Consumer Behaviour - Applications in Marketing (3rd Edition)
Consumer Behaviour - Applications in Marketing (3rd Edition)
Applications in Marketing
Consumer Behaviour
Applications in Marketing
3rd edition
Robert East
Jaywant Singh
Malcolm Wright
& Marc Vanhuele
SAGE Publications Ltd
1 Oliver’s Yard
55 City Road
Mathura Road
3 Church Street
Singapore 049483
© Robert East, Jaywant Singh, Malcolm Wright and Marc Vanhuele 2017
First published 2008.
Reprinted 2008, 2009, 2011 (twice), 2012.
Second edition published 2013.
Reprinted 2014 (twice).
This edition published 2017.
Apart from any fair dealing for the purposes of research or private study, or
criticism or review, as permitted under the Copyright, Designs and Patents
Act, 1988, this publication may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in any
form, or by any means, only with the prior permission in writing of the
publishers, or in the case of reprographic reproduction, in accordance with
the terms of licences issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency.Enquiries
concerning reproduction outside those terms should be sent to the publishers.
Library of Congress Control Number: 2016938426
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
ISBN 978-1-47391-949-5
Printed and bound by CPI Group (UK) Ltd, Croydon, CR0 4YY
Brief Contents
About the Authors
Preface
Acknowledgements
Praise for Previous Editions
PART 1 INTRODUCTION
1 Ideas and Explanations in Consumer Research
PART 2 CONSUMption PATTERNS
2 Customer Loyalty
3 Brand Knowledge, Brand Equity and Brand Extension
4 Stationary Markets
5 Market Dynamics
6 Consumer Group Differences
PART 3 EXPLAINING DECISION-MAKING
7 Predicting and Explaining Behaviour
8 Information Processing and Decision-Making
9 Consumer Satisfaction and Quality
PART 4 MARKET RESPONSE
10 Consumer Response to Price and Sales Promotions
11 The Retail Context
12 Word-of-Mouth Influence
13 The Response to Advertising
References
Index
Extended Contents
About the Authors
Preface
Acknowledgements
Praise for Previous Editions
PART 1 INTRODUCTION
1 Ideas and Explanations in Consumer Research
Section 1: The scope of consumer behaviour
Section 2: Consumer decision models
Section 3: Classifications and explanations
PART 2 CONSUMption PATTERNS
2 Customer Loyalty
Section 1: Brand loyalty in repertoire categories
Section 2: The rise of relationship marketing – customer
loyalty as retention
Section 3: Combination definitions of loyalty
Section 4: Reasons for defection
3 Brand Knowledge, Brand Equity and Brand Extension
Section 1: The mental representation of brands
Section 2: Brand equity, brand extension and brand alliances
Section 3: Sales losses by the parent of a line extension
4 Stationary Markets
Section 1: Modelling mature markets
Section 2: Single brand purchase patterns
Section 3: Patterns of purchase in the whole category
5 Market Dynamics
Section 1: Changes in aggregate sales
Section 2: Dynamic effects and brand loyalty
Section 3: The dynamics of new product adoption
Section 4: The sales dynamics of frequently bought
categories
6 Consumer Group Differences
Section 1: Relevant differences for consumer research
Section 2: National cultural differences
Section 3: Cultural differences in consumer research
Section 4: Age and gender differences in consumption
PART 3 EXPLAINING DECISION-MAKING
7 Predicting and Explaining Behaviour
Section 1: Definitions and measurements
Section 2: The theory of planned behaviour (TPB)
Section 3: Problems with the theory of planned behaviour
8 Information Processing and Decision-Making
Section 1: Schemas and attention
Section 2: Heuristics
Section 3: Processing value and probability
Section 4: Financial applications of prospect theory
9 Consumer Satisfaction and Quality
Section 1: Introduction
Section 2: Theories of consumer satisfaction
Section 3: Measuring satisfaction and service quality
Section 4: Outcomes of satisfaction and dissatisfaction
PART 4 MARKET RESPONSE
10 Consumer Response to Price and Sales Promotions
Section 1: Consumer response to price
Section 2: Estimating price sensitivity
Section 3: Psychological reactions to prices and price
changes
Section 4: Consumer response to sales promotions
11 The Retail Context
Section 1: Shopper choice
Section 2: Customer typologies
Section 3: The store environment
12 Word-of-Mouth Influence
Section 1: The nature of word of mouth
Section 2: The occurrence of word of mouth
Section 3: The impact of word of mouth
Section 4: WOM in the social network
Section 5: Applications of word-of-mouth research
13 The Response to Advertising
Section 1: Effective advertising
Section 2: Advertising frequency and concentration
Section 3: A model of advertising effect
Section 4: Specific effects
Section 5: The evolving media landscape
Section 6: Biometrics and consumer neuroscience
References
Index
About the authors
Robert East
is Emeritus Professor at Kingston Business School, Kingston
University, London, and Adjunct Professor at the Ehrenberg-Bass
Institute of the University of South Australia. He trained as a social
psychologist and is a postgraduate of London Business School. His
research has mainly focused on word-of-mouth patterns, where his
new evidence has shown that some widely-held beliefs are mistaken.
As a teacher of consumer behaviour, he has been keen to deliver
knowledge that is useful to students while not oversimplifying the
subject. This book reflects his iconoclastic research and his
commitment to a curriculum that is both intellectual and useful.
Jaywant Singh
is Professor of Marketing at Kingston Business School, Kingston
University, London, where he teaches consumer behaviour and
research methods. He applies quantitative research methods to unravel
how and why people buy goods and services, through the lenses of
brand management, ethical consumption, status consumption and
service management. He has published in leading academic journals
and regularly presents his research at international conferences. In his
teaching, he endeavours to deliver theoretically and empirically
grounded research knowledge that has direct applications in marketing
and business.
Malcolm Wright
is Professor of Marketing at Massey University, New Zealand, and
Adjunct Professor at the Ehrenberg-Bass Institute of the University of
South Australia. He applies empirical principles to marketing problems
and has made interrelated discoveries about brand loyalty, the use of
probability scales, new product forecasting and optimizing the
advertising budget. He has also published many articles critically
examining the foundations of popular marketing knowledge.
Marc Vanhuele
holds a PhD from UCLA and is Professor of Marketing at HEC Paris.
As an expert in consumer information processing, his research focuses
on how consumers treat price information. A second field of research
is how marketing managers can improve their decision-making
through better use of quantitative information on the consumer’s
mindset. His research has been published in leading academic journals.
He also works as a consultant to consumer goods and market research
companies.
Preface
Readership and Scope
We have designed this book to support courses in consumer behaviour at
Master’s level. It is also suited to more advanced teaching at first-degree
level. Our intended audience is those who see consumer behaviour as a
research-based discipline that addresses the problems raised by marketing
and consumer policy. The problems we explore are found in all advanced
and emerging economies, and for this reason we believe that the book will
be useful throughout the world.
This new edition updates the subject matter of the 2013 edition, reflecting
changes in the field in recent years, but its structure remains unchanged.
The book is selective in the research it covers, dealing in some detail with
the areas chosen. As before, the chapters are quite short and are intended to
support students who will also be reading original research papers. In
updating and revising the book, we found that we could often simplify and
clarify the text. The result is a book that is easier to read and no longer than
the previous edition.
‘This book provides a wonderful (and very unusual) balance between areas
of marketing that are often at odds with each other (or, worse yet, unaware
of each other) … I recommend it to any student, researcher or manager in
marketing.’
Where our knowledge is still sketchy, we have tried to indicate doubts about
the evidence or its interpretation. Such uncertainty propels research and as a
result creates new knowledge. Though not always welcome to students,
doubt is part of good education. Students who see the uncertainties in
consumer research should be more sceptical of unsupported opinions and
may be better placed to interpret and adapt to new findings when these
emerge. Each of the authors is an active researcher and has struggled to
understand the complexities of consumer behaviour over many decades. We
hope that this sharpens the account that we give. Inevitably, we have
omitted some fields of knowledge; in particular, we have left out some
topics that are well covered in more introductory consumer behaviour texts.
Often, the direction of an effect fits common sense; for example, consumers
buy more when the price is dropped. However, the benefit of a discount
depends on the amount of extra purchasing generated by, say, a 10 per cent
price cut, and here common sense does not supply an answer. For informed
action, we need to conduct systematic research, which allows us to measure
the size of any effect. Evidence is gathered using the methods of market
research, psychology and the social sciences. Using such methods, we seek
answers to such questions as:
Another set of questions comes from legislators and regulators, who have to
set the rules that affect marketing. Examples of their questions are:
These days, there is less enthusiasm for such models. One problem has
always been that they are hard to test because it is difficult to find
satisfactory measures for all the components (Ehrenberg, 1988). Another
problem with comprehensive models is that they overstate the rationality of
how consumers choose. If there is plenty of time and the decision is
important, then sometimes people will discover all the alternatives, evaluate
these, and then select the one that seems to be the best, but we know from
our own experience that we often simplify the process. Sometimes, we will
choose first and justify our behaviour afterwards – if we justify it at all.
Thus, although rational decision models might suggest what people ought to
do (normative), they are a poor guide to what people actually do
(descriptive). In practice, managers want to know what people actually do
since it is this behaviour that they are seeking to influence.
Textbooks now give more attention to ‘partial decision models’ where the
rationality of the process is incomplete; also, it is accepted that much repeat
purchase occurs automatically as a habit. Often, this range of decision-
making from rational to automatic is related to the degree of involvement
with the product. People are likely to be more involved and give more
thought to the choice when they are buying something for the first time and
this has important outcomes. To explain decision-making in more detail, we
focus on three models of consumer decision which have different
implications for managers (see Box 1.1). The models are:
The habit model – choice is controlled by managing stimuli (brand name, logo, pack
features, etc.) that have become associated with a product as a result of past purchases.
Sometimes this is called stimulus control.
The Cognitive Model
When consumers make an important purchase for the first time, they may
reflect on alternatives and discuss the pros and cons with others with the
intention of securing benefits and avoiding costs. This model, sometimes
called extended problem-solving, has always had its critics. Olshavsky and
Granbois (1979: 98–9) noted:
for many purchases a decision never occurs, not even on the first
purchase … even when purchase behaviour is preceded by a choice
process, it is likely to be very limited. It typically involves the
evaluation of few alternatives, little external search, few evaluative
criteria, and simple evaluation process models.
It is quite hard to find behaviour that fits the elaborate sequence of extended
problem-solving. Beatty and Smith (1987) found that people did not search
much before the purchase of durables and Beales et al. (1981) found that
few people in the USA consulted Consumer Reports. Carefully thought-out
decision-making is only likely for first purchases but these are quite rare,
even in consumer durable markets, since most purchasers are either buying
a replacement for an existing product or making an additional purchase. In a
study of white goods purchases in the USA, Wilkie and Dickson (1985)
found that two-thirds of the purchasers had bought the category before and
Bayus (1991), quoting US industry sources, found that 88 per cent of
refrigerators and 78 per cent of washing machines were replacements. In
these circumstances, a carefully thought-out comparison of brands is likely
to be the exception rather than the rule.
When the satisficing model applies, the order in which products are
evaluated is important since the first satisfactory solution will be the one
that is adopted. This means that more prominent alternatives have a better
chance of selection (see Box 1.3). Managers and marketers may be able to
use this fact to their advantage by keeping awareness of their brands high in
consumers’ minds.
Box 1.3 Diagnosis
Even in medicine, decisions may be simplified. Often, the symptoms are assessed and a
preliminary diagnosis is made, taking account of common illnesses; then other symptoms
are checked to see whether they confirm this diagnosis. Only if these other symptoms fail
to support the first diagnosis is a second one considered. This procedure may lead to the
over-diagnosis of common illnesses.
Although satisficing may not result in the optimal solution, it may use time
efficiently when this is scarce. However, when the outcome of the decision
is important, consumers and managers would make better decisions if they
forced themselves to consider a second alternative before deciding.
Influences on Decision-Making
It is easy to fall into the trap of assuming that decisions are made by people
acting on their own. Many choices are made in groups, and even when
people decide on their own they are often influenced by word of mouth
received previously from other people. At other times, people may base
their decisions on information received through the mass media (e.g.
advertising, newspaper, television and Internet reviews). People are
particularly likely to seek advice on matters that are obscure or difficult to
test in other ways; this is common when the recipient of the advice is
choosing for the first time or acting under changed circumstances, such as
when they move home and need to find service providers such as a dentist.
In later chapters on word of mouth and advertising, we consider in more
detail how these influences may affect choice.
In retrospect, you may be able to see defects in your decision-making process. Often, we will
lack enough prior experience, time or motivation to fully compare the options.
Purchase as Learned Behaviour
A person’s environment controls behaviour in two ways. First, the
environment makes some actions possible and other actions impossible to
perform; for example, some physical items can only be bought if they are
stocked by retailers. Second, when actions lead to positive outcomes they
are more likely to be repeated, and conversely negative outcomes make it
less likely that the action will be repeated. These reinforcement effects on
behaviour have been examined in learning theory; this is a systematic
description of the relationship between initial behaviour, its outcomes and
subsequent behaviour. Learning theory is relevant to both the reinforcement
and habit models.
Reinforcement
Early research in learning theory was done by Thorndike (1911), who
confined a hungry cat to a cage and placed food outside. The erratic
movements of the cat eventually released a simple catch and the cat
escaped. The cat took less time on subsequent trials and eventually it
released the catch immediately when it was placed in the cage. Thorndike
called this trial and error learning and it has some relevance to
consumption. People entering new markets are faced with a range of brands
and may make near random trials of alternatives until they come upon a
brand that they like.
In Thorndike’s work, the cat’s actions were driven by the outcomes: gaining
food and freedom. Skinner (1938, 1953) called such outcomes reinforcers.
He defined a reinforcer as an experience that raises the frequency of
responses associated with it, while a punisher reduces the frequency of such
responses. Reinforcers may be rewards or reductions in cost, while
punishers may be costs or reductions in reward. Reinforcement has most
effect when it occurs at the same time as, or just after, the response. Skinner
placed an emphasis on the way in which reinforcement changes the
frequency of the response, but reinforcement also strengthens the
association between stimulus and response and this is important for the
habit model. Figure 1.2 illustrates the effect of reinforcement.
We say that people have a habit when they regularly produce much the
same behaviour on encountering a particular stimulus. In the case of
supermarket goods, important stimuli are the colour, size and shape of the
pack. Williams (1966) found that colour positively affected buying
behaviour most, followed by size and then shape. Response to such stimuli
is automatic, so that no conscious thought is required when we pick a
laundry detergent brand in the supermarket. Habits sidestep cognitive
decision-making and leave us free to concentrate on other problems where
experience does not provide us with a ready response. However, even in
novel situations people may trade on already acquired habits. Consider the
person who is about to buy a car for the first time. Most first-time car
purchasers are familiar with cars, have been to car showrooms before, may
have bargained for goods before, may be knowledgeable about the ways of
salespersons, and may understand credit arrangements. Thus, even first-
time car purchasing may draw on previous learning, some of which may
have become habitual. Viewed in this way, even complex and novel
behaviour may call upon behaviours in a habit repertoire.
The habit model of consumption excludes planning before action but does
not imply that consumers never think about their habitual behaviour. People
may reflect on their actions after purchase either because of discussions
with others or because their purchase outcomes were exceptionally good or
bad. But this is unusual; generally, habit restricts experimentation, and as a
result consumers may be unaware of improvements in products from which
they could benefit. This suggests that, although habitual purchase is
frequently satisfactory, it is not always the best solution. Exercise 1.2 draws
your attention to habits you may have which may not best meet your needs.
Exercise 1.2 Habits
It is hard to detect habits that work against your own interests but consider these two areas:
1. Taking sugar in tea and coffee is a habit that adds to body weight and contributes to
tooth decay. When people give up sugar, they get used to it fairly soon, and after a few
weeks may prefer unsweetened tea or coffee. Is this not a habit worth changing?
2. If you make a regular journey to work, is the route optimal? People can discover journey
improvements after years of using a less suitable route that has become habitual.
How should marketers present new brands in markets where purchase is strongly habitual?
People also do many things that they would prefer to avoid, such as going
to work on congested public transport and waiting for flights in airports. In
many areas, such as education, medicine and legal advice, the opportunity
to influence a service by withdrawing custom or complaining is effectively
limited by the continuing need to use the service. There are other areas
where a lack of money prevents people from doing the things they might
wish to do; large houses and luxurious cars are possible for only a few. For
these reasons, we are sceptical of claims about the almost unlimited choice
available to consumers and how much autonomy they have. However, the
growth of the Internet has raised access to knowledge about goods and
services and assisted purchase; this may lead to a genuine increase in
consumer choice.
Decision-Making on the Internet
Increased use of the Internet and the facilities that websites offer may change
the rationality of choice. The ability to compare prices online generally
drives down the average price of goods and services bought online. The
proportion of UK shoppers who say they often consult the Internet before
making a purchase was 78 per cent in 2011, unchanged from the previous
year (Nielsen, 2011a). However, shoppers seem to be making more
purchases on the Internet. According to the Office for National Statistics
(UK), daily Internet use more than doubled in eight years to 2014 (see
Figure 1.4). In the UK, 74% of all adults reported buying goods or services
online. This had risen from 53% in 2008, with clothes the most popular
online purchase, bought by 49% of all adults (ONS data, 2014).
Figure 1.4 Changes in the use of the Internet by UK shoppers (Office for
National Statistics, UK, Statistical Bulletin 2014)
The Internet makes it easier to compare prices and specifications, and can
take some of the effort out of shopping. Search engines such as Google.com
assist in the identification of sources and products, while chatrooms and
blogs often provide user comment on different brands. Comparison sites
such as Shopping.com show the prices charged by different suppliers. Other
sites, such as Uswitch.co.uk, can compute the best value among service
providers and may facilitate transfer to a new provider. Websites for those
buying houses, shares, books and many other items aid choice by providing
easy comparison between alternatives. For example, an Australasian buyer
can use a site such as realestate.com.au to specify properties by location,
price and type, and can then inspect pictures of interiors. This helps to focus
attention only on those properties that meet the needs of the buyer. A
subscriber buying shares through a Web-based stockbroker such as
Hargreaves Lansdown (www.hl.co.uk/) can see the past return on specific
shares over different periods, and can compare this performance with other
shares and with standard indexes. On Amazon.co.uk, customers can read
reviews of a book before buying and be provided with information on new
books that are related to their previous purchases. On airline sites such as
ba.com, a traveller can pick travel dates that are cheaper. Quite clearly, the
Internet can be used by consumers to better assess alternatives, but how
much do consumers do this to improve their choices and lower their costs?
This evidence presents a somewhat confused picture. The Internet can assist
people to make better decisions and buy more cheaply, but the technology
may discourage experimentation when goods are regularly bought. In
addition, there are some sectors, such as grocery, where choice limitations
and delivery cost may raise the price that is paid online.
Section 3: Classifications And Explanations
Disciplines must organize and classify information in order to explain it.
Marketing is no exception and uses a number of classifications, some of
which are shared with other subjects. We start with one distinction that is so
ubiquitous that we scarcely notice it. This is the use of comparison in the
assessment of evidence.
The Principle of Comparison
Any judgement rests on implicit or explicit comparison. When we say ‘that’s
cheap’, we are comparing the price that is presented with some standard. That
standard might be given by another brand that is physically present, or it might
be an internal standard that we have built up from experience. Such
comparisons are fundamental to human judgements. We make sense of any raw
data by comparing these with objective standards, or with personal or social
norms. Comparison also occurs in the scientific assessment of findings. To
illustrate this, consider Table 1.1.
This table shows the ratings that owners gave to their car compared with the
best alternative that they could have purchased instead. The data come from an
Internet survey of 495 owners conducted in the UK. The numbers show that 64
per cent of respondents thought that their car was better than the best
alternative and 9 per cent thought that it was worse. This seems to show great
confidence among respondents in their choice of car. Our finding reflects a
general phenomenon called the endowment effect: objects are rated more
highly once they are owned (Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler, 1991a).
However, the assessments shown in Table 1.1 are difficult to justify. When
there are many alternatives, which are difficult to fully compare, it is quite
likely that another brand would have been better than the one chosen. Thus,
there seems to be an optimism bias in the assessment of possessions which is
revealed by making the question comparative. In Chapter 8, we study these
judgemental effects in more detail.
Sometimes, the standard of comparison that people use for judgements has an
objective basis: for example, the average price of a basket of goods in the
different supermarket chains or the fuel economy of different cars. But notice
that consumers have to discover and accept such standards if these are to affect
their judgements. Standards may be affected by marketing communications,
but mostly people appear to acquire price or quality norms from experience.
Such internal norms will be based on observations, discussions with other
consumers and information from the media, and are likely to be quite stable. In
these circumstances, what changes when marketers are successful in modifying
consumer behaviour? Usually, marketing activity alters the immediate
perception rather than the internal norm. When the price is cut, and more
people buy, it is because the new price is seen as cheap, compared with the
norm.
Categories, Brands, Variants and SKUs
Classifications are also made on the basis of the context in which decisions
are taken. We call anything a customer buys, whether a good or service, a
product. Then all products are divided into categories such as soup, wine,
mobile phone airtime supply, cars and hotels. Within a category, there will
be a number of brands available for consumers to choose from. Brands are
easily recognizable entities – such as Apple, Toyota and Disney – and
customers can become attached to one brand rather than another when
making repeated choices. Sometimes there are sub-brands, for example
Volkswagen has Polo, Golf and Passat. The branding is signalled primarily
by name, but also by logo, and the shape, colour and design of the pack or
product when this has a physical form. Advertising may attach other
associations to the brand, such as cartoon animals and musical themes. In
many cases, a company name is synonymous with the brand, such as BP,
but in other cases, the company owns a variety of brand names – for
instance, General Motors, Procter & Gamble and Unilever each manage
many brand names (e.g. Unilever owns Ben & Jerry’s, Bertolli, PG Tips,
Dove, Lynx and Timotei among other brands). Variants are subdivisions of
the product type so the Volkswagen Passat is available as a saloon or an
estate, and Heinz soups are available in different flavours or pack sizes.
