Many A Slip . Loose Ends in Valuation: Aswath Damodaran
Many A Slip . Loose Ends in Valuation: Aswath Damodaran
Aswath Damodaran
Aswath Damodaran 1
Some Overriding Thoughts
n The biggest reason for bad valuations is not bad models but bias. Building a
better valuation model is easy, but getting the bias out of valuation is difficult.
n Analysts who fault their models for not being more precise are not only
missing the real reason for imprecision (which is that no one can forecast the
future with certainty) but are also setting themselves up for false alternatives.
n Valuation is simple. We choose to make it complex. Complexity always come
with a cost….
Aswath Damodaran 2
So, you’ve valued a firm…
Cost of Capital
Aswath Damodaran 3
But what comes next?
Aswath Damodaran 4
1. The Value of Cash
n The simplest and most direct way of dealing with cash and marketable
securities is to keep it out of the valuation - the cash flows should be before
interest income from cash and securities, and the discount rate should not be
contaminated by the inclusion of cash. (Use betas of the operating assets alone
to estimate the cost of equity).
n Once the operating assets have been valued, you should add back the value of
cash and marketable securities.
Aswath Damodaran 5
How much cash is too much cash?
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
0-1% 1-2% 2-5% 5-10% 10-15% 15-20% 20-25% 25-30% >30%
Aswath Damodaran 6
Should you ever discount cash for its low returns?
n There are some analysts who argue that companies with a lot of cash on their
balance sheets should be penalized by having the excess cash discounted to
reflect the fact that it earns a low return.
• Excess cash is usually defined as holding cash that is greater than what the firm
needs for operations.
• A low return is defined as a return lower than what the firm earns on its non-cash
investments.
n This is the wrong reason for discounting cash. If the cash is invested in
riskless securities, it should earn a low rate of return. As long as the return is
high enough, given the riskless nature of the investment, cash does not destroy
value.
n There is a right reason, though, that may apply to some companies…
Aswath Damodaran 7
The Value of Cash
n Implicitly, we are assuming here that the market will value cash at face value.
Assume now that you are buying a firm whose only asset is marketable
securities worth $ 100 million. Can you ever consider a scenario where you
would not be willing to pay $ 100 million for this firm?
o Yes
o No
n What is or are the scenario(s)?
Aswath Damodaran 8
The Case of Closed End Funds
n Closed end funds are mutual funds, with a fixed number of shares. Unlike
regular mutual funds, where the shares have to trade at net asset value (which
is the value of the securities in the fund), closed end funds shares can and
often do trade at prices which are different from the net asset value.
n The average closed end fund has always traded at a discount on net asset value
(of between 10 and 20%) in the United States.
Aswath Damodaran 9
A Simple Explanation for the Closed End Discount
n Assume that you have a closed-end fund that invests in ‘average risk” stocks.
Assume also that you expect the market (average risk investments) to make
11.5% annually over the long term. If the closed end fund underperforms the
market by 0.50%, estimate the discount on the fund.
Aswath Damodaran 10
A Premium for Marketable Securities: Berkshire Hathaway
Berkshire Hathaway
45000 140.00%
40000
120.00%
35000
100.00%
80.00%
25000 Market Value/Share
Book Value/Share
Premium over Book Value
20000 60.00%
15000
40.00%
10000
20.00%
5000
0 0.00%
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
Year
Aswath Damodaran 11
2. Dealing with Holdings in Other firms
Aswath Damodaran 12
How to value holdings in other firms
Aswath Damodaran 13
How some deal with subsidiaries...
n When financial statements are consolidated, some analysts value the firm with
the consolidated operating income and then subtract minority interests from
the firm value to arrive at the value of the equity in the firm. What is wrong
with this approach?
