The Dynamics of Criminal Behavior: Evidence From Weather Shocks
The Dynamics of Criminal Behavior: Evidence From Weather Shocks
Brian Jacob
Lars Lefgren
Enrico Moretti
ABSTRACT
While the persistence ofcrimiruil activity i.s well documented, this may be due
to persistence in the unobserved determinants of crime. There are good
reasons to believe, however, tluit there may actually be a negative
relationship between crime rales in a particular area due to temporal
displacement. We e.xploit the correlation between weather and crime to
examine the short-run dynamics of crime. Using variation in lagged crime
rates due to weather shocks, we find that the positive serial correlation is
reversed. The.te findings suggest that the long-run impact of temporary
crime-prevention efforts may be .smaller than the short-run effects.
I. Introduction
Brian Jacnh Is assistant pmfessnr at the Jotin F. Kennedy School of Government at Hanard Vuiverxity,
Lars Lefgren is as.^istatit professor of ecnnomirs iil Brighum Young Univerxiiv. and Enrico Moreiti is
associate professor of economics at the University of California al Berkeley. The authors iluink Alberto
Ahadie, Dick Butler, Jne Doyle. Steve Levitt. Lance Loctmer. Erzo Lullinei; Frank Mclntyre. Hruee
Sacerdote. two referees, and seminar participants at the 2004 NtiER Summer Institute, BYU, Wisconsin.
Florida, and 201)4 AEA Meetings for useful suggestions. Email: Jacob can he contacted at
hrianjacoh@hurvard.edu. Leffjren can he contacted at l-lefgren'^hyu.edu. Moretti can he contacted at
moretti@econ.herkeley.edu. The datu used in thi.-i article can he obtained beginning January 2(X)fi
through December 2010 from Enrico Moretti, 549 Evans Halt, Berkeley. CA 94720-iliSO. e-mail:
Moretli(^ econ.herkeley.edu.
ISubmiiled February 2(H)(i; accepted October 2I)O6|
ISSN 022-166X E-ISSN 1548-8004 © 2007 by ihe Board of Regenis of ihe University of Wisconsin System
Figure 1
The Persistence of Crime
Note: This figure shows the coefficieni estimates from two separate regressions of currenl crime (vi-
olenl or property) on ten lags of crime (violent or property). The unit of observalion is a jurisdiclioti-
week. All crime rates are computed by dividing the actual number of crimes during a week hy the
average number of weekly crimes wiihiti the jurisdiclion. Other covariales include jurisdiclion fixed
effects. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the state*year*month level. Observations are
weighted by the mean number of all crimes within the jurisdiction.
crime is even higher—10 percent more property crime this week is associated with
over 3.1 percent more property crime the following week.'
One of the most common explanations for this autocorrelation is that potential
offenders are influenced by the criminal behavior of others. In other words, a crime
committed by one individual increases the likelihood that other individuals in the
same locality will engage in criminal activity. In addition to social interactions that
occur over a long time period through, for example, social learning, criminologists
have long argued that forces such as imitation and revenge may lead to social mul-
tiplier or contagion effects that operate over very short time horizons such as days or
weeks.^ However, the persistence in crime rales over time also could be explained by
the persistence of unobserved factors that determine the costs and benefits of criminal
activity such as police presence and poverty levels. Moreover, there are good reasons
to believe that, particularly over a short lime horizon, Iherc actually may be a nef>alive
relationship between crime rates in a particular area due to displacement^in other
words, the shifting of criminal activity from one time or location to another. A study
1. Correlation is positive for further lags. For example, a 10 percent increase in violent and property crime
this week is associated with 1.1 and 1.6 percent higher crime two weeks later respeetively.
2. See Cook and Goss (1996) and Braga ei al. (2001).
Jacob. Lefgren, and Morelti 491
of juvenile curfews in Detroit, for example, found that afternoon crime nearly dou-
bled after the introduction of the curfew (Hesseiing 1994).
Understanding the dynamics of criminal activity is of interest for both practical
and thcorciical reasons. If the timing of criminal behavior is more elastic to tempo-
rary changes in the costs of crime than is ihe tolal anmunt of criminal activity, then
the effects of a police crackdown in a given week may be partially offset by increases
in criminal activity in subsequent weeks. From a theoretical perspective, understand-
ing the dynamics of criminal activity is important because it sheds light on the max-
imizing behavior of criminals. Beginning with Becker (1968). economic models of
criminal behavior bavc generally been constructed and tested using a static frame-
work. While these models have been very useful in understanding some features
of criminal behavior, they are not well suited to explaining how criminal behavior
changes over time in response to changes in various costs and benefits. The economic
literature on crime dynamics is limited.'*
in this paper, we exploit the correlation between weather and crime to analyze the
short-run dynamics of criminal activity. Our aim is to determine the true persistence
of criminal activity by estimating the causal relationship between crime rates in dif-
ferent time periods within the same locality. In other words, does more crime today
lead to more or less crime tomorrow?
In order to eliminate any spurious serial correlation arising from persistent unob-
served heterogeneity, we use an instrumental variable strategy that is based on
weather shocks. Criminologists have long recognized that weather is strongly corre-
lated with short-run fluctuations in crime, with hotter weather generally associated
with more crime and inclement weather associated with less crime. Drawing on
crime-level data from the FBI's National Incident-Based Reporting System (NIBRS),
we construct a panel of weekly crime data for 116 jurisdictions from 1995-2001.
Simple OLS estimates contirm that violent and property crimes are highly correlated
over time within localities. Weeks with above (below) average crime rates are typi-
cally followed by weeks with above (below) average crime rates, even after control-
ling for a rich set of jurisdiction-specific seasonality effects.
However, when we instrument for lagged crime with lagged weather conditions,
we actually find the opposite result for both property and violent crime. The 2SLS
estimates reveal that weeks with above average crime rates are followed hy weeks
with below average crime rates. Notably, our results do not appear to be driven by
the persistence in weather conditions over time, or displacement of legal economic
activity. Our models control for a series of jurisdiction-specific seasonality measures
so that our identification essentially relies on deviations in expected weather patterns
that influence crime rates in a particular locale.
The magnitude of the displacement is substantial. A 10 percent increase in violent
crime due tu a weather shock reduces violent criminal activity by about 2.6 percent
3. Similarly, prior work diKunierits Ihal juvenile violence peaks in the afier-school hours on school days
and ill the evenings on nonschool days (Jacob and Lefgren 2003).
4. Otie notable exception is Lochner (19991.
5. ScvLTal channels are potentially resp<jnsilile for this correlation. Psychologists have shown ihai higher
icmperatiircs increase aggression directly (.'Xnderson 2{K11). Allcmalively. adverse weather conditions
may iiffeci the cost of execuling a paniciilar crime and/or Ihe availability and actions of potential victims.
We discuss the implicutitms of these various channels in later sections.
492 The Journal of Human Resources
6. The value of property stolen also displays signilicanl displacement: weeks where ihe value of siolen
properly Is high are followed by weeks where the value is low.
7. See, for example, the Mudies of [axi drivers by Farber (2005) and Camerer, Babcock. Lowenstien. and
Thaler (1997).
8. Sec studies of welfare recipienis—for example. Grogger and Michalop<»ulos (2003).
9. Note ihut we are not suggesting ihat the effects of such crackdowns •"decay" over time, but rather than
criminals shift criminal behavior to a later date.