In business, the term SKU (stock keeping unit) is used widely. This is a
unique combination of brand, variety, pack size, etc. that is required for
manufacturing and filling the shelves. The SKU is barcoded so that
automated systems can specify it in production scheduling and stock
control. Manufacturers and retailers often analyse consumer choice at the
level of the SKU. Research by Singh, Ehrenberg and Goodhardt (2004)
shows that buyers switch between SKUs in much the same way that they
switch between brands. In both cases, switching is related to the market
share of the SKUs.
Singh, Ehrenberg and Goodhardt (2008) show that product variants can
attract markedly different levels of loyalty. These different loyalty levels are
found to be closely related to the variants’ market shares – higher loyalty
predictably goes with higher sales. Some variants were found to be very
popular, and some were bought by only a small fraction of the market.
However, neither large nor small variants seem generally to attract a special
or unusually loyal customer base. Although product variants have their own
specific functional differentiation, this is seldom the focus of advertising
and promotion (except perhaps at launch). Instead, they are expected to ‘sell
themselves’, by their labelling, shelf space and familiarity. A problem here
is that, when the variants of different manufacturers are very similar,
advertising the variant may assist the sales of other manufacturers as well.
Choosing between product attributes and the variants offered remains
complex (e.g. Sharp and Dawes, 2001) and is subject to substantial market
research using focus groups, trade-off analysis and modelling.
In many categories, brands compete only with each other for the customer’s
attention, such as Colgate versus Aquafresh toothpaste. However, in the
food and entertainment fields this is less true. A frozen meal brand
competes with home cooking and restaurant meals, as well as with other
brands of frozen meals. Similarly, beer competes with wine and ten-pin
bowling competes with the cinema.
Table 1.2 shows that the share of brand recommendations closely follows the
market share of the brand. There is no mystery about this. As we saw earlier
with regard to cars, people are usually happy with the products that they own,
and East, Romaniuk and Lomax (2011) found an average of 71 per cent of
recommendations related to the informant’s main brand. So, the bigger the
brand, and therefore the greater the number of users, the larger will be the share
of recommendations. For this reason, managers need to take account of market
share before they assess the word of mouth about their brand. In Table 1.2,
Motorola is doing well because the rate of recommendation is ahead of market
share. If the rate of recommendation was assessed without taking account of
market share, Nokia would come top, but we can see that its performance is
just average for its size.
Exercise 1.3 Do big brands get more, or less,
negative word of mouth?
Recommendation is positive word of mouth. What about negative word of mouth? Develop
ideas about how negative word of mouth is produced. What will be the resulting relationship
between market share and the share of negative word of mouth?
When you get to Chapter 12, you will see our evidence on this topic.
Consumer Segmentation and Causal
Relationships
We often compare population segments: those who retain a brand versus
those who switch, heavy TV viewers versus light viewers, high
recommenders versus low recommenders, men versus women, etc. If we
have evidence about the consumption habits of different segments, we can
target those that appear to be most likely to purchase the category or most
open to switch brands. Consumer segmentation is an approach that is very
popular in marketing; it can work well even when we do not know why the
behaviour of one segment differs from that of another. For example, a
method used by those trying to harness word of mouth is to try to identify
those consumers who give more advice than others (the influentials). Once
they have been identified, the job of the marketer is to recruit them on
behalf of a promoted brand.
Opposed to behaviourism is the view that thought and feeling can produce
change in action directly. This is cognitivism and it lies behind rational
accounts of consumer decision-making. In its strongest form, experience is
interpreted and used to change attitudes and knowledge, which then control
behaviour. Thus, from a cognitivist perspective, behaviour may be modified
by communications that change attitudes and knowledge. Some support for
the cognitivist position can be found in the way public information
campaigns change behaviour (for example, anti-smoking advertising,
featuring the hazards of smoking, has been shown to be effective; see
Chapter 13).
There are also examples where behaviour precedes attitudes that support
behaviourism. Clare and Kiser (1951) asked parents of completed families
about the number and sex of the children that they thought were desirable.
There was a strong tendency for parents to prefer both the size and the sex
mix of the family that they already had; for example, if they had two girls
they stated that they felt two girls were what they would like if they were to
have their family again. At the time of the study, there were no ways of
controlling the sex of offspring, so a preference for the same sex balance
can only be explained as a product of experience.
In many other cases, the causal direction between attitude and behaviour
may be in doubt. The preferred number of children is a case in point.
Parents might have had two children because they wanted two; or, having
had two children, they might have come to prefer this number. Such
alternative explanations can often be seen in the social sciences. For
example, Marx argued that it was not ideology that determined social
relations but social relations that determined ideology. This is the
sociological equivalent of the primacy of behaviour over attitude and it is
contrasted with Hegelian philosophy favouring the primacy of ideas.
Sometimes Hegel’s account fits; paradoxically, Marxism itself was a
revolutionary ideology that created change.
The growth of the Internet suggests that people are now able to make better
choices (more suitable brands, lower prices), but it is not yet clear how
much this occurs.
In this chapter, we also introduced some of the ways in which data are
organized to create meaning: the use of comparison, types of category,
brands and variants, goods and services and market share.
Additional Resources
For an early challenge to comprehensive models of consumer behaviour,
read Olshavsky and Granbois (1979).
Part 2 Consumption Patterns
2 Customer Loyalty
Learning Objectives
When you have completed this chapter, you should be able to:
1. Report the different terms and measures that have been used to describe customer
loyalty.
2. Explain how different ideas about loyalty developed.
3. Explain how customer loyalty is divided between brands in repertoire categories.
4. Describe other habitual features of consumer purchase.
5. Discuss and criticize the main ideas in favour of encouraging retention in consumer
markets.
6. Show how design features of loyalty programmes trigger differences in consumer
behaviour.
7. Report research on the associations between different forms of loyalty.
8. Report on the reasons for defection in services.
(Loyalty schemes, which are really forms of retail promotion, are also covered in Chapter 11.)
Overview
There are three types of loyalty behaviour that consumers can show. First, when they buy
several brands in a category, consumers can give a high share to one of them. Second,
they can continue to buy a brand for a long time; this is retention. Third, they can give
positive advice about a brand and, by this action, recruit new customers. These three
forms of customer loyalty – share, retention and recommendation – ensure a continuing
revenue stream to the brand owner and reduce the need for the parent company to
promote the brand. Marketers therefore want to find and keep customers who exhibit
these forms of loyalty and, where possible, they want to encourage this behaviour.
Marketers are also keen to understand why customers switch away from a brand.
A second aspect to loyalty is the feeling that customers have about brands. We talk of
being satisfied by or liking a brand, being committed to the brand and, in the case of
business and service suppliers, trusting and being dependent upon them.
This subject is quite complicated. We have a common term, loyalty, but it has many
different forms and one form of loyalty may have a strong or weak relationship with
another. Also, the measure of loyalty that we use depends on the category. We use repeat
purchase to show retention in consumer durables and duration as a customer to show
retention for utilities and other services. In some fields, where consumers have a portfolio
of brands they regularly buy, we can use both share and retention to show the loyalty of
customers (e.g. to grocery brands, stores and airlines). To explore these issues, we
approach the subject historically, show how different measures of loyalty originated, and
examine some of the evidence associated with each form of loyalty.
Section 1: Brand Loyalty in Repertoire Categories
The Development of Panel Research
Research on brand loyalty, as a share of purchase, began with a paper by
Copeland (1923) in the first issue of the Harvard Business Review.
Copeland discussed a phenomenon he called brand insistence, which occurs
when a consumer refuses to substitute one brand for another. Copeland was
concerned with repertoire markets like groceries, where consumers often
purchase more than one brand in a category. In these markets, brand
insistence is an extreme form of share loyalty and is now called sole-brand
loyalty.
Initially, research into this field was held back because there were no sound
methods for measuring brand purchases. Retrospective surveys of purchase
may be used but consumers can easily forget some of the purchases that
they have made. To reduce this recall error, Churchill (1942) advocated the
use of panels of consumers, who agreed to make regular reports about their
household purchases. Initially, members were asked to provide weekly
reports of their household purchases, usually by keeping a diary of daily
buys.
Box 2.1 Methods for measuring purchases
The methods for measuring purchases by panel members have now evolved. One early
form of measurement was the ‘dustbin’ method, where the consumer retained all product
wrappers and agency staff counted purchases from those wrappers. But all wrappers may
not be kept, so this method is also fallible. When bar codes became universal, panel
members were given a bar-code reader and they used this to record their purchases when
they brought their groceries home. But even this is fallible because members may forget
to process purchases. An alternative method was developed by Information Resources
Inc. (IRI) in the USA. They provided the checkout scanners used in the stores of a
number of towns. When panel members used a store in these towns, they showed an
identification card and the store scanner sent data on their purchases directly to IRI for
processing. IRI used this method to link sales to advertising, but as we report in Chapter
13 even this approach may have weaknesses.
The first regular panel was run by a newspaper, the Chicago Tribune.
Brown (1953) used data from this panel and found that brand loyalty in a
household fitted one of four patterns:
Sole-brand loyalty.
Divided brand loyalty (polygamous).
Unstable loyalty (switching between brands).
No brand loyalty (promiscuous).
1. There is little brand awareness and the consumer does not remember previously
bought brands.
2. The category is one where consumers appreciate variety (biscuits, cereal, wine).
3. Customers buy discounted brands, which spreads their range of purchase.
4. The brand that the customer wanted was not available.
Apparent portfolio
1. The panel collects data on household expenditure. Members of a household may
prefer different brands. Individually, they could be 100 per cent loyal, but as a
household, they may show divided loyalty.
2. A household may buy different brands in sub-categories such as biological and
non-biological detergent. The household could be 100 per cent loyal in each sub-
category, but if the two forms of detergent are aggregated in market research data,
the household will not be 100 per cent loyal over all.
Share-of-Category Requirement
Cunningham’s (1956) share-of-purchase approach is now standard and is
illustrated with invented data in Table 2.1. In the table, the last three
numbers of row 1 show that, over one year, Household 1 devotes 50 per
cent of purchases to Brand A, 30 per cent to Brand B and 20 per cent to
Brand C. These percentages are the share-of-category requirement (SCR)
measures that were introduced in Chapter 1. Another measure that is often
used is first-brand loyalty. This is the share given to the most heavily
bought brand (e.g. Household 1 has a first-brand loyalty of 50 per cent). We
see in Table 2.1 how purchase patterns can vary and that some households
buy very little.
Exercise 2.1 Market share and average SCR
How do average SCRs relate to market share? Are they the same or different? Think about this
before looking below.
The average SCRs per brand are quite close to market share. Purchase frequencies differ across
households and light buyers tend to focus on market leaders (like consumers 6 and 10 in Table
2.1). This means that the average SCR of brand leaders tends to be a little above their market
share: 51 of the 89 purchases in Table 2.1 are for Brand A, which gives it a market share of 57
per cent, slightly below the mean SCR of 64 per cent for Brand A.
Another measure is the average first-brand loyalty in a category. What is the average first-
brand loyalty in Table 2.1? This is 50 + 60 + 67 + 50 + 64 + 100 + 56 + 50 + 80 + 100 divided
by 10, which is nearly 68. Figures of 50–70 per cent for first-brand loyalty are common for
grocery brands.
Customers who buy a brand only once in a period must have an SCR of 100
per cent; when the brand is bought twice, the SCR cannot be less than 50
per cent; and when it is bought three times, the minimum is 33 per cent.
These small-number effects mean that customers who rarely purchase in a
period tend to have higher SCRs than average and, conversely, those who
are sole-brand loyal are often light buyers. When more cases are obtained
by gathering data over a long period, the small-number effect disappears
and then light buyers are found to be somewhat less loyal (Stern and
Hammond, 2004).
Loyalty Proneness and its Correlates
Cunningham (1956) also wanted to know whether the loyalty that a consumer
showed in one category was related to their loyalty in another; he called this
loyalty proneness. In his research, Cunningham found little evidence of loyalty
proneness. Among 21 correlations between share loyalties for individuals
across different categories, the highest was 0.3. East et al. (1995) found
correlations averaging 0.46 between share-loyalty measures across four
grocery categories in a survey. This evidence indicates that it is realistic to
average a consumer’s loyalty scores across a range of categories to obtain a
score for individual loyalty proneness. Using this method, East et al. found that
a customer’s share loyalty to grocery brands was correlated with their store
loyalty (measured as share), total supermarket spending, lack of interest in
discounts and household income.
Note: The last three columns give the SCR loyalty to brands of each household and the means at
the base of these columns give the average SCR per brand; brand A, with a score of 64 per cent, is
more popular than brands B and C.
The association between brand loyalty and store loyalty that East et al. found
has been noted in other studies and a number of explanations have been
offered. One possibility is that loyalty to retailer brands (own label, private
label) explains the effect because the customer who buys more of a particular
retailer brand has to do this by shopping with that retailer. However, Rao
(1969) and East et al. (1995) both found that the correlation persisted after
removing store-brand loyalty, and Flavián, Martínez and Polo (2001) supported
this view with their finding that brand-loyal customers buy fewer private-label
goods. Another explanation is that those who use a wider range of stores (low
store loyalty) have a wider range of brands to choose from and this would tend
to reduce their brand loyalty. A third possibility is that the correlation between
brand loyalty and store loyalty may be explained if these forms of loyalty are
habits, and that some people are more habit-prone. This explanation is
supported by the finding that those with high brand and high store loyalty are
more likely to show another habit by having a routine day for supermarket
shopping (East et al., 2000). Habit proneness could relate to personality or
lifestyle. Habits, by their nature, tend to exclude new experience but they may
save time and effort (see Box 2.3).
Box 2.3 The habits of Gilbert & George
(from the Observer Magazine, 28 January
2007)
The artists Gilbert & George wear the same tailored suits day in, day out, and follow the
same routines 365 days a year. They get up at 6.30am and go round the corner to a café
for breakfast (they do not have a kitchen at home). They then work till 11, when it’s back
to the café for lunch, after which they put in a full afternoon until Paul O’Grady’s show
comes on ITV at 5pm … Dinner is taken in the same Turkish restaurant in Hackney every
night …They are often asked about these routines and complain that no one ever seems to
grasp that they stick to them, not for show, but to save time.
Other Habits
Purchase habits also apply to brands that we routinely do not buy. Most of
us will admit to avoiding certain brands and service providers. Research by
Hunt, Hunt and Hunt (1988) has thrown light on the way consumers hold
grudges against such brands or providers. Hunt et al. find that grudges
persist for a long time and usually begin with an emotionally upsetting
experience as a customer. Grudge-holders may give negative word of mouth
about the offending product when talking to others. Such brand avoidance
could have dire consequences for a manufacturer, but despite this it has
received little systematic study.
Beside brands, there are other product differentiators, and consumers can be
loyal to pack size, price level, country of origin, flavour and formulation
characteristics. For example, Romaniuk and Dawes (2005) found that,
although people bought a variety of different wines, they tended to have a
consistent pattern of preference for price tiers. Singh, Ehrenberg and
Goodhardt (2004) have illustrated regular patterns of purchase with regard
to other category divisions. The point that we emphasize here is that no
emotional commitment is needed for such effects. We argue that most
patterns of purchase, including loyalty, reflect habit rather than deeply felt
commitment.
Section 2: The Rise of Relationship Marketing –
Customer Loyalty As Retention
Relationship marketing (RM) has been described as ‘attracting, maintaining
and enhancing customer relationships’ (Berry, 1983: 25). In a business-to-
business (B2B) context, RM is an industrial philosophy that replaces the
competitive transaction between buyer and seller with a more cooperative
relationship (Grönroos, 1994). In a cooperative relationship, partners learn to
trust each other and reveal more detail about their needs to the other, which
improves mutual support. Relationship marketing has also been applied in
the business-to-consumer (B2C) field, particularly by those concerned with
services. As in B2B, some service relationships (e.g. dentist and patient) can
be characterized by trust and cooperation but this does not apply so well
when the business is large. There is still interdependence between a large
firm and its customers but any initiatives are likely to come from the firm
and to be automated using a customer database. Firms call this customer
relationship management (CRM). Much of the CRM conducted by large
firms is designed to increase sales by exploiting customer purchase habits
and this has little to do with cooperation. Most firms follow good-practice
rules so that their customers can trust them to deliver consistent quality
goods and services, but it does not go much further than that. For their part,
customers can be quite calculating. For example, they may participate in
loyalty schemes because they get a discount on purchases, or gain other
benefits, rather than because they like the firm.
The idea that customer retention increases long-term profit was given added
impetus by Reichheld and his associates in a series of papers (Reichheld and
Kenny, 1990; Reichheld and Sasser, 1990; Reichheld, 1993; Jones and
Sasser, 1995; Reichheld, 1996a). These ideas were brought together in a
book by Reichheld (1996b). Reichheld suggests that the value of a customer
grows with the length of time that they remain a customer (called customer
tenure). The reasons for this are illustrated in Figure 2.1. Reichheld argues
that, for each added year of tenure, the profit from a customer rises as the
acquisition cost is amortized, and as the customer spends more (revenue
growth), becomes easier to deal with (cost savings), introduces more new
customers (referrals) and is more tolerant of higher prices (price premium).
Also, and not shown in Figure 2.1, the longer customers stay, the more likely
they are to remain in the following year. This means that those who are
currently long-term customers are likely to give more profit than current
short-term customers in the future. An admirable feature of Reichheld’s
work is that he is very precise about the potential effects of customer
retention so that others can test these claims. Reichheld’s own evidence
tends to be based on case studies. Case studies serve well for teaching about
management practice, but as evidence they are not as valuable as systematic
studies that are set up to test a hypothesis. Case study evidence is often
already available when marketers begin to hypothesize and they may
unintentionally focus on the evidence that fits their theory. Below, we review
Reichheld’s claims.
Figure 2.2 Normal customer survival pattern (adapted from Reichheld, 1996b)
Fourth, are long-term customers more price-tolerant? Price tolerance is
particularly exploited by providers of financial services. For example, firms
may reduce interest rates on investments after an introductory period and rely
on the inertia of customers to minimize switching. In addition, mortgage,
insurance and credit card offers to new customers are often better than those to
existing customers. These tactics may produce short-term profit for the firm but
can irritate customers and lead to them switching. Reichheld makes it clear that
this sort of exploitation of customers is likely to be detrimental to the firm’s
profit in the longer run. In some fields, there may be no long-term price
premium. In three B2C companies that they studied, Reinartz and Kumar
(2002) found that long-tenure customers did not pay more than short-term
customers for the same goods. They also found that long-tenure customers
were more price-sensitive and that these customers expected better value when
compared with recent customers.
Fifth, do defection rates decline with tenure? In general, this is true. Reichheld
finds that a company typically loses about 15 per cent of its current customers
in the first year and 50 per cent over five years. If we follow a cohort of
customers and examine them over a period, we find that fewer and fewer
customers defect each year and that the decay curve levels out, as shown in
Figure 2.2. A study by East and Hammond (1996) estimated defection rates for
a range of groceries and found an average of 15 per cent defection in the first
year. In the second year, defection halved. This means that the customer’s
likelihood of defection declines with tenure. However, there must come a time
when changes in life stage (and even death) mean that customers no longer
need the category and defection may then rise. In addition, there are some
products and services which are only used for a limited period, for example
disposable nappies (diapers) and crèche facilities, and here we would see a
different pattern from that shown in Figure 2.2.
The Strategy of Customer Retention
The evidence summarized above indicates that the benefits of customer
retention in consumer markets have been exaggerated, and that those
benefits differ substantially between categories. One implication of this
evidence is that customer acquisition may bring more advantage, relative to
retention, than is conventionally recognized. We need more evidence of the
relative cost of sales gains through customer acquisition and retention, and
we also need more evidence on how increases in market share come about –
are such increases due primarily to the acquisition or retention of
customers? Two relevant studies are by East and Hogg (1997) and Riebe,
Wright, Stern and Sharp (2014). East and Hogg found that, when Tesco
overtook Sainsburys in 1995 as the leading UK supermarket, the Tesco
gains came equally from increased customer acquisitions and reduced
defection and Sainsburys lost customers because of reduced recruitment,
not because of increased defection. Riebe et al. found that acquisition was
much more important than defection in explaining market share changes for
(i) drug prescriptions among doctors and (ii) the choice of main bank for
consumer finance customers. Sharp (2010), and more recently Romaniuk
and Sharp (2016), also argue that brand gains come mainly from customer
acquisition and present evidence from several studies to support this view.
There are a number of other points that are relevant to the retention versus
acquisition argument. First, it is quite difficult to reduce defection.
Reichheld’s calculations suggest large gains in profit if customer defection
is reduced from 15 per cent to 10 per cent, but a one-third drop in defection
is a substantial amount. Reichheld did give some examples where defection
averaged only a few per cent a year, but in services where there is a specific
location for service delivery, a large part of the defection occurs because of
the relative inaccessibility of the service. For example, East, Lomax and
Narain (2001) found that 43 per cent of the defections from a main
supermarket were because the customer had moved home or because a
more convenient store had been built nearby. This sort of customer loss is
very difficult to counter.
A second point is mentioned by Reichheld but is sometimes forgotten by
those who espouse his arguments. This is that those customers who are
retained by a successful marketing intervention or service improvement are
not necessarily typical of the other customers of the service provider.
Customers who defect are obviously more mobile; when these customers
are retained through a marketing intervention, they may be more likely to
defect later.
A third point is that it is in the nature of loyal customers that they stay put.
They may not need incentives to stay; if this is so, investments in rewards
and product improvements may give little return with this group. Similarly,
it may be very difficult to prise away the loyal customers of competitors.
This leads to a paradox of loyalty. The most loyal customers may have the
highest value but they may not be the best segment for marketing
intervention because of their inertia. So which customers should be targeted
when we have evidence of their loyalty? Should you target your high-share
customers, who cannot increase their share much and also may not be
willing to change their habits? Or medium-share customers, who can
increase their share and may be more changeable? Or low-share customers,
who can increase their share substantially but again may be difficult to
keep? This is a complicated problem which requires category-specific
research.
