not trivial sums. You would expect them to have a joyous
impact on the winners and a positive effect on their personal
finances. (By the way, these numbers are quite accurate because the
U.S. Internal Revenue Service requires that all winnings above $600
be reported to them directly by the lottery organizers. Indeed, the
information about the names, addresses, county of residence, and
winnings is publicly available.)
Did the winners’ financial lives improve or worsen after their
wins? Some clever researchers at Vanderbilt University set out to
explore, using data on Florida lottery winners, whether the financial
lives of these lucky few improved after their jackpots.2 Granted,
coming to a consensus on how an “improved financial situation” is
defined can be difficult. However, one measure of financial well-
being that is both easy to define and easy to collect information
about is bankruptcy. The authors of the Vanderbilt study obtained
the electronic records for all personal bankruptcies filed in Florida
over a period of more than 20 years: from early 1985 (well before
the first person studied won the lottery) all the way to late 2007,
when the last individual in the lottery database received his or her
winnings.
3. If you are inclined, I urge you to read the paper “The Ticket to Easy Street?”
2 • WHAT IS THE POINT OF SAVING MONEY FOREVER? 49
dollars along the way. These individuals did not practice Long Divi-
sion by smoothing their consumption, and their irrational approach
actually left them worse off than before.
4. Collins, Morduch, Rutherford, and Ruthven, Portfolios of the Poor: How the
World’s Poor Live on $2 a Day.
50 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
income at all, and at other times, they earned more than their average
of $2 in a given day. (In other words, their average earnings were $2
per day, but with huge swings, or in the language of statisticians, a
very large standard deviation.)
And yet, despite these erratic circumstances, the authors found
that few of these families consumed based on their immediate, daily
earnings only. Instead, on days for which income was greater than
average, they set aside (relatively) substantial sums of money and did
not spend it. This fund served as a reserve for days in which they did-
n’t earn anything. By drawing on their reserve, on days when they
earned less than average, they would still consume relatively the same
amount compared to the days when things were better.
Now, although this seems like a commonsense solution preached
by any parent who has admonished his offspring to save for a rainy
day, the level of consistency in implementing this practice among the
world’s poorest families, in such dire circumstances, seems remark-
able. Overall, the authors claim that the consumption profile of the
world’s poorest families over their life cycle was relatively smooth and
based on an average of their meager daily earnings. In other words:
they practice Long Division.
Indeed, according to a review of the book in The Economist, “The
subjects used a combination of loans and savings to ensure their lives
were not, literally, hostage to fortune. Hardly anyone lived utterly
hand to mouth.” The review went on to say, “The research provides
evidence of the sophistication with which poor people think about
their finances.”5 It would seem that their behavior could serve as a
financial inspiration to us all.
annuities into (much smaller) lump sums, hence unraveling any pol-
icy benefits, it certainly makes me wonder whether money can actu-
ally be hazardous to your wealth.
At the very least, perhaps it’s a blessing in disguise that our most
valuable asset, human capital, can be monetized only slowly and with
great effort. Indeed, if you could take infinite advances against our
future labor income and sell it all in the marketplace today, you would
much likely be worse off in the long term. In the meantime, perhaps
the most rational approach to maximizing your financial well-being over
your lifetime is not to plan for a lottery win but to adopt the perspec-
tives of the world’s poorest people in planning your spending over time.
In this chapter you have learned what is probably the most funda-
mental axiom within strategic personal financial planning for individ-
uals, and that is the notion of consumption smoothing. That is, every
financial (and insurance) decision that you make in your life should
be motivated by the objective of removing the jagged corners and
rough edges in life. More on this in later chapters.
53
54 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
$ $ %
Main Residence Mortgage 111,618 152,988 46.3
Other Real Estate Mortgage 102,401 182,070 5.5
Line of credit (Unsecured) 3,891 24,679 1.7
Credit card 3,072 7,475 46.1
Student loans 12,288 22,016 15.2
Vehicle loans 11,776 14,951 34.9
Other debt 5,120 15,667 6.8
Sum of Percentages: 156.5
Total Debt in any Form: 68,916 129,026 77
early 2009), which is much higher than the rate of -0.4 percent
reported by the U.S. Department of Commerce for 2005.3
3. Source: U.S. Commerce Department News Releases, August 2008 and April
2009. In Canada, the personal savings rate was 1.2 percent in 2005 and 4.7 per-
cent in the first quarter of 2009. Canadian data from Statistics Canada, “Eco-
nomic indicators, by province and territory (monthly and quarterly),” from
CANSIM tables 079-0003 and 080-0014.
56 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
more. In fact, the greater the sum of percentages is here, the larger the
fraction of the population that has more than one type of liability.
Many students, for example, borrow from banks using a personal
line of credit, have credit cards, and participate in government stu-
dent loan programs. Now, many of these students might not have
much choice and are essentially forced to borrow from various
sources. Nevertheless, the evidence suggests that a large segment of
the borrowing population is able to consolidate and optimize their
debt, yet chooses not to.
I suspect that people might be spreading their debts across vari-
ous creditors—even in the absence of any liquidity constraints (which
are limits on the amount you can borrow)—to fulfill an unconscious
desire to compartmentalize their liabilities (that is, to break the total
amount down into easier-to-swallow chunks). Or perhaps this is a
remnant from our approach to asset management, in which we are
told not to place all our investment eggs in one basket.
Today, with interest rates at historically low levels and many Amer-
icans fretting about the prospect of higher rates going forward, I believe
it is important to deflect consumers’ attention away from speculating on
the direction of interest rates and more toward examining their own
personal financial balance sheets. Optimal debt management strategies
can and should be implemented independently of the direction of
short-term rates.
TABLE 3.2 How Many Months Does it Take to Pay Off a Debt of
$7,500 in $200 Monthly Increments and What is the Total Cost?
The results are as follows: It takes 40 months to pay off the line of
credit under a 3.25 percent rate and 41 months under the 5.25 per-
cent rate. In contrast, it takes 51 months to eliminate the credit card
debt charging 15 percent and a whopping 55 months to pay off the
credit card charging 18 percent. The total amount paid will vary for
each form of debt and interest rate. It ranges from $7,891 for the
lower interest line of credit to $10,852 for the retail credit card—a dif-
ference of $2,961. Accordingly, if this customer can choose to hold
her debt at 3.25 percent versus 18 percent, she will save nearly
$3,000—or 40 percent of the original debt amount—by using the line
of credit.
Now, if you go even further and assume a hypothetical consumer
who has three different types of debt: two credit cards (with rates of
15 percent and 18 percent) and a line of credit (charging 3.25 per-
cent)—all with the exact same hypothetical balance, the benefits
would be even more pronounced. In total, all the payments that must
be made to pay off the three accounts, that is, the line of credit and
the two credit cards at their respective rates, is $28,752. However, if
all three accounts were consolidated into the line of credit (that is, not
diversified), the payments would only total 3 x $7,891 = $23,672,
which represents potential savings of $5,080 over the life of the liabil-
ities. In addition, the total amount of debt would be eliminated faster,
saving 16 months, compared to waiting 55 months until the last pay-
ment on the retail credit card is made. Alternatively, transferring the
credit card balances to the (higher) 5.25 percent line of credit, versus
holding three separate accounts would result in total payments of
$24,460; leading to total savings of $4,292.
3 • HOW MUCH DEBT IS TOO MUCH AND HOW MUCH IS TOO LITTLE? 59
4. Stango and Zinman, “What Do Consumers Really Pay on Their Checking and
Credit Card Accounts?”
60 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
6. These are similar to group RRSPs in Canada. However, you can’t borrow against
the assets or from group RRSPs. You can withdraw the funds from an individual
RRSP to pay off high-interest debt, but this is a taxable event that complicates
the analysis and relative benefit.
62 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
at the same rate as the rest of the investments in the plan. However, if
the rate of interest you are paying on your debt exceeds a reasonable
estimate of this return, it actually makes sense to borrow from the
401(k) instead of from other sources. Why? Because your personal bal-
ance sheet will improve by swapping debts within the various silos.
When these economists began their study, they did not expect to
find many people who could actually borrow from their 401(k) plans
but chose instead to carry high-interest debt. And yet, this is exactly
what they did find. People preferred to carry high-interest debt
rather than borrow from their 401(k), even though it would save them
money in the long run.
Here are some summary statistics. In 2004, the most recent data
available to the authors, approximately 46 percent of surveyed house-
holds reported having a 401(k) plan. The ability to borrow from a
401(k) is something that is determined by the plan sponsors and the
company, and approximately 32 percent of households reported the
ability to take loans from their 401(k) plan. However, a mere 5 per-
cent of surveyed households reported having an outstanding 401(k)
plan loan. This is a small fraction of the total household population,
but it has actually doubled over the previous 12 years. Stated differ-
ently, the loan rate among eligible households was 16 percent. The
median outstanding loan balance was $4,000.7
The main insight from their study, which should resonate with
the results of the previous section, is that a much higher percentage
of eligible households had outstanding consumer debts, likely at rela-
tively higher interest rates given the cost of maintaining credit cards
and other such loans.
The authors claim that approximately 40 percent to 60 percent of
eligible households, depending on the assumptions used, would gain
from restructuring household debt and borrowing from 401(k) plans
instead. Ultimately, the authors estimate that U.S. households could
have shifted more than $9 billion in debt, which is $3,400 per house-
hold, to save $3.3 billion collectively, or an average of $200 per house-
hold per year.
