A Valuation Riddle Wrapped in A Mean Reversion Mystery Inside An Accounting Enigma
A Valuation Riddle Wrapped in A Mean Reversion Mystery Inside An Accounting Enigma
By Simon E. Nocera1
Lumen Global Investments LLC
San Francisco, July 2020
1
Simon E. Nocera (snocera@lumenadvisors.com) is the founder of Lumen Advisors and Lumen Global Investments.
Simon’s experience spans well over 25 years of global investment across various functions and firms – LGT, Soros,
DRCM, Lumen, etc. He is considered the pioneer of Emerging Markets, having managed the first SEC registered fund
dedicated to Emerging Markets. Simon was an economist at the International Monetary Fund for almost a decade
and holds a Research Doctorate from the University of Milan, Italy.
2
I am grateful for invaluable reviews and comments by Prof. Moustapha Awada (Florida Atlantic), Prof. Arnav Seth
(MIT), Prof. Donatella Taurasi (UC Berkeley), and Prof. Stephen Wallenstein (Duke). I am also indebted to my
colleague Marianne O for her unwavering support in writing this paper. All errors and omissions are mine only.
Page | 1
3
Soman, Nilesh. “Retracing the History of Price to Earnings Ratio.” Money Control, 11 Feb. 2014,
https://www.moneycontrol.com/news/business/personal-finance/retracinghistoryprice-to-earnings-ratio--
1185979.html.
Page | 2
4
Berkshire Hathaway Inc. Annual Report, 2000, p.14. He famously went on to say “Indeed, growth can destroy
value if it requires cash inputs in the early years of a project or enterprise that exceed the discounted value of the
cash that those assets will generate in later years. Market commentators and investment managers who glibly
refer to “growth” and “value” styles as contrasting approaches to investment are displaying their ignorance, not
their sophistication. Growth is simply a component -- usually a plus, sometimes a minus -- in the value equation”
5
During an annual meeting of investors, Charlie Munger of Berkshire Hathaway, or the “Richelieu of Omaha” was
very explicit in describing Berkshire’s valuation methodology (reproduced in a short YouTube video
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=5ioeNrmn4eY and concluded that, despite being widely quoted and revered
“… that practice of ours which is so simple is not widely copied … it is not the standard in the investment
management, even at great universities and other intellectual institutions”. Mr. Munger went on to say “… if we
are so right, why are so many eminent places so wrong”.)
6
Asquith, P., Mikhail, M.B., and Au, A.S. “Information Content of Equity Analyst Reports”, MIT Sloan Working Paper
4264-02*, 2004, Table 1: Panel A, p. 34. Re-printed in the Journal of Financial Economics, vol.75, no. 2, Feb. 2005,
pp. 245-282.
Page | 3
7
Note that Price to Earnings * Return on Equity = Price to Book
Page | 4
2.1 “The cynic knows the price [earning] of everything and the value of nothing “, Oscar
Wilde.
Despite all the cacophony and the zoo of value metrics and methodologies, the gold standard of
valuation is and remains beautifully simple. Conceptually, practically, logically, and otherwise the
monetary value of any investment is the sum of the future cash flow discounted back to present
value. The discount rate used in the calculation -- a.k.a. cost of capital, a.k.a. cost of equity -- is
by construction equal to the compounded return expected from the investment measured in
percentage. This truism is set in stone and few if any analysts worth their salt would even dare
questioning this universally accepted basic finance principle. The debate has been primarily
centered on the different, albeit crucial definitions of cash flow (e.g. Earnings, Dividend, Free
Cash Flow to the Firm, etc.) and the estimation of the discount rate.
Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller (M&M), in a series of papers considered to form the
foundation of Modern Corporate Finance Theory8, postulated that: the market value of a firm
will be equal to the net cash flow to shareholders generated from existing assets plus the net
8
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. "The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment". American
Economic Review, vol. 48, no. 3, Jun. 1958, pp. 261–297. JSTOR 1809766.
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. "Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction". American Economic
Review, vol. 53, no. 3, Jun. 1963, pp. 433–443. JSTOR 1809167.