Figure 2.3 Forms of loyalty (adapted from Dick and Basu, 1994)
These definitions of loyalty that combine feeling and action exclude
customers who stay with suppliers because of unthinking habit or simple
convenience. However, marketing is concerned with profits and it is through
customers’ actions that these are made. So should we see loyalty simply as
behaviour or as behaviour with attitude? Ryanair can make profits from
customers who use the airline regularly but may not like it. Indeed, for
brands in some utilitarian categories like bleach and sugar it is difficult to
generate much feeling. But when loyal behaviour is supported by a liking for
the brand, share loyalty and retention may be greater and more profit may be
made, so evidence is required on this. One study that did this was conducted
by East et al. (2005a); they used the Dick and Basu typology and
investigated retention and recommendation in car purchase and
supermarkets. For both supermarkets and cars, they found that greater
relative attitude was associated with more recommendation but had little
relationship with retention. They also found that customers who bought
mostly from one supermarket or had bought the same make of car on the last
two successive occasions (high past patronage) were somewhat more likely
to retain the supermarket or buy the last make of car again at the next
purchase, but that the level of past patronage had no effect on word of
mouth. Figure 2.4 summarizes these relationships with the dotted line
indicating a weak relationship. We conclude that retention and word of
mouth have largely different causes. One simple way of explaining the
relationships in Figure 2.4 is that ‘like correlates with like’. Past patronage
and later retention are alike because they are the same measure at different
points in time. Relative attitude and recommendation are alike because the
reasons that people have for liking a brand are likely to be much the same as
the reasons they give when they recommend it. This evidence indicates that
customer sentiments are important indicators of potential recommendation
and that past practice is a guide to future practice, but the study does not
show that there is an appreciable combination effect, for instance past
practice being a better guide to future practice when the brand is liked.
Some readers may find it puzzling that feelings like satisfaction have such a
weak relationship with retention but there are some good reasons why this
should be so. One reason is that usually the measure of satisfaction
employed is not relative. People retain a supplier because of the superiority
of that supplier over others and using a relative satisfaction measure is more
sensitive to this relative difference between alternatives. A second reason
for the weak association between satisfaction and retention can be found in
the reasons for defection. In services, defection may occur as a consequence
of specific failures, price changes or the emergence of superior competition,
as found by Keaveney (1995); such reasons are unlikely to be anticipated
by an earlier measure of satisfaction. A third reason why satisfaction fails to
predict defection well is that the defection may be involuntary, as was found
by East, Lomax and Narain (2001). People who move house will change
their main supermarket if their old one is now inaccessible; this does not
mean that it was unsatisfactory.
What does all this mean? Those who propose combination measures of
loyalty need to show that this approach is useful and that the segments in
Dick and Basu’s typology behave in different ways. In particular, they need
to show that the top-left loyalty segment shows more retention, share
loyalty and recommendation than other segments, at least in some
categories. If they cannot do this, the case for such combination measures
fails. Meanwhile, those who are interested in the prediction of retention and
recommendation need to treat these behaviours separately because they do
not appear to have much common causation.
Section 4: Reasons for Defection
As we have seen, retention is often based on inertia and consumers remain
loyal by continuing to do what they have done before. In some cases, that
inertia can be quite thoughtless as people continue with savings accounts and
utility suppliers, even when alternative suppliers offer much better value. In the
case of consumer durables, where an act of repurchase is required for retention,
there may be more thought, but even here the process may be fairly automatic.
A study by Lapersonne, Laurent and Le Goff (1995) showed that 17 per cent of
the respondents considered only the brand of their current car when
considering a replacement, while Dawes, Mundt and Sharp (2009) found that a
majority of customers considered only one brand when using financial
services.
We have mentioned how existing customers can attract new ones through
positive word of mouth. It turns out that defection is also contagious. Using
data on one million customers of a cellular phone company, Nitzan and Libai
(2011) showed that exposure to a defecting neighbour in their close social
network increased a person’s chances of defection by 80 per cent. Consumers
with more social connections were more affected. But heavy users and
customers with a longer tenure were less affected by their neighbours’
defections.
When people defect, they often have reasons. The reasons for defecting from
service providers were studied by Keaveney (1995) using her postgraduate
students as investigators. They gathered evidence from people outside the
university, asking them to focus on their most recent service defection, report
the service and describe what occurred. The narratives of what happened were
reviewed by judges, who produced a typology of eight reasons for defection
plus an ‘other’ category. Then the frequency of the different reasons was
assessed from the narratives. Some people had more than one reason for
defection, and in Table 2.3 we show the percentages for all the reasons cited
and the percentages when one reason was given. There is not much difference
between these two sets of percentages and we treat the average as typical of
what Keaveney found (column 4).
East, Grandcolas, Dall’Olmo Riley and Lomax (2012) used a different method
of measurement. They put Keaveney’s reasons into one item of a questionnaire
and asked survey respondents to state which of these reasons was the most
important in their decision to defect. This method should have reduced retrieval
bias because all the possible reasons were prompted. Keaveney aggregated the
data on all services mentioned by respondents but East et al. reported findings
for specific services. They chose some services that were delivered in a
particular location (e.g. a favourite restaurant) and some services where
delivery was independent of location (e.g. mobile phone airtime). They
reasoned that conditions would be much more important as a reason for
defection when service delivery was located because the inaccessibility of
some locations would cause involuntary switching. East et al. combined data
on the three types of service failure event and the two types of condition and
their aggregate results are shown in Table 2.4, together with Keaveney’s
frequencies for comparison.
Table 2.4 shows that East et al. found a much lower proportion of service
failure events compared with Keaveney (18 per cent instead of 50 per cent) and
a higher proportion of conditions (31 per cent versus 16 per cent). The
conditions came mainly from the located services, as expected. This evidence
suggests that it is difficult to retain customers in located services, and here it
seems better to go for a strategy of customer acquisition. Even when the firm is
not physically located, the scope for retaining customers may have been over-
estimated; Bogomolova and Romaniuk (2009) found that about 60 per cent of
brand defection in business-to-business financial services occurred for reasons
outside the control of managers, and only 4 per cent defected because of
service-related issues. This evidence indicates that attempts to retain customers
may have small effects.
Summary
Several behaviours indicate customer loyalty. These are share-of-category
requirement (in repertoire markets), retention and recommendation.
Feelings may also indicate loyalty. The main feelings are attitude,
satisfaction, commitment and trust.
To illustrate this thinking, we have set out one possible mental representation
map for iPhone in Figure 3.1. The mental node for iPhone could be linked to
a wide range of concepts and only some are shown. These include product
features such as reliability, ease of use and cost, as well as a wider range of
ideas. iPhones may be associated with Apple stores, with their novel store
layout and merchandising. Another connection is to the Apple Corporation
and its founder, Steve Jobs, who has been credited with a string of original
product developments. Other links might be to the vast range of apps that
can be downloaded, such as the one that allows users to identify birds from
birdsong. Brands are often associated with their competitors; in this case we
have shown Samsung and Nokia.
Brand Image
Gardner and Levy (1955) believed that brands had a social and
psychological meaning as well as a physical nature and that these feelings
and ideas about brands directed consumer choice; this thinking is also
conveyed by terms such as ‘the symbols by which we buy’, ‘brand
personality’ and ‘brand meaning’. These ideas are created in consumers’
minds by their experience with the brand, by word of mouth, and through
mass communications. To the extent that consumers have similar customer
experiences and similar exposure to word of mouth and mass
communication, we expect them to have similar brand images for products
such as iPhone.
Brand attitude is given by the positive and negative feelings about brand
features. Attributes like unreliability and cost are typically negative, while
ideas such as ease of use and wide functionality are usually positive. In
addition to this attribute basis for brand attitude, there is likely to be a ‘mere
exposure’ effect whereby links become stronger on repeated exposure
(usually usage but also exposure to advertising and word of mouth). This is
explained further in Chapter 8.
Brands are thought about and chosen in a variety of contexts and these
contexts affect whether recall or recognition is used to retrieve a brand from
memory. For example, a person might want to repair a broken jug and recall
that Loctite will do the job. Alternatively, the person might be in a DIY
store and see Loctite on the shelf, recognize it and then recall that this
product is needed to repair the jug. Brands with a physical form are
generally suitable for recognition because the brand ‘makes itself known’ to
the consumer in the store. Services are often harder to represent in the
environment and here the need for the category often occurs first, and then
the brand is recalled in response. Rossiter and Bellman (2005) use the
distinction between recall and recognition as a cornerstone of their
approach to designing effective advertising and choosing suitable media.
Visual media such as television are good for the recognition of physical
brands because they can display the product, but radio is good for
strengthening the link from category to brand and this medium therefore
aids recall.
The distinction between recall and recognition would have less relevance if
advertising and brand experience facilitated recall and recognition equally.
However, the linkages in the mental representation have direction and a
person who has a brand → category recognition may not have the same
degree of category → brand recall, even though the same nodes are linked.
The measurement of brand awareness should test these links separately.
Section 2: Brand Equity, Brand Extension and
Brand Alliances
Brand Equity
Biel (1991) describes brand equity as the value of a brand beyond the
physical assets associated with its manufacture or provision, and says that it
can be thought of as the additional cash flow obtained by associating the
brand with the underlying product. Because brand knowledge usually
changes slowly, a brand that is currently profitable is likely to continue to be
so (barring unforeseen disasters such as serious PR gaffs by company
employees that devalue the brand or superseding designs).
We should therefore conserve and exploit brands in the same way that we do
with other assets. Some marketers have taken a financial approach and tried
to value the additional profit potential offered by a brand. Indeed, some
companies now estimate the value of their brands on their balance sheets –
and certainly brand equity is of crucial concern in company mergers and
take-overs. A second customer-based research approach has focused on
consumer responses to the brand as measured by image, awareness, quality,
loyalty and specific market advantages (e.g. Aaker, 1991).1 These are the
precursors to financial benefit; without these consumer responses to the
brand, there would be no extra revenue stream or scope for brand extension.
In consumer behaviour, we are primarily interested in this second approach
and Figure 3.3 shows brand equity as the outcome of brand attitude, brand
strength and context. Context covers such matters as market size and
category differences such as the prominence of the category in everyday life.
In western countries, Sony usually tops the list and Samsung does less well
(but not in South Korea where it is a national premium brand). Sony’s
ascendancy probably reflects product quality, innovation and advertising
over many years. However, Sony is particularly focused on electronic goods
and the assurance offered by the brand name might be much weaker when
applied to a field outside electronics such as kitchen utensils. This
introduces the idea that the extension should fit the parent brand strengths.
New Brand or Brand Extension?
Brand equity will affect the success of line, category and geographical
extensions. A line extension is a variant within the category of a parent
brand (e.g. a new pack size). One form of line extension, known as a
vertical extension, introduces new lines at different price points (e.g. a
premium version and a basic version). A category extension occurs when a
brand name used in one category is applied in another category (e.g. when
Stella Artois, known for lager, introduced a cider). Some extensions are
more of a leap (e.g. when Amazon moved from being solely a retailer to
being a manufacturer, when it introduced the Kindle for reading electronic
books).
Nesting a new model name with the old one is not normally done in the car industry, but
it had to happen in Australia when Daihatsu found that its rather bizarre model name,
Charade, was better known than the parent brand, Daihatsu. When the time came to end
the life of the Daihatsu Charade, the company introduced the new model as the Daihatsu
Charade Centro in order to benefit from the positive brand image that the Charade had
gained amongst consumers (Sydney Morning Herald, 7 July 1995).
Line extensions are very common. In the USA, Aaker (1991) estimated that
about 90 per cent of new products in the packaged goods industry were line
extensions, though there was some cutback in line extension when the
Efficient Consumer Response movement got underway and reduced
wasteful marketing activity (Buzzell, Quelch and Salmon, 1991; Kahn and
McAlister, 1997). In 2004, Les Échos reported that new launches divided
into 18 per cent new brands, 17 per cent category extensions and 65 per
cent line extensions. Generally, the description of a product as a line
extension is appropriate when the variant can compete with its parent. For
example, those who buy fun-size Mars bars will usually do so instead of
buying the normal size Mars bar. Sometimes a line extension will raise
additional brand sales, but often it is defensive and designed to counter
competition and prevent sales erosion when new variants are introduced by
competitors. Normally, category extensions do not compete with sales of
the parent brand. For example, Porsche sunglasses do not compete with the
sale of Porsche cars and Caterpillar boots will not compete with the sale of
the company’s earth-moving equipment. Exceptions to this rule occur in
food and drink categories – for example, it is possible that instead of buying
a Mars bar, a customer may buy a Mars ice-cream or a Mars mini roll.
If a new name is used, managers should check that it is (1) different from
other brand names, (2) easy to remember, (3) translates well (the Vauxhall
Nova was unsuitable in Spain because it implied that the car would not go),
(4) available (many brand names are registered but unused by other
manufacturers), and most importantly, (5) extendable itself, since
extensions of a new brand can make further profits and help to justify
creating the new brand name. One reason for the loss of interest in
descriptive names such as ‘I Can’t Believe It’s Not Butter’ is that such
names offer limited scope for extension.
New brand names are expensive. McWilliam (1993) found that cost saving
was the most frequent reason cited by marketing practitioners for using an
extension. Smith and Park (1992) studied the effect of extensions on market
share and advertising efficiency, and concluded that extensions capture
greater market share and can be advertised more efficiently than new
brands. Doyle (1989) also found that extensions need less advertising and
noted that they are more readily accepted by distributors as well as by
customers. Tauber (1988) found that an existing name helps a brand to gain
shelf space in stores.
Smith and Park (1992) did not find that the efficiency of a new extension
was reduced by the number of extensions already made. Similarly, Dacin
and Smith (1993) found that consumer confidence in a new extension was
unaffected by the number of existing extensions, provided that the new
entrant was compatible with its predecessors. Dawar and Anderson (1993)
found that new lines were more acceptable if they were introduced in an
order that made them coherent with the products that had already been
introduced.
However, failure with a brand extension may damage the parent brand. This
may occur because the extension so enlarges the associations of the brand
name that it loses impact and all products under that name suffer in
consequence (Tauber, 1981). There may also be a negative effect on the
brand in downward vertical extension. Heath, DelVecchio and McCarthy
(2011) examined the effect on the parent brand of vertical line extension up
and down the quality range. They found that lower quality extensions
tended to reduce the parent brand’s rating a little and higher quality brands
tended to improve the rating quite substantially so that the effect was
asymmetric. Dall’Olmo Riley, Pina and Bravo (2015) found that the scale
of the negative effect depended on the product and that prestige brands were
more sensitive than luxury brands. However, they also found that the effect
was reduced when the downward extension had a much lower price.
Aaker and Keller (1990) found that potentially negative associations could
be neutralized by focusing on the attributes of the new brand rather than the
strengths of the parent brand. In a subsequent study, Keller and Aaker
(1992) examined how consumers saw the extensions to a brand when there
were, and were not, prior extensions. They found that, if the prior
extensions were regarded as successes, they improved the evaluation of a
new extension; if the prior extensions were unsuccessful, they diminished
the evaluation of a new extension. This suggests that brand owners should
be wary of extensions after a failure.
Consumer Acceptance of a Category Extension
Aaker and Keller (1990) took six well-known brand names and examined
how consumers reacted to 20 hypothetical category extensions. For example,
they suggested the idea of Crest toothpaste extending into chewing gum and
also Vidal Sassoon offering perfume. They found that three factors were
related to the attitude of consumers to the potential extension. One of these
was the fit between the categories of parent and offspring. A second was the
quality of the parent brand. The third factor was whether the extension was
seen as difficult to make by the owner of the parent brand. These
relationships are shown in Figure 3.4.
Sunde and Brodie (1993) failed to replicate Aaker and Keller’s (1990)
findings. Following this, Bottomley and Holden (2001) reviewed the
evidence on the acceptability of brand extension. They used data from the
original Aaker and Keller (1990) study and from seven replications. They
found that the original contentions of Aaker and Keller were broadly
supported: fit makes an extension more acceptable and the quality of the
parent brands increases acceptability provided that there is some fit.
However, we should note that Aaker and Keller’s method is quite weak; it
rests on the judgement of respondents about how they will behave in
hypothetical circumstances and this judgement can be mistaken.
Batra, Lenk and Wedel (2010) suggest that the success of an extension
depends on the atypicality of the parent brand as well as the fit of the
extension. By atypicality, they mean having abstract (rather than concrete)
associations since these can link to a wider range of categories. They suggest
that a beer brand such as Corona, which has ‘lifestyle’ associations, is
atypical compared to Heineken which is sold more on its performance as a
beer. Batra et al. proposed a personality-measuring procedure covering the
brand and the category that permits assessment of atypicality. Their initial
results are promising but this work still rests on perceptions of consumers
rather than their purchasing, which is the ultimate test. The circumstances
governing the success of an extension are also covered by Keller and
Lehmann (2006) in a wide-ranging review of the field.
Effective Marketing
Völckner and Sattler (2006) investigated ten factors that might predict
extension success and found that fit was the most important; however, they
also found that marketing support and retailer acceptance were needed as
well. This suggests that marketing effectiveness may play a large part in
brand extension success. Some poorly fitting extensions have worked
because the appropriate marketing structures were available. Marks and
Spencer, originally known for clothing, successfully diversified into food
because it had an effective system of sourcing and distribution; Bic, known
for disposable ballpoints and lighters, succeeded with a sailboard extension.
Neither of these extensions was an obvious fit. McWilliam (1993) points
out that marketers are very reluctant to see a failure as the result of poor
marketing, but this is often the reason. The potential of a category extension
is affected by market size, product quality, market growth, economies of
scale, distribution structures and profit margin, all of which should
influence the marketing strategy. From this standpoint, some incongruous
extensions may succeed because they are well marketed.
So, can we predict extension success?
It is clearly important that we understand how brands are accepted or
rejected and therefore what scope there is for extracting more profit from a
brand. However, the potential of a brand is difficult to measure. First, it
seems likely that the unconscious cognitive activity involved in brand
choice is large, and because it is unconscious it is difficult to represent and
measure this activity. Another problem is that brand choice is contextual. It
occurs under a variety of circumstances and these different circumstances
will relate to different parts of a consumer’s mental representation map.
This problem is aggravated when we take account of the way mental
representations differ between people. The theory of mental representations
may serve as a description of why certain effects are found, but it has
limited value as a predictive model.
We are also rather sceptical about the method used to determine the
acceptability of potential extensions such as that by Aaker and Keller
(1990). We do not dispute the findings of such work, now checked by
Bottomley and Holden (2001). What we dispute is the generalizability of
these findings to everyday life. Under research conditions people will report
on perceived quality and fit, but in the field marketing activity and
consumer adaptability may overcome a lack of fit. In addition, until the
work of Sattler et al. (2010), research in this area focused on the
acceptability of the extension without taking account of price and therefore
profitability.
Despite these problems, there are some areas of promise. It is clear that
brands do have value in the sense that people associate more benefits with
some well-known brands and may pay more for a branded product than a
functionally equivalent anonymous product. Tests based on such
comparisons are likely to indicate brand strength and extension potential.
1. Existing brands may lose sales to the new entrant in proportion to their
market share. This is the basic effect that may be expected when there are
no special affinities between brands.
2. An extra loss of sales occurs among brands that are perceived to be
similar to the new entrant. With a line extension, the main similarity is
likely to be the common brand name, with the result that the parent loses
more sales than would be expected from market share alone. Extra losses
may also be incurred when there are similarities of formulation,
packaging, pricing, positioning, targeting, distribution and physical
proximity to other brands in the store.2
Some data on the British detergent market illustrate the way in which
consumers shift support from existing brands to a new brand. Table 3.1 shows
how, 20 weeks after launch, the first liquid detergent on the British market,
Wisk, was taking customers from other brands (right-hand column). Wisk was
a new brand and took share from other brands roughly in relation to their
market share (the correlation is 0.85), though Surf, with its value-for-money
positioning, seemed to resist loss better. Because the sales loss is proportional
to existing share, big brands lose more volume than small brands.
This effect was further investigated in a study by Lomax et al. (1996). Using
new data, this work confirmed that Wisk took share in relation to the market
share of the other brands. A second study by Lomax et al. showed the
cannibalization effect of the same brand name when a concentrated version of a
German detergent took disproportionately more sales from its parent than from
other brands. In a third study, Lomax et al. examined the gains of Ariel liquid
detergent that followed Wisk onto the British market. Here, there was a parent
powder brand and it was anticipated that this would be cannibalized by the new
liquid formulation, but this did not occur. Instead, Ariel liquid gained sales at
the expense of the whole powder section. Though unexpected, this finding was
consistent with a notion of cannibalization barriers introduced by Buday
(1989). Consumers apparently saw the new product in relation to its
formulation rather than its branding. In the language of mental representations,
there may be limited linkage between versions of the brand across
formulations. This seems to be an advantage but there is a danger that, when
this occurs, the new entrant will gain less benefit from the common brand
name. A fourth study examined the sales of Persil liquid, which was launched
after Ariel liquid; again, the impact on the parent powder was not
disproportionate.
This work shows that excess cannibalization of the parent brand is not
inevitable and is reduced by pricing, targeting and positioning. More generally,
it seems likely that it is reduced by pricing, targeting and positioning the brand
so that it is more similar to competitor brands and less similar to the
manufacturer’s existing brands.
When line extensions are launched, they often take a large proportion of
their sales from the parent. Sometimes, this is accepted as part of the
evolution of the product, but it is attractive to get extra sales from a line
extension. There has therefore been some interest in how a new entrant to a
market draws sales from existing players. Sometimes, the sales losses of the
parent are modest because consumers use formulation, price or another
factor to distinguish the new line from the parent.
Additional Resources
Branding research is becoming specialized according to the context, such as
political branding, Islamic branding, digital branding, sensory branding and
arts branding. For a comprehensive treatment, read Dall’Olmo Riley, Singh
and Blankson’s (2016) edited book of chapters on the latest aspects of
branding, entitled The Routledge Companion to Contemporary Brand
Management.