One rather ironic positive aspect of the recent credit crisis and
the greater difficulty many consumers are experiencing in obtaining
consumer debt is they will likely increase the amount they borrow
from their 401(k) plans, simply because they have no other alterna-
tive. On the one hand, this act will clearly diminish and reduce the
long-term value of their retirement savings. And yet, this likely
implies they will not be paying high interest rates. Only time will tell
whether the good (lower rates) offsets the bad (lower retirement
balances).
8. Agarwal, Driscoll, Gabaix, and Laibson, “The Age of Reason: Financial Deci-
sions over the Lifecycle.”
64 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
worth much more if you keep consumption both smooth and rela-
tively modest, which can have desirable effects on your waistline, too!
1. The median U.S. net worth was $191K for couples without children and $141K
for couples with children. In Canada, the numbers are similar: in 2005, the
median net worth for couples without children at home was $242,900, which is
$53,900 (or 29 percent) more than couples with children under 18, whose net
worth was $189,000. For Canadian data, see The Wealth of Canadians.
69
70 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
issues are up for debate. However, it seems clear that decisions about
marriage and family have financial implications. In this chapter, I
devote my attention to the implications of life-cycle thinking, holistic
balance-sheet management, and the rule of Long Division to deci-
sions about childbearing and family formation (that is, getting mar-
ried and having kids, not necessarily in that order).
tax credits and deductions that are available in the U.S. tax code.) I’ve
included a basic calculator at www.qwema.ca to enable you to esti-
mate the cost today of raising your existing or planned kids to age 18.
This range, of course, does not include the escalating cost of college,
and it assumes the child actually moves out of the house at the age of
18. (How many kids do that nowadays?)
At first glance, it seems kids are terribly expensive. If this is so,
could paying parents to have children increase the supply of kids in a
society? Here is but one interesting case.
the low fertility rate among their shrinking population, the Govern-
ment of Quebec felt it had to do something, soon, or eventually there
would be no more Quebeckers. The human capital of Quebec was at
stake!
So, and this is where the story becomes relevant to money mile-
stones, in the 1980s the provincial government brought in a program
called The Allowance for Newborn Children or, as it became known,
“bucks for babies.” Under this program, parents were paid approxi-
mately $500 Canadian (CAD) (slightly less than $500 U.S. dollars)
upon the birth of their first child, and $1,000 CAD for their second
child. If they had additional children beyond two, they could get
much more, as much as $8,000 (nontaxable!) for each birth.
Now, do you think these payouts helped induce fertility and
increase the birth rate? Well, you might be surprised that the answer
is not by much. After all, when you compare a few thousand dollars in
government transfers to the potentially hundreds of thousands of dol-
lars in future costs to raise each child, it would be surprising if these
sums had any impact at all. In fact, the Government of Quebec
opened the cash registers even further with ongoing financial induce-
ments for children and even began to provide universal daycare at
greatly subsidized rates. But none of this helped much. Indeed, if the
decision not to have children was purely motivated by financial con-
siderations, you would have expected to see greater change to the fer-
tility and birth rate as the cash piled up in the hands of parents.
Interestingly enough, it was only after the provincial govern-
ment went one step further in 2006 and legislated the most liberal
and generous parental leave in the country—that is, the amount of
paid time parents can take off work to care for their children—that
there started to be some noticeable change in behavior. By 2006, the
fertility rate had increased to 1.62 children per female, and the
number of births has been rising each year since. The 2008 rate
was 1.74, which is the highest rate since 1976. Moreover, although
this change might have been a result of all the cumulative induce-
ments, perhaps the ability of working parents to actually stay
home and enjoy their children had the greatest impact of all. By the
way, as of early 2009, the population of Quebec had risen from 6.6
million in 1985 to nearly 8 million; the supply of human capital is
4 • ARE KIDS INVESTMENTS AND CAN MARRIAGES DIVERSIFY? 73
3. Statistics on the fertility, population, and birth rates in Quebec are taken from
the Institute de la statistique, Quebec; available at www.stat.gouv.gc.ca.
4. There is a persistent myth that Germany adopted age 65 as the standard retire-
ment age because that was Bismarck’s age. In fact, Germany initially set age 70
as the retirement age (and Bismarck himself was 74 at the time), and it was not
until 27 years later (in 1916) that the age was lowered to 65. By that time, Bis-
marck had been dead for 18 years. See the brief history at Social Security Online,
the official website of the U.S. Social Security Administration: http://www.
socialsecurity.gov/history/ottob.html.
74 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
5. Projections of worldwide dependency ratios are taken from The 2009 Ageing
Report by the European Commission.
4 • ARE KIDS INVESTMENTS AND CAN MARRIAGES DIVERSIFY? 75
lead to problems.6 For those of you who are wondering, the situation
in the United States isn’t as bleak, although it is certainly worrisome.
In 2010, the old-age dependency ratio is close to 20 retirees per 100
workers, and it is expected to hit 35 by the year 2050. These are not
European or Japanese numbers, partially because of the relatively
higher U.S. fertility rate of 2.1. Furthermore, the U.S. Social Security
system isn’t as generous (it doesn’t pay as much) as European or
Japanese state pension plans, which is yet another reason that the
United States has some time before it faces the PAYGO pension crisis
unfolding in many other countries, although the United States will
soon have to contend with this as well.
Interestingly, and more relevant to our discussion, when Chan-
cellor Bismarck’s pension scheme was introduced to the German
Reichstag back in 1881, he emphasized that the motivation for his
reforms was to preserve a sense of human dignity for the elderly and
to prevent them from having to rely on charity. Perhaps the PAYGO
pension system can be understood as the revenge of the elderly (Bis-
marck had just turned 66) and the infirm against the young and agile.
In fact, to quote a recent German study, “Bismarck wanted the pen-
sion system as a substitute for the transfer mechanisms of the tradi-
tional family that had been destroyed by the industrial revolution,
seeing it mainly as a means to avoid the neglect and mistreatment of
old people by their children.” The article continues that, “A PAYGO
system may serve as an enforcement device for ungrateful children.”7
6. See Beck, “A Slow-Burning Fuse,” especially “Scrimp and Save: Pensions Will
Have to Become Far Less Generous,” and “Suffer the Little Children: Most of
the Rich World is Short of Babies.”
7. Emphasis added. Sinn, “The Pay-as-You Go Pension System as Fertility Insur-
ance and an Enforcement Device.”
76 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
very long after. Indeed, if the German retirement system had added
as many years to the retirement age as have been added to overall
life expectancy over the last century, the official retirement age
would now stand at 95 years rather than 65!8 But now, as fertility
rates drop and life expectancies continue to rise, and as the tradi-
tional age of retirement has actually decreased since Bismarck’s ini-
tial proposal to 65, the sustainability of this model is increasingly
uncertain. And so, perhaps when you think about the high cost of
raising children, it’s worth noting that your kids might be your (only)
pensions given the current fiscal imbalances and structural deficits
of most government pension plans such as U.S. Social Security. That
is, investing in your kids’ developing human capital might help reduce
your own personal liabilities many years from now, in retirement.
What am I talking about?
Think back to the picture of the holistic personal balance sheet I
presented in the Introduction, “Human Capital: Your Greatest
Asset.” On the left side are capital assets, and on the right side are lia-
bilities. Some of these liabilities are explicit, such as the loans and
debts I discussed in Chapter 3 (“How Much Debt Is Too Much and
How Much Is Too Little?”), but many others are implicit. The birth of
a child creates an immediate, implicit liability on the parents’ holistic
balance sheet in that she or he must be cared for, and this requires
resources. This liability might explain why the net worth of families is
lower, on average. But there is another hidden liability on your holis-
tic balance sheet; one that your kids might actually be able to help
you offset—the cost and debts that can accrue as you age. For exam-
ple, people over the age of 65 spend about four times as much as
those under 65 on health care, and a 1997 study found the average
cost of nursing home care in the U.S. ranges from $36,000 to $80,000
per year.9 I am going to suggest that in most (if not all) families with
an above-average number of children—and yes, these families have
10. The discussion of transfers from grown-up children to elderly parents (or “chil-
dren as pensions”) is taken from Cigno, “How to Avoid a Pension Crisis: A Ques-
tion of Intelligent System Design.”
11. Duflo, “Grandmothers and Granddaughters.”
78 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
today but will help you smooth consumption tomorrow as he cares for
you in later years, either by supporting you financially or by providing
goods and services that you’d otherwise need to purchase. After your
kids are born, your balance sheet needs to adjust to include both the
implicit immediate liabilities associated with raising a child, but also
the future implicit asset they represent for you. As a parent, you are,
once again, wealthier than you think. And that measure doesn’t include
the cute dividends that having children can pay—that is, grandkids!
Now let’s look at how marriage changes our approaches to finan-
cial risk. I’ll focus on one population subset I find especially allur-
ing—Italian women.
the long run, men’s portfolios (especially those of single men) actually
earn less than female investors who are less prone to overconfidence.
I’m sure that you might resonate with this particular explanation—in
particular the women among you—but I believe there might be a
deeper and perhaps more satisfying explanation for the “single,
female, and safe” portfolio phenomenon. This alternative explanation
comes from a recent study of the marital habits and investment deci-
sions of Italian women, conducted by (Italian) researchers at the Insti-
tute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn.13 Now, being married to a
strong-minded Italian woman whose large family immigrated to
Canada in the 1950s, let me admit at the outset that first, I have to be
very careful about what I say here, and second, I’m clear that Italian
women don’t take any decisions lightly, especially decisions about
marriage. They think strategically, and children and the family are the
center of their universe. Indeed, as you will see, you can learn much
from the financial acumen of Italian women!
