Lnflation, Unemployment, and Monetary Rules
Lnflation, Unemployment, and Monetary Rules
_J
1 and Monetary Rules
The aim of this chapter is to move beyond the models presented in Chapter 2 so that
we can analyse inflation and the monetary mies that are used by contemporary central
banks-i.e. when lhe central bank sets the interest rate to stabilize the economy around
an inflation target. ln order to do this, we first introduce Phillips curves and show how
they are derived from the labour market diagram. The key to understanding the Phillips
curves is that when unemployment is at the equilibrium levei, inflation is co nstant;
when unemployment is lower, infl ation goes up and when unemployment is higher,
inflation goes down. This suggests that it might be possible to mn the economy at lower
unemployment but with a higher rate of inflation. However, as we shall see, such a trade-
off is only possible in the short mn because wage setters are concerned about the real
wage and they will react when their real wage is eroded by inflation by pushing up their
wage claims. ln the Iong mn, there is no trade-offbetween unemployment and inflation:
this is shown by a vertical long-mn Phillips curve.
Central banks are now typically viewed as operating monetary policy through adjusting
the interest rate in order to keep the economy dose to its inflation target at the equilibrium
levei of output. Since inflation is only constant at equilibrium output, this appears logica l.
The reason the central bank plays an active role in managing the economy is because the
economy is subject to ali kinds of disturbances that shift either inflation away from its
target or output away from the equilibrium levei or both. These shocks o r disturbances
produce changes in inflation that are persistent and costly to elimina te so there is a case
for the central bank intervening to try to minimize the fluctuati ons.
lf we take as an example a rightward shift of the IS curve as th e result of an invest-
ment boom, this will push inflation up. The higher inflation will get incorpora ted intu
future wage- and price-setting decisions and will o nly be squeezed out of the econo my
by a period of unemploym ent above the equilibrium. The aim of the central bank is tu
minimize the cost to the economy of this shock in term s of the higher intlation caused by
it and the higher unemployment required to reduce it. lt will raise lhe int erest rate soas
to dampen aggregate demand and guide the economy back toward target intlation anti
equilibrium unemployment. Thi s behavi our of the central bank is oft en described as th e
use of a 'reaction function' or moneta ry policy mie.
By combining the Phillips curve, the JS curve and the central ban k's mo netary mi e, we
have the so-ca lled 3-equatio n mudei, IS-l'C-MR . This mudei is a textbook versiun of the
one used in contemporary central banks anel in more atlvanced treatments of moneta ry
macroeconomics. ln Chapt er S, mo netary policy is cxplored in grea ter depth and we
68 THE MACROECONOMIC MODEL
Inflation is the rate of change of prices, which means the price levei today reflects the
pattern of past inflation. Unless inflation is negative, which is called deflation, the price
levei does not fali. If P is today's price levei and P_1 is last period's price levei, then the
rate of inflation over the past year is rr:
_ P-P_ 1
'll'=-p--·
-1
Fig. 1.4 in Chapter I displays the inflation rates in severa! countries from the 1960s to
the present: whilst inflation in the past decade has been low at 2 to 3% in many of the
OECD countries, it was much higher often at rates between 10 and 20% in the 1970s.
Policy makers are concerned about inflation. High inflation tends also to be volatile
and this creates uncertainty and undermines the way in which prices convey informa-
tion. As we shall see, it is costly to reduce high inflation-i.e. an increase in unemploy-
ment is normally required to bring inflation down. These reasons lie behind the so-called
inflation-targeting regimes of central banks. For a fuller discussion of inflation and its
costs, see Chapter 5. The objective of this section is to explore the or·g· f • fl . d
1 ms o m ation an
inflationary pressure.
(adaptive expectations)
where a is a positive constant less than or equal to one. lf past forecasting mistakes are
fully corrected so that a = 1, we have
' For r~cent evidence, see Christi ano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005); also Estrella and Fuhrer (2002). and
Muellbauer and Nunziata (2004).
70 THE MACROECONOMIC MODEL
f inertia in its interpretation.
, hasize the role o
lagged inflation and denote it by rr to emp
Wehave:
7í = rr1 + a(y - r,)
+ a (y-y,).
current ~nflation inflat:~ (nertia
.outputt·gapaugmented Phillips curve)
(iner 1a-
l d inflation term is interpreted
This is the inertia-augmented Phillips curve. When th e agge . expectations (rrE = 71' _ 1)
as reflecting expected inflation on the assumption of adapuve '
· sed·
the term Expectations-augmented Phillips curve 1s u ·
We now tum to extending the macro model by deriving the Phillips curves.
P=(l+íl) - : ,
w -T
b.P b.W b.>.