Notes
1 A well-known method of valuing brands in this way comes from the
Interbrand Group. Seven factors are considered: leadership, stability, market
stability, internationalization, trend, support and protection. Simon and
Sullivan (1993) describe a method that compares branded and unbranded
cash flows. Others have used the stock market to indicate the value of
brands by subtracting the value of fixed assets from the market valuation.
2 These affinity effects are also seen when consumers buy more than one
brand in a category. When they do this, their selection of brands may be
linked by a common characteristic such as brand name or product
formulation. This is discussed in Chapter 4.
4 Stationary Markets
Learning Objectives
When you have completed this chapter, you should be able to:
One reason for the relative stability of markets has been explained in
Chapters 1 and 2. Individuals form habits of purchase that limit change. In
Chapter 2, we noted that a typical brand loses about 15 per cent of its
customers over a year, and that those customer losses are usually offset by
customer gains.
The Value of Mathematical Models
If a market does not change, brand performance measures, such as repeat
purchase, the relative number of heavy and light buyers and the pattern of
cross-brand buying in a category, will be much the same each time they are
measured for a period of the same length. An effective mathematical model
will let us predict these brand performance measures from other simple
brand statistics. If a model is routinely effective, it acquires diagnostic
value. When the observed brand performance does not fit predictions from
the model, we need to find out why this is so and we may have to adjust our
marketing support for the brand. The model used to predict the purchase
patterns for a single brand is the negative binomial distribution (known as
the NBD), while a more complex model used for predicting purchasing and
cross-buying for competing brands is the Dirichlet (pronounced: Dir-eesh-
lay).
Ehrenberg and his colleagues established that how often people buy a
product, and which brands or products they buy, is largely habitual, with
individual behaviour aggregating to measures of brand performance which
follows regular law-like patterns (e.g. Ehrenberg, Uncles and Goodhardt,
2004). This approach is based on the NBD-Dirichlet model of purchase
incidence and brand choice in established, competitive markets.1 The
empirical finding that most markets behave in a predictable ‘Dirichlet’
manner, leads to two main conclusions:
Penetration = The number buying the brand at least once The total number
of potential customers
m = bw
Thus, when the penetration of Persil over three months is 0.25 and the
purchase frequency is 4, m = 0.25 × 4 or 1. (In words: when a quarter of the
population buys Persil, on average four times, then the average purchase
occasion rate in the whole population is one.)
When people buy more than one unit per purchase occasion, we multiply by
a correcting factor to get the sales rate. For example, if people buy, on
average, 1.2 units of Persil per purchase occasion, then the mean population
sales rate ms will be given by:
Answers:
1. 0.21/0.07 = 3.
2. In a stationary market, you double the purchase occasions if you double the period: 42
per 100.
3. m = bw; therefore 0.42 = b × 4.6. So b = 0.42/4.6 = 0.09, or 9 per cent.
Section 2: Single Brand Purchase Patterns
The Impact of Recent Purchase
How does recent purchase experience affect the next purchase? In
particular, is there a bias towards purchasing the same brand as last time?
Consider two people who have both bought Persil and Ariel an equal
number of times over the last six months, as below:
Both Philip and Elizabeth have bought Persil twice. Who is most likely to
buy Persil at their next purchase? If people learn more from their recent
experience, Philip is more likely to buy Persil next time. This is a first-
order explanation because it relates to the last purchase. A zero-order
explanation takes no account of the order of prior purchases and here there
would be no difference between Philip and Elizabeth in terms of their
likelihood of purchasing Persil. When the explanation is zero-order, we can
predict the likelihood of a future brand purchase using only the ratio of past
brand purchases.
Despite the routine timing of many shopping trips, brands are usually
bought at irregular intervals. There are several reasons for this. First, we
should note that most brands are bought quite infrequently. For example, a
typical US household buys a specific coffee brand about three times a year
and the category about nine times a year. This gives an average inter-
purchase interval between purchases of any brand of instant coffee of 5–6
weeks. Actual intervals differ because household consumption is varied and
shoppers may stockpile or run out. The prediction of when a specific brand
will be rebought is even more irregular because other brands in a category
may be bought instead. So, although there is a long-term average frequency
of brand buying, brand purchase occurs at irregular times. Mathematicians
describe this random pattern as a Poisson distribution.
However, people rarely buy a brand again immediately after purchasing it.
Because of this ‘dead time’ after purchase, the Poisson distribution does not
fit well for short periods (such as a week or less). Over the longer periods
covered in panel research, the fit of the Poisson assumption is close and
provides a basis for the mathematical models described later.
How Does Purchase Frequency Vary?
People differ widely in how much they buy of the category and of specific
brands. The range of purchase frequencies in a sample of buyers has a form
that is described by the Gamma distribution, like the one illustrated in Figure
4.1. This is a histogram of purchases of a frequently bought category in which
the largest number of buyers usually occurs at the lowest purchase frequency.
Few people buy heavily but those who do so are responsible for a large
proportion of a brand’s sales. Table 4.1 illustrates this with the purchases of
Kellogg’s Corn Flakes in the USA. In Table 4.1, you see that a sample of 100
households have bought 210 purchases of Kellogg’s Corn Flakes, 2.1 per
household, over three months. This average is based on the 55 per cent who
bought once, 22 per cent who bought twice, 8 per cent who bought three times
and so forth (a typical Gamma distribution). When we work out the sales from
these sub-groups we get the NBD distribution. This is the bottom row of Table
4.1 and it shows how important the few heavy buyers are for sales. Those who
bought six or more times – 5 per cent of all purchasers – were responsible for
20 per cent of sales.
Figure 4.1 Gamma distribution of purchase for a brand, showing that there are
many light buyers and few heavy buyers
In general, a substantial proportion of purchases are made by relatively few
heavy buyers; one rule of thumb, the heavy-half principle, is that the lighter-
buying 50 per cent are responsible for about 20 per cent of all purchases, while
the heavier-buying 50 per cent are responsible for the other 80 per cent. When
this rule applies, we find that the heaviest 20 per cent are responsible for about
50 per cent of sales. If you inspect Table 4.1, you will see that the 55 per cent
buying once are responsible for 26 per cent of purchases and the heaviest 23
per cent (buying three or more times) are responsible for 53 per cent of
purchases, so the data in Table 4.1 fit the heavy-half rule quite well. Other ratio
rules are more extreme. The best known is the 80:20 rule that 80 per cent of
purchases are made by the heaviest-buying 20 per cent of customers. The
precise ratio depends partly on the category. For example, if we investigated
those with savings accounts, we might find that very few heavy savers were
responsible for a large part of the total savings in a savings institution. The
ratio is less extreme when there is a natural ceiling on purchase within the time
period being studied, for example people rarely buy more than one newspaper
a day.
Ratios also depend on the period of time used to collect data. Because they buy
frequently, most heavy buyers will be sampled in any short purchase period.
Light buyers may not get around to buying in a short period, but as the period
lengthens more of them are captured. Therefore, if purchase data for instant
coffee are collected over a period of years instead of months, a greater
proportion of light buyers are recorded and the ratio moves from approximately
heavy-half to approximately 80:20. Ratio rules were first highlighted by Pareto,
an Italian economist, and they have been reviewed by Schmittlein, Cooper and
Morrison (1993).
The heavy-half principle shows that heavy buyers are an attractive segment in
many markets and marketers may therefore try to focus their efforts on them.
For example, promotions may give progressively more attractive benefits to
those who buy more and the frequent-flyer schemes that airlines run are
designed to benefit heavier users. Sometimes, it is possible to target heavy
buyers by using a particular distribution system. For example, a wine
warehouse, which sells wine by the case, may secure a larger proportion of
heavy wine buyers than a supermarket. Also, it may be useful to focus research
on heavy buyers since they are responsible for so much of the profit (e.g.
Hammond and Ehrenberg, 1995). In B2B marketing, key account management
has become a recognized speciality (the key accounts are the few big ones).
Ratio rules can apply to any phenomenon and Box 4.1 provides an interesting
example. Another application has been to the imprisonment of offenders. If
most crimes are committed by a relatively small group of offenders, crime will
go down if those offenders are imprisoned for longer.
Box 4.1 Weight of consumption among
feline consumers (Churcher and Lawton,
1987)
An interesting demonstration of how consumption varies was provided by a study of what
the cat brought home to households in a Bedfordshire village. Over 70 domestic cats were
studied over a year and their tendency to kill and bring home sparrows, frogs, rabbits,
mice and so on was studied. One cat was responsible for 10 per cent of the total kill,
while at the other end of the distribution several cats brought back nothing in a whole
year.
The ratio of light to heavy buyers depends on the break point chosen, but
we can compare the top 20 per cent of customers that are typically
responsible for 50 per cent of sales with the bottom 80 per cent of
customers that are responsible for the other 50 per cent. On this basis, light
buyers are four times as numerous as heavy buyers. Because of their
numbers, light buyers in aggregate may offer more scope for sales gain than
the heavy buyers. However, when purchasers of a brand can be addressed
individually, it is clear that more attention should be given to the few heavy
buyers. This is partly because they could buy more and partly because their
loss could be very damaging. Mass communications such as advertising are
effective at reaching the large number of light buyers, but when marketing
to customers needs substantial resources it may be better to concentrate on
the heavy buyers.
This analysis helps us to understand that repeat purchase rates depend mainly
on purchase frequency. A household that buys four times in one quarter is more
likely to re-buy in the next quarter compared with one that bought only once,
since the latter household may not need to buy again so soon. Because heavier
buyers are more likely to repeat, we find that the purchase frequency of repeat
purchasers is higher than the rate for the whole sample (by about 20 per cent).
In addition, new purchasers tend to be light buyers, and whatever the category,
their purchase rate usually does not rise much above 1.5 for any period.
The advertising was ineffective and the brand was creating normal repeat
purchase.
The advertising was effective and consumers were trying the brand, but
they were not repeat purchasing so the brand was not gaining sales.
To distinguish these two, we must derive the normal repeat-purchase rate for a
stationary market and see whether this is what is found in the panel data.
Evidence that repeat purchase is normal favours the first explanation and
means that the advertising should be changed or stopped. Evidence that the
repeat purchase is below the normal level supports the second explanation. In
this specific case, the evidence suggested that the brand was weak, and that
sales would collapse when the pool of potential trialists was exhausted, so the
brand should be dropped before more advertising money was wasted. In a
study involving purchase data on more than 30 new brand extensions, Singh et
al. (2012) found that the successful new extensions were showing ‘healthy’
repeat rates within two or three quarters of the launch, but those new
extensions that eventually failed showed declining repeat rates during the same
period. This study shows that managers can use repeat purchase norms to
measure the performance of their new brands and to plan the investment of
resources accordingly.
Section 3: Patterns of Purchase in The Whole
Category
We now address the following questions:
We see DJ as a statistical effect. Consider a board with 100 slots that can
receive counters. If you throw counters on to the board, the early ones will each
tend to get a slot on their own and each time that you do this, they raise the
percentage of slots with a counter (the ‘penetration’). As more counters are
thrown on to the board, they will increasingly land on slots where there are
already counters and this will raise the average number of counters in occupied
slots (the ‘frequency’). Figure 4.2 shows the theoretical relationship that
applies; further analysis of the theoretical double jeopardy line can be found in
Habel and Rungie (2005).
Notice that the relationship shown in Figure 4.2 is approximately linear for
much of the penetration range. The statistical relationship between penetration
and frequency will be disrupted in a number of ways in real markets. In
particular, there may be feedback effects so that, once consumers have bought a
brand, they may be more, or less, willing to buy the brand again. A second
empirical effect is that some consumers will never buy in some categories. For
example, those who do not own a cat rarely (if ever) buy cat food. This ‘out-of-
the-market’ effect will vary across categories and buying segments, and it
means that predictions should be corrected to take account of those who are in
the market.
The case report (Channon, 1985) shows that, following the advertising, 40 per cent of
users were trying the product in the new ways suggested in the campaign. However, the
sales increase that was noted was still largely due to a gain in penetration in line with the
double jeopardy rule.
For the reporting periods used in market research, most sales changes affect
penetration, but Treasure (1975) pointed out that when sales are aggregated
over longer periods, changes in purchase level appear to be based more on
changes in purchase frequency and less on penetration. This difference
arises because of the way in which light buyers are counted over short and
long periods. Over short periods, an infrequent buyer tends to be a non-
buyer in the reference period and is therefore registered as a penetration
gain when he or she buys in a later period. Over longer periods, the
infrequent buyer is more likely to purchase in the reference period and
therefore any gain in purchase in later periods will be recorded as a
purchase frequency gain. There is a danger of too rigid an interpretation of
the double jeopardy pattern; the important matter here is that it is light
buyers who produce most of the change in brand purchase.
Patterns of Multi-brand Purchase
As we saw in Chapter 2, most buyers buy more than one brand in a category. In
many grocery markets, the average share-of-category requirement (SCR) is
around 30 per cent; this means that for every three purchases of a given brand,
the average buyer makes seven purchases of other brands. Ehrenberg (1988:
190) remarks that ‘buyers of one’s brand are perhaps mostly heavy buyers of
some other brand or brands, who occasionally also buy your brand’.
Is there a pattern to this multi-brand buying? There are two possibilities. One is
that certain brands are mutually substitutable. If most buyers see brands X and
Y as almost the same, we would expect a higher than average purchase rate for
Y among purchasers of X and vice versa. Such cross-purchasing of brands
would create purchase sub-sets or market partitioning. Ehrenberg and
Goodhardt (1979) demonstrate that this effect does occasionally occur, such as
in children’s cereals where those who buy one sweetened cereal are more likely
to buy another sweetened cereal rather than an unsweetened brand. An
alternative pattern is that the purchase of one brand is unrelated to the purchase
of other brands, and purchase rates simply reflect the penetrations of the other
brands. We find both effects in grocery markets. The basic pattern is that other-
brand purchasing is directly proportional to the penetrations of the other
brands. Ehrenberg (1988) calls this the duplication of purchase law.
Superimposed on this pattern are some cases of market partitioning.
Some people expect more market partitioning because they see some brands as
close alternatives. Yet while many of us will have our own personally preferred
groupings of brands, there may be little agreement between individuals. For
example, in the toothpaste market, during the course of a year one person may
buy Colgate and Aquafresh, another person Aquafresh and Macleans, a third
Macleans and a retailer’s private label. When these diverse combinations are
put together, the different individual cross-preferences will average out so that,
usually, there is not much evidence of market partitioning at an aggregate level.
When partitioning does occur, it can usually be connected with distinct product
features such as price, product form (e.g. flavour, pack type) or a common
brand name, rather than with the less tangible claims of the brand that may be
identified in advertising. Collins (1971) has reviewed this issue.
Table 4.4 shows how buyers of one brand of toothpaste also bought other
brands. These brands are arranged in market share order by column and row.
The bottom row shows the average cross-purchase (or purchase duplication –
the mean percentage of people buying a ‘column’ brand in addition to their
‘row’ brand). Table 4.4 shows some partitioning. There is a higher level of
cross-purchase between Colgate GRF and Colgate gel than is implied by
average cross-purchase. Compare the 32 per cent for Colgate gel bought by
Colgate GRF buyers with 24 per cent average duplication, and compare the 53
per cent for GRF bought by Colgate gel buyers with 35 per cent average cross-
purchase. This effect is common where two products with the same brand
name compete in the same field; it provides a basis for line extension since
some of the tendency to buy a brand seems to pass to the new line (see Chapter
3).
Cross-purchase and Positioning
Positioning is heavily emphasized in marketing. It is the set of beliefs about
the brand that the manufacturer and advertising agency seek to establish in
the minds of potential purchasers: in other words, it is an intended brand
image. One implication of the cross-purchase evidence is that new brands do
not need to have some unique formulation or brand image to succeed, a
finding which has worried those who attach strong importance to brand
positioning. If cross-purchase between brands depends largely on
penetrations, with exceptions relating only to price, formulation or brand
name, we must conclude that positioning, with its implication that each
brand occupies a distinct niche in the minds of consumers, is poorly
supported. When advertising does succeed, it may be because it has been
effective at producing high brand awareness and not because the brand is
seen as subtly different from other brands in its category. Indeed, many
successful brands may do well because they are perceived as typical of other
brands in the category, rather than as different from those brands. Thus,
manufacturers often focus on the strategy which Ehrenberg (1988) called
‘me-too’, i.e. copying the formulation and appearance of existing successful
brands and thereby trading on established purchase habits. This is a strategy
much used by retailers when they offer private label brands.
But niches can occur. One interesting case arose when the fashion designer Burberry
launched a wide range of lower-price brand extensions which were taken up by ‘chavs’.
In the UK, this is a term used for those perceived as ‘uneducated and uncultured people’
(Wikipedia). Their endorsement of Burberry was unwelcome for the fashion house
because it could lead other potential buyers to avoid the brand.
These patterns are observed in the raw purchase data and are also closely
predictable from the Dirichlet model. Major exceptions from the Dirichlet’s
predictions are noticeably uncommon, but there may be minor exceptions or
deviations from the model’s predictions. In many cases, the exceptions are
simply explicable as one-off events (e.g. a serious stock-out or disruption
because of weather conditions, a strike or a fire in the warehouse) or
statistical anomalies (e.g. with small brands, the underlying customer
sample might be small, leading to a statistical sampling effect).
The Dirichlet Predictions
Table 4.6 shows the Dirichlet model predictions for the performance measures.
The predicted values (denoted by T for ‘Theoretical’) are derived from a few
inputs – brand share, penetration and average purchase frequency. The model
input data should apply to a specific time period – in Table 4.6 the data are for
a year – but note that the predictions can be for time periods of different length
(an average week, an average month, a year, two years, and so forth).
The model predictions in Table 4.6 are close to the observed values for almost
all measures. The closeness of the fit is clearly demonstrated in terms of low
mean absolute deviations (MADs) between the observed and the theoretical
values at the bottom of the table. There are no major deviations. The slight
under-prediction by the model for the penetration of 100%-loyal buyers is
possibly due to low sample sizes. Another possible deviation is for heavy
buyers of Crest Complete, which may be due to its unique product properties,
or it could be another statistical sampling effect because the brand is small and
therefore sample sizes are small.
There is also increasing evidence to suggest that these patterns persist over
more extended periods of time – that, for example, patterns described for
one year are likely to be evident in the following years. There may be
volatility in the market shares of specific brands, but the underlying patterns
of buyer behaviour persist (Uncles et al., 2010b). Some of the discrepancies
are likely to recur, as has been found for the excess brand loyalty that has
been described for high market-share brands (Pere and Dawes, 2012).
The penetration, purchase frequency and market share of a brand are key
statistics. These measures encode most of the buying propensities of
consumers so that there is no need to know anything more about the brand
in order to predict other brand performance statistics. This makes
mathematical modelling possible.
Brands have few heavy buyers but these are responsible for a large part of
the sales; the heaviest 20 per cent of buyers typically account for about 50
per cent of the purchases. However, because there are many light buyers
and some new buyers, a change in the purchasing of these groups can have
a substantial effect on sales. Over shorter periods (3–12 months), sales
changes are mostly seen as a change in penetration, as occasional buyers
return to the category, with only a small change in purchase frequency in
line with the rule of double jeopardy.
The NBD and Dirichlet models rest on assumptions that purchase incidence
is Poisson, that purchase rates in a population of buyers are Gamma, and
that (in the case of the Dirichlet) there is no market partitioning. The
predictions from such models usually fit the data derived from panel
research. When the fit is poor, the model provides benchmark norms for
interpreting the unusual brand performance.
In the first section, we discuss how seasonality and sales promotions lead to fluctuations
in sales for mature markets, and how the baseline level of sales is affected by different
elements of the marketing mix. The second section describes the dynamic patterns in
loyalty underlying stable markets. We document these, show how they lead to dynamic
equilibrium and discuss the effects of disturbing this equilibrium. In doing so, we extend
some of the material from Chapter 4. In the third section, we consider the launch of major
innovations. These may create new markets or lead to the complete substitution of an old
way of doing things. We draw on the theory of innovation diffusion, as described by
Everett Rogers, introduce the technology substitution model and give an overview of
Frank Bass’s model of new product adoption. Finally, we consider innovation in
frequently bought categories, such as grocery products. These categories exhibit recurrent
minor product innovation, but arguably with a different social dynamic from that found in
the work of Rogers and Bass. We document the growth of first purchases for these minor
innovations and discuss the development of loyalty to such new products.
Section 1: Changes in Aggregate Sales
Variations in Demand – Seasonality and Sales
Promotions
Most of the sales fluctuations seen in mature markets are transient, and do
not affect the baseline level of demand for a brand or category. Businesses
typically experience large swings in demand that simply relate to the time
of the year, holidays, sales promotions and other events. More butter and
soup are sold in winter. There is little demand for Easter Eggs at Christmas.
Americans buy barbecue sauce in summer, with demand skyrocketing for
the 4th of July, assisted by heavy sales promotion. Similar patterns can
occur in durables and business-to-business markets. The weather, holidays
and tax refunds all nudge consumers towards buying certain products at
particular times. Even sales targets and discounting policies can lead to
seasonality in demand (see Box 5.1).
Box 5.1 Discounts create irregular sales
Early in his career, one of the authors worked for a large American computer company
where the need to meet sales quotas led to a crescendo of effort at the end of the year. If
sales were slow, management would authorize company-wide promotions in the final
quarter, in the hope that they could still achieve their targets. Some customers responded
to this by adjusting their capital purchase cycle. When pressed about low sales mid-way
through the year, sales staff would tell management that their customers ‘liked to buy at
the end of the year, when the discounts are offered’.
This figure shows spikes that increase sales by as much as 150 per cent
above the baseline level. They tend to be about four quarters apart. In other
words, the spikes occur at the same time (or season) every year. Why are
these sales spikes so large? Because sales promotions are often timed to
match holidays or seasonal upswings in demand, giving a large combined
effect. As mentioned in Chapter 4, despite the magnitude of these changes
there is usually little long-term increase in average yearly sales or in
customer loyalty. This is because most of the extra sales come from a
brand’s existing users (Ehrenberg, Hammond and Goodhardt, 1994a; Gupta,
Van Heerde and Wittink, 2003).