Getting back to our study: researchers at the IZA used data from
the Bank of Italy’s survey of Household Income and Wealth, which is a
detailed dataset similar in scope and purpose to the U.S. Survey of
Consumer Finances, during the period 1989 to 2006. The authors pre-
sented evidence, consistent with the international evidence, that
unmarried Italian women are the least likely to hold risky investment
assets such as corporate stocks and common shares. Married women, in
contrast, don’t exhibit the same reluctance to assume investment risk.
The researchers found that in 1989, the first year for which they
had data, single (Italian) females allocated almost 90 percent of their
investable financial capital to safe assets and only negligible amounts
to risky investments. In contrast, in the same year, married (Italian)
females had closer to 85 percent in safe assets and a much larger frac-
tion in risky investments. Although the reported differences might
not appear substantial, these numbers are statistically significant and
quite robust across more than 71,000 individual observations. More-
over, this variation in risky versus safe asset holdings could not be
explained by age, income, wealth, or education. In other words, even
13. Bertocchi, Brunetti, and Torricelli, “Marriage and Other Risky Assets: A Portfo-
lio Approach.”
80 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
after separating the data into groups of people with equal education,
equal wealth, equal income, and so on, the researchers observed the
“single, female, and safe” phenomenon. So what happened? Could
marriage have changed Italian women’s risk tolerance or emboldened
them to invest more like men? It seems that marriage enamors
women...to the stock market.
The authors’ explanation for this increased risk tolerance was not
psychological, biological, or behavioral. Rather, they attributed this
behavior to the intuitive concept of the family balance sheet and the
value of human capital. In the authors’ words, “Our hypothesis is that
marriage may work as a sort of safe asset when women make portfolio
decisions.” In my words, women focus on the holistic balance sheet of
the family unit and make investment decisions based on all sources of
human capital. After they are married, their holistic balance sheet
gains another source of stable income that then enables them to take
on greater investment risk, even if their so-called personal risk toler-
ance remains unchanged.
In Italy, divorce did not become legal until the mid-1970s. As you
might imagine, the Roman Catholic Church tried hard to prevent the
legalization of divorce by lobbying for various referendums when the
legislation was introduced, but by 1974, it was (finally) possible to
divorce in Italy. Initially couples could obtain a divorce only after five
years of legal separation, but the (reported) divorce rate jumped from
virtually zero in the early 1970s to almost 30 percent by the end of the
decade. By 2006, the Italian divorce rate was approaching 50 percent.
The reason this is relevant to our study is that as divorce rates
increase—all over the world, and not just in Italy—you would expect
to see a gradual erosion of the perception of marriage as a safe asset.
In other words, the observed difference between the financial capital
allocations of (currently) married females and (currently) single
females should weaken. And, in fact, that is exactly what our Italian
authors observed over the 18 years of data. They conclude, “The dif-
ferential behavior of single women has evolved over time, and this
evolution, rather than being determined by exogenous [external] vari-
ations in risk attitudes, can be related to the increased incidence of
divorce and the expansion of female labor market participation. Our
results suggest that women’s perception of marriage as a safe asset, as
reflected by their portfolio choices, has been shaped by the transfor-
mation of the structure of the family and society.” In other words,
Italian women are no longer placing as much stock, literally, in mar-
riage as a safe asset but are hedging their risk (of marriage break-
down) by increasingly investing like single women.
From my perspective, these findings fit quite nicely with my posi-
tion that many of the decisions people face over their human life
cycle, such as marriage and the possibility of divorce, are (at least par-
tially) driven by holistic balance sheet and income smoothing consid-
erations. That is, when you make milestone decisions, whether about
kids or marriage (or divorce), you should always keep an eye on the
financial angle.
14. Scott, Small, and Finkel, “Fatal (Fiscal) Attraction: Spendthrifts and Tightwads
in Marriage.”
4 • ARE KIDS INVESTMENTS AND CAN MARRIAGES DIVERSIFY? 83
Either way, the results of the above study serve to remind us that
although it might be optimal to think of the family unit as a diversify-
ing source of human capital, which then allows you to better smooth
consumption and practice (what I call) Long Division in a rational
manner, there are many other psychological factors that can have an
extraneous impact on the monetary milestones in your life. Perhaps
diversification is good when it comes to financial capital, but not when
it comes to emotional attitudes to money. In other words: Don’t count
on your spouse to bail you out of your attitude toward spending—or
understand that if you do, your marriage might suffer as a result.
In late 1994, just around the festive Christmas and New Year’s
time of year, the State of Minnesota carried out what can be
described only as a cruel experiment on its citizens. When I tell this
story to my students, they often shudder and some even groan aloud.
I like to start my lecture (and now this chapter) with the story of this
infamous experiment because it can teach us quite a bit about the
most unpleasant, reoccurring financial milestone in everyone’s life:
April 15, which is the deadline for filing taxes in the United States.1
Here’s what happened in Minnesota. Approximately 47,000 taxpay-
ers who filed their (1993) tax returns properly and on time were cho-
sen at random in April 1994 by the Commissioner of Revenue for an
“experimental treatment” in anticipation of the next tax filing season.
From this large group, one subgroup received a generic letter
reminding them to file their taxes honestly and on time. Another
subgroup was informed they had been selected to access special
assistance in compiling their federal tax returns by calling a free help
line. Finally, about 2,000 people were informed by the commis-
sioner, in writing, that the tax returns they were about to file would
be closely examined by the Department of Revenue. Their names
had been randomly generated, and their selection for this subgroup
had nothing to do with (and was not motivated by) their behavior or
compliance in the previous year. Each one of these 2,000 people was
told in advance that they would be audited no matter what they did,
who they were, and how they completed their tax returns. Under
85
86 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
By the way, all this information was publicly disclosed and pub-
lished (a few years after the experiment) by a number of researchers
involved in the project, including economics professors at the
National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), which is the pri-
mary source for the preceding numbers and the conclusions.2 The
NBER economists analyzed the results of the experiment in conjunc-
tion with the staff from the Minnesota Department of Revenue, and
their published paper offers some novel insights into the magnitude
of tax evasion and the behavior of individuals facing a tax audit.
viewed their inevitable date with the tax inspector like experienced
tourists visiting an outdoor Moroccan bazaar. The tourist wants to
buy an exotic carpet or antique vase at the lowest possible price, and
the vendor wants to extract the highest possible selling price. The
tourist starts with a ridiculously low and actually insulting bid for the
item, which is more often than not followed by a ridiculously high
offer from the vendor. This haggling process continues back and
forth over a number of bargaining rounds until some equilibrium
point is reached between the tourist’s initial bid and the vendor’s ini-
tial offer. And so, what is the true price of the carpet or vase? Who
knows? All that is known is what this particular haggling session
ended with as an agreed-upon price. Tomorrow, later this afternoon,
or next week, the same item will be sold for a completely different
price depending on the next tourist’s bargaining stamina and negoti-
ating appetite and ability. This is what the researchers were saying:
The true amount of tax owing is not fixed but is arrived at through the
process of negotiation.
Thus, perhaps in contrast to a classical view of the tax code and
regulations as setting out fixed and unvarying obligations, there actu-
ally isn’t a universal and rigid agreed-upon measure of undisputable
personal tax liability. Maybe our tax liabilities are subjective and
negotiable, especially for those in the very high-income (and self-
employed) groups that have many more opportunities to haggle. Get
the right tax accountant or tax lawyer on your side of the stand and
your visit to the Moroccan bazaar will turn out differently. Of course,
at relatively low levels of income and in one-dimensional situations in
which your only income comes from an employer from which taxes
have already been withheld by the time you get your pay, your free-
dom to negotiate is down to virtually zero. This is why the Min-
nesotans with income less than $100,000 who now faced a certain
audit were so much more careful and declared greater relative
income. But at higher and more complex levels, it becomes a game
between you and the tax authorities. In fact, perhaps even at lower
levels one should adopt a souk-like attitude to taxes.
Hopefully you can (now) see why the results from the experiment
have direct implications to anyone who faces an income tax milestone.
I am obviously not advocating tax evasion or avoidance. I am advocating
extreme tax awareness, tax vigilance, and tax efficiency.
90 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
Teaching this one-week course has been a revelation for both the stu-
dents and for me. They are fascinated by how people deal with money
milestones in North America, and I am equally fascinated by what
they teach me about how things work in South America.
One of the rather surprising things I learned about financial plan-
ning in Uruguay is that salaries, wages, and income tend to be
reported and discussed on an after-tax as opposed to pre-tax basis.
(This is true in Argentina and Brazil as well.) In other words, if you
happen to be asked (and you are willing to divulge) how much you
earn, the number you give is likely to be in after-tax dollars. This is
not just some odd habit or convention. When you get a job offer and
you are told that your salary is 100,000 pesos, the employer means net
to you, after withholding, after deductions, and after taxes. That’s the
number on the check and deposited into your bank account as your
take-home pay. Now compare this to North America. When I got my
first part-time summer job (back in New York City in the 1980s), I
was shocked to get my first paycheck. The number was nothing near
what had been promised in my employment contract! Then, after a
few minutes, it hit me. Taxes were owed and were being deducted at
source. The salary I had been promised was on a pretax basis. On an
after-tax basis (that is, the dollars I could actually consume), the num-
bers were 30 percent lower. Moreover, in some jurisdictions and at
higher income levels, the gross versus net can hit 50 percent.