P = ·
ln the sim pie
. case. where average labour productivity (>.) is
· constant, the only determinant
o f ch anges m umt 1abour costs is money wage changes:
-w ·
b.P b.W
p
INFlATION, UNEMPLOYMENT, MONETARY RULES 71
w WScurve
p
Wz - -- -- - - -- -
: :1 _-_-_-_----~~-~p-_~,~-=~2~_%
____-r:--- ~ ::::::::~ _;J~~p5_:.'.CU~rv
~e
Eo E2 E
Figure 3.1 Upward pressure_on inflation when employment is above equilibrium employment;
downw ard pressure on 1nflat1on when employment is below equil ibrium employment
o E1 4 o 4 4
1 E1 4 o 4 4
2 E1 4 o 4 4
3 E1 4 o 4 4
4 -2 2 2
1 Eo
2 -2 o o
2 Eo
3 Eo o - 2 -2 - 2
Money wages have risen by 4% and so unit labour costs have risen by 4%. Therefore firms
must raise prices by 4% in order to keep their profit margin unchanged. We have deduced
that price and wage inflation remain unchanged at 4% per year and the economy remains
at point A (see Fig. 3.1). This is illustrated as Case 1 in Table 3.1 .
Suppose now that employment is at E2 , which is higher than the equilibrium and that
lagged in.flation is 4%. With employment of E2, the real wage on the WS curve lies 2%
above w (shown by the 'gap' in Fig. 3.1 and Table 3.1). Money wages will have to be
1
raised by 4% to keep the real wage unchanged; they will be raised by another 2% to take
72 THE MACROECONOMIC MODEL
th . . by 4% + 2% = 6%). With
e real wage up to W2 on the WS curve (money wages wtll nse t reserve their profit
a money wage rise of 6%, firms will increase prices by 6% so ~sfl o _P is higher than .
10
margin. Thus, we observe wage and price inflation of 6%-i.e. at!O~ h • bin
the . . wages and pnces ave nsen y
th prev,ous period. The other thing to note is that stnce . • ated by wage setters.
e sarne amount, the real wage is w 1 and not the W2 ant1ctp .
· h ·se in 10flat1on . from 4% to
U nemployment lower than the ERU is associated wtt ª n . .. .
6%. But inflation will not remain at 6% because the labour market is not m equthbnum.
Th al . 1wage of w 2 • When wages are
e re wage outcome was w 1 yet wage setters requ1re a rea
next set, the 'catch-up' wage increase is 6% to cover past inflation so money wages will
· b • ·11 b aised by 8%. We observe the
nse Y8% to take the real wage to w 2 • ln tum, pnces Wt e r . . ..
phenomenon that unemployment below the equilibrium rate is assoc1ated w1th nsmg
inflation (see Table 3.1). nd
If we take the converse case of unemployment above the ERU ª employment of
Eo, the sarne reasoning gives the result that inflation is falling. At h~gh unem~l~yment,
workers' power in the labour market is weakened, which is reflected 10 th e positive slope
of the WS curve. At employment of less than E,, the WS curve is below the PS curve.
ln such a situation, the increased competition for jobs means workers will not be able
to get money wage increases of the full 4% that would maintain their real wage. The
money wage increase set by wage setters is 4% minus the 'gap' of 2%, i.e. 2%. With their
costs rising by 2%, firms raise their prices by 2%, keeping their profit margins unchanged.
Thus inflation falls to 2% (see Table 3.1). Since wages and prices have increased by the
sarne amount, nothing happens to the real wage. ln the following period, the negative
gap between the WS curve and the prevailing real wage persists. Once again, the market
conditions mean that wage setters will be unable to maintain the real wage of Wt: the
money wage increase is 2% minus the 2% gap, i.e. money wages will not rise at ali. ln
period 3, as we can see in the table, money wages and prices fall by 2%. Unemployment
above the ERU is accompanied by falling inflation.
These results can be illustrated using a Phillips curve diagram. This has inflation on
the vertical axis and output on the horizontal one. Just like the SAS curves of Chapter 2,
which refered to the price levei not the inflation rate, the Phillips curves are intimately
related to the wage-setting and price-setting curves and are best understood when drawn
on a diagram directlybelow the WS/PS diagram (see Fig. 3.2).
ln reality, there is nota one-for-one relationship between a rise inoutput anda fali in
unemployment. When output rises, workers who have been kept on the pay-roll but have
not been fully employed (e.g. working shorter than normal hours) may be fully utilized
with the result that higher output does not-at least initially-entail a rise in employ-
ment. This is called labour hoarding. Second, even if employment rises, unemployment
does not necessarily fall if the new jobs are taken by those who were not previously in the
Jabour force. People of working age who are neither employed nor unemployed are called
economically inactive and the decision of whether or not to participate in the Jabour
market is responsive to economic conditions.