Aswath Damodaran 14
3. Other Assets that have not been counted yet..
n Unutilized assets: If you have assets or property that are not being utilized
(vacant land, for example), you have not valued it yet. You can assess a
market value for these assets and add them on to the value of the firm.
n Overfunded pension plans: If you have a defined benefit plan and your assets
exceed your expected liabilities, you could consider the over funding with two
caveats:
• Collective bargaining agreements may prevent you from laying claim to these
excess assets.
• There are tax consequences. Often, withdrawals from pension plans get taxed at
much higher rates.
Do not double count an asset. If you count the income from an asset in your
cashflows, you cannot count the market value of the asset in your value.
Aswath Damodaran 15
4. A Discount for Complexity:
An Experiment
Company A Company B
Operating Income $ 1 billion $ 1 billion
Tax rate 40% 40%
ROIC 10% 10%
Expected Growth 5% 5%
Cost of capital 8% 8%
Business Mix Single Business Multiple Businesses
Holdings Simple Complex
Accounting Transparent Opaque
n Which firm would you value more highly?
Aswath Damodaran 16
Sources of Complexity
n Accounting Standards
• Inconsistency in applying accounting principles (Operating leases, R&D etc.)
• Fuzzy Accounting Standards (One-time charges, hidden assets)
• Unintended Consequences of Increased Disclosure
n Nature and mix of businesses
• Multiple businesses (Eg. GE)
• Multiple countries (Eg. Coca Cola)
n Structuring of businesses
• Cross Holdings (The Japanese Curse)
• Creative Holding Structures (Enronitis)
n Financing Choices
• Growth of Hybrids
• New Securities (Playing the Ratings Game)
Aswath Damodaran 17
Reasons for Complexity
n Control
• Complex holding structures were designed to make it more difficult for outsiders
(which includes investors) to know how much a firm is worth, how much it is
making and what assets it holds.
• Multiple classes of shares and financing choices also make it more likely that
incumbents can retain control in the event of a challenge.
n Tax Benefits
• Complex tax law begets complex business mixes and holding structures.
– Different tax rates for different locales and different transactions
– Tax credits
n Deceit
Aswath Damodaran 18
Reasons for Complexity
n Control
• Complex holding structures were designed to make it more difficult for outsiders
(which includes investors) to know how much a firm is worth, how much it is
making and what assets it holds.
• Multiple classes of shares and financing choices also make it more likely that
incumbents can retain control in the event of a challenge.
n Tax Benefits
• Complex tax law begets complex business mixes and holding structures.
– Different tax rates for different locales and different transactions
– Tax credits
n Deceit
Aswath Damodaran 19
Measuring Complexity: Volume of Data in Financial
Statements
Aswath Damodaran 20
Measuring Complexity: A Complexity Score
Aswath Damodaran 21
Dealing with Complexity
n The Aggressive Analyst: Trust the firm to tell the truth and value the firm
based upon the firm’s statements about their value.
n The Conservative Analyst: Don’t value what you cannot see.
n The Compromise: Adjust the value for complexity
• Adjust cash flows for complexity
• Adjust the discount rate for complexity
• Adjust the expected growth rate/ length of growth period
• Value the firm and then discount value for complexity
Aswath Damodaran 22
Estimate a complexity discount to value
1. One is to develop a rule of thumb, similar to those used by analysts who value private companies to
estimate the effect of illiquidity.
2. A slightly more sophisticated option is to use a complexity scoring system, to measure the
complexity of a firm’s financial statements and to relate the complexity score to the size of the
discount.
3. You could compare the valuations of complex firms to the valuation of simple firms in the same
business, and estimate the discount being applied by markets for complexity. With the hundred
largest market cap firms, for instance:
PBV = 0.65 + 15.31 ROE – 0.55 Beta + 3.04 Expected growth rate – 0.003 # Pages in 10K
Thus, a firm with a 15% return on equity, a beta of 1.15, and expected growth rate of 10% and 350 pages
in the 10K would have a price to book ratio of
PBV = 0.65 + 15.31 (.15) – 0.55 (1.20) + 3.04 (.10) - .003 (350) = 1.54
4. If a firm is in multiple businesses, and some businesses are simple and others are complex, you could
value the company in pieces attaching no discount to the simple pieces and a greater discount to the
more complex parts of the firm.