Page | 5
k = The discount rate, a.k.a. expected return of the investment, a.k.a. cost of capital.
The simplest and most revealing application of this valuation methodology is the (universally
accepted) determination of the price of a bond, i.e. a financial instrument that pays a fixed cash
flow periodically and a principal amount at maturity. Again, no serious financial analyst would
even dare questioning this widely accepted identity:
9
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. “Dividend Policy, Growth, and the Valuation of Shares”, Journal of Business, vol. 34,
no.4, Oct. 1961, pp. 411-433.
Page | 6
YTM = the yield to maturity that the bond will generate at a price P, i.e. the expected return
The convenience here is that a bond typically pays a fixed amount (ergo the “fixed income” label).
Extending this methodology to any other investment where the cash flow is not predetermined
obviously creates some challenges. If the investment does not have a fixed payment for a fixed
number of periods, then the calculation moves from the realm of certainty (the fixed coupon) to
a more difficult exercise of forecasting the future. Applying this methodology to the world of
equities where the payments in the future are uncertain (if not random) and are dependent on
varying drivers such as growth, interest rates, profits, etc. makes the application of DCF to the
valuation of equities challenging, requiring several estimates … and often pushing practitioners
to look for alternatives and shortcuts such as the deceptive multiples. As mentioned earlier, it is
precisely this need for more challenging “homework” and “binding” assumptions that is often
cited as the principal drawback of the DCF methodology, despite its unquestionable conceptual
superiority.
𝑡= ∞
𝐷𝑃𝑆𝑡
(1) 𝐼𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑖𝑛𝑠𝑖𝑐 𝑉𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒𝐷𝐷𝑀 = ∑
(1 + 𝑘)𝑡
𝑡=1
Where:
𝐷𝑃𝑆𝑡 = the dividend at time t
k = expected rate of return, a.k.a. cost of equity.
Next, and to make the cash flow further closer to “fixed”, the model assumes that the dividend
will grow at a constant rate, the Constant Growth Model, a.k.a. the Gordon Growth Model. The
assumption is realistic when applied to firms that have reached a “steady state” or a state where
Page | 7
𝐸(𝐷1 )
(2) 𝑉𝑆𝑡𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑦 𝑆𝑡𝑎𝑡𝑒 =
𝑘−𝑔
Where:
E (𝐷1 ) = Expected Dividend for next period
k = Expected Return, a.k.a. cost of capital
g = Constant growth rate
Typically, the growth rate for the steady state is assumed to be the same as the economy 11. This
assumption however can be further refined to zoom on to the key fundamental drivers of value,
and then relate these to the market price and multiples. From basic equity algebra, the Dividend
for period 1 will be equal to:
10
For the mathematical derivation of this equation, see Bodie, Zvi, Kane, Alex, and Marcus, Alan J. Investments.
Irwing, 1989, p. 475.
11
Typical assumption is: over the long term a firm cannot grow at a rate higher than the economy, otherwise, the
firm eventually becomes the economy. By contrast, the firm can grow at a rate lower than the economy; it will just
fade over time and disappear as a financial/economic concern.
Page | 8
This market value equation can finally be expressed as a Price Earnings Ratio by simply dividing
each side by the Earnings at time 0:
If the P/E in turn is stated as a forward P/E, i.e. in terms of next year Earnings, then equation (5)
can be further simplified as:
Despite its apparently restrictive assumptions (constant growth, steady state, etc.,) equation (6)
has several revealing considerations and applications that warrant close attention. To start with,
it is the first “revealing” outcome of this paper as it clearly outlines how the P/E ratio can explicitly
be linked (is dependent) with fundamentals, i.e. determined by those same fundamentals
explicitly needed in a DCF … and which are apparently dreaded by the diehard users of multiples.
Equation (6) unmistakably shows how the P/E ratio is an increasing function of the payout ratio
and the growth rate and a decreasing function of the discount rate k. Thus, using the P/E as a
value metric conceptually means accepting unambiguously the fundamental assumptions of
payout ratio, growth and discount rate concealed in the ratio … i.e., accepting unspecified
fundamental assumptions determined by someone else!