The combination of labour hoarding and changes in the labour force mean that a 1%
change inoutput growth above or below its trend tends to be associated with respectively
a fali or rise in the unemployment rate of less than 0.5 percentage points. This empír-
ica! relationship between changes in the growth rate relative to its trend and changes
INFLATION , UNEMPLOYMENT, MONETARY RULES 73
w
p
2%
-2% PS curve
WScurve
Eo Ez E
Inflation (1T)
1
Vertical Phillips curve (VPC) ---+
Phillips curves:
PC (1T 1=6%)
PC(1T 1=4%)
PC (1T 1=2%)
PC (1T 1=0%)
1
Phillips curves for the examples in Table 3.1. With 1r = 1r_ 1 = 4%, we have identified
three feasible inflation and output pairs: at E1 , 1r = 4%; at Ez, 1r = 6%; and at Eo, 1r = 2%.
This is the Phillips curve for 1r1 = 4% and we show it in Fig. 3.2. To emphasize that the
Phillips curve is only defined for a given 1r1 , it is labelled PC( 1r1 = 4%). Using the data in
2
Table 3.1, we can plot the other Phillips curves and they are shown in Fig. 3.2.
2 Note that in the alternative interpretation of the role of lagged inflation in the Phillips curves, expected
inflation is equal to lagged inílation (7rE = 7r _ i) and the fa mily of Phillips curves (e.g . PC(1l = 4%) ) is
described as 'expectatio ns augmented'.
74 THE MACROECONOMIC MODEL
1r = 1r 1 + a(y - y,)
(3.1 )
7r 1'- 1 +a(y -y,)
current inflati on inflation in ertia outp ut ga p
J Note that if lhe PS curve was downward ~l~ping, the slope of the Phillips curve wo uld be sleepe r, refl ecling
lhe slope o f both the WS and lhe PS curves. l h IS m1rrors lhe discussion in Ch a pter 2 aboul lhe slo pe o f lhe SAS
curve. 4 Phillips ( 1958).
INFLATION , UNEMPLOYMENT, MONETARV RULES 75
1T
X
6%
4%
e
X
X
2%
10
.,;
8
.,
"""'3: 6
.,
. .. .
>,
e:"'
o ., 4
-
E~
o o.
QJ
. • ... . . ..
... •. . ..
2
•-i..
e:
"'e.,
.e:: o .. . •• . +•
.
õ
"'
e,:
-2 . .
•
-4
o 3 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11
Unemployment, %
• Can the government use policy to shift the economy from its customary position at
point A to a higher levei of activity at point B (in Fig. 3.3)? The policy maker may be
tempted to doso in order to reduce unemployment at the cost of a small rise in
inflation.
Suppose that the government increases the money supply (to shift the LM cu rve to the
right). The interest rate falis and output is raised via higher investment spending. Unlike
the random shocks that shifted the economy from A to D to B to C to A etc. in the world
76 THE MACROECONOMIC MODEL
. d 1·fferent situation: the governrnent
of the original Phillips curve, we have here ªquite. . with 1ower unemployrnent
. . fers a s1tuat10n
1s seeking to keep output at y 2 because it pre nc for the economy to be near
nd
even if there is some inflation. Eventually, th e te e they will build the 2% p.a.
. O f workers-1.e.
point B is likely to figure in the calculattons . . f m zero to 2% p.a. At this
. d. fl fon w1U nse ro
mflation into their wage claims: expecte m ª 1 ment disappears because
. . fl t'10 n and unemp1oy
pomt, the long-run trade-off between tn a . h 1't olicy of holding output
. . . t ersists w1t s P
the Ph1lhps curve sh1fts up. lf the governmen P . Case 2 in Table 3.1 and the lower
at Y2, the Phillips curve will continue to sh1ft up as in .
.h • reasing inflat10n.
unemployment will be associated w1t ever-mc . . onomics called the
. · f something m ec
This example
.. provides an important . 11lustrat1on
. . ·° .
d by Philhps seeme d to suggest
Lucas cntique. s White the relationsh1p ongmally eSttmate . d
1 ment th1s co 11apse as soon
the existence of a trade-off between inflation and unemp oy '
. . e only existed because govern-
as the government tried to exploit it. A stable Ph111 1ps curv .
• 1 Th tusion that the pohcy maker
ments did not systematically try to make use of 1t. e cone
· 11· bove the levei of output at the
cannot choose any point other than one on a vertICa me a .