Aswath Damodaran 23
4. The Value of Synergy
n Synergy can be valued. In fact, if you want to pay for it, it should be valued.
n To value synergy, you need to answer two questions:
(a) What form is the synergy expected to take? Will it reduce costs as a percentage of
sales and increase profit margins (as is the case when there are economies of
scale)? Will it increase future growth (as is the case when there is increased
market power)? )
(b) When can the synergy be reasonably expected to start affecting cashflows?
(Will the gains from synergy show up instantaneously af ter the takeover? If it will
take time, when can the gains be expected to start showing up? )
n If you cannot answer these questions, you need to go back to the drawing
board…
Aswath Damodaran 24
A procedure for valuing synergy
(1) the firms involved in the merger are valued independently, by discounting
expected cash flows to each firm at the weighted average cost of capital for
that firm.
(2) the value of the combined firm, with no synergy, is obtained by adding the
values obtained for each firm in the first step.
(3) The effects of synergy are built into expected growth rates and cashflows,
and the combined firm is re-valued with synergy.
Value of Synergy = Value of the combined firm, with synergy - Value of the
combined firm, without synergy
Aswath Damodaran 25
Synergy Effects in Valuation Inputs
Aswath Damodaran 26
5. Brand name, great management, superb product …
Aswath Damodaran 27
Valuing Brand Name
Aswath Damodaran 28
6. Defining Debt
Aswath Damodaran 29
Book Value or Market Value
n For some firms that are in financial trouble, the book value of debt can be
substantially higher than the market value of debt. Analysts worry that
subtracting out the market value of debt in this case can yield too high a value
for equity.
n A discounted cashflow valuation is designed to value a going concern. In a
going concern, it is the market value of debt that should count, even if it is
much lower than book value.
n In a liquidation valuation, you can subtract out the book value of debt from the
liquidation value of the assets.
Converting book debt into market debt,,,,,
Aswath Damodaran 30
But you should consider other potential liabilities
n If you have under funded pension fund or health care plans, you should
consider the under funding at this stage in getting to the value of equity.
• If you do so, you should not double count by also including a cash flow line item
reflecting cash you would need to set aside to meet the unfunded obligation.
• You should not be counting these items as debt in your cost of capital
calculations….
n If you have contingent liabilities - for example, a potential liability from a
lawsuit that has not been decided - you should consider the expected value of
these contingent liabilities
• Value of contingent liability = Probability that the liability will occur * Expected
value of liability
Aswath Damodaran 31
7. The Value of Control
n The value of the control premium that will be paid to acquire a block of equity
will depend upon two factors -
• Probability that control of firm will change: This refers to the probability that
incumbent management will be replaced. this can be either through acquisition or
through existing stockholders exercising their muscle.
• Value of Gaining Control of the Company: The value of gaining control of a
company arises from two sources - the increase in value that can be wrought by
changes in the way the company is managed and run, and the side benefits and
perquisites of being in control
Value of Gaining Control = Present Value (Value of Company with change in control -
Value of company without change in control) + Side Benefits of Control
Aswath Damodaran 32
A Simple Example
n Assume that a firm has a value of $ 100 million run by incumbent managers
and $ 150 million run optimally. The firm creates 10 million voting shares and
offers 70% to the public.
n Since the potential for changing management is created by this offering, the
value per share will fall between $10 and $15, depending upon the probability
that is attached to the management change. Thus, if the probability of the
management change is 60%, the value per share will be $13.00.
Value/Shr = (150*.6+100*.4)/10 = $13
n If you have shares with different voting rights, the voting shares will get a
disproportionate share of the value of control…
Aswath Damodaran 33
Valuing minority interests…
n Assume that this is a private firm(with a status quo value of $ 100 million and
an optimal value of $ 150 million) and that you are buying 49% of this firm,
with the current owner holding on to 51%. How much you would pay for the
49%?