Jacob. Lefgren, and Moretii 493
A. Property Crime
Given the financial motivations underlying property crime, a standard labor supply
Irainework provides considerable insight regarding the potential displacement of
property crime. Displacement, if it occurs, would plausibly come about through an
income effect—in other words, a transitory increase in the benefits of crime generates
a positive Income effcci which reduces the incentive to commit crime in subsequent
periods. This suggests that displacement will not occur when individuals urc unable
to borrow and save. During lucrative periods, for example, nothing is saved so the
next period's choice of crime is unaffected. Likewise during lean times, offenders
are unable to affect available income in subsequent periods by borrowing. This type
of period-by-period maximization also would occur if individuals were completely
myopic (Case I). If. on the other extreme, criminals are farsigbted and have access
to good credit markets, there will also be no displacement because a transitory
change in the price of criminal activity will have a negligible effect on lifetime in-
come (Case 2). In order to generate a linkage between lagged and current criminal
activity, it is necessary lo construct a model that allows individuals to cither save
or borrow across periods. On the other hand, the credit market must be sufficiently
imperfect or the lime horizon must be short enough for a transitory shock in the ben-
efits of criminal activity to have a meaningful income effect (Case 3).
We'll now formalize this intuition in the context of a simple model. We assume
that an individual's utility each period is defined over consumption, c. and leisure,
/, in the following way: u, = u{c,J,). We will assume that u(c,.l,) is increasing in
both arguments and strictly concave. Each period a criminal must allocate a single
unit of time between leisure and property crime, s. Because this time constraint must
hold with equality, it must be the case that /, = 1 - s,. Each period, an individual
earns MV.V, from criminal endeavors, where w, is the net wage from criminal endeav-
ors. Note that w, reflects both the abundance of criminal opportunities and the period
specific costs of engaging in criminal activity. In the context of our empirical anal-
ysis, Huctuations in the weather generate variation in vtv^perhaps due to weather-
related changes in the supply of targets or in the disutility of committing crime
outdoors.'"
Case I
The first case worth discussing is one in which individuals are unable or unwilling to
save or borrow. In this case, the agent faces the following budget constraint: c,'^w,s,
each period. We assume that the criminal maximizes discounted lifetime utility sub-
ject to the budget constraints he faces. It is trivial to show that the first-order condi-
tions are equivalent to those obtained from the period-by-period maximization
problem. This is because each period's utility and budget constraint is unaffected
by that which has gone before or that which will occur later. For this reason, a tran-
sitory shock to the benefit (wage) of property crime can have no impact beyond the
current period. '
10, Similar results could be obtained by assuming that weaiher affects the utility cost nf engaging in crim-
inal activity.
494 The Journal ot" Human Resources
Case 2
Another extreme case is that criminals are farsighted and have access to perfect cap-
ital markets. While it is unlikely that most offenders have access to sophisticated
capital markets, it still may be useful as a benchmark. Abstracting from uncertainty,
each offender chooses a series of consumption and criminal activity to maximize his
lifetime utility. The Lagrangian for the offender's optimization problem is:
max
where r is the interest rate at which an offender can borrow or lend, and Tis the num-
ber of periods and is assumed to be large. In order to understand how a transitory
change in the wage of crime affects .subsequent criminal behavior, it is helpful to ex-
amine the first-order conditions:
1y
+r
together with the budget constraint. Equations 2 and 3 must hold for all t. It is now no
longer true that the first-order conditions are equivalent to those consistent with
period-by-period optimization. Instead, the ability to borrow and save implies that
the marginal utility of lifetitne income. \ . is a function of the wages of crime in every
period. Thus, while an increase in w, can induce a substitution effect that causes
s, to rise, the only mechanism through which it can affect .s,+ \ is through \ . This
corresponds to an income effect. In dynamic models of labor supply, it is generally
assumed that the lifetime income effects of a transitory wage shock are minimal—
limiting the temporal displacement of property crime.
Case 3
Consider a model identical to the one above except with 7=2. For simplicity, assume
that the discount rate and the interest rate are both zero, and the utility function is
separable in consumption and leisure. Under these assumptions, the first-order con-
ditions are identical to those in Equations 2 and 3. What happens to crime at Time 2
when there is an exogenous shock to the net benefit of committing crime in Period 1 ?
The comparative statics are straightforward:
(4) ^ = - ^ i i < o
dw flj dw
where dX/dW] <0 and the number in the subscript denotes the time period. Equation 4
indicates that an increase in the first-period wage of crime will reduce the amount of
criminal activity committed in Period 2. This occurs because a transitory increase in
Jacob, Lefgren, and Moretti 495
lhe benefits of crime generates a positive income effect (lowering the marginal utility
of wealth), which reduces the incentive to commit crime in subsequent periods. As-
suming that the substitution effect dominates the income etTect in the first period,'' a
transitory increase in the wage of crime will initially lead to higher levels of crime
Eint! will then reduce subsequent criminal activity. In this case, we will observe tem-
poral displacement of property crime.
Even in this third case, it is interesting to question what type of property crime
would generate the strong income effects necessary to observe temporal displace-
ment. Clearly, it is unlikely that stealing a small inexpensive item could have any
significant income effect. If any displacement occurs, we should observe it only
for crimes that involve goods with substantial monetary value. Notably, this is
exactly what we observe in the data. We find that car theft is characterized by toial
displacement, while all other property crimes are characterized by virtually no
displacement.
where I'l is violence in the first period, g\ {v\) is an increasing but concave function
of V|, and fl| is an exogenous per-unit cost of violence. Second-period utility is given
by the following:
where i'2 is violence in Period 2, S is the fraction ofthe benefits of violence that carry
over to the next period, 52(i'2+Sv'i) is an increasing and concave function, and
02(v[) is the per-unit cost of committing violence in the second period.
11. If we thought of the amount of properly crime as the dolhirs jjenerated from crimimil activily. M^,.V,. the
nmouril criminal aclivity in Period 1 necessarily increases. In oiher words, the ainouni stolen would rise-
even if the iiinuuni of time spent on criminal activity declined. In ihis case, a rise in lhe Perit>d I wage of
crime would inerea.se Peritxl 1 erime and reduce Period 2 crime. This would lead to the temporal displace-
ment of property crime.
496 The Journal of Human Resources
In our model, the per-unit cost of violence in the second period. 92(vi). is an in-
creasing and convex function of first-period violence. This assumption seems plau-
sible.'^ The criminal's optimization problem involves choosing Periods 1 and 2
violence to maximize utility over the two periods. The first-order conditions of this
problem are the following:
and
These conditions define the equilibrium level of crime in the two periods.'^
What happens to violent crime if the cost of first-period violence exogenously
increases (for example, because of a weather shock)? It is not surprising that that
an increase in first-period violence results in a decrease in violent crime in the first
period: ^ < 0 . ' " * The comparative static for second-period crime is more relevant for
our analysis. In particular, what happens to violent crime in Period 2 when there is an
exogenous shift in the cost of violent crime in Period I?
The denominator of Equation 9 must be positive in order for the second order con-
ditions to hold. Both terms in the numerator are positive suggesting that second-
period violence is likely to increase in the first-period cost of violence if either the
benefits of violence are durable (8>0) or the marginal cost of second-period vio-
lence is rising in first-period violence. These findings suggest that the displacement
of violent crime can occur under plausible conditions.