· · rh·11· curve This is a useful remmder
ERU, has led to the not10n of a vertical long-run 1 1ps ·
when analysing policy, and is shown in the Phillips curve diagram as VPC. 1t may be
noted, that if governments cease to try to run the economy at unemployment below the
ERU, the original Phillips curve of a stable trade-off may well reappear in the data.
7r=L1+ a (y-y,)
=> (1r - 'lr- t) = a (y - Ye)
lf(1r - 1r_1) < O,
then a (y - y,) < O
=> y < y,.
s This was one ol lhe contributions for which Robert Lucas was -1 d.
(Lucas (1976)) . ci e m lhe award of the Nobel prize in 1995
INFLATION, UNEMPLOYMENT, MONETARY RULES 77
1T
VPC
7
F/
6 --- - - -- -- ----- - \ ----
5
F''.
4
3
1TT =2
Yc y
We can also demonstrate the point using an example and a diagram. 6 ln Fig. 3.5, the
economy is at point B with high inflation of 8% (on PC(rr1 = 8)). lt is assu med that
the central bank wishes to reduce inflation to its target rate, which is 2%. The Phillips
curve shows the feasible inflation and output pairs, given last period's inflation, of 8%.
The only points on the curve with intlation below 8% are to the left of B, i.e. with high er
unemployment. With Phillips curves like this, disinflation will always be costly. lt should
be clear that if the influence of the past on wage setters could be wiped away, then the
possibility of a costless disinflation emerges: this amounts to saying that the policy maker
could shift the PC(rr1 = 8) down, e.g. to PC( rr 1 = 2). ln this case, the economy would
jump from B to A.
Returning to the Phillips curve PC(rr 1 = 8), we assume that the central bank has chosen
to raise unemployment to point F. lnflation falis to 6% anda new Phillips curve PC( rr1 = 6)
arises. The central bank can then choose a point on PC(rr 1 = 6), point F'. This leads to
a downward shift in the Phillips curve, which is not shown. Eventually, lhe ob jective of
inflation at 2% is achieved and the economy remains at the ERU.
l> Note that we have specified a linear Phillips curve, which is rcflccted in the diagrarn. ln St:'Cti on 2.6 we return
to questi on of the implications of linear as compared with convex Phillipscurves.
i Thi ssounds innocent enough but as weshall see in Chaptcr 5, if the central bank aim s for an un employmen t
rate below th e ERU, it will no t be able to get infl ation down to its target of rrr :;; 2'Hi. Th ls is lmown as the
inílation-bias problem of monetary policy.
78 THE MACROECONOMIC MODEL
1r VPC
- -]3_
8
6
5 PC(rr 1=3)
4
PC(rr 1=2)
3
e
y
Ye
• inflation inertia is absent. This means there are no nominal rigidities in the economy
in wage- or price-setting behaviour or institutions that operate to produce inflation
inertia. And adaptive expectations play no role in wage setting. Instead, the so-called
rational expectations hypothesis holds. Hence, we have
7r = 7rT + E
i.e with inflation remaining constant at the target, apart from unforeseen shocks.
Rational expectations of inflation mean that the onlydifference between what agents in
the economy expect inflation to be and what it turns out to be is something random: they
do not make systematic errors. Another way to express this is that the agent's subjective
expectation of inflation is equal to the 'objective' expectation given ali the available
information about the structure of the economy and about policy that is available at the
time the expectation is formed. Because ali of the information available is used in forming
the expectation, there is no correlation between the error term and the information
available when the expectation is formed. When applied to inflation in our model, the
rational expectations hypothesis means that:
where E is the 'objective' expected value and the Phillips curve is now:
This says that with rational expectations, when output is at equilibrium, inflation is at
target apart from a random shock. We can express this another way, by rearranging as
80 TttE MACROECONOMIC MODEl
follows
l T )
y-y,= -(rr-rr -(
Q
(ir - ;l ).
=
(3.2)
Hence.y = y, + _!_ ( ir - rrE)
o inflation surprise
• in the Lucas surprise supply equation, causality goes from a deviation in inflation
from its expected value to a change inoutput rela tive to equilibrium.
The Lucas supply equation highlights the fact that under the assumptions of ratio-
nal expectations, policy credibility, and the absence of inflation inertia, since it is only
unanticipated changes in inflation that can affect output, systematic monetary policy
is ineffective in altering the levei of activity in the economy. There is also no need for
systematic policy because the economy returns directly to equilibrium once a shock to
inflation has disappeared. These are strong assumptions. As we shall see in the rest of
this chapter and in Chapter 5, because of the presence of inflation inertia, a variety of
economic disturbances shift the economy shift the economy away from equilibrium and
it does not return costlessly to equilibrium of its own accord. As a consequence, central
banks do engage in systematic monetary policy to stabilize the economy.