Aswath Damodaran 34
Tube Investments: Status Quo (in Rs)
Return on Capital
Current Cashflow to Firm Reinvestment Rate 9.20%
EBIT(1-t) : 4,425 60% Expected Growth Stable Growth
- Nt CpX 843 in EBIT (1-t) g = 5%; Beta = 1.00;
- Chg WC 4,150 .60*.092-= .0552 Debt ratio = 44.2%
= FCFF - 568 5.52 % Country Premium= 3%
Reinvestment Rate =112.82% ROC= 9.22%
Reinvestment Rate=54.35%
Terminal Value 5= 2775/(.1478-.05) = 28,378
Aswath Damodaran 35
Tube Investments: Higher Average Return(in Rs) Return on Capital Improvement on existing assets
12.20% { (1+(.122-.092)/.092) 1/5-1}
Current Cashflow to Firm Reinvestment Rate
EBIT(1-t) : 4,425 60% Expected Growth Stable Growth
- Nt CpX 843 60*.122 + g = 5%; Beta = 1.00;
- Chg WC 4,150 .0581 = .1313 Debt ratio = 44.2%
= FCFF - 568 13.13 % Country Premium= 3%
Reinvestment Rate =112.82% ROC=12.22%
Reinvestment Rate= 40.98%
Terminal Value 5= 5081/(.1478-.05) = 51,956
Aswath Damodaran 36
Tube Investments : Should there be a corporate governance
discount?
Aswath Damodaran 37
8. Distress and the Going Concern Assumption
Aswath Damodaran 38
Current Current
Revenue Margin: Stable Growth
$ 3,804 -49.82% Cap ex growth slows Stable
and net cap ex Stable Stable ROC=7.36%
decreases Revenue EBITDA/ Reinvest
EBIT Growth: 5% Sales 67.93%
-1895m Revenue EBITDA/Sales 30%
Growth: -> 30%
NOL: 13.33%
2,076m Terminal Value= 677(.0736-.05)
=$ 28,683
Term. Year
Revenues $3,804 $5,326 $6,923 $8,308 $9,139 $10,053 $11,058 $11,942 $12,659 $13,292 $13,902
EBITDA ($95) $ 0 $346 $831 $1,371 $1,809 $2,322 $2,508 $3,038 $3,589 $ 4,187
EBIT ($1,675) ($1,738) ($1,565) ($1,272) $320 $1,074 $1,550 $1,697 $2,186 $2,694 $ 3,248
EBIT (1-t) ($1,675) ($1,738) ($1,565) ($1,272) $320 $1,074 $1,550 $1,697 $2,186 $2,276 $ 2,111
+ Depreciation $1,580 $1,738 $1,911 $2,102 $1,051 $736 $773 $811 $852 $894 $ 939
- Cap Ex $3,431 $1,716 $1,201 $1,261 $1,324 $1,390 $1,460 $1,533 $1,609 $1,690 $ 2,353
- Chg WC $0 $46 $48 $42 $25 $27 $30 $27 $21 $19 $ 20
Value of Op Assets $ 5,530 FCFF ($3,526) ($1,761) ($903) ($472) $22 $392 $832 $949 $1,407 $1,461 $ 677
+ Cash & Non-op $ 2,260 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
= Value of Firm $ 7,790 Forever
- Value of Debt $ 4,923 Beta 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 2.60 2.20 1.80 1.40 1.00
= Value of Equity $ 2867 Cost of Equity 16.80% 16.80% 16.80% 16.80% 16.80% 15.20% 13.60% 12.00% 10.40% 8.80%
- Equity Options $ 14 Cost of Debt 12.80% 12.80% 12.80% 12.80% 12.80% 11.84% 10.88% 9.92% 8.96% 6.76%
Value per share $ 3.22 Debt Ratio 74.91% 74.91% 74.91% 74.91% 74.91% 67.93% 60.95% 53.96% 46.98% 40.00%
Cost of Capital 13.80% 13.80% 13.80% 13.80% 13.80% 12.92% 11.94% 10.88% 9.72% 7.98%
Riskfree Rate:
T. Bond rate = 4.8%
Risk Premium
Global Crossing
Beta 4% November 2001
+ 3.00> 1.10 X Stock price = $1.86
Aswath Damodaran 39
Valuing Global Crossing with Distress
n Probability of distress
• Price of 8 year,t=12%
8 bond issued tby Global Crossing =8 $ 653
120(1- p Distress ) 1000(1- p Distress )
653 = Â t
+
t=1
(1.05) (1.05) 8
Aswath Damodaran 40
9. Equity Value and Per Share Value
n The conventional way of getting from equity value to per share value is to
divide the equity value by the number of shares outstanding. This approach
assumes, however, that common stock is the only equity claim on the firm.