Many managers are surprised when they first see such period-to-period
sales variations, so it is important to be aware of them. The size of these
variations can cause supply problems and managers should take steps to
avoid stock-outs during periods of heavy demand, such as sales promotions.
Measuring Long-Term Sales Performance
These transient changes in demand make it difficult to identify baseline
demand or the underlying trend in sales. Figure 5.1, for example, shows an
upward trend over time, although this is hard to pick out at first glance. One
reason why market share is a popular measure of performance is that it
controls for some of these fluctuations; Seasonality and holidays should
affect all competitors equally, so market share is a more stable measure of
performance than raw sales data. In addition, many companies measure
market share using statistical techniques that further reduce the period-to-
period variation in the data and enable a clearer picture of trends in sales to
emerge.
Ataman, Van Heerde and Mela (2010) used such advanced procedures to
analyse an extensive dataset from France. They found that, for mature
brands, product line expansion was most effective for increasing baseline
demand, followed by increases in distribution, increases in advertising and,
lastly, price discounting. This analysis did not consider the costs of these
initiatives and so the conclusion relates only to effects on sales and not
profit.
We know from Chapter 4 that the NBD model describes the normal patterns of
light buying, heavy buying and repeat purchase. We can expand on this, using a
technique called conditional trend analysis (CTA). Conditional trend analysis
was developed by Goodhardt and Ehrenberg (1967) to extend the NBD to
different classes of buyers, so that repeat purchase can be predicted for light
versus heavy buyers, or indeed for any group of buyers who made a specified
number of purchases in the first period analysed. Managers should be
interested in this, because of the sales importance of heavy buyers, the desire to
increase the purchase rate of light buyers, and the need to convert some
proportion of zero buyers into regular customers. In particular, managers are
often concerned that a loss of loyalty from heavy buyers presages a decline in
brand sales and share. CTA reveals the level of repeat purchase that should
usually be expected for each group of buyers – heavy buyers, light buyers –
and even the purchase rate to be expected from people who were zero buyers in
the previous period.
First, look at the set of buyers who made a single purchase in period 1. They
are important, as they make up 65 per cent of all buyers. Given that they
bought once in period 1, a manager may expect them to continue buying at the
same rate. It may be a surprise to find that this set of buyers makes just 0.6
purchases (on average) in the second period. Likewise, the set of buyers who
bought twice in the first period drops to 1.2 purchases in the second period and
the heaviest buyers have gone from an average 4.8 purchases down to 2.7.
In fact, the values in Table 5.1 are theoretical norms, rather than observed
values. They are just what we would expect in a normal, mature, stationary
market. Period 1 shows familiar NBD patterns; most buyers make only one
purchase, and 35 per cent of buyers account for 59 per cent of sales. In period
2, we simply see how the NBD plays out over time. We see how the 50 per cent
repeat-purchase rate is distributed across heavier and lighter buyers, and that
the average number of purchases for each group declines in period 2. Instead of
thinking of this as undesirable, we should recognize it as the typical pattern of
purchasing over time. Heavier buyers show higher repeat rates simply because
they are heavier and more regular buyers to start with. Despite this, their
purchases decline in the second period, exhibiting the familiar statistical
phenomenon of regression to the mean.
Total sales remain stable because those who do not repeat purchase in period 2
are balanced by an influx of other regular buyers. These are households who
did not purchase in period 1, but are nonetheless established buyers of the
brand. Similarly, a reduction in purchase frequency by some buyers will be
matched by an increase in purchase frequency by others. Rather than a ‘leaky
bucket’ in need of constant replenishment, this is the normal pattern of buying
in repertoire markets.
The CTA model does slightly overstate the sales importance of repeat
purchases by period 1 buyers, so Trinh et al. (2014) proposed the Poisson log-
normal model as a more accurate alternative. Unlike CTA, the Poisson log-
normal model requires highly specialized statistical methods, and the
improvement is incremental rather than being a fundamental change. CTA
therefore continues to be a useful practical approximation for buyer flow
analysis.
Erosion of Loyalty in Repertoire Markets
The previous section demonstrated that much apparent erosion in loyalty is
simply due to customer purchase rates fluctuating from period to period.
That is not to say that there is no true erosion of repeat-purchase loyalty.
There is, but it is smaller than implied by a simple buyer flow analysis. True
erosion is revealed by examining the decline in repeat-purchase rates for the
whole customer base. For example, East and Hammond (1996) examined
repeat-purchase rates for supermarket products and found that they declined
from around 55 to 47 per cent over a year. This is eight percentage points,
and 8/55 is 15 per cent of buyers. Similar observations can be found in
Zufryden (1996). In a study of four brands in two segments, he observed
year-to-year retention of first-brand loyalty ranging from 79 to 86 per cent.
Thus, erosion ranged from 14 to 21 per cent. These values are a little higher
than those of East and Hammond (1996), perhaps because a loss of first-
brand loyalty does not necessarily represent a complete switch. It may
simply be a downgrade to a lower position in a customer’s repertoire, such
as moving from a favourite to second-favourite brand.
So, there is erosion but it occurs slowly. The leaky bucket theory is not
wrong, but the holes are quite small.
Defection and Churn in Subscription Markets
Leakage is often more obvious in subscription markets, where consumers
have only one supplier, such as insurance, banking, utilities and mobile
phone airtime. These markets may be based on an annually renewable
contract, as in the case of insurance, or they may be a ‘tenure’ contract in
which the subscription continues until terminated, as with banking or
utilities. Some markets, such as hairdressing or the family doctor, are
thought to show the same kind of persistent subscription-like behaviour,
even when choice is not constrained by a contract (Sharp, Wright and
Goodhardt, 2002).
Some evidence on the reasons for switching banks comes from Lees,
Garland and Wright (2007). They found that, in New Zealand, a change of
main bank was due to better offers 32 per cent of the time, to product or
service failures 31 per cent of the time, to reasons beyond the bank’s control
(such as moving house) 22 per cent of the time, and to a combination of
these reasons 15 per cent of the time. Bogomolova and Romaniuk (2009)
examined brand defection for a business-to-business financial service and
found that 60 per cent of defection was for reasons that managers could not
control. Chapter 2 carried evidence of defection in other categories.
However, work in this area tends to overlook the fact that defection
reduction is bounded. That is, defection rates are subject to double jeopardy
in the same way as other loyalty metrics (Wright and Riebe, 2010) and so
are not easily changed without a substantial accompanying change to
market share. Thus, if a brand has 6 per cent defection, this can only be
reduced a little without violating the principle of double jeopardy.
Furthermore, no matter how superior the product or service, some loss of
customers will occur due to market exit, changes in customer requirements,
or other matters beyond the control of managers.
Answer: Assuming your market share has been in a dynamic balance and that all customers
buy at the same rate, your 10 per cent annual defection rate will have been matched by a 10 per
cent annual customer acquisition rate. If your defection rate halves to 5 per cent while your
customer acquisition rate remains constant, you will grow by 5 per cent of your customer base
per annum. That is, your market share after T years can be found by a simple compounding
formula, as follows:
3% × (1 + .05) ^ T
We suggest you conduct a simple spreadsheet analysis to find the answer. We did this and
found that market share will rise above the 10 per cent threshold in the 25th year. However,
defection reduction can be an expensive exercise so there is a risk that market share growth
will not be matched by profit growth.
Comment: This example is somewhat similar to that of MNBA, outlined in Reichheld and
Sasser (1990). Reichheld and Sasser were more concerned with customer lifetime value than
with growth. However, we hope our example makes it clear that brand growth requires a
broader explanation than just defection reduction, especially when brands have a relatively low
market share.
Ask yourself the question: what else could lead to brand growth?
Observing Market Change
One consequence of occasional buying and relatively low levels of erosion
is that marketing actions can take a long time to bear fruit. Exposure to
advertising, for example, cannot affect brand choice until the next purchase
occasion. Similarly, defection-reduction programmes seek to plug a leak
that may be fairly small to start with, while attempts to acquire customers
will be limited by the number entering the market or seeking to make a
change. So it may take some time for marketing initiatives to play out in
changes to sales. An exception is sales promotion, which tends to have a
large effect during the period of the promotion, leading to the spikes in sales
seen in Figure 5.1.
In Rogers’ work, these ideas are more fully developed and integrated, with
diffusion defined as ‘the process in which an innovation is communicated
through certain channels over time among the members of a social system’
(Rogers, 2003: 5). Rogers believed that adoption follows a normal
distribution curve, with time as the x-axis and number of adopters as the y-
axis. Figure 5.2 shows this normal curve. There are two versions: the
standard normal curve of (non-cumulative) adoptions in each period and the
S-shaped curve of total (cumulative) adoption. Historical examples of new
products that become widely established include black and white televisions,
computer chips, air conditioning units, facsimile machines and first-
generation mobile telephones. Modern examples might include rooftop solar
power generators, ultra-fast broadband and various forms of wearable
computing such as the Apple Watch.
There is also the perceived risk of an innovation. The higher the price, the
less the confidence in after-sales service, or the harsher the returns policy,
the more reluctant people will be to adopt. Rogers’ adoption characteristics
also have an indirect impact on perceived risk, which will be reduced by
trialability and observability but increased by problems of compatibility or
complexity.
This approach has come in for some serious criticism. Bass (1969) famously
described Rogers’ approach as ‘largely literary’. Wright and Charlett (1995)
pointed out that Rogers’ adopter categories were a post hoc tautological
classification system, of no value for forecasting. This is because Rogers’
categorization depends on the standard deviation from the mean time to
adopt. Innovators are all those up to 2 standard deviations before the mean
time to adopt; early adopters are between 2 and 1 standard deviations from
the mean time to adopt; and so on. Yet neither the mean nor the standard
deviation can be calculated until the diffusion of the innovation is complete,
at which point the adopter categories have little managerial value.
The long leadtime that can occur before an innovation takes off is sometimes
explained by the characteristics of the most innovative people. Rogers notes
that innovators are often ‘deviants’, somewhat apart from the rest of the
social system: they might be metaphorical hermits in the wood, dwelling
apart from the community, or perhaps the archetypical computer geek. While
such people may be innovative, they could have little social influence, so
their behaviour has little effect on the broader community. Diffusion will
only take off when more influential people, well connected within the social
system, adopt the innovation. In a tribal village, this might be the chief or the
chief’s wife. In western social networks, it may be opinion leaders or
celebrities, or people who offer marketplace advice to many others, such as
Feick and Price’s (1987) ‘market mavens’ (if they can be found; see Chapter
12). Rogers places such people in the early adopter category.
While these ideas offer insights into ways of speeding up adoption within
particular social systems, they are not necessary to explain the S-shaped
curve that we see in practice. A long lead-time can be explained through the
cumulative effects of social forces, as we shall see later. Nonetheless,
Rogers’ work is very useful. The concept of an idea spreading through a
social system via specific communication channels underlies much
subsequent work on innovation diffusion. The insight that adoption follows a
normal curve has been borne out in many product categories.
Fisher and Pry’s Technology Substitution Model
Rogers’ adopter categorization exploits the properties of the S-shaped
normal distribution curve, but is not helpful for forecasting. Marketers need
to make forecasts to assist launch decisions on new products, set targets
against which performance can be assessed, and allocate marketing
expenditure.
Fisher and Pry (1971) showed how to use an S-shaped curve to forecast the
replacement of an inferior technology with a better one that meets the same
need. This process is called technology substitution. They dealt with the
problem of an indeterminate leadtime by assuming the substitute technology
must achieve a several per cent market share before complete substitution
could be guaranteed to occur. They then treated substitution as a logistic
function of time.2 This has the practical effect of transforming the S-shaped
cumulative adoption curve into a straight line. Extrapolation through
regression then yields a forecast. Fisher and Pry validated this model over 17
diverse data sets and found surprisingly accurate results.
Although quite old now, Fisher and Pry’s (1971) model is likely to continue
to be of great importance as we undergo accelerating technological
substitution in areas such as telecommunications, computing and home
electronics. This model has the useful feature of forecasting the dynamic
decline of the old technology as well as the growth of the new one. This is
potentially very helpful to companies in fields such as telecommunications,
where there are substantial but declining revenue streams from products such
as fixed-line telephone connections.
Source: Interstate Commerce Commission, Statistics of Railroads 1925–1960, as cited in Moore and
Pessemier (1993: 79)
Postscript: The forecasts were based on data up to June 2006, at which stage 71 per cent
of Internet users had broadband. This was forecast to grow to 95 per cent by the end of
2008. In 2009 a press release from Nielsen online revealed that the actual figure for
broadband penetration in 2008 was 97 per cent.
In the first period (usually a year), the probability of adoption, given that no
adoption has yet taken place, is simply p, and the predicted number of
adopters is p × m. However, as more of the population adopts, social
influence (q) increases and the probability of adoption becomes p + q ×
[Y(T)/m]. This basic equation can be expressed in a variety of forms, both
algebraic and probabilistic and for either cumulative or non-cumulative
adoption.
The mix between internal and external influence can be seen in the Bass
curve in Figure 5.5, estimated on data for first-time use of a telephone
enrolment system at Massey University in New Zealand. The parameters of
this curve are p = 0.10, q = 0.47, and m = 5,788. This p value is quite high
for Bass modelling, so the adoption curve starts at a point well above zero,
peaks early, and is over quickly. This shows the extra flexibility of the Bass
model compared to a simple normal distribution curve.
Validation, Replication and the Extension of the
Bass Model
Box 5.3 notes a famous case of forecasting success for the model but Bass
may have been lucky on this occasion. More cases are needed to assess it. In
a review of early replications, Wright, Upritchard and Lewis (1997) noted
that a poor fit was sometimes found for the model outside North American
and European settings. They also found that its predictive ability was limited
by variations in the early data. As early sales (or adoptions) are quite few,
fluctuations are proportionately larger and so have a larger effect on long-
term forecasting accuracy. Putsis and Srinivasan (2000) subsequently found
that Bass model forecasts generally do not stabilize until the peak of the
adoption process has passed. Also, the assumption of constant social
influence may be an over-simplification. As we shall see in Chapter 12,
word-of-mouth production may vary with the period a person has owned a
product.
It would be much more helpful to apply the model before the launch of a
new product. Then it could be used for initial sales forecasting, launch
decisions, capacity planning and marketing budgeting. Two traditional
approaches to doing this are to forecast by analogy or to use management
judgement.
The techniques for applying managerial judgement are not made very clear
in the literature and should generally be seen as a last resort. Managers may
not understand the social basis or typical values of the Bass model
parameters p and q and will therefore have little basis to apply their
judgement. Also, Armstrong (1985) has evaluated evidence on the
performance of subjective estimates – managerial judgement – in
forecasting. He found that they do not perform well compared to forecasts
from objective methods and that integrating objective information with
managerial judgement typically provided substantial improvements over
managerial judgement alone (Armstrong, 1985: 387–420). So it is doubtful
whether management judgement will show much accuracy unless the judge
already has substantial experience with the Bass model and takes steps to
combine this judgement with other, objective, information.
Lessons for Market Dynamics from the Bass
Model
What lessons does the Bass model offer us in understanding market
dynamics? First, consider the domain of the model. It concerns new
products, not brands. It is typically applied to high-value products or
services that have long inter-purchase times. These may be completely new
or substantial technological improvements (although it can be applied to
other behaviours if true adoption data are available, as in Figure 5.5). Bass
modelling has shown that sales curves following the introduction of such
products and services will be roughly normal or S-shaped.
Second, the exact shape of the curve will depend on social factors relating to
the social system involved. Understanding the relative importance of these
external and internal influences will give richer insights for marketing
planning and more accurate forecasts of product sales growth.
Third, a long lead-in time can be explained simply by the values of the
parameters. It will occur if the innovation parameter, p, is relatively low.
Rapid acceleration of adoption will then occur if the innovation parameter, q,
is relatively high.
Examine each one of the four examples and then consider the questions that follow:
For each curve, identify a social system and innovation it could be describing. (Hint: think
about the level of innovation and the extent of word-of-mouth recommendation.)
Consider Rogers’ innovation characteristics. How might they affect the shape of the
cumulative adoption curve?
Which do you think are the most and least common shapes? Justify your answer.
Section 4: The Sales Dynamics of Frequently
Bought Categories
Low-Innovation Products
Section 3 described what we know about sales changes that occur when
new categories are introduced, or when technological substitution causes a
wave of change in an existing durable category. Yet most new products are
much more mundane and involve incremental ‘me-too’ products in familiar,
frequently bought, low-value and low-involvement categories. We cannot
expect that the same dynamic processes will necessarily apply in such
different circumstances. Rather, new products in these frequently bought,
low-involvement categories rely on familiarity and existing memory
structures, as discussed in Chapter 3, and most sales come from repeat
purchases rather than from the initial adoption decision. Occasionally, there
may be a major innovation, such as the first olive oil spread or low-fat
calcium-enriched milk. However, even these are typically presented as new
brands launched into a familiar category (yellow fats and milk,
respectively).
Now, consider a low-value, frequently bought item. The low value means
lower risk. Also, it may be one of many dozens of regularly purchased
product categories. The category is less likely to be a topic of conversation
– who talks much about toilet paper, bleach, milk, baking powder, flour,
light bulbs, butter and the like? Of course, there will be exceptions – a
cooking club may talk a great deal about a new type of flour. However, such
exceptions represent a small fraction of the buyers and we are not aware of
any corresponding light bulb-changing or milk-drinking clubs.
Rogers’ adoption characteristics can easily be applied to such low-value
incremental innovations in frequently bought categories. We suggest that
such innovations are familiar (compatible), simple (not complex), cheap
(trialable) and widely present on the shelf (observable). So there are few
barriers to the adoption of such a new product, provided it has a relative
advantage. Conversely, such products are less likely to be topics of
conversation, so there will be relatively little social influence.3 The
probability of adoption remains constant over time rather than increasing as
social influence increases; however, the number of adopters falls with each
period as the pool of those who have not yet adopted shrinks. The result is a
curve whose shape is known as exponential or an exponential decline.
Figure 5.6(d) in Exercise 5.2 shows the pattern of cumulative adoption for
such an exponentially declining adoption curve.
Exercise 5.3 Sketch an exponential decline
curve
It’s easy to see for yourself how an exponential decline curve works. Imagine that a population
of 100 people has an adoption rate of 10 per cent. In the first period, 10 will adopt; in the
second period, 9 (10 per cent of the remaining 90 who had not yet adopted); in the third period,
8.1 are expected to adopt (10 per cent of the remaining 81); and so on:
In Excel, calculate the number of adopters for each of the first 20 periods. Assume a
population of 100 and an adoption rate of 10 per cent. (Hint: you might find it helpful to
have columns for those yet to adopt, adopters in the period, and total adopters to date.)
Graph both the cumulative and non-cumulative adoption curves.
Repeat the exercises for adoption rates of 30 per cent and 5 per cent.
Empirical Patterns in First Purchases
The shape of adoption curves for frequently purchased products has been
studied empirically. Wright and Stern (2015) examined 12 national product
launches and 19 controlled test market product launches for a variety of
frequently bought categories. Figure 5.7 sketches some of their findings. It
is noteworthy that the individual product launches showed similar patterns,
despite varying degrees of innovativeness in the product or brand being
launched.
These curves are not obviously S-shaped and so show little evidence of an
increasing word-of-mouth effect (although see note 3). They show an
exponentially declining pattern of growth in first purchases. There is a
slight bend in the curve for national launches, although this may be due to
distribution growth. Yet, even with this, the curve still generally follows the
declining exponential pattern. Nonetheless, it is worth remembering that
changes to distribution are a primary cause of changes to baseline sales;
availability is a necessary precursor to purchase. This is confirmed by the
work of Ataman, Mela and Van Heerde (2008), who show that distribution
plays the greatest role in the success of new brands in repeat-purchase
markets.
After the First Purchase
For durable products, adoption and sales are measured by the simple act of a
purchase. However, the picture is not so clear for frequently bought items
such as groceries. Exponential models of cumulative first purchase do not
assume that the first purchase is an adoption, or tell us what the long-term
purchase frequency will be. We might instead expect buyers of these new
products to make one or two trial purchases before choosing either to drop
the new product or to include it in their repertoire. This is the traditional
view in most consumer behaviour texts and it is consistent with Rogers’
theories on innovation diffusion, with exposure being followed by evaluation
and then an adoption or rejection decision.
How could such near-instant loyalty come about? One explanation is that
new brands in low-involvement categories are immediately included in the
consumer’s repertoire. The trial curve may then just reflect distribution
growth, the occasional nature of category purchases, and the shuffling of
purchases around the consumer’s repertoire.
A further difficulty is that early buyers are more likely to be heavy buyers;
Taylor (1977) demonstrated this, Fourt and Woodlock (1960) made a similar
assertion and Stern and Wright (2016) have confirmed it. These heavy
buyers may complete trial purchases and evaluations quickly. Therefore,
initial repeat-purchase figures may be misleading, as they combine heavy
buyers, whose repeat-purchase rate has settled down, with lighter buyers
who may still be making evaluative purchases. So the overall repeat-
purchase figure will keep changing until light buyers have finished making
evaluative purchases.
Fader, Hardie and Huang (2004) took a different approach. They adapted a
standard trial-repeat model to allow consumers’ purchase rates to be revised
after experiencing the new product. The result was an extremely accurate
forecasting performance for the single brand that they examined. This
suggests that their assumption, that purchase rates are revised slightly
following experience, is a reasonable one, although replication across other
data sets would give more confidence in their conclusions. Some indirect
support for Fader er al.’s approach is provided by Singh et al.’s (2012) study
of sales growth for 47 brand extensions in the UK. They found that, in the
third quarter after launch, those with a positive sales trend had an average
repeat purchase rate of 32 per cent, while those with a negative sales trend
had an average repeat purchase rate of 22 per cent. This difference is
consistent with a post-experience revision of purchase probabilities
suggested by Fader et al. (2004).
Fourth, the launch of new products is a major source of more rapid and
enduring change. Sociology helps us to understand the underlying forces,
while models such as the technology substitution model and the Bass model
provide tools for analysing and forecasting new product adoption. Fifth,
social forces may be different for low-value, frequently bought items. We
can capture the first purchase process in these markets with exponential
models (which assume little social influence). For repeat purchase, the
analysis is a little more complicated, due to early trial by heavy buyers, the
large number of light buyers and the unclear role of evaluative purchases.