12. Violent acts in Che lirst period may result in arTest or increased police supervision: injuries sustained in
the first period could hamper ihe ability to commil violent crime in the second period: or for crimes such as
domestic violence, it is possible Ihat guill over a violeni acl in Period I would increase the cost of com-
mitting a similar acl in Period 2.
14. In particular, ^ = -^ where A is the determinant of the matrix of second order conditions and must be
positive in order for ihe second order conditions to hold.
Jacob. Lefgren, and Moretti 497
where crimeij reflects the level of crime in jurisdiction ( in period t and p, reflects
the causal effect of an exogenous increase in criminal activity on the next period's
crime. Following the models presented in Section II, p , is the net effect of social
interactions and displacement. The empirical challenge is that crimcj,- \ is almost
certainly positively correlated to the error term r.,,. since factors affecting the costs
and benefits of crime are likely persistent over time.
The ideal instrumental variable is correlated with criminal activity in period /-1 but
uncorrelated to the error term. One candidate instrument is the weather. The corre-
lation between criminal activity and weather conditions has been well documented."
It has been hypt)thesized that higher temperatures might increase aggression directly
(see Anderson 2001), thus providing a transitory increase in the net benefit of crim-
inal activity. Adverse weather conditions may affect the cost of executing a particular
crime, due to changes in the ease of transportation or the likelihood of witnesses to
the crime, which may influence the chance of arrest.
In this model, the structural equation is given by:
where i indexes jurisdictions, and / indexes time period (in our analysis, a week).
weather,, is a vector of weather variables, and the vector X,, includes jurisdiction
*year fixed effects, jurisdiction-specific fourth order polynomials in day-of-year
and fixed effects for each month. The first stage is given by:
15. See Cohn's (1990) extensive literature review on the subject. More reecm work on ihe issue by Rotiiin
and Cohn (2()00) and Field (1992) conHrms tbe tintling.
16. One might t>e concerned [hat thi.s instrumenting siraicgy docs not work tieciiu^ Ihe firsi ,stage seems
inconsisieni wiiti tbe recursive structure of the data-generating process. However, it is trivial to show tbat,
il' the exclusion restriction holds, our strategy yields an unbiased estimate of p , .
17. To understand wby we do this, suppose tbat criminal aciivity is generated by a Poisson process, the
mean and variance or crime with a jurisdiction both equal c,. We discuss below that we normalize crime
rates by the mean weekly incidence over the sample—doing so yields point estimates that can be inter-
preted as percentage effects, tn this case, the variance of the normalized crime measure is l/C,. By weight-
ing each jurisdiction by c,. wtiich is the approximate inverse of the variance of its residual, we increase the
precision of our estimates.
498 The Journal of Human Resources
absence of good controls for current weather, lagged weather may be directly cor-
related with current crime because it will contain information regarding current
weather. While we do control for current weather conditions in our models, it is pos-
sible that weather within a period is measured imperfectly, in which case lagged
weather still may provide information regarding the unobserved aspects of current
weather. For example, one day's maximum temperature likely provides informa-
tion regarding the weather conditions at 1 a.m. of the next day. The combination of
serial correlation in weather, along with imperfect measures of weather conditions
in any one period, will violate the assumptions necessary for satisfactory identifica-
tion and result in a positive bias in the coefficient on lagged crime. We can show that
this bias decreases as the length of the time window expands. (For a fonnal proof, see
Appendix A in Jacob. Lefgren. and Moretti 2004.) Additionally, we later show the
results of a "reverse experiment" in which we estimate Ihe effect o\ future crime
on current crime, and instrument for future crime with future weather. The instru-
ment coefficient on future crime is insignificant, suggesting that this type of bias
in insignificant.
A second concern is that weather may lead to the displacement of noncriminai
economic activity. To the extent that criminal activity is follows noncrimina! eco-
nomic activity, apparent displacement of criminal activity may not generalize to set-
tings in which noncriminai activity remains constant. To assess whether empirically
this is an important source of bias, we examine three pieces of evidence, all of which
are discussed in detail in Section VI. First, we provide evidence that some noncrim-
inai activities—namely, traffic patterns—are not significantly displaced by weather
conditions. Second, we compare lhe impact of lagged crime on indoor and outdoor
crimes separately. Third, we explore whether the relationship between the victim and
offender of violent crime is associated with the magnitude of displacement. Taken
together, these three pieces of evidence indicate that our finding of temporal dis-
placement is unlikely to be driven only by noneriminal economic activity.
Finally, in interpreting our estimates it is important to realize that our strategy
yields a particular local average treatment effect. LATE (Imbens and Angrist
1994). The estimates presented bere reflect the impact of an exogenous increase
in those crimes that are elastic to weather conditions. We will provide evidence in
Section VI that weather affects a broad range of criminal behaviors. It is possible,
however, that the set of criminals whose behavior is affected by the weather is
different from the set of criminals who vary their behavior in response to transitory
law enforcement activity. Thus, our findings might not fully generalize to other
contexts.
IV. Data
Crime data are from the FBI's National Incident Based Reporting
System (NIBRS), which was established as a voluntary crime reporting system in
January 1989. The unit of observation in NIBRS is each criminal incident reported
to police. NIBRS is organized into a system of files that gives information regarding
type of offense, time, date, and location ofthe incident, characteristics ofthe victims
and offenders, as well as the value and amount of any stolen property or illegal drugs.
Jacob. Lefgren, and Moretti 499
The massive detail of the database allows us to aggregate data into categories and
time periods of our chtwsing. Unfortunately, many of the largest jurisdictions do
not to participate in NIBRS. The 2001 data file contains information on over three
million incidents reported in 3.611 different jurisdictions including Austin. Texas,
and Cincinnati. Ohio. Most jurisdictions in the sample, however, are very small with
more than 70 percent reporting fewer than 500 crimes for the whole year. Earlier
sample years contain information on even fewer juri,sdictions.
Because the most severe crimes occur infrequently in the jurisdictions that we ob-
serve, we focus our analysis on broad aggregates such as violent and property crime.
Violent crimes include simple and aggravated assault, intimidation, homicide, man-
slaughter, and sex crimes. Property crimes include extortion, counterfeiting, fraud,
larceny, vehicle theft, robbery, and stolen property offenses.'** Data on weather are
from the National Climatic Data Center (NCDC). They contain daily readings of
minimum and maximum temperature, and inches of precipitation for 24,833 weather
stations in the United States. We average these weather measures across stations
within each county to construct a county-level panel of daily weather conditions.
As discussed in Section IV, we aggregate the daily data lor both crime and weather
to the weekly level in order to reduce any bias due to the autocorrelation of
weather.'"^ Our primary analysis sample includes 116 jurisdictions for the period
1995-2001 with a total of 26.338 jurisdiction-week observations. Tn order to maxi-
mize the statistical power of our estimates, we have cho.sen the largest jurisdictions
for which NIBRS data is available. While NIBRS is by no means a nationally rep-
resentative sample of police jurisdictions in the United States, and the largest juris-
dictions in the country tend not to participate, our sample does include a relatively
diverse set of cities and counties. (For a complete list of the jurisdictions included
in our sample, see Table 6.)~"
Because some jurisdictions are larger than others, it is helpful to normalize the
crime rate across jurisdictions to reduce heteroskedasticity. This specification also
allows weather to have the same percentafie effect on the crime rate—regardless
of jurisdiction size. Researchers often address these concerns by using the natural
log of the crime rate. This specification is not well suited for the current paper be-
cause, when examining specific types of crimes, it is sometimes the case that no
18. Robbery is included as a propeny erime because the underlying motive is financial. Vandalism is ex-
cluded for tbe same reason.