One corollary of the above findings is that equation (6) seems to violate part of the M&M findings
and their widely accepted work on Corporate Finance and valuations. In fact, a fundamental
finding of M&M’s seminal work is that the dividend policy (i.e. payout ratio) will have no effect
on the value of the firm12. Under perfect market assumptions, the rational investor will be
indifferent to receiving cash flow in the form of dividend or capital gains. The implication is that
if management increases the dividend payout, it will have to reduce investments, thus reducing
the intrinsic value of the firm and the terminal price of the stock. While correct, this violation
does not reject the basic finding that multiples are explicitly driven by fundamentals.
12
Miller, M. and Modigliani, F. 1961, Op. Cit.
Page | 9
𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠1 𝑷 𝟏
(7) 𝑃 = 𝒂𝒏𝒅 =
𝑘 𝑬 𝒌
That is, the price of the stock is simply the present value of a stream of Earnings all paid out as
dividend, and the corresponding P/E is equal to the reciprocal of the cost of capital15. Thus, one
paramount deduction from (6) is that stocks do not become “growth stocks” because Earnings
are growing; they become growth stock only if investments are growing … and investments will
grow only if they generate returns higher than the cost of funding them, i.e. returns greater than
k. Thus, growth is not THE driver of high P/E, excess return over the cost of capital is … and by-
the-way, growth will generate value! To quote M&M again, “The essence of “growth”, in short,
is not expansion, but the existence of opportunities to invest significant quantities of funds at
higher than “normal” rates of returns.”16
The logic at the base of equation (7) is sometimes (regrettably) used as a conceptual cover by
some analysts and investors to determine the aggregate cost of capital for a market or an
economic system, i.e. determining k as the reciprocal of the P/E. The loose reasoning is that, if
one is considering the entire economy as the market, or tacking an average of all sectors and
industries, the original assumption of constant growth at the base of equation (5) makes sense
13
The “growth” and “value” factors. Value Investment, for some reason, has completely lost its intrinsic value
connotation and is now broadly defined as “… stock with low Price to Book ratio”.
14
If the payout ratio is equal to 1 (all the earnings are distributed as dividend), then:
𝑔 = 𝑅𝑂𝐸 𝑥 (1 − 1) = 0
15
Depreciation is equal to Capex , hence Net Operating Profit after tax is equal to cash flow.
16
Miller, M. and Modigliani, F. 1961, Opt. Cit., p. 417.
Page | 10
1
(7𝑎) 𝑘̂ =
𝑝/𝑒
Figure 1 below plots this “derived” measure ( 𝑘̂ ) against the level of the S&P500 for well over
three decades. The degree of dispersion and volatility of 𝑘̂ over time is alarming if one were to
methodically use this market metric to determine the intrinsic value of any investment or, worse
yet, use it as a signal to invest. Now, some investors smooth out this cyclical volatility hindrance
of the P/E by using cyclically adjusted Earnings, or the famous CAPE ratio (Cyclically Adjusted
Price-to-Earnings Ratio) of Prof. R. Shiller17. However, and as further elaborated below in section
3, Earnings are just an accounting suggestion. Hence, cyclically adjusted Earnings (CAPE) are just
an average of accounting suggestions18 … i.e., alchemy is prospering in the world of finance.
Figure 1
S&P500 vs. the Market Capitalization Rate
3500 9%
1500 4%
3%
1000
2%
500
1%
0 0%
9/1/1987
9/1/1988
9/1/1989
9/1/1990
9/1/1991
9/1/1992
9/1/1993
9/1/1994
9/1/1995
9/1/1996
9/1/1997
9/1/1998
9/1/1999
9/1/2000
9/1/2001
9/1/2002
9/1/2003
9/1/2004
9/1/2005
9/1/2006
9/1/2007
9/1/2008
9/1/2009
9/1/2010
9/1/2011
9/1/2012
9/1/2013
9/1/2014
9/1/2015
9/1/2016
9/1/2017
9/1/2018
9/1/2019
Source: Bloomberg
Despite the restrictive assumptions, the steady state construct is sometime used to estimate
(albeit very roughly) the level of expectation priced in the market. Recalling the M&M framework
17
Campbell, John Y. and Shiller, Robert J. “Stock Prices, Earnings, and Expected Dividends” in Papers and
Proceedings of the Forty-Seventh Annual Meeting of the American Finance Association, Chicago, Illinois, 28-30 Dec.