n In many firms, there are other equity claims as well including:
• warrants, that are publicly traded
• management and employee options, that have been granted, but do not trade
• conversion options in convertible bonds
• contingent value rights, that are also publicly traded.
n The value of these non-stock equity claims has to be subtracted from the value
of equity before dividing by the number of shares outstanding.
Aswath Damodaran 41
Amazon: Estimating the Value of Equity Options
Aswath Damodaran 42
Reinvestment:
Cap ex includes acquisitions Stable Growth
Current Current Working capital is 3% of revenues
Revenue Margin: Stable Stable
Stable Operating ROC=20%
$ 1,117 -36.71% Revenue
Sales Turnover Competitive Margin: Reinvest 30%
Ratio: 3.00 Advantages Growth: 6% 10.00% of EBIT(1-t)
EBIT
-410m Revenue Expected
Growth: Margin: Terminal Value= 1881/(.0961-.06)
NOL: 42% -> 10.00% =52,148
500 m
Term. Year
$41,346
Revenues $2,793 5,585 9,774 14,661 19,059 23,862 28,729 33,211 36,798 39,006 10.00%
EBIT -$373 -$94 $407 $1,038 $1,628 $2,212 $2,768 $3,261 $3,646 $3,883 35.00%
EBIT (1-t) -$373 -$94 $407 $871 $1,058 $1,438 $1,799 $2,119 $2,370 $2,524 $2,688
- Reinvestment $559 $931 $1,396 $1,629 $1,466 $1,601 $1,623 $1,494 $1,196 $736 $ 807
FCFF -$931 -$1,024 -$989 -$758 -$408 -$163 $177 $625 $1,174 $1,788 $1,881
Value of Op Assets $ 14,910
+ Cash $ 26 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
= Value of Firm $14,936 Forever
Cost of Equity 12.90% 12.90% 12.90% 12.90% 12.90% 12.42% 12.30% 12.10% 11.70% 10.50%
- Value of Debt $ 349 Cost of Debt 8.00% 8.00% 8.00% 8.00% 8.00% 7.80% 7.75% 7.67% 7.50% 7.00%
= Value of Equity $14,587 AT cost of debt 8.00% 8.00% 8.00% 6.71% 5.20% 5.07% 5.04% 4.98% 4.88% 4.55%
- Equity Options $ 2,892 Cost of Capital 12.84% 12.84% 12.84% 12.83% 12.81% 12.13% 11.96% 11.69% 11.15% 9.61%
Value per share $ 34.32
Riskfree Rate :
T. Bond rate = 6.5% Amazon.com
Risk Premium
Beta January 2000
4%
+ 1.60 -> 1.00 X Stock Price = $ 84
n Investments which are less liquid should trade for less than otherwise similar
investments which are more liquid.
n The size of the illiquidity discount should depend upon
• Type of Assets owned by the Firm: The more liquid the assets owned by the firm,
the lower should be the liquidity discount for the firm
• Size of the Firm: The larger the firm, the smaller should be size of the liquidity
discount.