19. In .some jurisdictions, multiple weeks in a single montb contain noeriminalactivity due tomisreporting
by tiic police agency. In these cases, we restrict the sample in following manner. We drop jurisdiction-
monih observations in whicb the monthly crime rate is more (ban twice the jurisdiction-specific interquar-
lik range below the median. We use the monthly crime rate because in some jurisdictions, it might be the
case tbat no crime occurred over several day.s or weeks. By using a longer time periixl. we are more con-
lidcnt (hat we are excluding observations with gross underreporling. We choose lo restrict the sample on the
basis of median and interquartile range becau.se these measures are less sensitive to periodic massive under-
reporting than are the mean and standard deviation. However, if monthly crime is normally distribuied. our
exclusion re.strittion corresponds to months in which criminal activity is more ihan 2.67 standard deviations
below the mean.
20. For example, the jurisdietions in our sampte span t7 states, witb 3 percent of jurisdictions from the
Northeast. Til percent from the Midwe.st. 63 perceni from the South, and 18 percent from tbe West, The
live jurisdictions in our sample witb the largesi number of crimes reported areChatlan(X)ga. Tenn.: Cincinnati.
Ob. Austin. Tex; Nashville, Tenn.; and Memphis. Tenn. Tbe jurisdictions with the live smallest nuniher of
crime reported are R<K:k Hill. S.C; towa City. Ia,; Burlington. Vt.; Riley County. Kan.; and PtKatello. Id,
500 The Journal of Human Resources
crimes of a particular type occur during the course of a given week. Our large sample
size and massive number of covariates complicate the use of count models. Thus, in
our primary specifications our measure of criminal activity is the number of crimes
committed during the week divided by the average weekly incidence in the jurisdic-
tion during the sample period.
In our sample, the mean weekly temperature in our sample is 58 degrees Fahren-
heit, in the average week, there is only 0.11 inches of daily precipitation. In the 18
percent of weeks that experience some snowfall, there is an average of 0.40 daily
inches of snowfall. Note that a number of jurisdictions appeared to be somewhat in-
consistent in reporting snowfall. For this reason, we include only measures of tem-
perature and precipitation in our preferred specifications, though our estimates are
robust to the inclusion and use of snowfall.
V. Empirical Findings
A. Graphical Relationship between Lagged and Current Crime
Figures 2a and 2b illustrate the baseline serial correlation of crime in our data. To do so,
we regress the violent or property crime rate in Period t on ten lags of crime within
0.1
0.08
o
U
ja 1).U6
If 0.04
¥ 0,02
H 1 I ' I
2 3 4 5 fi ' 9 I)
-0.02
Lag (in weeks)
Figure 2a
The Estimated Relationship between Current and Lagged Violent Crime
Notes: Each panel figure shows the coefficient estimates from a regression of current violent crime on
10 lags of violent crime. The unit of observation is a jurisdiction-week. All crime rates are computed
by dividing the actual number of crimes during a week by the average number of weekly crimes
within Ihe jurisdiction. Other covariates include average temperature and total precipitation in tbe
current period; jurisdiction-year fixed effects, jurisdiction-specific fourth order polynomials in day-
of-year. and fixed effects for month. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at tbe state*year
*month level. Observations are weighted by the mean number of all crimes witbin tbe jurisdiction.
Jacob. Lefgren, and Moretti 501
9 I
Figure 2b
The Estimated Relationship between Current and Lagged Property Crime
Notes: Each panel figure shows the coefticieni estimales from a regression of current property crime
on 10 lagsot property crime. The utiil of obser\alion is a jurisdiction-week. All crime rates are com-
puted by dividing the actual number of crimes during a week by the average number of weekly
crimes wilhin Ihe jurisdiclion. Other covariates include average temperature and imal precipita-
tion in the current period; jurisdiction-year fixed effects, jurisdiction-specific fourth order polyno-
mials in day-of-year, and fixed effects for month. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at
the state*year*month level. Observations are weighted by the mean number of all crimes within
the jurisdiction. ,
the same jniisdiction, controlling for the same set of covariates that will be used in
our primary estitnation—namely, jurisdiction*year fixed effects, jurisdiction-specific
fourth order polynomials in day of year as a smooth control for seasonality. month
fixed effects, and average temperature and total precipitation in Period / as controls
for current weather conditions. Standard errors are clustered by state-year-month to
account for spatial and temporal correlation. The figures present the coefficients on
all lagged crime variables. Figures 2a and 2b differ from Figure 1 in that it includes a
detailed set of controls."'
The top panel shows that violence during each of the past five weeks is a statisti-
cally significant predictor of violence in the current period. The coefficients on the
lags start at 0.065 and generally fall with distance from the reference week. By Week
6. the coefficients are statistically insignificant. In the bottotn panel, we see that the
21. On average, about 93 violent crimes are reported each week in our jurisdictions; ^b of these are simple
assauli (for example, violence noi involving a weapon or serious injury), and 17 are aggravated assault. In
iiboui 70 percent of cases, the viciim knows ihe offender—indeed about 23 percent of all violence is K--
iween family mtmhers. Propeily crime is more common than violent crime wiih nearly 240 reported inci-
dcTils per week. About 60 percenl of ihese incidents involve larceny of some type. Other types of property
crime are far less common. All of Ihese means are calculated weighting each jurisdiction by the average
number of weekly crimes in the jurisdiction.
502 The Journal of Human Resources
serial correlation for property crime is even higher than that for violent crime (for
example, the coefficient on the first lag is 0.22), but the autocorrelation appears to
decay in a similar way. While these conditional correlations are statistically signif-
icant, it is interesting to note that they are smaller than the unconditional correlations
presented in Figure I. This suggests that factors associated with jurisdiction-specific
time and jurisdiction-specific seasonality effects (for example, factors such as sea-
sonal changes in the economy, or police interventions) have a strong influence on
crime rates.
22. Tbere is a convex relationship between temperature and crime—very hoi temperatures re.'iult in a more
than proponional increase in violence—but a concave relationship tietween precipitation and violence. (.See
Table 3 in Jacob. Lefgren. and Moretti 2C)04,)
23. Higher precipitation appears to be associated with increases in the incidence of burglary. We speculate
that precipitation may reduce the probability of detection, perhaps because there are fewer people arouttd to
serve as potential witnesses or tbere is reduced visibility.
Jacob, Lefgren, and Moretll 503
— — r - tf-j
• ^ r ^ i n r^i
u-i O — O
.-. p r-i
o o o o -o o d
* #
yD O d *—•
-S .5 5 3 — 00 fN <n
p p
2 ^ 4O •^ — — p
d d d d d d
^O O (^-l
p q 5 30 p Tf
d c d K d d
c * o ON — — 00
" D. iO ^P r t —
"5 Ii « ! 10 o —' p r- p r-i
d d d £
•c O ^ ON U-1
S — rt Q
cs I p p ON ON
•^ u =^ d d d d
m — p
o o o o 00 o_ o
O ^ £ 1 r^ d d
*
*
o
f—• 1—1
1 H
ON
OC
o o <n o
o o o o tN o
*
* *
o , ,
.00
.02
.47
.17
s
0 0 0 0
a.
o
x:
P 9
d d
* —
-s:
I1
bo <
— o c
p p "*
00 o d
— ri
"^ '—'
oo 00 r-'
r- (N (y.