1987. Journal of Finance, vol. 43, no. 3, Jul. 1988, pp. 661-676.
18
One of the top 5 U.S. investment houses actually calculates the market ERP (Equity Risk Premium, or cost of
capital less the risk-free rate), by subtraction from the reciprocal of the CAPE a Zero-Coupon yield, all adjusted for
inflation.
Page | 11
19
Mauboussin, Michael J. and Callahan, Dan. “What Does a Price-Earnings Multiple Mean? An Analytical Bridge
Between P/Es and Solid Economics.” Global Financial Strategies, Credit Suisse, 29 Jan. 2014.
20
A similar technique is also described in various publications by McKinsey, see “All P/E are not Created Equals”,
McKinsey on Finance, Spring 2004, pp. 12.
Page | 12
(1 + 𝑔)𝑛
𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠0 𝑥 (𝑃𝑎𝑦𝑜𝑢𝑡 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜) 𝑥 (1 + 𝑔) 𝑥 (1 − )
(1 + 𝑘)𝑛
(8) 𝑃0 = +
(𝑘 − 𝑔)
𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠0 𝑥 (𝑃𝑎𝑦𝑜𝑢𝑡 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 ) 𝑥 (1 + 𝑔)𝑛 𝑥 (1 + 𝑔𝑛 )
(𝑘𝑛 + 𝑔𝑛 )(1 + 𝑘)𝑛
Where:
𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠0 = Earnings at time 0
Payout Ratio for the first n years
𝑃𝑎𝑦𝑜𝑢𝑡 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 after year n and at perpetuity
g = growth rate in the first n years
𝑔𝑛 = growth rate after year n and in perpetuity
k = Discount rate (a.k.a. required rate of return) for the first period
𝑘𝑛 = Discount Rate after year n
Now dividing each side by 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠0 to get the P/E ratio as done above for equation (5):
(1 + 𝑔)𝑛
𝑃 𝑷 (𝑃𝑎𝑦𝑜𝑢𝑡 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜) 𝑥 (1 + 𝑔) 𝑥 (1 − )
(1 + 𝑘)𝑛
(10) = = +
𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑠0 𝑬 (𝑘 − 𝑔)
(𝑃𝑎𝑦𝑜𝑢𝑡 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 ) 𝑥 (1 + 𝑔)𝑛 𝑥 (1 + 𝑔𝑛 )
(𝑘𝑛 + 𝑔𝑛 )(1 + 𝑘)𝑛
Just like equation (6) above, equation (10) clearly and unquestionably defines the P/E ratio in
terms of fundamentals. Equation (10) quantitatively describe that the P/E ratio will increase
Page | 13
21
Hint: DPS = Book Value x ROE x Payout Ratio
Page | 14
22
Some erroneously also call it “equity duration”, equating it to the very rigorous, analytical, and meaningful
metric for bonds.
23
If one blindly believes in the stability (stationarity) of the mean -- as everyone using this approach implicitly does
-- one only needs to know how to add or subtract, literally!
Page | 15
Figure 2
Netflix
An Outlandish P/E ... Prelude for Massive Returns
$500 Source: Bloomberg 450
$450 400
10 Year Average P/E to 2012
$400 350
roughly ~3x the LT market P/E,
$350 right at the start of a 1,116% 300
$300 rally over the next ~10 years!