When I tell my South American students that you can be prom-
ised and guaranteed $100,000 in salary, but never really get that
(ever) because of taxes, they chuckle at the naiveté of Americans and
Canadians who are fooled by pretax numbers. In fact, they can’t help
but wonder why anybody bothers to quote, reference, or cite on any-
thing but an after-tax basis. I think there is much to learn from these
Uruguayans. It’s time to focus much closer attention on the after-tax
returns, after-tax income, and the general tax efficiency of our
investments and our personal income statement. That is: Keep an
eye on your business partner throughout the entire year, not just in
April.
92 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
think about it, getting a lump sum and large refund after you file your
tax returns, and getting a smaller-than-required paycheck during the
year, violates the number one axiom of money milestones: Long Divi-
sion. Getting a large payment later instead of many smaller earlier
ones is the exact opposite of consumption smoothing.
According to two economists at the University of Michigan and the
Federal Reserve Board, the puzzling preference for over-withholding
is especially prevalent among individuals with low and moderate
incomes.4 These economists designed and helped administer a ques-
tionnaire that they sent to more than a thousand such households,
partially to understand why they were engaging in this seemingly irra-
tional behavior. The authors of this study (and their staff) interviewed
more than 1,000 households in the Detroit metropolitan area, where
the median income is approximately $49,000 per year. They were
careful to skew their sampling toward lower and middle-income fam-
ilies. Participants were asked whether they received a tax refund (80
percent of those who filed said yes), whether they used a tax preparer
to help them file the returns (66 percent had), and whether they
received an advance against their refund (a refund anticipation loan,
which can be quite costly in terms of interest rates).
However, here is where it is puzzling. Respondents were asked
specifically if they would like to get “a paycheck that is $100 larger
each month than your current one, with a tax refund that is $1,200
smaller.” This question was reversed, and the same group was also
asked if they would rather get “a paycheck that was $100 smaller each
month, with a tax refund that is $1,200 larger at the end of the year.”
No matter how the question was phrased, it seems that over one-third
of the group would rather have more withheld in exchange for a big-
ger refund—that actually has a lower present discounted value. More
than half the participants were happy with the status quo (that is,
their smaller paycheck and larger refund), and less than 20 percent of
the group “woke up” to the financial advantage and stated that yes,
they actually would like less withheld and a smaller refund.
The authors were struck by the lack of rationality in all this and
not just because it violates some theory of how people are supposed
to behave. They found that a large majority of low and middle income
taxpayers would prefer to over-withhold and pay more taxes than
needed so that they could get a refund at tax filling time. In other
words, “many of [these] individuals would like to use the federal with-
holding system in effect to save in a temporarily illiquid manner.”
They note that, in contrast to peoples’ observed behavior, “many [low-
and middle-income people] would benefit from having their refund
distributed evenly throughout the year, particularly in light of the
credit constraints and high cost borrowing opportunities available to
this group.” The authors ultimately conclude by saying “that tax filers
want to over-withhold means they are willing to pay in order to save.”
That is, their study found that people with less money and a clear
identified need for the tax return funds do not take advantage of
opportunities to put that (their!) money in their pocket earlier—and
they actually, in effect, pay the government for the use of their money
before it is refunded to them—both in foregone interest and because
a high proportion of the people surveyed take out refund anticipation
loans and “pay a non-trivial fee to a tax preparer, in order to expedite
the receipt of a tax refund.”
In the end, the researchers determined that this phenomena falls
outside the realm of rational behavior and could be explained only as
suggesting that tax filers “seek a pre-commitment device against the
tendency to over-consume.” That is, the households were ensuring
they didn’t overspend during the year, by allowing their “business
partner” to keep more than the partner’s share of income as a kind of
informal loan until tax time. Effective? Maybe. Irrational? For sure.
have to worry about paying any capital gains (and hence income)
taxes until you sell the investment at a profit. In between the pur-
chase and sale, the only taxes you have to concern yourself with are
possible interest (on bonds) and dividends (on stocks) that you might
receive during the holding period. These are taxable in the year in
which you receive them.
Now let’s think about a typical mutual fund that invests in a com-
bination of (many) stocks and (many) bonds. If the manager of the
mutual fund holds on to those stocks and bonds—and doesn’t buy
and sell them very often—then the only taxes you, as a fund holder,
must worry about are the same dividend payments and interest
income that are passed through to you.
On the other hand, if the fund manager engages in frequent trad-
ing of the investments, and turns over the stocks and bonds on a reg-
ular basis, you might find yourself paying capital gains on profits
made by the manager, even though you bought and held the mutual
fund itself. Therefore, when a mutual fund manager who buys and
sells various stocks and bonds advertises that it earned 10 percent (for
example) in a given year, there are three quite different possibilities
for how this 10 percent was obtained:
• The entire 10 percent might be due to interest or dividends
received, or both, even if the underlying securities themselves
didn’t increase in value.
• Alternatively, the stocks and bonds in the fund might have
increased in value without being sold, and in addition, they
earned some dividends and interest.
• Finally, the return might result from the investments them-
selves being sold for a profit.
All three options and any combination of these options can lead
to the 10 percent. Now, this whole discussion might seem rather aca-
demic. After all, who cares how the 10 percent came about, as long as
it’s 10 percent? But from a tax point of view, how the return was
derived can make an enormous difference. If the bulk of the gains
came from “realized gains” (when a security is sold after having
appreciated in price), you, as the mutual fund shareholder, will be
liable for much more in taxes than if the gains were unrealized. Typi-
cally, mutual fund shareholders will be informed at the end of the tax
96 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
year (by the company, your broker, or your advisor) exactly how much
is taxable and how much is deferred.
Now, here is where this gets interesting. When you go into a local
bank, credit union, or savings and loan association and are told that
the interest rate on a one-year deposit is 5 percent, this obviously
means that a $100 investment will grow to $105 by the end of the
year. But remember, if these funds are sitting outside of a tax shelter
like an IRA (or RRSP in Canada) or 401(k) plan, the $5 gain will be
taxable. So, really, you don’t get $5 on the $100 investment; you don’t
really get 5 percent. Yet, the bank can advertise 5 percent as the inter-
est rate. The same thing applies to mutual funds. They can advertise
that a fund earned 10 percent last year, but this is only on a pretax
basis. On an after-tax basis this number can be as low as 5 percent
depending on how much of the gains within the fund were realized
versus unrealized.5 Moreover, when investment fund companies
advertise that their funds beat 95 percent of all other funds, or that
Fund A was better than Fund B, all this is only on a pretax basis (and
is actually applicable only to people who don’t pay taxes).
Reversals of Fortune
In fact, a very intriguing (and early) study by two Stanford Uni-
versity economists, published by the National Bureau of Economic
Research in 1993, examined the performance and growth of U.S.
mutual funds during the 1963–1992 period on both a pretax and
after-tax basis.6 They calculated and compared the return that a hypo-
thetical taxable investor would receive in each of these funds. They
then arrived at the rather surprising result that “the differences
between the relative ranking of funds on a before and after-tax basis
5. Recently the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) in the United States
has imposed disclosure guidelines on mutual funds for reporting after-tax returns.
The SEC requires mutual funds to disclose after-tax returns for one-, five- and
ten-year periods in prospectuses and fund profiles prepared after February 15,
2002. After-tax returns must be calculated using the highest individual federal
income tax rate. In Canada, this is not the case, and this disclosure is not provided
by the companies.
6. Dickson and Shoven, “Ranking Mutual Funds on an After-Tax Basis.”
5 • GOVERNMENT TAX AUTHORITIES 97
are dramatic, especially for middle and high income investors. For
example, one fund that ranks in the 19th percentile on a pretax basis
ranks in the 61st percentile for an upper income taxable investor.”
This means that a fund that seemingly performed worse than fully 81
percent of its peers when viewed on a pre-tax basis rose to beat out 61
percent of those peers when the after-tax return is considered.
These types of result are not limited to U.S. mutual funds. In fact,
partially inspired by the previously mentioned study, together with
some colleagues, I conducted a similar study in Canada using Cana-
dian mutual funds. The study was published in the Canadian Tax
Journal, and the results were similar to the United States.7 We exam-
ined ten years’ worth of investment returns from 343 equity and bal-
anced mutual funds managed by Canadian companies. Overall, we
found that the ranking of mutual funds on a pretax basis is signifi-
cantly different from their ranking on an after-tax basis. Moreover,
two different funds that had relatively similar performance on a pre-
tax basis had a 46 percent chance their ranking was reversed on an
after-tax basis. We also found that mutual funds that reported top
quartile (top 25 percent) performance on a pretax basis often had mis-
erable (bottom quartile) performance on an after-tax basis. Finally, for
someone in the highest marginal tax bracket, the average mutual fund
lost approximately 135 basis points to taxes on fund distributions.
Over time, the cost of inefficient income tax management can
wipe out any investment gains beyond low-turnover index funds. In
other words, you can hire a brilliant manager to buy and sell stocks
for you, and they might outsmart the overall market by a few percent-
age points each year. But, if that entire extra return, which the profes-
sional investment managers have christened using the Greek symbol
alpha, comes from excessive buying and selling, you might end up
worse off after tax. This point was made succinctly in a lovely article
that was written by two well-known money managers in 1993 and
published in the Journal of Portfolio Management, appropriately
called “Is Your Alpha Big Enough to Cover Its Taxes?”8 In contrast to
you would be wrong on two counts. First, if you are in the 40-percent
tax bracket (just to keep things simple), your true (net) financial
capital is only $160,000, because $40,000 of the money in the IRA
belongs to your partner, the tax authority. This is not a hypothetical
liability in the distant future: It belongs to them today. Second, of the
$160,000 that is yours, approximately 62.5 percent is invested in
stocks and 37.5 percent is invested in bonds. You have more equity
than you think, and you might want to lighten up on the risk.