One approach is to assume near-instant loyalty. Another is to use statistical
models that allow purchase rates to be revised after experience with the new
product. Recent evidence shows that differences in repeat-purchase rates for
succeeding and failing brand extensions can be detected in the third quarter
after launch.
1. Identify consumer differences that are relevant and those that are less useful to
marketers.
2. Categorize cultures along the dimensions proposed by Hofstede.
3. Give examples of how these dimensions have been used in consumer research.
4. Understand the criticisms of Hofstede’s approach.
5. Describe how values can be used to understand fundamental consumer motivations.
6. Explain how gender and age are related to consumption.
Overview
Marketers need to take account of group differences when they design and promote
products, since what may appeal to one group may be of no interest to another. Group
differences may reflect local conditions or history and may be related to ways of viewing
the self and others in society. Some differences, such as individualism versus
collectivism, can be seen as orientations shaping consumer consciousness; these have
interested social scientists who seek to characterize pervasive features of whole societies.
Other differences relate to divisions within society and we focus on age and gender since
there are new developments here.
We start by asking what differences are relevant in consumer research and note that many
personality differences are hard to use because it is difficult to target people with a
particular disposition unless this is associated with physical segregation or differential
consumption of media. Deep-seated cultural differences are approached via Hofstede’s
(1980, 2001) five dimensions and Rokeach’s (1973) value system. We look at the use of
these ideas in consumer research and show that it may be quite difficult to derive
predictions from them. We also note that there may be simple social differences in
consumption that are best revealed by market research rather than academic study.
Contrasted with consumer group differences is the idea of convergence – that a process of
globalization is ongoing and that societies, at least in market practice, are becoming
similar. We explore this idea and look in particular at China, comparing it with the West.
On age, we focus particularly on the older members of society. The proportion of over-
65s is growing rapidly and represents a considerable burden on more productive, younger
groups. Though many are poor, much wealth is held by the older generation and recent
work has focused on the relatively conservative decision-making of older consumers. On
gender differences, there is evidence that women form more interpersonal bonds than
men, which affects their loyalty patterns.
In this book, we do not cover segmentation by brand. This is because there is a body of
robust evidence showing that there is generally little difference between the customers of
any two brands in a category. Brands do not usually differ enough to appeal to different
sub-groups in the population. Uncles (2011) summarized the empirical evidence on
comparisons of user profiles of directly competing brands. Through a series of replication
studies and extensions, it was confirmed that user profiles of directly competing brands
seldom differ. The study used data spanning 25 years, across 50+ categories and 60 data
sets, and confirmed lack of user segments for brands in emerging markets, private labels,
variants and composite segments. Similar findings are reported in other studies. For
example, in a study on Japanese buyers’ purchase intentions, Singh, Dall’Olmo Riley, et
al. (2012) showed demographic similarity across the users of top Japanese grocery
brands. Similar findings were also reported by Uncles and Lee (2006) amongst Australian
customers and in the UK by Singh, Ehrenberg and Goodhardt (2008).
Section 1: Relevant Differences for Consumer
Research
Segmentation, a fundamental notion in marketing, means grouping
consumers into discrete segments according to their similarities or
differences. The segments may differ in needs, consumption habits,
responsiveness to marketing actions, etc. Although it is useful to diagnose
differences between consumers concerning a specific product or issue with
dedicated market research, understanding the fundamental drivers that
account for differences across a broad range of behaviour may have more
potential if these can be directly addressed.
Although Hofstede’s work was very influential, it also met with criticism. A
fundamental concern was that he carried out an eclectic analysis of data,
based on theoretical reasoning and correlation analysis. In other words,
although his framework is based on hard data, he uses some creativity in the
analysis. McSweeney (2002) summarized this verdict in the title of his
article ‘A Triumph of Faith – A Failure of Analysis’. He also attacks the
assumption that one can extrapolate the results of IBM employees to an
entire nation. IBM employees may not be representative of their nation.
McSweeney thinks they may even be atypical. Moreover, the number of
relevant questions in the IBM questionnaire was limited, and they may not
be adequate to test Hofstede’s propositions fully. The questionnaire was not
designed to identify national cultures, and questionnaires designed for this
specific purpose by other researchers have produced different results (see
below). A third critique is that what Hofstede uncovered in the workplace
may be situationally specific and not transferable to other situations (e.g.
home, retail behaviour, recreational consumption). Fourth, again on the
method side, McSweeney objects to the way in which Hofstede sought to
validate his results by an analysis of historical and contemporary events,
and he claims that these illustrative stories ignore counter-evidence. The
2001 edition of the book also presents cross-validation with other studies
and claims that the findings are consistent with those from 140 other
studies. A further criticism comes from Ailon (2008), who argues that,
rather than capturing and mapping differences in societal values, Hofstede’s
work actually constructs reality and is therefore a product of a specific
cultural milieu and knowledge-producing tradition. It therefore reaffirms a
scheme in which western values are always the idealized reference point.
Hofstede anticipated this criticism; he realized that his personal value
system might influence the results and therefore outlined in the book his
personal position on various questionnaire items. Revealing this potential
bias does not of course eliminate it.
It is interesting that the work on cultural values discussed here was done by
psychologists. Until the 1980s, culture was still thought of as ‘out there’ rather
than as an individual disposition (Triandis, 2004). Most psychologists therefore
held the view that cultural differences were a topic for anthropologists to work
on. A major turning point came with the publication of a review by Markus and
Kitayama (1991) that showed major cultural differences in cognition, emotion
and motivation. The authors proposed that the self-construal of interdependence
with other individuals guides people in many Asian cultures, whereas it is
independence that is the guiding construal in western cultures. These differences
manifest in people’s consumption behaviour and could influence brand-buying
behaviour.
Different societies share different values and value types, but not all
combinations are possible. The simultaneous pursuit of some value types is
possible while other combinations are incompatible.
Section 3: Cultural Differences in Consumer
Research
The research in cultural psychology discussed in the previous section has
influenced consumer research and marketing in two ways. First, it has
helped us to segment markets and to understand their differences so that
segments can be targeted with different strategies and marketing plans.
Second, it has aided researchers in testing their theories on how opposite
mindsets such as individualistic versus collectivistic affect consumer
behaviour. Cultural psychology has indicated that nations have different
cultural mindsets and that consumer researchers need to take this into
account when developing and advertising products, especially those
designed for export to other national markets. Below we give two examples
of these influences.
Cross-National Comparisons of Consumer
Psychology
Steenkamp and Geyskens (2006) examine how country characteristics
influence the perceived value that consumers derive from visiting websites,
using data from almost 9,000 consumers in 23 countries. In general, the
experience of visiting a website has a utilitarian (acquiring useful
information) component and an emotional component (the authors focus on
pleasure and arousal). According to the authors, consumer evaluations of
websites (in this case for consumer packaged goods) are driven by
perceived privacy and security, customization to the individual’s needs, and
congruity with the local culture. The central proposition of this research is
that the perceived value of the experience and the website characteristics
mentioned above are influenced by the characteristics of the consumer’s
country. The authors examine the influence of individualism/collectivism
and propose that when national-cultural individualism is high, the effect on
perceived value of the emotional experience, of the perceived privacy and
security protection, and of the customization, is great.
‘Acing the last exam. Winning the big race. Receiving deserved
recognition. Ohio Flag Beer. Celebrating life’s accomplishments.’
‘Reminiscing with old friends. Enjoying time together with family
during the holidays. Relaxing near the fire with best friends. Ohio Flag
Beer. Celebrating the relationships that matter most.’
They compared the effect of each appeal on two samples: Chinese students
(born and raised in China), as members of a collectivistic culture, and North
American students, as members of an individualistic culture. The results
showed a pattern opposite to the expectations: Chinese students showed
more positive attitudes towards the advertisement and brand when exposed
to the ego-focused emotions, as compared to the other-focused emotions,
while for American students the scores were reversed. As explanation, the
authors propose the novelty of the appeal as the driving factor. For members
of a collectivistic culture, ego-focused appeals are more unusual and
therefore trigger more attention. Similarly, the North American students
may have found the collectivist messages unusual and were therefore more
responsive to them. This idea was tested in a new study with ads for colour
film that showed either (individual) happiness or peacefulness. The results
confirmed that the novel thoughts provoked by an unusual appeal drove the
subsequent attitudes to the advertisement and to the brand.
It seems reasonable to argue that meaning differences that are introduced in translation
may be a basis for apparent cross-cultural differences. Such concerns are alleviated when
studies using different methods and measures converge on the same outcome – if they do.
Note that this problem is not necessarily removed by conducting all studies in English
since this restricts sampling to those familiar with English, and even in such sub-groups
there may be differences of usage.
Other problems in comparing across cultures include differential response rates, differing
responses to incentives and variation in the tendency to please interviewers.
Market-Relevant Facts
Broad cultural differences between nations are of great interest but
sometimes quite specific facts about difference in practice and thinking are
important. For example, when Levi 501s were relaunched in Europe by
BBH and McCann, they argued that jeans were perceived differently in the
USA and Europe and, because of this, the existing US advertising was
inappropriate for Europe (see Box 6.2).
There are other cases where cultural differences have particular forms that
marketers should know about. For example, it is common practice on the
Indian Subcontinent to stay with relatives. Indians and Bangladeshis have
been heard to complain about the discomfort that occurs when relatives
squeeze up to make room for a visitor. Sometimes the visitor would prefer
to stay in a hotel but this would cause offence. Hotel firms in the West that
seek to expand in other countries need to know about such practices.
Globalization
Up until now we have stressed the cultural differences among consumers
living in different regions of the world. However, with the globalization of
markets, these differences may be diminishing and the debate of
globalization versus localization has concerned international marketing
practitioners in the past few decades. Advocates of globalization stress a
convergence of consumer attitudes and behaviours across geographical
boundaries and try to identify and reach consumer segments across
boundaries with common products and marketing programmes. In this
context, three Dutch researchers segmented European consumers from 11
different countries using a means–ends chain survey (Ter Hofstede,
Steenkamp and Wedel, 1999). A means–ends chain examines how
consumers connect to a product by asking questions about the link between
attributes (e.g. organically produced, low fat) and benefits (e.g. spending
less money, good taste) and the link between benefits and values (e.g. self-
respect, warm relationships). They identified four cross-national segments
that were then linked to descriptive data on socio-demographics, product
consumption and media usage, and information on personality and attitudes.
Box 6.2 A small difference in perception
When Bartle Bogle Hegarty and the McCann agencies handled the relaunch of Levi 501
jeans in Europe in 1985, they refused to use the US advertising (Feldwick, 1990). Their
analysis was that, in the USA, jeans were workaday clothes and increasingly old-
fashioned, but in Europe wearing jeans could still be a fashion statement. Moreover, 501s
had genuine provenance and were worn by a small number of opinion leaders. Thus, the
agencies sought to re-establish the slightly baggy 501s as ‘the right look’ for young
people, the definitive classic jean. To do this, they needed different advertising.
A set of commercials was developed of which the most famous was ‘launderette’,
featuring Nick Kamen sitting in a launderette in his boxer shorts as he waited for his 501s
to wash; the music backing was Marvin Gaye’s ‘I Heard It Through the Grapevine’. It is
still to be found on YouTube if you search using ‘Levi’ and ‘launderette’. These ads
multiplied Levi’s sales twenty-fold in the next three years at a higher price, and it was
claimed that even sales of boxer shorts increased.
The point of this example is that the successful strategy related to a difference in
perception about jeans – hardly a matter of cultural difference but immensely important to
the success of the advertising. Such differences of perception are more a matter of market
research than cross-cultural investigation, but they cannot be ignored by marketers.
Marketing in China
China, as well as being the home of a large part of the world’s population,
has shown a spectacular rate of GDP growth. In 2010 it was 10.4 per cent
(World Bank). Despite concern about the decline in China’s growth in
recent years, 6.9 per cent was reported for 2015. Meanwhile, western
markets have recorded low or negative growth.2 Because of its importance,
we have compared China with western markets. How different is China?
Although Chinese consumers buy different foodstuffs from the West, many
other aspects of purchase are very similar and the Chinese are purchasing a
large number of luxury brands from the West, from perfume to whisky.
Uncles (2010: 70) believes that the main theme is convergence: ‘Significant
aspects of the Chinese retail landscape now conform to what might be
described as an international norm and, superficially at least, consumer
attitudes and behaviours appear to be more alike.’ Uncles (2010: 70) notes
that ‘retail formats, institutions, infrastructures, and management practices
are becoming similar to those seen in international markets’. In grocery
retailing, hypermarkets and supermarkets are rapidly growing and took 62
per cent of grocery sales in 2008, a figure not far behind that of many
western countries. By comparison, traditional retailing such as wet markets
is stationary. Uncles notes that much of the modern retail expansion is
driven by international companies such as Carrefour and Tesco, who often
work in partnership with Chinese companies. This speeds up the transfer of
western business practice.
Chinese consumers accept the new pattern of retailing. One reason for this
is environmental determinism. In Chapter 1, we noted that behaviour is
moulded by the conditions under which people live; the environment
defines what actions are possible and rewards and punishes behaviour
according to how it fits the environmental conditions. It is hardly surprising
that attitudes and values develop that broadly endorse a retail system that is
well established, and it would be naïve to assume that values always come
first and systems are developed to be consistent with them. This control by
the environment is enhanced when urban renewal projects replace the
traditional market with a western format. Uncles notes that more traditional
retailing practices persist in China but points out that there are
corresponding traditional forms in the West.
Uncles, Wang and Kwok (2010b) studied brand performance metrics to see
whether patterns familiar in the West are also found in China. As elsewhere,
they found the double jeopardy effect with toothpaste and soy sauce in two
different cities, Shanghai and Xi’an, which was consistent over five years.
They also showed that multi-brand loyalty was the norm, just as it is in
Europe, Australasia and the USA. In two other studies, Uncles and Kwok
(2008, 2009) examined patterns of category purchase by store. Again, the
Dirichlet patterns were found: what people buy may differ but how they buy
fits patterns of behaviour found in the West.
Market research has focused on the goods and services that are typically
bought by consumer segments. However, to explain preferences among older
consumers, it is necessary to study how the process of decision-making
varies with age. So far, this aspect of decision-making has focused mainly on
variations in cognitive and affective processes as people age (Lambert-
Pandraud, Laurent and Lapersonne, 2005; Cole et al., 2008; Drolet, Schwarz
and Yoon, 2010; Lambert-Pandraud and Laurent, 2010).
Figure 6.2 The repeat purchase of cars by age group (from Lambert-
Pandraud, Laurent and Lapersonne, 2005)
The conservatism of older buyers could relate to cognitive decline, which
increases the cognitive effort in decision-making and pushes the older person
towards decision heuristics such as choice repetition or purchase deferral
(Phillips and Sternthal, 1977; Lambert-Pandraud et al., 2005). However,
there is evidence that it is the speed rather than the ability to process
information that is measured in tests of cognitive process (Roedder-John and
Cole, 1986; Cole and Houston, 1987). This suggests that older people may
have the capacity to decide effectively but make less use of this capacity
because of their slower processing speed.
From Figure 6.3, we can see that word of mouth about brands received by
respondents falls sharply with age. On average, respondents aged 65 and
over receive 1.5 instances of WOM compared with 3.9 by those aged 25.
Men tend to report receiving more WOM than women, except in the 65+
segment. A number of explanations could fit these findings. The older
respondents might recall fewer instances of advice because of cognitive
decline, but against this the effect is fairly continuous over the age range,
and seems to start before the age when cognitive decline is believed to begin.
Also, retirement, the death of friends and the departure of children from the
household – all leading to reduced social contact – are consistent with the
decline in advice observed. The same research also examined the period of
time that respondents had owned their current brand in seven categories and
this period jumped to nearly twice the level for post-65-year-olds. Using
regression analysis, the researchers examined whether the volume of word of
mouth received was related to the length of time that the current brand had
been owned (which was seen as evidence of purchase deferral). It was found
that the greater the volume of positive advice received, the less the purchase
deferral.
Figure 6.3 Average sum of received positive and negative WOM about
brands by age and sex (from East et al., 2014b)
Applying this thinking, Melnyk and her co-authors (2009) propose that
women may be more loyal to individual employees, while men are more
loyal to companies/brands. In a scenario study, the authors present
participants with a situation where instead of going to the closest bakery for
a birthday cake, there is the option of going to a bakery owned and run by
somebody they went to high school with. In an alternative condition, the
word somebody is replaced by a group of people. In subsequent studies, the
authors asked participants directly whether they were more loyal to
individual service providers or to companies in different categories for their
actual consumption behaviour. Across these studies, they show that women
do not always exhibit more consumer loyalty than men, but their loyalty
does indeed extend to individual employees, while men show more loyalty
to companies. They also found evidence that these types of loyalty are
driven by the quest for relational versus collective interdependence, for
women and men respectively.
The difference in loyalty between men and women found by Melnyk et al.
(2009) could be underpinned by genetic difference or adjustment to social
norms. The generalizability of the findings will depend on which
explanation applies; if the difference relates to role differences that are
widely found in western economies, we might find varying patterns of
loyalty in other societies where the role relationships are different. This
would mean that the loyalty difference is more cross-cultural than inherent
in genetics. From the findings of Melnyk et al., we might expect women to
talk more about categories where interpersonal relationships are common.
Some unpublished work at Kingston University indicates the product fields
that women talk about to others more than men. Men talk more about
mobile phones, airtime suppliers for mobile phones, computers, credit cards
and bank accounts, while women talk more about holiday destinations,
luxury brands, supermarkets, restaurants and coffee shops. These
differences fit gender roles. Women may give more advice about
supermarkets because they do so much more food shopping than men
(Chang-Hyeon, Arentze and Timmermans, 2006), yet women also use
phones more than men, according to Nielsen (2011b) in evidence from the
USA, and despite this men appear to talk more about them. Perhaps devices
like phones, being impersonal, attract more interest from men. Whatever the
bases for these differences, they are of importance to marketers and ad
agencies in making decisions about the targeting and content of
communications.
Summary
The cultural environment in which an individual is raised and lives shapes
his or her perceptions, dispositions and behaviour. National cultural
differences have been studied extensively, largely under the influence of
seminal work by Hofstede. Hofstede categorizes countries on the level of
power distance that is accepted by their members, their tolerance for
uncertainty, the degree to which economic achievement versus caring for
other people is valued, the degree to which the delay of gratification is
accepted, and the degree to which individuals are supposed to look after
themselves or remain integrated in groups. This last dimension, referred to
as individualism versus collectivism, has been much used in consumer
research. An excellent mapping of all relevant cultural differences is
provided by Schwartz and Bilsky (1990); based on the Rokeach Value
Survey, they identify ten value types.
Usunier, J.C. and Lee, J. (2011) Marketing across Cultures, 5th edition,
Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Notes
1 Answer to Exercise 6.1:
Define attitude, belief and intention, and explain how these concepts are measured.
Understand the expected-value theory of attitude applied to products.
Report on the research linking behaviour to attitude and intention.
Describe the theory of planned behaviour, its applications, strengths and weaknesses.
Understand the problems of predicting behaviour.
Overview
The cognitive approach to consumer behaviour relates consumers’ attitudes, beliefs and
intentions to their behaviour. Among the theories used, the theory of planned behaviour
(TPB) has been most successful, although a number of problems with this theory remain.
We first examine the nature and measurement of attitudes, beliefs and intentions and their
relationship with behaviour, and then we explain how the TPB can be used to predict and
explain behaviour. This has a clear relevance to marketing: we need to predict purchase
and to understand why people prefer one brand to another if we are to create products in
the right quantity and of the right quality.
Section 1: Definitions and Measurements
Attitudes are what we feel about a concept, which may be a brand, category,
person, theory or anything else we think about and attach feelings to. An
important class of concepts is actions, particularly commercially relevant
behaviour such as buying, renting, using and betting. We focus on attitudes
to such actions because it is these attitudes that best predict the actions.
Thus, it is the attitude to playing the National Lottery or buying a smart
phone that most interests us. Compared with the attitude to the action, the
attitude to the object (the National Lottery or the smart phone) is less
directly related to the action.
The first scale measures the likelihood of the outcome, while the second
measures the value of the outcome if it occurs. These seven-point measures,
called semantic differential scales, were first used in research by Osgood,
Suci and Tannenbaum (1957). We usually denote the likelihood measure as b
(for belief) and the evaluation measure as e. The full outcome measure is the
product of b and e, which we call the expected value of the outcome. An
expected value can be negative as well as positive because the evaluation
can be negative.
The Expected-Value Theory of Attitude
Most of the alternatives from which we choose are multi-attribute. To
assess the value of going to Wales for a holiday, I have to take account of
weather, cost, travelling effort, food, opportunities for recreation, etc. Using
the method above, we can measure an expected value for each outcome,
and my overall (or global) attitude to going to Wales for a holiday is given
by the sum of the expected values. So, if A is the global attitude:
or A = Σ biei
Elicit salient beliefs. In a sample of people from the target group, ask each person
questions about the advantages and disadvantages of the defined action. After each
response, prompt with ‘anything else?’ but do not press hard for ideas. Record the
responses for each person. A typical encounter might be:
Q. Can you tell me what you think are the advantages of getting a new computer?
Q. Anything else?
Q. Anything else?
A. Not really.
Q. Can you tell me what you think are the disadvantages of getting a new computer?
Q. Anything else?
Q. Is there anything else that you can think of about getting a new computer?
A. No.
Consider the negative action. Certain actions may have different salient beliefs
associated with not doing the action. For example, ‘not having children’ and ‘not taking
drugs’ may be seen as actions with their own rationale and are not just the opposites of
having children and taking drugs. For such negative actions, it is wise to also elicit
salient beliefs about the negative action.
Be aware of salient referents. Ask each respondent in the sample whether there are
people or groups who think that the respondent should do the defined action. Repeat
with ‘should not’. Ask if there are other people or organizations that come to mind when
they think of the action. Use the prompt ‘anyone else?’ but do not press for responses.