250
$250
200
$200
150
$150
$100 100
$50 50
$0 0
9/1/2003
3/1/2004
9/1/2004
3/1/2005
9/1/2005
3/1/2006
9/1/2006
3/1/2007
9/1/2007
3/1/2008
9/1/2008
3/1/2009
9/1/2009
3/1/2010
9/1/2010
3/1/2011
9/1/2011
3/1/2012
9/1/2012
3/1/2013
9/1/2013
3/1/2014
9/1/2014
3/1/2015
9/1/2015
3/1/2016
9/1/2016
3/1/2017
9/1/2017
3/1/2018
9/1/2018
3/1/2019
9/1/2019
3/1/2020
Source: Bloomberg
Even assuming that comparisons with historical averages are fair game, the question remains:
which historical period? The last 100 years? 50 … 30 … 20 years? A question with many, albeit all
subjective answers. In addition, the dilemma is that as illustrated in Figure 3 below, the P/E ratio
can exhibit quite a bit of dispersion around pretty much any mean (arbitrarily) selected, swinging
by more than 50 percent from peak to trough, several times during the 30 years reported.
24
John Maynard Keynes famously wisecracked: “In the long term we are all dead.”
Page | 16
25
20
15
10
PE_RATIO Av. 1980
5
10/1/1981
11/1/1982
12/1/1983
10/1/1994
11/1/1995
12/1/1996
10/1/2007
11/1/2008
12/1/2009
9/1/1980
1/1/1985
2/1/1986
3/1/1987
4/1/1988
5/1/1989
6/1/1990
7/1/1991
8/1/1992
9/1/1993
1/1/1998
2/1/1999
3/1/2000
4/1/2001
5/1/2002
6/1/2003
7/1/2004
8/1/2005
9/1/2006
1/1/2011
2/1/2012
3/1/2013
4/1/2014
5/1/2015
6/1/2016
7/1/2017
8/1/2018
9/1/2019
Source: Bloomberg
In order to remove both the Earnings volatility and the (arbitrary) selection of the historical
period, Nobel Laureate R. Shiller developed an ingenious methodology, the Cyclically Adjusted
Price Earning, defined as the ratio of the current stock price divided by a 10-year moving average
of inflation-adjusted Earnings. The approach makes total conceptual sense as the average
Earnings of a cycle will have much better information contents than the Earnings of a single
(random) year. Despite its popularity however, the CAPE has failed to provide a reliable
investment signal, in particular continuing to point to sizeable market overvaluation by remaining
above the historical average for the better part of the last 30 years, with the notable exception
of 2009 (see Figure 4 below). As further elaborated below in Section 3, while the CAPE concept
is convincing, the problem may very well be with the Earnings, a variable that is derived applying
accounting guidance and suggestions, thus making the CAPE an average of “suggestions”!
Page | 17
Source: https://www.multpl.com/shiller-pe
The next common application is to relate equity multiples to one or more comparable firms, the
logic being that similar business will have similar capital requirements, similar capital structure,
will be dependent on the same economic trends, will have similar profit margins and risk, and
will face similar competition. It stands to reason therefore that they should also have similar
valuation … and, according to convention, they should also have similar multiples!
In a perfect market, there is no question that that should be the case, especially if the comparison
is based on the same set of fundamental value drivers … i.e., the same set of fundamental drivers
identified in equation (10) above! The trouble is that it is extremely difficult to find two
businesses that are the same or at least “within the ballpark” to justify comparisons and assess
value. And it is equally difficult to substantiate this approach empirically.
Table 1 below reports the main fundamental value drivers together with the main multiples for
the most popular Tech stocks, i.e. the famous FAANG25 group slightly expanded. The last line
reports the deviation of each variable from its mean. As can be appreciated, the deviation is
massive in pretty much all cases, making any comparison futile. Yet, these names and their
multiples, together or worse yet as a group, are very often referred to when debating value in
the entire Tech sector.