•* O 6
'OP'*.
o o o o god
s
3 -i
2 2
sr I
504 The Journal of Human Resources
8p p
a. o O
p P
O d
Cu
go
m d d
a. p p
o
C/3
do
•s •=
O O ^ •—•tn
(N — O Q "*
p p in p 1/^
d d o^ d d
o o —o o
1^
3 -S
Jacob, Lefgren, and Moretii 505
0.05
O.IM
0.0.1
[),02
0.01
-0.01
-0,02
-0.03
Week
Pereem Violeni Cnme above Normal
Degrees above Ntirmat
Figure 3a
Heat Waves and Violent Crime
Notes: For each panel, we regressed temperature on month fixed effects. Jurisdiction*year fixed
effects and jurisdiction-specific fourth order polynomials in day of year. We included periods in
our sample in which !he temperature in week 0 was more ihan 6 degrees Fahrenheit above predicted
(using our controls) and the temperature in Week I wiis within 3 degrees of predicted. For each week,
we show ihe average temperature residual—weighting each jurisdiction by the average number of
crimes committed during a week. We also show the average violent crime residual, which is obtained
hy running a regressions with controls discussed above.
24. We define unusually hoi weeks as those in which ihe average weekly temperature is 6 degrees Fahrenheit
warmer ihan predicted after conirolling for jurisdiclion-year fixed effects and jurisdiciion-specific fourth
order polynomials in day of year. To he included in our sample, the temperature of the following week must
be within three degrees of the predicted lemperature. There are 1,1 OS such week.s in our sanfiple.
506 The Journal of Human Resources
0.04
-0.04
Week
PerL-ent F^operty Crime aht)ve Normal
Degrees above Nomial
Figure 3b
Heat Waves and Property Crime
Notes: For each panel, we regressed temperature on month lixcd etTects, jurisdicti()n*year fixed
effects and jurisdiclion-specific fourth order polynomials in day of year. We included periods in
our sample in which ihe temperature in week 0 was more than 6 degrees Fahrenheit above predicted
(using our controls) and the temperature in Week 1 was witliin three degrees of predicted. For each
week, we show the average temperature residual—weighting each jurisdiction by the average number
of crimes eommitted during a week. We also show the average property crime residual, which is
obtained by running a regressions with controls discussed above.
Violent crime, however, is nearly 2 percentage points lower than normal, suggesting
displacement of about 40 percent over ihe subsequent week. Over the next ten weeks,
both temperature and the rate of violent crime bounce around the predicted level,
though violent crime is unusually high eight weeks after the hot week. Figure 3b
shows the analogous results for property crime. During the initial hot week, property
crime is more than 2 percentage points higher than expected. The following week it
is about 0.5 percentage points lower. This is again consistent with displacement,
though the drop in Week 1 is smaller than for violent crime, in the subsequent weeks,
we again see a small amount of variation around the predicted crime rate.
25, We do not use snowfall due to concerns about the consistency of data collection. (.)ur estimates arc
robust Hi the inclusion of snowfall measures.
26. In theiiry. one limitalion of this type of clustering is that we allow for arbitrary auiocorrelation beiween
two weeks in the same month, siate. and year, but not between Iwd weeks in different months, even if they
are consecutive weeks. We assume thai this is not a major problem in our context. We have expcrimenied
with different clusledng, including ones that include shorter and longer periods, and found our standard
errors to be robu.si.
508 The Journal of Human Resources
q — p
OCiocio OO
5 o o o o o o o
o o d o d o o o
•a
o *
•E CT^ v^ C^ O^
^ q q q
o o o o
•c
u rj
[^
O r- 00
Q ^ O
rj
f i
o o o o o
d d d d d
>
O^ ^ ^ rN C"!
O lo r- w-i
rj q — q
d d d d
r- o^ fN 00
q qq w~.
t^
q qQ
d d d d
r^ q
d d
•S-
*
m O
00 —
q q
d d
r.1
•c c
u u u u
Jacob. Lefgren. and Moretti 509
q
O O^ d •3 *
*
* --^
NO O c>5 [/;
00 —I OO
—q
d d O "-1
-C- oo O c^ wi in V)
S r- A 00 .!> .0) .oj
Sj -a -5 =
o o — o
I •—OC ' - ' .2 s -j -a
t u n
— q >-
d d
o o
— oo _
^ s =^
<N
io 1/: 1/1
d d r-i 9d rM
(111
c a
C
C3
£ .£ 1 u
p
— q
ent!
d d o Q
.a
*
* —.
O m
sD <n 00
rj q lo
r*^ in 1/1 W5 1/1
gu'§
^ ^ ^ ^
d d ro
_ : =o
1 rM f^-
00 —
o o
1-1
E u *
_ y 5 o
E ,CJ
TVI
D -t! -a
c v: u ^ (J 2 ^
•n o -c O "> JJ •? u
510 The Journal of Human Resources
r o O f o c X o r l O
— p — o q q o q r n f N
oododdodcio
Q\ O ^ f^^ d r^ ^ 00 O^ 'O
(NO — q q q q p - ^ q
d d d d d d d d d d
-o
o
•c
a. > o ^
— q — q q q
c ^
[^ 00 m 00 — oc
_c d d d d d d d d
u w w w
U
E ni o m o OS —
o rn q
5 o
fvi q _ o q q
d d d d d d
I 3
o o r-
!!: o Hi g R —
d d d d d a>
^ 1
I *
*
*
o *I N 0 0 OO
fN o
o o
d d d d do
» *
*
o oc
so 00
(N
o
r
CN q (N q
d d d d
"fc^
:^
I
u a
E B
OLS
3 •c
U
•c
U
•c
u
•c
u
I
Jacob, Lefgren. and Moretti 51
^3 C 1. n
u u o u
3 T3 ' ^ £
ill o ~
•op
alue
rf
'ifhi
ags
c
2 >
o 13
-g
tio
1^
O^ •a
3 u *3
CO c 3
u • r ;
<N
= i^
.iJ J^ .!> ,.<u
c= S U 5 S
ft ^ ^ ^
•a c '5 S
.I 2
t o a 'S
'^ 3 'J e "
g =•
o ,Q. 3
3£ fS6 "3 •
yj i/j i« i/i
- >•>->•>•
6 5 «2
c E 5 *
1
l-s ^ '^ I i
E ^ •- ^
<U O
-I S^ "> Cl. C
- 33
^_
on .C
" X
C ^ S c^ — r. = ..
;3 -D
["3
P 7, " - •=
•f ^ "^ 1 S t^
•.
bji
C
1^
:3
—
.^
to
u
^ "O tJ ^ K
k. ± 3 O CL, Q ;> u ''^ fl>
Z =6 S k, 5
512 The Journal of Human Resources
significantly different than both zero and one. The effects are somewhat smaller for
property than violent crime, but are still substantial. In Column 8. the sum of Ihe four
lagged crime measures is - 0 . 3 3 , which implies that tor property crime, the displace-
ment that occurs over one month is roughly 50 percent more than that which occurs
over one week.