(Recent work has often included measures of what salient referents think the respondent
will do as well as should do.)
Think about control factors. Ask each respondent about conditions that make the
action easier or harder to perform. Again, prompt with ‘anything else?’
Refine the list of beliefs. Combine similar beliefs. Compile a list of modal salient
beliefs using the ones most frequently mentioned. The decision to include a belief
depends on the frequency with which it is mentioned and the time and money available
to support the research. When the questionnaire is intended to be used both before and
after exposure to advertising or the product, it is important to include beliefs that may
become salient as a result of this exposure.
After similar responses have been grouped together, the list of modal salient
beliefs is usually quite short. Complex issues, such as getting married or
buying a house, may have about ten salient beliefs relating to attitude;
simpler issues, such as buying specific chocolate bars, will have fewer.
Do Attitudes Predict Action?
Our interest in attitudes is partly based on the belief that they predict behaviour.
Following Allport (1935), an attitude is usually seen as ‘a preparation or
readiness for response’ and thus should be a predictor of behaviour, except
when freedom of action is restricted. However, when Wicker (1969: 65)
reviewed 47 studies on attitudes and behaviours, he concluded that: ‘It is
considerably more likely that attitudes will be unrelated or only slightly related
to overt behaviors than that attitudes will be closely related to actions’.
Schuman and Johnson (1976) suggested that other unreported variables affect
behaviour in addition to attitude. This was supported in work by Fishbein and
Ajzen (1975), Ajzen and Fishbein (1980) and Ajzen (1985, 1991). These
researchers showed that, in addition to attitude, behaviour is controlled by
beliefs about the wishes of people and groups important to the respondent, and
by beliefs about the way personal ability and the environment can promote or
restrict behaviour.
Another example of using the wrong attitude takes the form of trying to predict
what people will do from measures of past satisfaction. As we saw in Chapter
2, satisfaction can be a poor predictor of future behaviour because people can
be positive about their past experience with a product without necessarily
wanting to use it in the future. Needs change and sometimes products change
so that what was satisfactory in the past may not be expected to be satisfactory
in the future. A somewhat better prediction of retention would be obtained by
using the attitude to ‘buying the product again’.
Specifying Measures
From this work, it is clear that the more compatible the measures of attitude
and behaviour, the more they will correlate. Compatibility is specified by
target, action, context and time (think TACT). In the case of oral contraceptive
use, the target is the oral contraceptive, the action is using it and the
context/time is implicit in its use. In other cases, the context and time could be
more important. For example, I might avoid shopping in my local supermarket
on a Saturday morning because the store is so busy at that time. In addition to
the TACT variables, it is important to ensure that respondents are talking about
their own attitudes and behaviour rather than some general idea. Ajzen and
Fishbein (1977) applied these compatibility criteria in a meta-analysis of 142
attitude–behaviour associations. They sorted the studies into those with low,
partial and high compatibility between the measures and sub-divided the last
group because some measures were not clearly specified. Table 7.2 shows their
findings. It is clear that low compatibility between attitude and behaviour
explains why many previous studies showed a weak connection between
attitude and behaviour.
Swimming is:
For me, going swimming in my local swimming pool over the next month is:
There are two reasons for discrepancies between predicted and actual
purchase: first, the true probability of purchase may be inaccurately
measured by the scale point checked by the respondent, and second, people
may change their intention or be unable to fulfil it (Bemmaor, 1995). The
second inaccuracy is difficult to avoid but the first type of discrepancy is
reduced by improved scaling. Juster (1966) used an 11-point, verbally
referenced scale to measure the likelihood of purchase (see Box 7.1). In a
review of intention measurement, Day et al. (1991) argue that the best
results are obtained using a Juster scale, and Wright and MacRae (2007)
show that the predicted purchase proportions obtained using the Juster scale
were unbiased estimates of the actual purchase proportions found from
panel data or purchase recall.
Box 7.1 The Juster scale
This is an 11-point scale with verbal descriptions and probabilities associated with each number:
Normally, with durable goods like cars, a large majority of people express no
intention of buying in the next year so that even a small percentage of this group
who do buy provides a large fraction of the total number of buyers. Pickering and
Isherwood (1974) found that 55 per cent of all buyers came from the group
expressing no intention to buy. Theil and Kosobud (1968) in the USA, and Gabor
and Granger (1972) in Britain, found that 70 and 65 per cent of purchasers
respectively were in the group stating a zero-purchase probability.
The extent to which people fulfil their intentions was reviewed by McQuarrie
(1988), who assembled data from 13 studies. McQuarrie found that those who
intended to purchase did so, on average, 42 per cent of the time, whereas those not
intending to purchase did not purchase 88 per cent of the time; this asymmetry is
probably related to the fact that it is easier not to do something than to do it (see
Box 7.2).
Box 7.2 Reasons for inaction
Why don’t people do as they intend? East (1993) found that only two-thirds of those
intending to apply for shares in British government privatizations actually did so. When
the other third were asked why they had not followed through on their intention, they
were equally divided between changing their mind (e.g. because the investment looked
less advantageous) and inertia (e.g. forgetting, too much trouble). Pickering (1975)
investigated the failure to follow through on an intention to buy consumer durables. In
this case, respondents had usually changed their mind due to unforeseen circumstances,
such as lack of money, or because their current durable was lasting better than expected.
Discrepancies between attitude and behaviour may also increase with the
period that elapses between attitude measurement and behaviour
measurement. The longer the period, the more opportunity people have to
change their minds in response to new information or changed
circumstances. For example, the attitude to voting for a political party may
be affected by unfolding political events, and a measure of voting attitude
taken close to an election should naturally be expected to have more
predictive value than one taken a year before. However, although this effect
of time lapse seems common sense, a study by Randall and Wolff (1994)
found no evidence that the length of the interval was related to the
correlation between intention and behaviour.
One study has raised some concern about the prediction of behaviour from
intention. Chandon, Morwitz and Reinartz (2005) found that correlations in
surveys between intention and subsequent behaviour are increased by the
process of asking about the respondent’s intentions. It appears that, after
questioning, respondents are more likely to do what they said they were
going to do.
Section 2: The Theory of Planned Behaviour
(TPB)
Attitudes, intentions and behaviour have been combined in a comprehensive
model of consumer choice called the theory of planned behaviour (TPB).
Figure 7.1 illustrates this theory and Figure 7.2 shows it applied to playing
the UK National Lottery.
The TPB was developed over a long period, starting with Fishbein’s (1963)
expected-value theory of attitude. This theory was extended in a number of
studies to predict intention and behaviour (e.g. Ajzen and Fishbein, 1969;
Ajzen, 1971; Ajzen and Fishbein, 1972). In addition to attitude (AB), the
authors included subjective norm (SN) as a determinant of intention. SN
measures the person’s beliefs about what other people think they should do.
This extended model was renamed the theory of reasoned action by Ajzen
and Fishbein (1980) in a book in which they applied the theory to practical
concerns such as health, consumer behaviour and voting. In 1985, Ajzen
introduced the TPB by adding perceived control (PC) as a determinant of
intention. PC measures a person’s beliefs about the opportunities for an
action which are based on the environment and their own abilities. The
relative strengths of AB, SN and PC in determining an action are given by
the weights w1, w2 and w3. Since these weights vary from category to
category, they are established empirically, using regression analysis or
structural equation modelling.
As can be seen from Figure 7.1, the three global variables determine
intention, which then determines behaviour. The weight w4 reflects the fact
that circumstances may stop people from realizing their intentions, or that
their intentions could change. Finally, the model includes a second direct
effect of perceived control on behaviour, with weight w5. This covers
behaviours such as giving up smoking and eating less where a lack of
personal control can undermine intention. This might apply to compulsive
gamblers who find the National Lottery difficult to resist.
This theory also covers altruistic behaviour, which can be driven by the
subjective norm, and it takes account of a person’s self-assessed abilities and
opportunities. As such, it is an advance on simple subjective expected utility
(SEU) models that do not allow for such influences. The subjective norm is
an internalized influence, exerting its effect through the agent’s memories
and values. The social agents that are recalled need not be present, or even
exist, for them to have an effect. In recent work, a measure called the
descriptive norm has been added. This is what others expect that the
respondent will do (as opposed to should do). For example, Forward (2009)
found that adding a descriptive norm variable to the model improved the
prediction of driving violations. Similarly, White et al. (2009) found that the
addition of the descriptive norm improved the prediction of recycling
behaviour. The TPB can be used to explain any behaviour where there are
reasons for action, but it is more appropriate for explaining category use than
brand use where there are few differences in beliefs and attitudes between
brands. Among the many behaviours to which the TPB has been applied are:
taking exercise, attaining college grades, condom use, health self-
examinations, escaping addiction, blood donation, mothers’ diet
management of their babies, food choice, recycling, buying environmentally
friendly products, Internet use, reducing risky driving, accident avoidance,
seeking funding, buying gifts, applying for shares in initial public offerings,
and complaining.
Level 1: Behaviour
The immediate precursors of behaviour in the TPB are intention and
perceived control, so one form of explanation concerns the relative impact
of these two factors. This has been examined by Madden, Ellen and Ajzen
(1992) who found that perceived control is usually the weaker factor.
Perceived control is likely to become important where there is substantial
difficulty in performing the predicted behaviour.
Level 2: Intention
Next, we need to know the relative importance of AB, SN and PC in
predicting intention. This varies from application to application. For
example, Jaccard and Davidson (1972) found that, among college women,
the use of the contraceptive pill was associated more with AB than with SN;
this probably reflected the importance of avoiding pregnancy for this group
at that time. Davidson and Jaccard (1975) found that among married
women with children, the intention to use the contraceptive pill was more
determined by SN.
Sometimes, the obvious reason for an activity is not its prime motivation.
Membership of sports clubs may be driven by the need to meet people, for
example. East (1993) found that application for shares in state privatizations
was driven more by access to finance, a PC factor, than by the expected
financial outcomes, an AB factor. This suggests that business people should
not become too focused on the good quality of their product or service since
many of the people who might buy it may be constrained by finance or
other control factors.
Box 7.3 An application to giving up
cigarettes
In 1978, the UK Joint Committee on Research into Smoking recommended that a new
study should be undertaken on attitudes towards smoking. One stimulus for this work was
a 1977 report on attitudes and smoking behaviour prepared by Fishbein for the US
Federal Trade Commission. This recommended a shift of focus from ‘attitudes to
smoking’ to ‘attitudes to giving up cigarettes’. The new study was conducted for the
Office of Population Censuses and Surveys by Marsh and Matheson. The findings were
published by the government in 1983 but the main features appear in a paper by Sutton,
Marsh and Matheson (1990). The research measured AB and confidence in being able to
stop smoking, which was a form of PC measurement, but no measure of SN was made.
The researchers predicted behaviour on the basis of the difference between the expected
values of stopping and continuing to smoke. It is this difference that shows the personal
gain or loss of taking one option rather than the other. The research showed that the
majority of smokers accepted that smoking causes lung cancer (73 per cent) and heart
disease (59 per cent), but the study also showed that most of these people believed either
that they did not smoke enough to do any damage or that any damage was already done
and was irreversible. For such people, cessation held little promise of reduced risk. The
only smokers who saw a benefit in stopping were the minority who believed both that
they had an enhanced risk and that cessation would diminish this risk. The researchers
predicted that these people would make more attempts to stop and this was confirmed
when the smokers were followed up six months later. This evidence therefore supports a
causal process from attitude to action.
This research showed where to place the emphasis in health education in order to
encourage people to try to quit smoking; for example, by explaining that the risk from
cigarettes is related to the number smoked, that there is no threshold at which health
hazards begin, and that there are health benefits for nearly all people who stop smoking.
The study also showed that eventual success in quitting was strongly dependent on
confidence, and that health education should therefore emphasize ‘how to stop’ methods
which would build this confidence.
Set up different scales for each item and the form of the items from input. If using a program
package, mistakes and poor grammar in the questionnaire need to be eliminated by word
processing. In particular, the phraseology for control items can be clumsy and needs
adjustment. Despite this, using a program speeds up questionnaire development. Some items
are added automatically but these may be deleted if not required. The questionnaire will
usually cover two sides of paper when printed in a two-column landscape format (10 point).
The questionnaire looks better if scale referents such as ‘extremely’, ‘quite’ and ‘slightly’ are
italicized. The scaling is designed for a proportional font such as Times New Roman.
1. Create products between outcome probability and outcome evaluation (and the
corresponding products for the referent and control beliefs, but see later comment,
Multiplying Ordinal Measures).
2. Produce three sum measures by aggregating products for the outcome, referent and
control items.
3. Aggregate measures for each of the global variables and intention when more than one
scale is used. (A reliability test may be appropriate here to check that each scale is
measuring the same variable.)
Next:
Thus, beliefs and the other components of the TPB should mediate the effect
of external variables, as shown in Figure 7.3. This argument has been tested
in a number of studies by including external variables in the regression
analysis to see whether these significantly improve the prediction of
intention compared with the global variables alone. Often, demographic
variables have little effect; for example, Marsh and Matheson (1983) found
no direct effects of age or sex on intention in their study on smoking
cessation, and Loken (1983) found no direct effect of external variables on
television watching.
Despite the lack of support for the theory, the issue of how experience
affects the different beliefs underlying global variables is important and
deserves further study. In many TPB studies, SN is a relatively weak
determinant of behaviour and there has been some tendency to downgrade it
(e.g. Sheppard, Hartwick and Warshaw, 1988). Armitage and Connor
(2001) found that part of the weakness could be attributed to poor
measurement.
Deliberate and Spontaneous Action
Fazio (1990) divides the explanation of behaviour into two fields. Where
decision-making is deliberate, Fazio supports the TPB, but when the
decision is spontaneous, he proposes a different model in which attitude
comes first. This second model is shown in Figure 7.4.
Fazio argues that attitude activation occurs only when the object and its
evaluation have been well established in memory, usually through direct
behavioural experience. Thus,the spontaneous production of behaviour is
restricted to familiar contexts, leaving planned behaviour to explain the more
unusual situations. However, this rather cosy division of the field has been
disrupted by evidence from Bargh et al. (1992) that a wide range of objects
can elicit attitude-driven effects. This casts doubt on the separation between
the automatic and deliberate control of behaviour. It seems possible that
these two types of explanation may often work together. Fazio (1990)
showed that responses in measurements of deliberate behaviour are affected
if people are asked to focus on emotion-evoking objects before
measurement. Baldwin and Holmes (1987) found that systematically
different measurements were obtained when different social referents were
visualized before response. These findings reflect the effect of automatic
processes even when people are making considered responses.
Adjustments and Alternatives to the Theory of
Planned Behaviour
A number of researchers have suggested modifications of the theory.
Bagozzi and Kimmel (1995) and Bagozzi (1992) suggested distinctions
between intention, desire and self-prediction, and Armitage and Conner
(2001) found some support for these distinctions. There have also been
proposals to include a moral norm to cover the respondent’s personal
normative control, but this has been found to have an additional predictive
function only for some actions.
In its present form, the theory includes only one type of subjective norm –
what respondents think that others think that they should do. As noted
earlier, what others actually do (descriptive norm) exerts an additional
influence on behaviour (Deutsch and Gerard, 1955). When descriptive
norms are included, predictions are usually better supported (Rivis and
Sheeran, 2003). Other developments are possible; Armitage and Conner
(2001) separate measures for the control element in the theory into the
control that a person has by virtue of his or her abilities and the control that
is made possible by the environment. However, all these adjustments raise
the complexity of the theory and make it harder to use.
However, there is a concern about the methods that have been used to test
the theory. If the theory is causal, it should be possible to supply
information and then observe how the effects of that information change the
components of the theory. This requires research designs in which
comparisons are made between experimental conditions that induce
changes of belief. The fact that there is little published evidence of this sort
may indicate that little has been done in this area or that the results of such
research have not been conclusive.
The TPB (Ajzen, 1985, 1991) formalizes this link between beliefs,
attitudes, intentions and behaviour. In this theory, there are three global
variables – attitude to a behaviour, subjective norm and perceived control.
These three variables have a combined effect on intention. Behaviour is
predicted by intention and perceived control. The global variables rest on
beliefs about the outcomes of behaviour, the referents who think that a
person should or should not engage in the behaviour, and the ability and
opportunity to engage in the behaviour. The TPB provides different levels
of explanation which can be used in product positioning, development and
advertising themes.
Additional Resources
Issues on the nature of attitudes and their relationship with behaviour are
well discussed in Chapter 4 of Eagly and Chaiken (1993) and in Eagly and
Chaiken (2005). A review of the TPB is provided by Ajzen (2002) and by
Armitage and Conner (2001). Ajzen’s website is
www.people.umass.edu/aizen/faq.html (note: ‘aizen’ is an alternative
spelling).
8 Information Processing and Decision-
Making
Learning Objectives
When you have completed this chapter, you should be able to:
1. Understand the way schemas and response competition are involved in thinking.
2. Explain what is meant by a heuristic mechanism and describe how these mechanisms
may bias decision-making.
3. Describe how human beings respond to objective probability and value.
4. Understand the ideas of framing, mental accounting and editing.
5. Describe how this work can be used to influence others and improve consumer choice.
Overview
In the previous chapter, the theory of planned behaviour was described. Though it assists
prediction, this theory does not really describe how people think. People do not assign
likelihoods and evaluations, multiply them and sum the products to form their attitudes.
Planned behaviour theory works as if people figure out their interests in this way, but no
claim is made that they actually do so.
The notion of the schema was implicit in the early work by Bartlett (1932)
on remembering. Bartlett wrote of the ‘effort after meaning’ and showed
how unusual structures that fell short of representing any object were
interpreted by reference to more familiar ideas. One of Bartlett’s stimuli
was a diagram of an ambiguous object that was variously recognized as a
battleaxe, turf cutter, anchor or key, although it was not quite like any of
them. People were using the schema for a more familiar object to make
sense of the ambiguous object.
When more than one schema fits a situation, people experience response
competition as they struggle to give meaning to the stimulus (see Box 8.1).
This leads to extended attention as people grapple with the problem.
Box 8.1 Response competition
Response competition is demonstrated by the Stroop test. In this test, you are asked to call
out the colour that is written the moment that it is displayed. In one condition, the word is
RED written using a red colour; in the other condition, RED is written using a blue colour
and, in this second case, respondents take longer to respond than in the first condition. In
the second case, two competing responses are aroused – to say ‘red’ (reading the word)
and to say ‘blue’ (the colour of the text) – and the competition delays the production of
the correct response.
Managing Schemas
Since thought is guided by schemas, it follows that negotiation and other
forms of influence may succeed by manipulating the selection of schemas
that people use to interpret their experience. One standard ploy in
negotiation is to try to anchor the discussion around a particular range of
outcomes. Early in the discussion, a negotiator might say, ‘The normal rate
for this type of work is £1,000 a day’. This can constrain offers to those
fairly close to the rate mentioned. Turning to advertising, schemas may be
used to develop the product concept. For example, ‘No FT, no comment’
implies that those who read the Financial Times are likely to be better
informed – it conjures up a notion of the business expert dispensing
wisdom. Often, public relations exercises can be seen as attempts to
manipulate the schemas used in judgement. For example, firms may play up
their green credentials by drawing attention to their energy-saving actions.
Some interesting examples of schema management are shown in Box 8.2.
Do People Like Response Competition?
Jokes are often based on response competition. People may anticipate one
outcome and have their expectations confounded at the punchline. But other
forms of response competition may be disliked. Even jokes may be disliked
when a person is under stress. The explanation for this variable reaction is
that it depends on the degree of arousal of the person involved. Boredom
(low stimulation) and high stress (high stimulation) are both conditions of
high arousal. People prefer an intermediate level of stimulation because, in
this region, arousal is lower. Conceptual conflicts may be welcome when
people are inactive or bored (e.g. when watching television) because the
extra stimulation will reduce arousal; at other times, unusual stimuli may
raise arousal (Berlyne, 1965; Berlyne and McDonnell, 1965) and, when this
occurs, the stimuli may be disliked. This explains why Harrison (1968) and
Saegert and Jellison (1970) found that stimulating objects were often
disliked.
Box 8.2 New schemas for old
An activist group took on the tobacco companies in Australia. The group was called the
Billboard Utilising Graffitists Against Unhealthy Promotions (BUGA UP) and it
specialized in ‘refacing’ tobacco posters. When a cigarette company offered a car as a
prize, the poster was given the caption: ‘From the people who put the “car” in
carcinogen’. The adjustments to the posters, and the speeches in court when members of
the group were prosecuted, gave entertainment to many Australians, who much
appreciated the sight of multinational tobacco companies being humbled in this way.
When a tobacco company sponsored work at the Sydney Opera House, well-dressed
members of BUGA UP distributed leaflets expressing regret at this unsavoury association
between tobacco and the arts. Another BUGA UP enterprise sabotaged a Marlboro ‘Man
of the Year’ competition in Australia. BUGA UP proposed its own candidate – a man
disabled by smoking, confined to a wheelchair, and smoking through the hole in his throat
provided by a tracheotomy operation. The man himself was a willing accomplice and
starred in a poster which was printed and sold in large numbers. The schema of the strong
heroic figure that Marlboro had tried to cultivate was ridiculed. In its place were put the
schemas of disease and disability which are more accurately related to smoking
cigarettes. A further ‘anti-promotion’ counteracted the distribution of free cigarettes in
shopping malls. To most people, a gift is a kindness and the giver is regarded as well-
meaning. To oppose such promotions, BUGA UP arranged for children to parade around
the mall with banners saying ‘DANGER – DRUG PUSHERS AT WORK’. This changed
the perception of the tobacco companies’ motives from kindness to self-interest. Tobacco
companies have a squalid record of refusing to admit to the hazards of their products;
they are licensed drug sellers and an important part of their public relations has been to
counter such facts by sponsoring orchestras, sport and research. BUGA UP’s achievement
was to reassert the drug-seller schema as the one by which the tobacco companies’
actions could be judged.