25
Facebook, Amazon, Apple, Netflix, Google
Page | 18
Long
Market Cost of Term EV/EBIT
Cap ROIC * Equity Growth P/E P/B DA
Name (in B $) **
Apple Inc $ 1,863 28.76 8.61 11.60 33.40 26.03 22.46
Amazon.com Inc $ 1,559 9.42 7.00 32.26 121.69 21.51 35.96
Alphabet Inc $ 1,006 13.42 - 15.83 33.92 4.86 18.88
Facebook Inc $ 718 21.03 8.42 23.69 30.81 6.51 18.95
Alibaba Group Holding Ltd $ 692 7.40 10.70 23.50 44.23 6.44 36.50
Tesla Inc $ 277 4.32 12.15 35.00 646.62 28.33 70.96
NVIDIA Corp $ 271 20.15 10.55 18.78 82.43 20.87 65.86
Netflix Inc $ 220 14.13 7.39 32.13 75.68 23.87 57.73
Baidu Inc $ 42 1.26 10.94 7.00 20.66 1.83 16.70
Twitter Inc $ 29 (11.61) 10.01 9.50 -- 3.76 52.88
Average $ 667 10.83 8.58 20.93 121.05 14.40 39.69
Deviation from the mean $ 604 10.87 3.26 9.53 188.32 10.00 19.69
Source: Bloomberg as of August 4, 2020. *Return on Invested Capital. ** As calculated and reported by Bloomberg.
Table 2 below reports the same variables for a group of US National regulated utilities, that is a
group of stocks which can justifiably be classified as “steady state” businesses and are therefore
highly and directly comparable. Despite the more homogenous and legitimate grouping, the
deviation from the average for each variable is nonetheless large enough to challenge
comparisons across businesses that should be extremely similar.
Page | 19
26
For a thorough review of this practice, see Rosenbaum, J., Pearl, J. Investment Banking. John Wiley & Sons, Inc.,
2009.
Page | 20
40
30
20
10
Source: Bloomberg
Page | 21
35
% Diff. 25%
30 Source: Bloomberg
Linear ( % 20%
25
Diff. )
20 15%
15 10%
10
5%
5
0%
0
-5 -5%
12/1/1990
10/1/1991
12/1/1995
10/1/1996
12/1/2000
10/1/2001
12/1/2005
10/1/2006
12/1/2010
10/1/2011
12/1/2015
10/1/2016
8/1/1992
6/1/1993
4/1/1994
2/1/1995
8/1/1997
6/1/1998
4/1/1999
2/1/2000
8/1/2002
6/1/2003
4/1/2004
2/1/2005
8/1/2007
6/1/2008
4/1/2009
2/1/2010
8/1/2012
6/1/2013
4/1/2014
2/1/2015
8/1/2017
6/1/2018
4/1/2019
Source: Bloomberg
As can be appreciated, the difference is not only sizeable but has been on an upward trend for
the last 30 years reported in the graph. The impact on the P/E using the two different versions of
Earnings is equally sizeable. The graph below illustrates this point by reporting the percentage of
underestimation of the P/E ratio using the final Earnings instead of Earnings before extraordinary
items. The conclusion is the same: an ever and growing presence of items that are considered,
i.e., justified by the accounting principles, “unusual and infrequent”! And yet, most of the
financial media “narrates” only on the basis of the final reported “unusual” Earnings and then
goes on to compare it with history, markets, etc. This in turn is leading others to refer to good-
old mean-reversion arguments, comparing historical “usual” Earnings with “unusual” ones … the
alchemy of finance continues to prosper!
Page | 22
Source: Bloomberg
Source: Bloomberg
Table 3 below extends the same exercise across a few selected well-advanced markets reporting
the percentage difference between final Earnings and Earnings before extraordinary items. The
curious thing is that the extraordinary items seem to occur with frequency and size only in the
US markets. Even removing the US small caps (RTY) massive dispersion from the table, the
difference between the S&P and other major benchmarks is staggering … these “other” markets
never seem to suffer either gain or pain from extraordinary events, and when they do, the impact
is miniscule … intriguing!