It might take time to get used to this way of thinking, but it is per-
fectly consistent with the overall approach I have taken during the
entire book. To help you out, I’ve created a calculator at www.qwema.ca
that enables you to divide your assets to take into account the amount
you owe your “permanent business partner,” the tax authority. And
I’ve included a calculator that can help you calculate the tax implica-
tions of investing in tax-paid or tax-deferred accounts—IRAs versus
Roth IRAs in the United States and Tax-Free Savings Accounts ver-
sus RRSPs in Canada. And, finally, I’ll talk more about asset alloca-
tion and how human capital affects the mix later in Chapter 8
(“Portfolio Construction: What Asset Class Do You Belong To?”), but
hopefully you get the main idea here.
Bottom line, from now on, please, next time anybody quotes an
investment return, interest rate, salary or wage, ask yourself—and
him or her—what does this imply on an after-tax tax basis? Make
sure your perpetual tax partner doesn’t get more than their fair share
of your hard-earned cash. This money milestone is one that you
should pay attention to on a daily basis.
1. In Canada, the median mortgage amount for a principal residence jumped from
$79,490 to $93,000 between 1999 and 2005 (in constant 2005 dollars), and the
proportion of the personal balance sheet occupied by the primary residence
increased from 36.3 percent to 38.6 percent over the same period. See Statistics
Canada, The Wealth of Canadians.
101
102 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
2. As quoted in Streitfeld, “The Pain of Selling a Home for Less Than the Loan.”
6 • CAN YOU EAT YOUR HOUSE OR WILL IT EVER PAY DIVIDENDS? 103
Region % Change
Chicago -7.9%
Las Vegas -36.7%
New York -0.9%
Detroit -34.3%
Seattle 15.6%
Minneapolis -20.9%
Composite-10 index -15.28%
2010/2011, but the fact remains that housing can decline in value, and
for prolonged periods. It is definitely not a risk-free investment.
This distinction is basic, and it will not come as a surprise to any-
one reading this book. And yet, it seems to me that this back-to-basics
element of the housing money milestone has gotten downplayed in
the discussions of housing over the past few years, which have
focused on housing as an investment—whether “good” (when hous-
ing values are rising) or “bad” (when values are falling).
3. Data taken from the American Housing Survey, conducted by Bureau of the
Census for the Department of Housing and Urban Development.
6 • CAN YOU EAT YOUR HOUSE OR WILL IT EVER PAY DIVIDENDS? 105
4. Yao and Zhang, “Optimal Life-Cycle Asset Allocation with Housing as Collateral.”
See also Kraft and Munk, “Optimal Housing, Consumption and Investment
Decisions over the Life Cycle.”
6 • CAN YOU EAT YOUR HOUSE OR WILL IT EVER PAY DIVIDENDS? 107
5. The PSID is a longitudinal panel survey of U.S. families that measures eco-
nomic, social, and health factors over the life course and across generations.
Data have been collected from the same families and their descendants since
1968.
108 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
6. Yao and Zhang, “Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Choices with Risky Hous-
ing and Borrowing Constraints.”
6 • CAN YOU EAT YOUR HOUSE OR WILL IT EVER PAY DIVIDENDS? 109
other forms of “glue” that hold a community together. But what does
social capital have to do with housing? There is actually a strong link
between home ownership and social capital, which is one of the rea-
sons policy makers in the United States (and, to a lesser extent, in the
rest of the world) have encouraged and promoted homeownership.
Please note that I am not veering from my mandate of discussing
money milestones and personal finance when I mention the role of
social capital. The reality is that social capital also serves a smoothing
function. How so? If you live in a community or society with high
social capital values, you are much less likely to experience disrup-
tions in your standard of living. Think about the neighborhood or
community where you live. If you happen to run out of flour while
baking a cake or need to jump-start your vehicle to get to work one
morning, how many neighbors within short walking distance would
you feel comfortable borrowing the cup of flour or jumper cables
from? All of them? Some of them? None of them? And do you know
the names of all your immediate neighbors?
These might sound like unimportant and even off-topic ques-
tions, but they can have a profound impact on financial matters.
Although it doesn’t belong on the personal balance sheet, social capi-
tal is an asset class you can invest in by creating it. Individuals can do
this on a community-specific basis; for example, you can arrange a
monthly “neighbors’ barbeque” for everyone on the block. Specific
communities (and religions and schools) can produce social capital as
well. Researchers—mostly sociologists—have developed indices of
social capital that they’ve used to indentify regions of the country that
score highly, versus poorly, in this dimension. (Apparently Vermont
and Minnesota score highly but Georgia and Tennessee do not.)
At this point, you may be asking, what does all this have to do with
housing?
Well, according to a recent study by researchers at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago and the Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency; housing, social capital, and financial well-being are all
intertwined.7 According to the authors, greater homeownership rates
percent less likely to default on credit cards and 32 percent less likely to
file for bankruptcy. Finally, homeowners—and keep in mind that home
ownership provides another proxy for social capital—are 17 percent
less likely to default and 25 percent less likely to declare bankruptcy.
In sum, I suspect that people grossly underestimate their home
ownership expenditures. They overestimate the amount by which the
house will appreciate over time. They tend to live where they work
(obviously), which means that their housing capital (which is a subset
of financial capital) is exposed to the same economic risks as their
human capital. And yet, the one thing an investment in housing might
achieve is that it creates its own investment in social capital. Perhaps
this one factor outweighs the many other negatives and makes this
particular money milestone worth pursuing.
113
114 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
2. At the end of 2007, according to the Canadian Life and Health Insurance Asso-
ciation, 20 million Canadians owned a combined amount of more than $3.1 tril-
lion of life insurance.
7 • INSURANCE SALESMEN AND WARRANTY PEDDLERS 119
insurance company will pay out the death benefit (or face value) of
the policy to your beneficiaries.
I explored the concept of insurance as a human capital hedge in
my earlier book (Are You a Stock or a Bond?). At this point I want to
simply emphasize and remind you that as you age and progress
through the human life cycle, the argument (and the need) for life
insurance to protect human capital is much weaker because the value
of human capital declines with age. When you are retired, for example,
it is hard to justify the payment of large insurance premiums to protect
human capital that has a low value. So, in preparation for retirement,
you should have converted a large portion of your human capital into
financial capital, and you should thus be more concerned about pro-
tecting this financial capital that must now sustain you for the rest of
your natural life than protecting your human capital (or your phone!).
Indeed, likely the only argument for maintaining a large and perma-
nent insurance policy at advanced ages is for estate planning or tax
purposes. Life insurance is about smoothing income for your family
and loved ones across alternative future universes: It is not meant as a
consolation prize for the living or as a reward to your spouse for put-
ting up with an old cranky nuisance (that would be you, in retirement).
If you have insurance at later stages in life, the premiums you’ve been
paying and will continue to pay for many years to come would have
likely been better off deposited in some bank account.
According to historians, the origin of the idea that life insurance is
for protecting the value of human capital, and that you should accord-
ingly use an estimate of total future earning power to determine a
suitable amount of life insurance, is Professor Solomon Huebner. Just
shy of a hundred years ago, Huebner taught the first formal courses
on life insurance at the Wharton School of Business at the University
of Pennsylvania. He also wrote the foundational textbooks on life
insurance and helped create the modern insurance industry associa-
tion.3 Huebner outlined his “human life value” approach to life insur-
ance in a series of lectures beginning in 1919. An academic review of
3. For an interesting history on this impact of Dr. Huebner on the entire insurance
industry, see the article by Creek, “Solomon Huebner and the Development of
Life Insurance Sales Professionalism.”
120 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
4. Calculations based on the RP-2000 Healthy Annuitant and the 1996 Annuity
2000 mortality tables, from the Society of Actuaries. See www.soa.org for more.
5. Miller, Page, Stevens, and Filipski, “Why Are Recessions Good for Your
Health?”
122 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
just a public policy curiosity. For those concerned about the holistic
management of risk for the household and the value of all assets on
the personal balance sheet, this evidence brings yet another dimension
to the interaction between human capital, financial capital, and the
role of insurance. If you follow the findings of the research paper, you
can almost think of health itself as a personal asset class that is nega-
tively correlated to the economic environment and the performance
of your stock portfolio. (That is, your health moves in the opposite
direction to the economy.) At the extreme, it seems long periods of
unemployment and reduced income, paradoxically, might imply that
you need to save even more money for retirement. How ironic is that?
6. See Auerbach and Kotlikoff, “The Adequacy of Life Insurance Purchases,” and
Bernheim, Lorni, Gokhale, and Kotlikoff, “The Mismatch Between Life Insur-
ance Holdings and Financial Vulnerabilities.”
7 • INSURANCE SALESMEN AND WARRANTY PEDDLERS 123
socioeconomic spectrum. (Again, you can see that averages can con-
ceal as much as they reveal.)
Another puzzling phenomenon regarding the purchase of life
insurance was reported by researchers at Florida State University.