To this point, we have examined up to four lags. However, it is possible that dis-
placement could operate over an even longer time horizon. To examine this possibil-
ity, we calculate IV estimate for both violent and property crime in which we include
up to ten lags and present the results in Figures 4a and 4b. Note that these results are
directly comparable to the OLS estimates shown in Figures 2a and 2b. The top panel
shows the results for violent crime. As we saw earlier, the first, second, and fourth
lags are statistically significantly different from zero. The others hover around zero
but are not consistently of one sign or another. At -0.37, the sum of the ten lags is
negative and statistically significant at the 10 percent level, suggesting that all of
the displacement in violent crime occurs within a month. The bottom panel shows
the results for property crime. In contrast to the results we found earlier, none of the
lags is statistically different from zero. Furthermore, the sum of lags is only -0.14
and statistically insignificant. Though the point estimates suggest that little displace-
ment occurs over 10 weeks for property crime, the standard error on the sum of co-
efficients is too large to rule out substantial displacement. For both violent and
1
1
1
5 ] ;)
Figure 4a
IV Estimates of the Relationship between Current and Lagged Violent Crime
Notes: Panels show the (V estimates from a regression of current violent crime on 10 lags. The unit of
observation is a jurisdiction-week. All crime rates are compuled by dividing the actual number of
crimes during a week by ihe average number of weekly crimes within the jurisdiction. Other cova-
riates include average temperature and total precipitation in the current period: jurisdiciion-year lixeii
effects, jurisdiction-specific fourth order polynomials in day-of-year, and fixed effects for month.
Lagged crime is instrumented using lagged average temperature and total precipitation. See the text
for more details. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the state*year*month level. Observa-
tions are weighted by the mean number of all crimes within the Juri.sdiction.
Jacoh, Lefgren, and Morelli 513
0.3
•€ 0.2
IC
B
O
u 0-1
•£ 1
* "5 0
1
| | •
1)
1"
•
•
-O.I
• 1
a -0.2
1 -0.3
-0.4
Lag (in weeks)
Figure 4b
IV Estimates of the Relationship between Current and Lagged Property Crime
Notes: Panels show the IV estimates from a regression of curretit property crime oti 10 lags. The unit
of observalicn is a jurisdiction-week. All crime rates are computed hy dividing the actual nutnber of
crimes duritig a week by the average number of weekly crimes withiti the jurisdiction. Other cova-
riates include average temperature and lotal precipitation in Ihe current period, jurisdiction-year fixed
effccis. jurisdiction-specihc fourth order polynomials in day-of-year, and fixed effects for month.
Lagged crime is instrumented using lagged average temperature and total precipitation. See the text
for more details. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the state*year*month level. Observa-
tions are weighted by the mean number of all crimes within the jurisdiction.
property crime, however, the results do stand in stark contrast to the positive OLS
estimates.
27, In practice, the difference between simple and aggravated assault tan be fairly small. Indeed, relatively
minor differences in the seriousness of injury can lead to a dilTerent categorization.
514 The Jounial of Human Resources
rale of the specific type of crime under examination while the right-hand-side vari-
able is a lagged measure of all violent or property crime.""
Table 4 shows the findings for violent crime. The results suggest that an exogenous
increase in violent crime leads to subsequent reductions in most violent crime cate-
gories. In particular, a 10 percent increase in all violent crime reduces simple and
aggravated assaults by 3.5 and 2.9 percent respectively. Similarly, a U) percent
Increase in all violent crime reduces violent crime against family members and indi-
viduals known to the offender by nearly 3.0 percent over one week. We see similar
effects for crimes with and without weapons. The IVe.stimate for violent crime by
strangers is not statistically significant, though the point estimate suggests some dis-
placement.~ !n all cases, when examining a four-lag model, we observe substantial
displacement for all types of violent crime.^" While our specification allows us to
examine whether or not displacement occurs for particular crimes, it is not possible
to compare tbe magnitudes of the coefficients across crime types. Still, these models
allow us to conclude that temporal displacement of violence appears to operate for a
variety of different types of violent crime.
In Table 5, we examine the findings for different types of property crime. Remem-
ber that the simple labor supply framework outlined in Section II predicts that dis-
placement should only operate for property crimes involving a fairly large monetary
value, since the predicted income effect of stealing small items (for example, a candy
bar) is likely trivial. Consistent with that prediction, the point estimates for the IV
results suggest substantial displacement only for burglary and vehicle theft, although
only Ihe effects for vehicle theft are statistically significant. Interestingly, the 2SLS
estimates for vehicle theft for four lags show enormous displacement. Because many
property crimes—particularly those in the categories of larceny, shoplifting or
robbery—involve relatively small amounts of money, it is not surprising that we find
little effect for these crimes.
To more accurately capture property crime displacement, we estimate a model in
which we measure property crime by the total value of the property stolen during a
particular period.^' Interestingly, the results in Column 7 indicate statistically sig-
nificant displacement over a one-week period. A 10 percent increase in the value
of property stolen in one week is associated with a decline in value of property stolen
in the following week by nearly 6 percent. The results for the four-lag model are not
precise enough to be informative. Overall, these results for property crime suggest
some displacement over a short time period, although the results are not as robust
as for violent crime.
28. Note thai these models assume ihal there is no displacement from violeni to property crime, or vice
versa. While ihis is probably not strictly true, it is likely that the magnitude of this type of displacement
is second-order. Estimates from models where the right-hand-side is the specific crime under consideration
are available upon request. In general. Ihey are qualitatively similar to the ones shown here.
29. We expeci gang violcnt-c might be disproponionately coneentrated in the category of violent crime by
strangers. To the exteni thai one expects the violent crime displacemeni to refleci gang activity, the insig-
nificance of the displacement result t'nr violence committed by strangers is a bit surprising. This could re-
flect, however, the imprecision of the point estimates.
30. These estimates arc computed from separate regressions in which we incltjde one or lour lags.
31. As with the other models, we normalize by diving by the average for the jurisdiction over the entire
sample period. We obtain comparahle results if we use the log of the total value of stolen property.
Jacob, Lefgren, and Moretti 515
o q q
d d
— rn
d d
— q
d d ^ >
§Is a
010
.272
209
506
165
Yes
094
Yes
066
(N
> U '5 ^ o o o o
o
o o o o
* *
036**
268**
*
033)
ll
017)
(0.107)
(0.244)
Yes
Yes
o o o d o d
>u
090**
219**
*
5
212)
029)
015)
104)
021
Yes
Yes
.2 I o o o o o o d
> "c i3
498**
080**
280**
180**
c 03
063)
022)
Oil)
140)
=3
Yes
Yes
U
o o o o o o o o
I CQ
^ o — (N
o o OO 00
I ^ .£ .« *" (N q
d d
— o
o o
u
c
lis
CO <
00
q q
d d
—
o o
S (NCN
<N q d d
d d
a *
00 —
(N q — q
_ u q q
d d d d d d
d d
« O
I
t/1
516 The Journai of Human Resources
c u t: o
c u =•
E i:!
S 2
i/1 [/I •i I
-i i/i ^ 2
•2 r^ ^ I c ,2
I ££ a 1/5 l/l • ^ •=
" . - | XI
>,
III
is the
that
ou
E
•3 2 i « Sg_^
•c OE I
3 .o
•S'^'BJi
^ U ^
B
•c .?s ^
u C ^= C Ml
> 'C ^ ^
u £
e 1
is.- •5 S
— »: .ii C
v: DTJ
.2 E I S nil-
T3
> 'S [1. 5 5I g
*• OJ >» C
'-- E. — 3
Is O > . «J O
Xn s s E ^-
00
^ s= = ^ = u
O §
^ o c P
ssau
"a.
i- E !>•? u o
« c I- u
lent
o •E ^I
c 5 i-'S •.s :-5
u
i cor
;sdi
lenti
>
_i
a- a •£
u
cri
•a
.d
•s
n -^
O
Si 3
(J — ^ ir; w ra "'
•u 'B a is 5 Cl.,
I I I I 4.1
T po
6.=o
ear
ef
I O 'C O
•3 3
i^ Oj U ;r Q
Jacob. Lefgren, and Morelti 517
0.