• Health of the Firm: Stock in healthier firms should sell for a smaller discount than
stock in troubled firms.
• Cash Flow Generating Capacity: Securities in firms which are generating large
amounts of cash from operations should sell for a smaller discounts than securities
in firms which do not generate large cash flows.
• Size of the Block: The liquidity discount should increase with the size of the
portion of the firm being sold.
Aswath Damodaran 44
Empirical Evidence on Illiquidity Discounts: Restricted
Stock
Aswath Damodaran 45
Cross Sectional Differences : Restricted Stock
n Silber (1991) develops the following relationship between the size of the
discount and the characteristics of the firm issuing the registered stock –
LN(RPRS) = 4.33 +0.036 LN(REV) - 0.142 LN(RBRT) + 0.174 DERN + 0.332
DCUST
where,
RPRS = Relative price of restricted stock (to publicly traded stock)
REV = Revenues of the private firm (in millions of dollars)
RBRT = Restricted Block relative to Total Common Stock in %
DERN = 1 if earnings are positive; 0 if earnings are negative;
DCUST = 1 if there is a customer relationship with the investor; 0 otherwise;
n Interestingly, Silber finds no effect of introducing a control dummy - set equal
to one if there is board representation for the investor and zero otherwise.
Aswath Damodaran 46
Using the Study Results to Estimate Illiquidity Discounts
n Approach 1: Use the average liquidity discount, based upon past studies, of
25% for private firms. Adjust subjectively for size - make the discount smaller
for larger firms.
n Approach 2: Estimate the discount as a function of the determinants - the size
of the firm, the stability of cash flows, the type of assets and cash flow
generating capacity. Plug in the values for your company into the regression to
estimate the liquidity discount.
Aswath Damodaran 47
Liquidity Discount and Revenues
Figure 24.1: Illiquidity Discounts: Base Discount of 25% for profitable firm with $ 10 million in revenues
40.00%
35.00%
30.00%
Discount as % of Value
25.00%
20.00%
15.00%
10.00%
5.00%
0.00%
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 100 200 300 400 500 1000
Revenues
Aswath Damodaran 48
An Alternate Approach to the Illiquidity Discount: Bid Ask
Spread
n The bid ask spread is the difference between the price at which you can buy a
security and the price at which you can sell it, at the same point.
n In other words, it is the illiqudity discount on a publicly traded stock.
n Studies have tied the bid-ask spread to
• the size of the firm
• the trading volume on the stock
• the degree
n Regressing the bid-ask spread against variables that can be measured for a
private firm (such as revenues, cash flow generating capacity, type of assets,
variance in operating income) and are also available for publicly traded firms
offers promise.
Aswath Damodaran 49
A Bid-Ask Spread Regression
n Using data from the end of 2000, for instance, we regressed the bid-ask spread against
annual revenues, a dummy variable for positive earnings (DERN: 0 if negative and 1 if
positive), cash as a percent of firm value and trading volume.
Spread = 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (Annual Revenues) -0.015 (DERN) – 0.016 (Cash/Firm Value) –
0.11 ($ Monthly trading volume/ Firm Value)
n You could plug in the values for a private firm into this regression (with zero trading
volume) and estimate the spread for the firm.
n To estimate the illiquidity discount for a private firm with $209 million in revenues, 3%
in cash as a percent of value and positive earnings.
Spread = 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (Annual Revenues) -0.015 (DERN) – 0.016 (Cash/Firm Value) –
0.11 ($ Monthly trading volume/ Firm Value)
= 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (209) -0.015 (1) – 0.016 (.03) – 0.11 (0) = .1178 or 11.78%
Aswath Damodaran 50
Returning to the beginning…
Aswath Damodaran 51