While examining comprehensive sales data from national insurance
companies, the researchers noticed odd and unpredictable spikes in
the regional purchase of life insurance. They couldn’t explain these
results by looking at promotional offers, discounts, or any other supply-
driven explanations. But, they noticed that, for example, suddenly and
seemingly without cause, weekly sales of life insurance in the State of
Georgia would triple. Or over the course of a month, five times as
many people would apply for life insurance compared to typical
sales volumes.
After scratching their collective heads about this, and running a
variety of statistical tests on the numbers, the researchers decided to
scan the local papers for clues. Perhaps, they figured, a local celebrity
had died, or there had been a major traffic accident fatality or other
corresponding sudden increases in mortality. But it turns out, oddly
enough, that the answer was not in the obituaries section of the news-
paper but in the front page and the weather sections. The regions
with these inexplicable jumps in life insurance purchases had also
recently experienced spikes in serious hurricanes and tornados. Now,
these natural disasters didn’t necessarily kill or even seriously injure
anyone. Sure, the property damage was extensive, which you’d think
might increase the demand for an interest in property and home
insurance, but surprisingly, it also increased the demand for life insur-
ance. According to the researchers this irrational effect can actually
persist for years after large and well-publicized natural catastrophes.
In their words: “Research indicates that the occurrence of a catastro-
phe may lead to an increase in risk perception, risk mitigation, and
insurance purchasing behavior.”7 I think this example actually gets to
the core of how most people treat life and other insurance transac-
tions. That is: Our decisions tend to be emotional and fear-driven, as
opposed to fully rational. Few consumers treat the insurance mile-
stone as part of the life cycle smoothing exercise I previously
7. Fier and Carson, “Catastrophes and the Demand for Life Insurance.”
124 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
TABLE 7.1 You Are 45 Years Old. What Are Multiple Paths of the
Future?
Event (Possible Probability It Will Magnitude (If It Happens to You)
State of Nature) Happen to You
Earth gets sucked No reliable data We are all dead. Don’t bother worry-
into a black hole available ing about it!
Get struck by 5–20% Can be surprisingly benign, although
lightning death from cardiac arrest is common.
Get life insurance if you need it, not
“lightning-strike insurance.”
Get sick from the 20% Annoying. A few days of missed work.
flu this year Do not insure.
Your $110 phone 100% Trivial. No disruption. No insurance!
breaks
As you can see, some events are extremely likely and not very
costly; whereas others are extremely unlikely and extremely costly.
You want to insure (that is, smooth across alternative universes) only
those events that have a relatively small chance of happening and that
are likely to disrupt your and your family’s standard of living.
I’ve provided you with some irrational and rational ways to think
about insurance milestone decisions. Now you might be wondering
how I personally handle these decisions. How rational am I in practice?
7 • INSURANCE SALESMEN AND WARRANTY PEDDLERS 125
actually thought it covered. After all, you are making a claim on your
own reserve fund. You only have yourself to argue with.
In closing: The point of insurance is to smooth your lifestyle over
alternative universes. Insurance isn’t an investment or a form of pro-
tective magic. It is important to understand that the investment
return from buying insurance is always negative. That is, you can’t
make money “on average,” and the insurance company make money
“on average” at the same time. Instead, they charge you—and every-
one else—more than the amount they expect to pay out. Otherwise
the company would go bankrupt, and you wouldn’t get paid either.
So, take advantage of this risk pooling mechanism—but don’t go
there for a leisurely swim.
129
130 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
Robert
Ending Account Value: Sally
End Date
know a Robert or two. For Robert, and others like him, it seems as
though the “stocks for the long run,” buy-and-hold approach has not
worked out. Indeed, the stocks for the long run mantra is increas-
ingly in question: At the end of June 2009, U.S. stocks have under-
performed long-term Treasury bonds for the past 5, 10, 15, 20, and
25 years. In addition, new research on the earliest period of stock
returns has suggested there are methodological flaws in how returns
have been calculated that should cause investors to seriously ques-
tion whether what we’ve been told about stock market returns over
the long period holds any water today.1 Now, I am quite sure that
most prudent financial advisors would never advise Robert to allo-
cate 100 percent of his retirement account to equities, whether U.S.
or international. Perhaps his portfolio would be tempered with some
asset allocation to bonds and other asset classes. The possible alloca-
tions are endless—and indeed, some alternate Roberts might be
ahead of Sally. At the same time, many others who have been buying
and selling (as opposed to simply buying and holding) for the last 20
years have ended with much worse account values than all the previ-
ously mentioned scenarios. A March 2009 study finds that although
the SP500 produced an annualized return of 8.35 percent over the
20-year period ending on December 31, 2008, the average equity
investor who jumps in and out of the market had a return of just 1.87
percent during the same period, or less than inflation.2 Like Robert,
the average investor failed to beat even the risk-free return available
from T-bills. And consider that beating Sally’s results isn’t setting the
bar very high, given the little skill that implementing her strategy
requires.
So what are the alternatives to ending up in Robert’s shoes?
Surely Sally’s strategy isn’t the only appropriate investment approach
to save for retirement; might Robert’s strategy ultimately outperform
Sally’s? Absolutely. However, the reality is you don’t know whether it
will, it will take time to find out, and you don’t even know how long it
might take. Right now, what I do know is that over the 19-year time
horizon I examined, which is as long as many people’s entire invest-
ment savings time span, Robert’s strategy did not end up producing a
1. See Zweig, “Does Stock Market Data Really Go Back 200 Years?”
2. DALBAR, Inc., QAIB 2009.
8 • PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION: WHAT ASSET CLASS DO YOU BELONG TO? 133
premium over Sally’s very basic, risk-free approach. And it isn’t very
useful (to Robert) to suggest that Robert, who wants to retire now,
adjust his timeframe to some uncertain period so that his stocks for
the long run, buy-and-hold approach has a chance of producing
results that surpass Sally’s.
So what are investors to do? In the next section, I take a look at
some alternative ways to approach investing for retirement, including
some new ways to think about your approaches to risk and your labor
market income, and—to revisit the Introduction: “Human Capital:
Your Greatest Asset”—how to include your human capital when you
allocate your overall retirement savings portfolio. These new ways of
thinking take us beyond the standard retirement planning concepts of
investment time horizons, risk aversion, and investor confidence.
are many other careers whose wage profiles are relatively sensitive to
these kinds of changes. Income from careers that are not correlated
to economic cycles can be thought of as bond-like, whereas income
from careers that are correlated can be thought of as stock-like.
Now, at the outset of this section, I said I was going to explain my
thinking about the conditions under which individuals should and
should not expose their financial capital to stock market risk. What I
am going to suggest is that the amount of risk you take with your finan-
cial capital should be determined holistically, by including both human
and financial capital in the equation, and by assessing and including
the investment characteristics of your income from human capital.
Ok, that’s a mouthful. Let’s unpack this a bit. The two dimensions
I asked you to think about earlier are whether your labor market
income is flexible (versus rigid), and whether it is correlated with
financial market cycles (whether it is stock-like or bond-like). When
these two dimensions come together, you can refer to them as FeBo
(flexible, bond-like) and RiSo (rigid, stock-like).
All else being equal, having a FeBo-like job—think of a barber
who can set his own hours, work on weekends if he wants, and earn
income that is relatively immune to a recession—means you can
afford to invest a substantial portion of your financial capital in more
risky ventures like the stock market. This is because if things don’t
work out for your financial portfolio, you know that your human cap-
ital will not be affected. More important, you can “undo” the damage
done to your wealth by a falling stock market by working some extra
hours (weekends, late nights) to repair your portfolio. Sure, this isn’t
your preferred strategy, but it’s a backup plan.
In contrast to the barber, think of the investment banker’s admin-
istrative staff at a large investment house. I consider this to be RiSo
human capital. They probably don’t have the flexibility to work over-
time, and yet if something happens to their company or the stock
markets, they are less likely to be employed, less likely to earn a
bonus, and less likely to derive dividends from their human capital.
They might earn more than the barber, but the RiSo-like characteris-
tics of the job implies that their retirement savings and investments
should be allocated more toward safer bonds.
Individuals with rigid (nonflexible) income that is sensitive to the
stock market should have little if any equity exposure in their financial
136 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
Total Human
$500 $200
Capital
+ +
Financial
$100 $200
Capital
= =
Total
$600 $400
Capital
Desired
Holistic
60% 40% 60% 40%
Risky/Safe
Mix
Implied
Holistic $360 $240 $240 $160
Portfolio
Financial
Capital $110 ($10) $190 $10
Allocation
110% -10% 95% 5%
Note: All dollar values are in thousands
asset allocation of 110% risky assets and -10% safe assets. In other
words, he borrows 10% of the risky portfolio value and invests that as
well. In sum, his holistic allocation will be 60% risky and 40% safe.
There are many possible permutations, but hopefully you get the point.
their “risk aversion” has decreased, but that their existing assets have
moved from the human capital side of the ledger to the financial cap-
ital side, and the correct risky/risk-free allocation should be main-
tained for the entire personal balance sheet.
If, on the other hand, your labor market income is rigid and
stock-like (RiSo), in the early years of your savings you will also want
to allocate a higher proportion of your financial capital to safe risk-
free assets such as bonds. As you age, and your total balance sheet is
(ideally) composed increasingly of financial capital, the proportion of
risk you can take with your financial capital will increase while your
holistic risky/risk-free ratio will remain constant.
In other words, age or time alone doesn’t necessarily determine
how much of your nest egg (investment, financial capital) should be
allocated to risky stocks versus safe bonds. It really depends on the
overall composition of your balance sheet.