•a X)
0 0 0 0
S o
* — —.
O w"i (^ r-
(^ rT) ^ '•C
(N O O f^ mp p ^
o c; d o d d d d d
— f:n 2; 00
fN p u~, rj 'J; p p Tt
d d d d d d —d
o
— S 3 — '^ '^
00 • * fn p rj —
d d d d d d d d
u
•c sO io r ; tN
r^, f. O >ri
— q ' r'j p
p <N rn
O
00 — ^
p p
rJ OO Tt q — (N
d d d d d d d d
r- — O 00
tN p ri p •jj; p rn
d d d d d d d
*I
O
11
518 The Journal of Human Resources
•O JO
U 'C
E
i3 'i
w- •a
"p
Q.
•y. u
J= <T1
X) 5 U
o 5
t-
• ~
on 2
S •= c i i
5 iJ r ^ c
> H CQ Oil ^ — EA
'C cm ,p o .D
S- J5 "• •= O
p In
_ S
CQ
1
U E y •- =5
.? 5 y «
o
r? b « t: s;
s •£ £ S ii
I ^ T3 -g " O g^
•B E 5 - fc •S
ii K~
k- 3 OJ 4j ^'J tn
•E ;., ^ 5 g ^
f-3
^•2
I CJ
<U
C
O
I
m
a. c
5 Og CL
11
.^ E
I I -f «
~ ^II^ '
it c
3 o
Jacob, Lefgren. and Moretti 519
32. Tbe traffic volume daia includes hourly traffic counts for each traffic station provided by permanent in-
road traffic monitors. Geographic identifiers allow one to link each station to states and counties. Traffic
data arc available for 66 of the 92 counties included in the crime analysis. Recall that our primary analysis
sample for crime includes 116 jurisdictions in *)2 counties in 17 states. For more infonnation on the traffic
data, see: Office of Higbway Policy Information at http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/policy/ohpi.
33. To be consistent wiih the crime estimates, we normalize these measures by dividing weekly counu by
ihf average for that counly over tbe sample periixJ.
34. These results are reassuring, although ideally, one would like lo look at a broader set of measures of
economic activity to draw more general conclusions. A recent paper looks at the effect of weather on retail
sales (Starr-McCluer 2(XM)). The author finds some evidence o!" displacement. tJnusually cold tem[>eratures
in a given month lend to depress sales in ihat month, but they lead to higher sales in the following month.
The current and lugged effects do not completely offset each other. Moreover, unusually warm weather is a
given month increa.ses sales, but reduces sales in the month after. The current and lagged effects roughly
offset each other. Unfortunately, data on retail sales are available only at the monthly level, which makes
the comparison with our analysis difficult.
520 The Journal of Human Resources
ounty
CO X
$ $^ U H <:
Q CO 1^ * •"•
"! sz H
u •d -^ -
i CO
oanoke.
ioux Cil
iley Cm
3
aUna. K
oseville
andy, U
ock Hil
aginaw.
3
re a O c C
o I/:
Si _re E d ,o _re E
>
3
•o
aj
o c
o
o X Xu
i cu 5 1 a: a: t o CO to
D.
n o o o o o o o o o o
CO
o ooooo
fN fN fN fN tN fN
o o o o
f - l fN (N f^J r>l
c I I ! 1 ^ J
I J I I J
O
u X u
o HH •*<'
> o O U 0
33
oh d
: o
aho
nc iq i j j D
a jUi ju gC CE B
h PC : C^
U O O O X X X X X •o O T
a.
C/5 N f N N rjrJfNfN
I I I I I I
c c
•c
Jacoh. Lefgren. and Moretti 521
u 5 $
u
I j c/j U SB
00 oij.2 l< O C -3
te
C C — •3 C
- -;^ ^
•4_i 'V^ <y:
> ^
J u
z z c
nty,
o £^
ou I/;
OJ H c U
o , H "XI - * Oti
L.
rt
P u= 5 •= O, CQ - ii .n
U
^"^ ^^ 3
'c '
X)
> s g —, CD
ran
>^ X 3 C c o
s aj o >,
_1 HJ -J -J Z Z ooO
u < O
> U u
Q !^ < c/1
z 3 c c
< - ?
Vlen
luff:
Spri
U O H
iy
Cou
VA
H
> T3 X
rfie]
ttes
o ni
bia.
CQ .
c C >
C I'; 'o ^~ S= o
.2 S o 3 2 E £ c >
re <u (jj P b > <U c 3 C
x: .c o o o o o O (5
U U u U U Uu U U U U U U Q
522 The Journal of Human Resources
ododocJdodo
o
*w-i *
— r j — i - g - — r- — m —
i^poppppoooo
d d d d d d d d d d
o
1 ^
OS ( ^
O —
p —
> 3" d d
r-i
00 O
d d
CN
I — (NOfNp — — fNpTf
r^
CN
dddddddddd
* * *
— fO 3^ fN (N f . C-, r-t GO r^,
Oppppppp CN
(N
o o
p (N 3 rj— w-1 C
(^ p
d d d d cr! d
•5-
r-1
-J —
o - O C do
'—' <n
cr-
BA
4.
S 2
o
Jacob, Lefgren, and Moretti 523
C. Persistence in Weather
A third potential problem is that weather, when measured at high frequency, is seri-
ally correlated. While we control for current weather conditions in our models, it is
524 The Journal of Human Resources
possible that weather within a period is measured imperfectly, in which case lagged
weather still may provide information regarding the unobserved aspects of current
weather which would, in turn, directly impact current crime. As discussed earlier,
this will violate the assumptions necessary for satisfactory identification and result
in a positive bias in the coefficient on lagged crime. It is possible to show that this
bias decreases as the length ofthe time window expands. For this reason, we aggre-
gate to the weekly level.
To examine whether this sonrce of bias is empirically unimportant in our current
framework, we conduct a '"reverse experiment" where we estimate the effect of
fuinre crime on current crime, and instrument for future crime with future weather.
Specifically, we estimate a specification in which the dependent variable is crime in
Period t, but the right-hand-side variable is crime in Period (+\ and the instrument
is weather conditions in Period f+\. If measurement error in weather conditions is
an important source of bias, the bias would be similar whether we look at lagged
or future crime. Thus, we would expect the estimated impact of future crime on cur-
rent crime to be positive and statistically significant. This is not the case (see Jacob,
Lefgren, and Moretti 2004). In particular, the estimated impact of future crime is
small in magnitude and statistically insignificant for both violent and property
crime. This suggests that our results are not materially affected by imperfect weather
measures.
VII. Conclusion
In this paper, we exploit the correlation between weather and crime
to examine the short-run dynamics of criminal activity. In sharp contrast to the po.s-
itive serial correlation in crime rates reported in most studies, we find that higher
crime in one week is followed by less crime in subsequent weeks. These lindings
suggest that the positive serial correlation in crime commonly reported is not an en-
dogenous process driven by the optimization of oftenders, but likely reflects persis-
tence of unobserved factors that influence of criminal activity.