Table 3 SPX RTY SXXP TPX UKX
12/31/2002 68.12% -192.82% 2.80% 0.29% 3.44%
12/31/2003 10.97% 264.34% 1.27% 2.63% 2.78%
12/31/2004 15.06% 76.81% 0.73% 0.00% 0.46%
12/30/2005 6.60% 30.05% -1.06% 0.02% -0.90%
12/29/2006 4.86% -10.63% 0.86% 0.04% 1.35%
12/31/2007 19.42% 77.57% 1.26% 0.04% 0.78%
12/31/2008 182.86% -111.65% -3.20% -0.17% -22.18%
12/31/2009 13.73% -227.56% 1.47% -0.36% 2.99%
12/31/2010 5.86% 6.49% -0.39% 0.02% 0.61%
12/30/2011 6.68% 37.91% -1.16% 0.00% 0.31%
12/31/2012 15.17% 63.19% -0.29% -0.02% 0.72%
12/31/2013 5.15% 38.79% 0.86% 0.01% 1.33%
12/31/2014 9.78% 41.88% -1.51% 0.01% -2.01%
12/31/2015 21.78% 11107.41% 0.07% -0.03% 0.03%
12/30/2016 13.43% 154.59% 0.86% 0.00% 0.67%
12/29/2017 12.97% -1104.93% -6.19% -0.01% 0.57%
12/31/2018 14.03% 179.97% -1.57% 0.01% -6.34%
12/31/2019 9.48% 1841.21% 0.88% 0.00% 0.05%
Average 24.22% 681.81% -0.24% 0.14% -0.85%
Source: Bloomberg. RTY= US small caps, SXXP= Europe, TPX= Japan, UKX=UK Footsie 100.
Page | 23
27
For the sceptics, please note the seldom but unfortunately practiced form of aggressive accounting, legal in most
cases yet distorting. See for example https://www.accountingtools.com/articles/what-is-aggressive-
accounting.html.
28
Jack L. Treynor, was a key member of a tiny group of theorists from which the efficient market hypothesis (EMH),
the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), and the random walk hypothesis emerged in the 1960s. In the words of
Robert Merton, a Nobel laureate, Treynor was “… a leader in the intellectual development and incorporation of
modern finance into practice”. Although others who worked on related ideas received Nobel Prizes, Mr. Treynor is
recognized as one of the discoverers of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), a cornerstone contribution to finance
that codifies the role of risk in expected investment returns.
29
Treynor, Jack L. “The Trouble with Earnings.” Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 28, no. 5, Sep-Oct. 1972, pp. 41-43.
30
Treynor, Jack L. “Feathered Feast: A Case.” Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 49, no. 6, pp. 9-12, 1993, doi: 10.2469.
Page | 24
4. Conclusions
Whether analytically, descriptively, or practically, the principal conclusion of this paper is that
Multiples have no theoretical underpinning and, more to the point, have zero economic value
meaning. They remain for all intents and purposes a matter of market convention and
convenience. Indeed, the myths and manias of using them in investment parlance may have more
to do with behavioral sciences than finance or economic science; as the title of this paper
insinuates, multiples might be a perfect example of financial alchemy!
As presented in our analysis, Multiples are “alleged” to incorporate into one single number the
combined economic impact of several drivers of value, such as profitability, risk, cost of capital,
growth, time, etc. The snag is that the value of these drivers is hermetically concealed into one
ratio, e.g. a ratio that, as put by Jack Treynor “… has taken on a kind of mystical significance
completely unrelated to economic reality.31” To that end, Multiples are of little use to the
fundamental investor concerned primarily with extracting from current market conditions the
implied expectation for these drivers and then assessing their likelihood. I.e. multiples are of little
use to fundamental investors that would rather dissect the present instead of blindly forecast
the future … very often a painful exercise in overconfidence.
Our postulate is that, while it was defensible to use Multiples during the time of “Abacus and
small data”, it is reprehensible that in the modern time of quantum computing, Big Data, AI,
FinTech, etc. multiples continue to be widely preferred over more robust, gold-standards of
valuation grounded on sound economic principles. Thus, our conclusions and practitioner
recommendation are to treat multiples for what they are: a widely popular momentum indicator
and a barometer of market sentiment.
31
Treynor, Jack. 1972. Op. CIt.
Page | 25
Page | 26