It must be noted that there are many other variables in retire-
ment income planning this model doesn’t include. We haven’t consid-
ered tax (see Chapter 5, “Government Tax Authorities: Partners,
Adversaries, or Bazaar Merchants?”), pensions (Chapter 9, “Retire-
ment: When Is It Time to Shutter the Well and Close the Mine?”),
how to convert financial capital to income streams in retirement, and
a whole host of important issues. However, what this chapter intends
to provide is a new and hopefully useful way to approach the alloca-
tion of your personal financial resources—one which explicitly takes
your human capital into account.
Do you now wonder what the proper allocation of your financial
assets is, given your holistic personal balance sheet? I have included a
calculator that can enable you to work this out for yourself, at www.
qwema.ca. You can model different proportions and scenarios to see
the varying ideal allocations of your financial capital.
multiple bear and bull markets. That is, it seems as though the con-
ditions that prevailed during MBA students’ courses of study (and
which affected their chances of working on Wall Street) actually
impacted their career paths not just immediately out of school but
two decades later! If you went to work on Wall Street right after
graduating, your likelihood of working there later on was actually 50
percent higher.
Although it might not be surprising that careers and job paths are
rather “sticky,” it is interesting to quantify the magnitude of this
effect. The study found that 15 years after graduation, investment
bankers from Stanford’s MBA program could expect to earn $1.2 mil-
lion per year, whereas management consultants earned half of that, at
approximately $645,000 per year. Whether any of these (historical
average) numbers will persist going forward remains to be seen. But
one thing is certain, the state of the economy and the market can have
an enormous impact on your lifetime earnings—not just when you
enter the labor market but throughout your career. The final sen-
tence in the article makes this point—and is the reason I have men-
tioned this study. The author writes, and I quote, “The results also
suggest that risk-averse MBA students, especially those interested in
Wall Street careers, may want to take actions to insure themselves
against the random wealth effects imposed by stock returns while
they study. These students should short the stock market upon enter-
ing school so that their portfolios hedge their expected labor income.”
In finance, short selling—also known as shorting—is the practice
of selling assets, usually securities, borrowed from a third party with
the intention of buying identical assets back at a later date to return to
the lender. A short seller hopes to profit from a decline in the value of
the assets, when he will pay less to repurchase the assets than he
received on selling them. So in this case, MBA students could use
short-selling strategies so that if markets decline while they are in
school, thus decreasing their expected salaries upon graduation, they
can nevertheless generate personal profits. In essence, this strategy
allows the student to profit in both bull and bear markets—in a bull
market, from their MBA degree, and in a bear market, from the short
selling strategy. In sum: Your current financial capital allocation
should be based on the risk classification of your human capital, even
before you get your first job!
8 • PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION: WHAT ASSET CLASS DO YOU BELONG TO? 143
B’s restaurant, your meal is now one bowl of salad and four slices of
pie—as though the menu determined the outcomes!5 Clearly, this is
a form of long division and smoothing, but it does not make much
sense. After all, just because the owner of the restaurant decided to
offer six different kinds of pie at the dessert buffet, doesn’t mean you
should have one slice of each for lunch.
5. This effect was dubbed the 1/n heuristic, which describes the finding that the
greater the number of choices available (n), the finer people sliced their invest-
ment allocations.
6. Bodie, Merton, and Samuelson. “Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice
in a Life-Cycle Model.”
8 • PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTION: WHAT ASSET CLASS DO YOU BELONG TO? 145
7. Perhaps the shortest version of Paul Samuelson’s rebuttal of the “stocks for the
long run” argument is summarized in this 1997 quote: “Canny risk averters
should always keep in mind, in a rational, non-paranoid way, the pains they will
feel in...probability-calculated bad-outcome scenarios. (Ask yourself: Will step-
ping down toward a poverty level, when that rarely but inevitably does happen,
outweigh for me the pleasures that occur in those likely outcomes when my
equity nest egg does increase?) When we each do that, those of who truly are
more risk averse will rationally hedge our bets by limiting our exposure to
volatile equities.” As quoted in Bodie, “Letter to the Editor: Are Stocks the Best
Investment for the Long Run?”
146 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
1. North Dakota State Economic Brief, vol. 17 (no. 10), October 2008.
147
148 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
2. Statistics in this paragraph are from the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ National
Compensation Survey: Employee Benefits in Private Industry, available at http:/
/www.bls.gov/NCS/.
3. Pierlot, “A Pension in Every Pot.”
4. Public sector employment stands at about 6.3 percent of the total U.S. labor
force versus 19.7 percent in Canada. U.S. data from Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Canadian data from Statistics Canada.
152 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
All these different demographic and labor market trends have left
future retirees (including the many baby boomers on the verge of
retirement today) with a shrinking pot of money and no guarantees.
In the language of the holistic balance sheet, as pensions have moved
from Defined Benefit to Defined Contribution and even disap-
peared, retirement income liabilities have shifted from the corporate
to the personal balance sheet. In this new reality, you might have a
more marketable and portable human capital than before, you might
have a large sum of financial capital (the Defined Contribution plan)
you are managing, but you now also have to face the liabilities.
This trend of declining pension coverage, to me, is truly a shame,
given the strong link between true (Defined Benefit) pensions and
life cycle smoothing. What you are left with is the increasing personal
importance of the “retirement” milestone for today’s workforce. That
is, providing for your income needs over your lifetime after you have
left the paid labor force is increasingly up to you.
the relatively high personal risk run by those with Defined Contribu-
tion plans.11
12. Milevsky and Promislow, “Florida: Pension Election from Defined Benefit to
Defined Contribution and Back.”
158 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
And so, to conclude the story, when the dust settled on this massive
pension experiment, a mere 4 percent of the people who got the offer
decided to convert or transfer from the pension plan to the investment
plan. Yes, you read that correctly; only four in a hundred people
decided to take the responsibility of accumulating funds and providing
an income stream in retirement upon themselves. The majority of
Floridians were effectively saying, I do not want a number, I want a
pension.
Now, Florida wasn’t an isolated case of one lone southern state
trying to do away with its Defined Benefit pension plan by stealth.
Many other states have considered or are in the process of consider-
ing the same move, and have followed the results of Florida’s process
quite closely. Moreover, the U.S. government, which is responsible
for Social Security, the largest Defined Benefit plan on the planet,
might even go the same route one day. As unlikely as it seems given
the recent performance of the stock market, many commentators
(many more Republicans than Democrats, not surprisingly) have
advocated that the U.S. should follow the model set out in Florida
and allow people to opt out of the Defined Benefit aspect of Social
Security. In fact, although the proposal was heavily criticized and
then abandoned, one of President G.W. Bush’s campaign platforms
in the 2000 election was to offer Americans individual accounts as an
optional alternative to Social Security, similar to Florida’s plan. Isn’t
it interesting that during the same time, the president’s younger
brother was overseeing the Florida experiment? Boy, I would have
loved to be a fly on the wall at their Thanksgiving dinner.
consumption was $50 in cold hard cash and another $50 in the
imputed cost of time. Thus, you really spent $100 baking the cake.
What the study found was that although retirees might appear to
be spending less than one would expect in the first few years of retire-
ment, they are, in fact, substituting their personal time and spending
that time instead! Economists call this “home production.” If you
focus exclusively on the dollars and cents flowing out of their bank
account, you will miss the possibly larger flow of (the dollar value of)
time—you won’t solve the puzzle.
Now, this is more than just a frivolous accounting exercise: It
actually helps refine our understanding of life-cycle planning. This
research can serve a warning sign to those who blithely think they will
need “much less” when they retire. Maybe you’ve seen the evidence
of retirees with (lower) spending getting by on less. Or you might
have personal evidence from a relative who does not spend very
much in retirement. Yet, it would be dangerous to extrapolate this
anecdotal evidence to your own retirement. In all likelihood your
great-aunt is spending more time cooking her own food, shopping for
a better deal on milk and eggs, or standing in line for a half hour to
get the early bird dinner special at Denny’s in Boca. This doesn’t
imply you will be doing the same during your own retirement. You
have to be willing to substitute large amounts of your own time to
reduce your expenditures, or cash outflows. But your total consump-
tion (properly defined to include your time) might only be marginally,
if at all, lower.
given a choice between a lump sum and periodic annuity.17 And there
are a number of companies who offer to convert your annuity into
cash (...at a discount rate of 21 percent).
Ironically, the authors of the study concluded that because so
many people selected the lump sum, despite the fact the annuity was
worth almost twice as much, these (suboptimal?) choices actually
saved the U.S. taxpayers $1.7 billion in severance costs.
Now, some might wonder if this choice was driven by tax consid-
erations, medical concerns, and other such factors. However, the
researchers determined that the choices did not affect the benefits
(or after-tax payments) received by these individuals. It is also hard to
argue that the U.S. government would renege or default on the annu-
ity promise to the U.S. military—after all, they’re the ones with the
guns! Nor can you pin this decision on a lack of sophistication or lack
of education—these are Air Force pilots and officers, after all. These
folks can figure out how to land an F16 on a ship in the middle of the
ocean. I’m sure they can work out the present value of an annuity and
compare it with a lump sum.