The magnitude of displacemenl in violent and property crime over a short-time
horizon is substantial. A 10 percent increase in violent crime in one week leads to
a 2.6 percent reduction in violent crime the following week. Over the course of four
weeks, over half of the initial increase in violence will be mitigated through displace-
ment. The results for property crime are somewhat smaller—a 10 percent increa.se in
property crime results in a decrease of 2.0 percent the following week—and appear
lo be limited to high value property crimes, vehicle theft in particular.
The propeny crime results suggest that criminal behavior is consistent with a stan-
dard labor supply framework, where the observed displacement can be explained by
an income effect. Criminals who are prevented from committing propeny offenses in
a given week engage in higher levels of criminal activity during the subsequent
weeks to make up for lost income. This behavior is consistent with a model in which
offenders have at least some foresight and/or are some liquidity constraints. Consis-
tent with the predictions of the model, we find that displacement arises only for
crimes that involve highly valuable propeny. such as vehicle Iheft.
In the case of violent crime, a possible interpretation of the results is that the ben-
efits of violence may be durable—^in other words, the marginal utility (cost) of vio-
lence is decreasing (rising) in the amount of violence committed during the prior
week. This would be true if. for example, an assailant who "seules a score" in
one period feels less need to do so in a subsequent period. Similarly, a husband
who abuses his wife in one period may be less inclined to do so in the next period,
perhaps because of a sense of guilt or because he has received a warning from the
police.
Besides its theoietical implications, the uncovering of substantial temporal dis-
placement also may have important policy implications. Our findings suggest that
the long-run impact of temporary crime-prevention efforts may be smaller than the
shon-run effects. In the case of violent crime, the shon-run impact of a one-week
35. Incarceration may in theory be a factor behind the displacement of property and violent crime. H<tw-
L'ver. given the low arresi and conviclion rates, it is unlikely thai incarceration could explain a substantial
ponitin of ihe obser\'ed displacemenl. Consider, for example, that each incident of violence reported pro-
duces only about 0.4 arrests. It is likely that ai least half of ihese are either nol charged with an offense or
released almost immediately on bail (Dilulio 19%). Furtheniiore, even if the remaining individuals are in-
volved in a reported aci of violence 10 limes per year, incarceration could only gener.ile displacement of
about 4 percent over one week, a small traction of the total effect. This is even truer for property crime,
where clearance rates arc much lower \ related possibility is that the cost being caught is an increasing
and convex function of ihc number of crimes committed. Because we are looking at week-io-week variation
in crime rates, we suspect that in our context, this is not empirically very relevant. For most crimes, II is
unlikely that ofienders are caughl, arresled. tried, sentenced, and freed in one week.
526 The Journal of Human Resources
crime-prevention effort will be twice as large as the impact over one month. To the
extent that policy makers engage in short-term policy experiments or anti-crime
crackdowns, standard policy evaluations may prove misleading.
It should be noted, however, that the estimates presented here reflect a particular
local average treatment effect—namely, the impact of lagged crime that is elastic lo
weather conditions. The relevance of our results for policy depends upon the extent
to which the set of criminals and crimes whose behavior is affected by the weather is
similar to the sets which respond to transitory law enforcement activity. Although we
show that weather affects a broad range of criminal behaviors, it is important to rec-
ognize that our findings might not fully generalize to other contexts, particularly
those that involve longer-term interventions such as improving economic opportuni-
ties for potential offenders or short-run interventions that involve the incapacitation
of many potential offenders. It is also important to note that changes in weather con-
ditions have no lasting impact on the perceived costs of criminal activity. This differs
from extended police crackdowns, in which offenders may only gradually realize that
the program has ended. The effects of such programs have been shown in .some ca.ses
to extend even beyond the duration of the crackdown (see Sherman 1990). To the
extent that police engaged in shorter and more predictable crackdowns, our findings
would be more relevant
Finally, it is useful to consider how these results inform the literature on social
interactions. To the extent that social interactions operate at the week-to-week fre-
quency we examine, our estimates should be interpreted as the net effect of these so-
cial interactions and displacement. In this case, our results suggest that the total
temporal displacement more than offsets social interactions operating at the weekly
level. Given the relatively high frequency of our data, our estimates cannot speak to
the possibility of social interactions that operate in the long run through, for example,
social learning. Thus, these findings do not rule out the importance of social interac-
tions for explaining long-run differences in crime rates across k^alities.
References
Anderson. Craig A. 2(X)1, "Heat and Violence." Current Directions in Psychological Science
IO(l):33-38.
Becker. Gary. 1968. "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach." Journal of Political
Economy 76(3): 169-217.
Braga. Anthony A.. David M. Kennedy, Elin J. Waring, and Anne M. Piehl. 2001. "Problem-
Oriented Policing. Deterrence and Youlh Violence: An Evaluation of Boston's Operation
Ceasctire." The Journal of Research in Crime ami Delinquency 38:195-225.
Camerer. Colin. Linda Babcock. George Lowenstien. and Richard Thaler. 1997. "Labor
Supply of New York Cily Cab Drivers: One Day at the Time." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 112(2):407-l L
Cohn, Ellen G. 1990. "Weather and Crime." British Journal of Criminology 30(1): 51-64.
Cohn. Ellen G., and Jame>; Rolton. 20(X). "Weather. Seasonal Trends and Property Crimes in
Minneapolis, 1987-88: A Moderator-Variable Time-Series Analysis of Routine Activities."
Journal of Environmental Psychology 2O(3):257-72.
Cook. Philip J.. and Kristin A. Goss. 1996. "A Selective Review of Ihe Social-Contagion
Literature," Working paper. Raleigh: Duke University.
Jacob, Lefgren, and Morelti 527
Dilulio, John J. ! 9 % . "A New Crime Wave." Investor's Business Daily, March 6.
Farber, Henry. 2005. "Is Tomorrow Another Day? The Labor Supply of New York City Cab
Drivers." Journal of Political Economy 113(l):46-82.
Field. Simon. 1992. "The Effect of Temperature on Crime." British Journal of Criminology
32(3):34O-5!.
Grogger, Jeffrey, and Charles Michalopoulos. 2003. "Welfare Dynatnics under Time Limits."
Journal of Political Economy 11 U3):530-54.
Hesscling, Rene B. R 1994. "Displacement: A Review of the Empirical Literature." In Crime
Prevention Stiulie\. ed. R.V. Clarke. 2. Monsey, N.Y.: Criminal Justice Press.
Jacob. Brian. Lars Lefgren, and Enrico Moreiti. 2004. "The Dynamics of Criminal Behavior:
Evidence tmm Weaiher Shocks." NBER Working Paper No. 10739.
Jacob, Brian, and Lars Lefgren. 2003. "Arc Idle Hands [he Devil's Workshop? lncapacitation.
Concentration and Juvenile Crime." American Ectmtmiic Review 93(.'));I360-77.
Lochner, Lance. 1999. "Education, Work, and Crime: Theory and Evidence." RCER Working
Papers No. 465. New York: University of Rochester.
Rotton, James, and Ellen G. Cohn. 2000. "Violence Is a Curvilinear Function of Temperature
in Dallas: A Replicalion." Jotinuil of Personality and Social P.sychology 78(6): 1074-81.
Sherman. Lawrence W. 1990. "Police Crackdowns: Initial and Residual Deterrence." Crime
ami Justice 12:1-48.
Starr-McCluer, Martha. 2000. The Effects of Weather on Retail Sales. Federal Reserve Board
Discussion Series.