So, perhaps the takeaway is what behavioral economists called
anchoring.18 If somebody suddenly and out of the blue offers you a
sum of money, or an offer to take it as a periodic annuity, chances are
people want the money now and do not take the annuity. (Although I
would argue you should take the annuity when the equivalent rate is
19 percent!) They have anchored on the lump sum available today, as
opposed to a stream of income, in smaller amounts, that will flow at
some point later, even if the stream of income adds up to a larger
amount than the lump sum, over time. In contrast, when people work
for an employer for 10, 20, or 30 years under the expectation that they
will get a pension one day, and they are given the option of converting
this into a defined contribution plan (à la Florida), they would rather
have the safety and security of the lifetime pension. That is, they have
17. See, for example, comments from Dr. Joel Slemrod (Professor of Economics at
the University of Michigan) as quoted in Fox, “The Curious Capitalist: How the
Payoff Decisions of Lottery Winners Have Shifted the Income Distribution.”
18. Thaler and Sunstein, Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and
Happiness.
9 • RETIREMENT 165
20. Assets and Health Dynamics of the Oldest-Old (AHEAD) is a national survey of
community-based Americans born in 1923 or earlier. It is sponsored by the
National Institute on Aging. The focus of the AHEAD survey is to understand
the impacts and interrelationships of changes and transitions for older Ameri-
cans in three major domains: health, finances, and family.
9 • RETIREMENT 167
Finally, where does all of this leave you? Ideally, make sure some of
your household retirement income comes from a pension that pays life-
time income for the rest of your life—even if you have to create your
own “pension plan” using purchased annuities. This insures you against
longevity (something I discussed in Chapter 7) and will likely make you
a happier retiree. In addition, most important, if somebody wants to
offer you the choice between a relatively low lump sum and a relatively
higher periodic annuity, or the choice between a Defined Benefit pen-
sion and a Defined Contribution investment account, remember what
happened in sunny Florida. Those folks know retirement.
1. Ok. Technically I don’t eat shrimp. But I’m sure you get the point.
169
170 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
for the most part, every single person can recall—and quite vividly—
some bad financial decision they made in the past. During the fright-
ening period around fall 2008, when banks and insurance companies
were on the verge of failing all around us, answers to this question were
self-evident: everybody regretted the stocks and mutual funds they
held. Then as the real estate crisis played itself out, people regretted
the house they purchased. I also heard from people who regretted the
business deal they partnered on; they regretted the job they accepted;
they regretted the tenant they rented their apartment to; they regret-
ted the car that turned out to be a lemon; and so on. The replies were
fast and furious and easy for people to recollect.
To misquote the great Frank Sinatra, in today’s economy, we’ve
all had quite a few regrets. Hey, who doesn’t have a lousy mutual fund
they should have sold months ago, or an expensive house they shouldn’t
have bought, or a great investment they missed out on. Nearly every-
one has some personal or anecdotal story of financial regret, usually
employing the general syntax: “If only I had...back when...we would
be rich today....” Often these stories are nostalgically transmitted
from parents to children and across generations, which can influence
financial attitudes towards risk taking and decision making for
decades. Everyone has some financial decision they regret.
But then, with these same audiences and groups I follow up with
a subsequent question:
What was the best financial decision you made in your life?
Oddly enough, the replies to this question are fewer and farther
between. The best decision is not immediately obvious or easy to rec-
ollect. Yes, I occasionally hear of the apocryphal penny stock that has
“done very well” or the special mutual fund that “worked out nicely,”
but there is much less conviction and feeling compared to the deci-
sions they regret. Sure, a handful of people talk nostalgically about
the decision to get married or even the decision to get divorced. One
or two mention their grandkids (not the kids, oddly). I even had one
person tell me that the best decision was buying a lottery ticket a few
years ago, which ended-up winning the jackpot! Yet, one thing is
quite clear. The memories aren’t as vivid, the stories aren’t as clear,
and the examples are few. Does this imply that most of their decisions
CONCLUSION 171
have been failures? I doubt it. I believe they are not thinking broadly
enough about what constitutes a regretless financial decision.
Indeed, rarely do people include human capital considerations as
part of their financial decisions, despite the fact they have a much
greater impact on their personal balance sheet. I never heard people
say to me in response to my question: going to college, or not major-
ing in art, or not taking a particular job after college, or insuring the
house that never burned down was the best decision I made.
In fact, these same individuals with so many financial regrets
rarely recollect the fuzzy decisions they made years ago with little
fanfare, which paved the way for their relative prosperity and thriving
daily life. Who commits to memory the job offer they didn’t take from
the company they don’t remember, which then happened to declare
bankruptcy a few years later? Or what about the mutual fund they
briefly considered purchasing, but then forgot about, that was even-
tually frozen or liquidated for pennies on the dollar? Think about it.
You might remember the rare near-miss, but what about the much
more frequent far-miss? Alas, it seems that human beings are hard-
wired to unearth some regret from nearly all outcomes.
Making the best decision at each money milestone in your life is
just as important as NOT making the wrong one, but is obviously less
memorable. As I have argued in this book, it is very important to
properly identify all the money milestones in our life and approach
them in a more strategic manner. Do this by recognizing the interac-
tion between all disparate factors that impact the assets and liabilities
on you personal balance sheet.
Agnew, J.R., L.R. Anderson, J.R. Gerlach, and L.R. Szykman. “Who
Chooses Annuities? An Experimental Investigation of the Role of
Gender, Framing and Defaults.” American Economic Review,
Papers and Proceedings, 2008. Volume 98 (2): 418-22.
Barr, M.S., and J.K. Dokko. Paying to Save: Tax Withholding and
Asset Allocation Among Low and Moderate Income Tax Payers.
Washington, D.C.: Federal Reserve Board, 2007.
177
178 YOUR MONEY MILESTONES
Baum, Sandy, and Jennifer Ma. Trends in College Pricing. The Col-
lege Board, 2008. Available at www.collegeboard.com/trends.
_____. “Letter to the Editor: Are Stocks the Best Investment for the
Long Run?” Economist’s Voice. The Berkeley Electronic Press, Feb-
ruary 2009.
Cole, Shawn, and Gauri Kartini Shastry. “Smart Money: The Effect
of Education, Cognitive Ability, and Financial Literacy on Financial
Market Participation.” Harvard Business School Working Paper
Number 09-071, 2009.
Hankins, Scott, Mark Hoekstra, and Paige Marta Skiba. “The Ticket
to Easy Street? The Financial Consequences of Winning the Lot-
tery.” Vanderbilt Law and Economics Research Paper No. 09-01,
April 27, 2009. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/
abstract=1324845.
Jeffrey, R.H., and R.H. Arnott. “Is Your Alpha Big Enough to Cover
Its Taxes? The Active Management Dichotomy.” Journal of Portfolio
Management 19, no. 3 (Spring 1993): 15–25.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J., and Scott Burns. Spend ‘Till the End: The
Revolutionary Guide to Raising Your Living Standard Today and
When You Retire. Simon and Schuster, 2008.
Miller, D.L, M.E. Page, A.H. Stevens, and M. Filipski. “Why Are
Recessions Good for Your Health?” American Economic Review 99,
no. 2 (2009): 122–127.
North Dakota State Economic Brief, vol. 17 (no. 10), October 2008.
Reed, Matthew. “Student Debt and the Class of 2007.” The Project
on Student Debt, October 2008. http://projectonstudentdebt.org/.
Rick, Scott, Deborah A. Small, and Eli Finkel. “Fatal (Fiscal) Attrac-
tion: Spendthrifts and Tightwads in Marriage.” February 27, 2009.
Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1339240.
“Risk Aversion: The Bonds of Time.” The Economist, January 10, 2009.
Streitfeld, David. “The Pain of Selling a Home for Less Than the
Loan.” New York Times, September 18, 2008.
Yao, R., and H.H. Zhang. “Optimal Life-Cycle Asset Allocation with
Housing as Collateral.” Working Paper, University of North Carolina,
Chapel Hill, March 2004.
Zweig, Jason. “Does Stock Market Data Really Go Back 200 Years?”
Wall Street Journal, July 11, 2009.
INDEX
NUMBERS (ARMs), 102
adjusted gross income
1/n heuristic, 144
(AGI), 86
2007 Survey of Consumer
after-tax returns, 94-96
Finances, 57
allocation of stocks and bonds,
401(k) plans, 143. See also
136-138
retirement
Allowance for Newborn
borrowing from, 61-63
Children, The, 72
A alpha, 97
American Council of Life
“A Pension in Every Pot,” 151 Insurers, 118
accounts American Economic Review,
debt, 53 162, 165
affect on value, 60-66 American International Group
“Debt Literacy, Financial (AIG), xix
Experiences and anchoring, 126
Overindebtedness,” 66 Annual Survey of Colleges, 31
diversity of, 54-56 annuities, 120, 122
education, 31-32 payouts, selecting over lump
home ownership, 101-109 sums, 161-166
management, 56-60 pensions, 153-154
silos, 57 women and, 165-166
smoothing, 67 “Annuities and Retirement
mental, 60 Satisfaction,” 154
taxes on retirement, 98-99 Are You a Stock or a Bond?, 9
adjustable rate mortgages Argentina, 91
185
186 INDEX
W–Z
wages, education
considerations, 20-21
Wall Street Journal, 15
warranties, 113-114, 117
Wealth of Nations, The, 8
well-being, financial, 109
Well-Being of Retirees,
The, 155
West Africa, 49
Wharton School of
Business, 119
“Who Chooses Annuities?,” 165
“Why Are Recessions Good for
Your Health?,” 121
windfalls, 44, 47
winning lotteries, 44, 47
withholding taxes, 92
women and annuities, 165-166
World Bank, 19
www.qwema.ca, 43
Yale University, 29
York University, 2
This page intentionally left blank