Mere Exposure
Response competition has been used to explain an interesting phenomenon
first reported by Zajonc (pronounced Zi-onse, 1968). Zajonc observed that
repeated exposure to a new stimulus often made people like it more. This
effect of mere exposure was so called because the change in the observer’s
evaluation occurs without the use of reinforcement (discussed in Chapter 1).
Zajonc observed this effect in both laboratory and field experiments, using
nonsense words, obscure characters and photographs of unknown faces as
the unfamiliar stimuli. For example, in Zajonc and Rajecki’s (1969) field
experiment, nonsense words such as NANSOMA were printed like
advertisements in campus newspapers. Later, the researchers got large
numbers of students to rate the words on evaluative scales and there was
clear evidence that the frequency of exposure correlated positively with the
evaluative rating. Zajonc’s explanation for this was that the nonsense words
created response competition in the minds of readers and that this was
reduced as people developed a familiarity with the nonsense word after
repeated exposure. If the response competition created by nonsense words
is generally disagreeable, a reduction in competition (e.g. through
familiarity with the nonsense word) should produce a more positive
evaluation. Harrison (1968) measured response competition as the time
delay before any response to the stimulus and found that the delay was
reduced as the number of exposures increased. Lee (1994) offered another
ingenious explanation which was based on the availability heuristic
discussed later in this chapter: repeated exposure speeds up recognition; the
stimuli that we recognize more easily tend to be those that we like; this
association guides judgement and leads us to give such stimuli higher
evaluations.
However, not all stimuli become more liked on repeated exposure. This
suggests that prospective brand names (which are often like nonsense
words) should be pre-tested to see whether they are well liked after they
have become familiar.
The Response to Thought and Feeling Stimuli
We tend to think that recognition is a necessary precursor to any evaluation
of a stimulus. If you do not know what the concept is, how can you have
any affective response to it? Strangely, it seems that we can have an
evaluative response without recognition. Zajonc (1980) showed that thought
and feeling are initially processed independently, and Kunst-Wilson and
Zajonc (1980) found that evaluative responses occurred slightly ahead of
recognition. Zajonc points to the survival value attaching to a fast response
to dangerous stimuli: it is better to jump without thought than to recognize
that it is a car that is hitting you!
Fast recognition judgements of the sort studied by Zajonc are quite different
from the choices typically faced by consumers, but these studies show how
unconscious mechanisms can underlie consciously experienced thought and
feeling.
Attention and Value
In decision-making, the observable action is often restricted to the overt choice.
However, when the alternatives are physically present, it is possible to observe
the direction of gaze and to infer from this which alternative a person is
thinking about. Gerard (1967) used this method of investigation; he employed
two projectors to show two alternatives (Impressionist paintings), while light
reflecting off a mirror attached to the back of the participant’s head showed
which alternative was receiving attention. A multi-channel recorder logged the
data. Gerard reported that the participants looked most at the alternative that
they did not choose and suggested that they were trying to come to terms with
not having this alternative.
To test Gerard’s result, East (1973) conducted two experiments using a battery
of slide viewers connected to a hidden time recorder (illustrated). As in the
earlier study by Gerard (1967), the choice was made between French
Impressionist paintings. The participants were led to believe that they would
get a poster of the picture that they chose. Control of the viewing equipment
was left entirely in the hands of the participant so that the time spent on the
different alternatives was unconstrained.
East’s first experiment presented subjects with two alternatives, while a second
experiment presented three alternatives. Both experiments had two levels of
choice difficulty: high, between alternatives that had previously been rated
equally by the subject, and low, between alternatives that had been rated
unequally.
The results showed that the subjects spent more time looking at the alternatives
that they liked, so that the ratio of attention times was an approximate function
of the ratio of the evaluations (see Table 8.1). East’s result was the opposite of
Gerard’s reported findings and it is possible that, with Gerard’s rather
complicated method for recording attention, the records were inadvertently
linked to the wrong alternative. A later study by Russo and Leclerc (1994)
supported East’s finding. Russo and Leclerc used video equipment in a
simulation supermarket situation and measured the number of eye fixations on
alternatives (rather than duration of time spent) at different phases in the
decision sequence. They found that in the main phase of the decision the
number of fixations clearly favoured the alternative later chosen. In another
study, Pieters and Warlop (1999) also found that more attention was paid to the
alternative that was eventually chosen.
Thus, there is a simple mechanism that directs attention to the more valued
alternative. This mechanism is unconscious; when asked about their potential
behaviour, people do not know which alternative they would look at most. This
evidence suggests that the more valued features of a person’s environment
generally get more attention than those of lesser value. We can see that this
mechanism helps people to benefit from their environment. To avoid harm, it is
likely that people attend more to unpleasant stimuli than to neutral ones but we
do not have data on this.
If evaluation guides attention, it means that second and third preferences will
get proportionately less attention and their worthwhile attributes are less likely
to be discovered. Only when investigation of the first preference leads to it
being down-rated will more time be allocated to lesser alternatives. This
mechanism therefore carries a bias in favour of existing preferences but it is an
efficient way of using time since it ensures that little time is wasted on low-
rated prospects. Given this evidence, people may be encouraged to buy an
initially lower-rated brand if information about this brand is attached to a
message on the initially preferred alternative, since it is then more likely to
receive attention. This may be done in comparative advertising, and there is
evidence that small brands benefit from this (Grewal et al., 1997).
Section 2: Heuristics
Exercise 8.1 Availability effects
In the UK, approximately 600,000 people die each year from all causes. How many people die
prematurely each year from the following two causes? Enter the figures that you think apply:
Smoking:
Road accidents:
The judgement of risk is notoriously erratic. Some of the reasons for this
may lie in poor information about actual risks in the media, but judgement
may also be distorted by heuristic thinking. Lichtenstein et al. (1978)
suggested that the risk of occurrences that are referred to often in the media
becomes exaggerated because of the availability heuristic. Those who
completed Exercise 8.1 are likely to have overestimated the risk of death
from road accidents because these events are more salient in media reports.
Smoking deaths are less well reported and are likely to be underestimated.
The approximate annual numbers of deaths in the UK in 2013 were:
All causes 576,000
Smoking (approx.) 100,000
Road accidents 1,713
A cab was involved in a hit-and-run accident at night. Two cab companies, the Green
and the Blue, operate in the city. You are given the following data:
85 per cent of the cabs in the city are Green and 15 per cent are Blue.
A witness identified the cab as a Blue cab. The court tested his ability to identify
cabs under appropriate visibility conditions. When presented with a sample of
cabs (half of which were Blue and half of which were Green), the witness made
correct identifications in 80 per cent of the cases.
Question: What is the probability that the cab involved in the accident was Blue rather than
Green?
Thus, participants tended to take note of the witness’s skill in recognizing cabs and ignored the
market shares of the two cab companies. Clearly, if there had been no Blue cabs, the witness
could not have been right so the proportion of Blue cabs is relevant. The probability that the
witness was right is the ratio of correct identification of cab colour as blue to total
identification as blue (both correct and incorrect). The chance that the cab was Blue (0.15) and
was recognized correctly (0.8) is 0.15 × 0.8, and the chance that the cab was Green (0.85) and
was recognized wrongly as Blue (0.2) is 0.85 × 0.2. The required ratio of correct identification
to total identifications is therefore:
( 0 . 15 × 0 . 8 ) ( 0 . 15 × 0 . 8 ) + ( 0 . 85 × 0 . 2 ) = 0 . 41
The tendency to ignore base rates, such as the market share of the cab
company, is the basis of the representativeness heuristic. Likelihood is
judged by reference to visible similarities rather than background
probabilities. For example, a person may be seen as a barrister because of
features of dress and delivery of speech. In this case, the judgement draws
on the stereotype of a barrister, but such a judgement takes no account of
the low number of barristers in society which makes it unlikely that a
person belongs to this group.
The bias towards the witness test in Exercise 8.2 may also relate to the fact
that this test is an event. As previously reported, events are more available
than continuing states such as market share. We seem to be tuned to change
and direct our thinking to the more active aspects of a problem. In contrast,
data dealing with unchanging features of our environment do not attract as
much attention. This mechanism serves a useful purpose by drawing
attention to happenings that may require a response but it can cause
mistakes in some cases. For example, it may lead to consumer financial
decisions that are related to active features of the environment rather than to
their impact on wealth. Wealth is a state rather than an event and does not
usually figure in individual judgements even though, normatively, it should.
People are also prone to give more weight to causal data, which is related to
change. For example, respondents are more likely to agree with the
proposition that a girl has blue eyes if her mother has blue eyes than a
mother has blue eyes if her daughter has blue eyes, though the two events
are equally probable (Tversky and Kahneman, 1980). The mother-to-
daughter inheritance is causal, unlike the daughter-to-mother relationship.
The focus on events rather than states and the different heuristic rules were
described by Kahneman (2002) as intuitive thinking in his presentation
following his award of the Nobel Prize for economics. Kahneman likens
such thinking to the way perception seems to be governed by mechanisms
over which we have little conscious control. What we perceive is a function
of the context from which reference points are drawn. Small changes in
problems can affect the reference points and change the judgement. There
are criticisms of this work; see, for example, Gigerenzer (1991), who has
raised questions about the interpretation of effects (response by Kahneman
and Tversky, 1996).
Relevance to Marketing and Management
The greater cognitive availability of events and causal data has a relevance
to marketing. For example, we may exaggerate the scope for market
interventions, such as brand extension. As we saw in Chapter 4, conditions
such as market share control the likely outcome of such interventions, but
these conditions may get less attention than they deserve because of their
constancy.
In addition, retrieval bias will move decisions towards the option that is
easiest to bring to mind. This may lead us away from the prevention of
undesirable occurrences before they happen (proaction), and as a result we
may have to respond to undesirable occurrences after they have happened
(reaction). The choice between proaction and reaction depends on costs.
Sometimes, it is best to let things happen and then to focus resources on the
problem – management by exception – but in other cases, for example
avoiding accidents, prevention is usually best. Our point is that there is a
bias against proactive intervention because successful prevention produces
no visible outcome and this choice is therefore less cognitively available. In
sum, retrieval bias will operate in favour of the visible, well-defined events
and against those that are hard to bring to mind. This suggests that people
may:
Figure 8.1 shows another interesting effect. This is the steepness of the
negative part of the value function in comparison to the positive part. This
effect is captured by the aphorism losses loom larger than gains and, more
formally, as loss aversion. Loss aversion is behind the endowment effect
which is that people often demand much more to give up an object than
they would be willing to pay to acquire it. Generally, people will be
reluctant to trade what they own, except at a high price. The endowment
effect has been demonstrated in a number of studies reviewed by
Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler (1991a). One simple example of the effect
is the reluctance of people to engage in a 50:50 win/lose bet. On average,
people will only wager a dollar on a coin toss if they can win more than two
dollars. Not surprisingly, the endowment effect has been tested by critics;
see, for example, Shogren et al. (1994).
As we stated, gains and losses relate to some reference point. In some cases,
it will be a prior cost. For example, a person may see the $20,000 cost of
building work on a newly acquired house as an addition to the $1million
price paid for the house. Viewed like this, the $20,000 seems a modest
increment to the purchase price, but ten years later, when the purchase of
the house has faded into the past, further building work costing $20,000
will be evaluated on its own and will be psychologically more painful.
Thaler (1999) points out that the extent to which a cost is psychologically
linked to a benefit can vary. When people pay a fixed cost for a service,
irrespective of their amount of use, usage is decoupled from the payment
since any extra use is free. Another decoupling occurs when a credit card is
used. This postpones payment and also aggregates costs into one bill, which
reduces the total psychological cost compared with the sum of several
smaller separate costs (because of the curve in the utility function).
Probability
What are your answers to Exercise 8.4?
Exercise 8.4 The Allais paradox (Allais, 1953)
Allais asked one group of subjects to choose between two options:
Faced with the choices in Exercise 8.4, Allais found that 80 per cent of
respondents preferred option B to A but 65 per cent preferred option C to D.
This seems paradoxical because the ratio of the probabilities is the same in
each choice pair. One explanation for this pattern is that probability is
weighted as it is converted to subjective probability. Figure 8.2 shows how
the weighting of objective probability reduces the subjective impact of high
probabilities and increases the impact of low probabilities. The x-axis is
objective probability and the y-axis is the weighted outcome. Applied to the
data in Exercise 8.4, the weighting reduces the appeal of A and increases
the appeal of C.
The weighting of small objective probabilities fits the evidence that people
are positive about insurance and like to place long-odds bets. Above an
objective probability of 0.40, the weighting depresses subjective probability
so that risks are subjectively discounted; for example, a 50 per cent
probability is nearer to 40 per cent, subjectively. At the extremes, the
weighting is unstable; a one in a thousand chance may be dismissed as no
chance or taken seriously (bettors on national lotteries accept very long
odds).
The sensitivity near the reference point (0, 1) is illustrated by Exercise 8.5.
Exercise 8.5 Risk preferences
Suppose that you have a 99 per cent chance of getting $1,000. How much would you
pay to move that probability to certainty?
Suppose that you have a 50 per cent chance of getting $1,000. How much would you
pay to move that probability to 51 per cent?
Suppose that you have a 0 per cent chance of getting $1,000. How much would you pay
to move that probability to 1 per cent?
Most people will pay more in the 0 per cent and 99 per cent conditions for a
1 per cent increment in probability, but the long-run benefit of a 1-per-cent
gain in probability is the same at any point on the probability range.
Prospect Theory
Kahneman and Tversky (1979) and Tversky and Kahneman (1992)
incorporated the subjective conversion of value and probability into a
theory of choice called prospect theory, and they proposed that the choice of
an alternative (prospect) is established in two stages. In the first stage, the
choices that are framed in a communication are restructured or edited by the
receiver. Then, in the second stage, the receiver chooses the best option
based on the values assessed in the first stage.
When you have decided, consider how you would react to these alternatives:
The second pair of alternatives in Exercise 8.6 is the same as the first (A =
C, B = D). Yet Tversky and Kahneman found that 72 per cent preferred
programme A to B and 78 per cent preferred programme D to C. By
framing the problem in terms of the gains (lives saved), it is possible to
steer preference to the risk-averse option, A, rather than B. In the second-
choice pair, the framing in terms of lives lost makes people risk prone and
steers them to option D. Using the appropriate frame is clearly a ‘must’ for
anyone in the field of persuasive communication.
In negotiation, our editing processes may lead us into a poor deal and we
should beware of the way the other side frames choices. It is wise to focus
on the total cost of a deal. Give way on small items but resist concessions
on the larger ones. It could even be worthwhile to include small items in a
proposal so that you can concede them later.
Thaler (1999) introduced the term mental accounting, which covers some of
these editing functions. This uses the metaphor of accounting to explain the
way in which people organize, evaluate and keep track of activities. As in
accounting proper, people maintain separate accounts for different
activities; for example, they may accept the idea of flying business class to
Australia and back at an extra cost of $6,000 but find it difficult to justify
spending $6,000 to reduce discomfort over two days in another area of their
life. Also, people may close an account after a defined period; gamblers on
the race track tend to think of gains or losses over a day and investors in the
stock market may operate with a one-year horizon.
Box 8.4 The Nudge Unit
Thaler and Sunstein (2008) have written a popular book called Nudge in which they argue
that national administration can be much more effective if it incorporates the known
findings from mental accounting and other psychological research. They focus on
activities such as paying taxes, investing in pensions and securing organ donation. These
ideas have caught the interest of governments. In the UK, the Cabinet Office is advised
by a ‘Nudge Unit’, which claims to have saved substantial sums of money by simple
changes such as the redrafting of letters to tax payers.
Section 4: Financial Applications of Prospect
Theory
Prospect theory provides explanations for some puzzling behaviour. We
now provide several examples of its explanatory power, drawing on a
review by Camerer (2000).
Investment
One of the effects of loss aversion is that investors may tend to hang on to
losers and sell winners in share markets. Investors may have some
equilibrium concept in mind, believing that the swing of the pendulum will
take a losing stock back towards its purchase price and that a rising stock
could similarly fall. They may also be reluctant to sell a losing stock
because this turns a potential loss into an actual loss, so that it is more
painful. From a rational standpoint, the buying price is sunk cost and should
not figure in the decision to sell shares, except for calculating any capital
gains tax. The selection of an alternative to sell should be based on the
prospective return, based on the current valuation of the share.
Long-shot bias, or something rather similar, may lie behind the persistent
value premium effect in share investment. Value or income stocks typically
give fairly high dividends and sell at prices that are rather lower than is
justified by their fundamentals. Value stocks are contrasted with growth
stocks that pay low dividends. With growth stocks, investors forgo current
income and hope for more rapid growth. By analogy, the growth stock is
rather like a long shot, and some companies, like Google and Apple,
emerge to give spectacular results. However, the fundamentals are just that
and Dimson, Marsh and Staunton (2004) find that, in the long run, value
stocks give a distinctly better performance, and show a premium of about 3
per cent per year over growth stocks. This effect is transnational. In a
comparison of 14 countries, only one country (Italy) showed a superior
return from growth stocks.
Impact on Economics
Economics is founded on rational assumptions. These include an
assumption that the accumulation of wealth drives individual behaviour and
that alternatives should be assessed against this wealth criterion. However,
it is apparent that individuals do not think about their wealth but instead
about gains and losses relative to norms defined by the context.
Furthermore, they operate with a number of accounts so that a gain in one is
not necessarily offset (in their minds) by a loss in another. This pattern of
behaviour violates the principle of fungibility, that money in one account is
as good as money in another account. Also, it is possible to construct
choices where preferences violate the principle of dominance. People may
prefer A to B and B to C, but C to A.
Thus, people do not think according to the canons of economic logic, and
traditional economics has been severely challenged by prospect theory.
Previously, economists have argued that wealth will increase most rapidly if
people act rationally and money is fungible. This is a normative theory.
They claim that those who do not apply normative economic principles will
lose out, so that self-interest or reinforcement will direct behaviour towards
a rational pattern. Thus, actual economic behaviour will be driven towards
the rational pattern. But if people do not act rationally, normative
economics needs to take this into account. The most rational policy is to
anticipate the irrationality of others and adapt to it. Therefore, a study of
everyday decision-making is needed so that the rational person (or policy-
maker) can exploit the systematic biases in the choices of others.
Problems with Prospect Theory
The possibility of using prospect theory to explain behaviour, choose
profitably and negotiate successfully has seized the imagination of
researchers but the potential may be reduced when the theory is more
widely evaluated. Van der Plight and van Schie (1990) gathered evidence
on risk aversion and risk proneness among European populations. Their
work confirmed Kahneman and Tversky’s findings, but the effects were less
strong. In addition, Leclerc, Schmitt and Dubé (1995) found that people
making decisions under risk are often risk averse about time loss when,
according to prospect theory, they should be risk prone. The value of time
has now been examined in a series of studies by Festjens and Janiszewski
(2015).
Many of the studies on prospect theory have used hypothetical and rather
artificial examples. In these studies, the judgement of the majority has been
used and it would be interesting to know more about those people who do
not fit the model. However, there is plenty of field evidence which supports
the theory – though often only after ad hoc assumptions have been made
about the mental accounting period and the separation of accounts.
We convert objective value and probability into subjective forms. The effect
of this is that people are risk averse on gains and risk prone on losses at
medium and high probabilities. The value function is steeper in the negative
region. This gives rise to loss aversion and makes people more reluctant to
part with things that they own.
The way choices are presented (framed) and the information processing of
receivers (editing) affect the way in which decisions are made. If the
framing is manipulated, people can be pushed towards particular
alternatives. People tend to think in terms of different accounts which may
be closed after different periods. Thus, mental accounting, loss aversion and
risk tolerance will affect the evaluation of prospects.
Much of the work referenced here has come from two volumes edited by
Kahneman, Slovic and Tversky (1982) and Kahneman and Tversky (2000).
In particular, read Thaler (1999) ‘Mental accounting matters’ (reprinted in
Kahneman and Tversky, 2000: 241–60). Kahneman (2012) has incorporated
many of the findings from this research stream in his book Thinking Fast
and Thinking Slow. This book brings out the practical implications for
decision-making and national policy in a thoughtful and accessible way.
9 Consumer Satisfaction and Quality
Learning Objectives
When you have completed this chapter, you should be able to:
Because of the impact on the bottom line, especially in the long run,
companies want to diagnose satisfaction and quality problems as quickly as
possible by intercepting unhappy customers (see Box 9.1). Many now scan
the Internet to identify incidents. They also want to make an overall
assessment of their performance, benchmark it against industry standards
and competition, and track their performance over time to check if changes
in their way of operating have the desired effect. However, quantifying
dissatisfaction and comparing levels of satisfaction reliably across different
product or service categories or in different countries is not straightforward.
Standardized measures have been developed (mainly SERVQUAL), but
these have been criticized.
Some problems persist for a long time before a solution is found. Many of these solutions
could have been invented earlier; what is often missing is the idea, rather than new technology.
Consider the wheels on luggage which are now so common. These could have been produced
years before they became common. Often, people may not have had the idea for the innovation
because habituation stopped them from recognizing a problem. Can you think of products that
we take for granted but which could be made better?
Two additional determinants are shown in Figure 9.2 – we show these with
dotted lines because they are not part of the core disconfirmation model. The
perception of the performance of the goods or services affects satisfaction
directly; the better it is, the more we like it. Expectation also has a direct
effect. There is variation in the emphasis placed on the different factors
affecting satisfaction. Some researchers (e.g. Oliver, 1980, 1981; Swan and
Trawick, 1981) have emphasized expectations, while others (e.g. Churchill
and Surprenant, 1982; LaTour and Peat, 1979; Tse and Wilton, 1988) have
given attention to perceptions. Several studies (e.g. Oliver, 1980; Swan and
Trawick, 1980) found that satisfaction is influenced mainly by
disconfirmation. At odds with these results, Churchill and Surprenant (1982)
found that satisfaction with a video disc player was determined by perceived
product performance, and any disconfirmation had no additional impact on
satisfaction. It is therefore quite likely that the relative importance of the
different components of the model depends on the category.
Sometimes subtle cues can change the attribution that is made and therefore
influence the satisfaction with a consumption experience. Pham et al.
(2010) show that the presence of mirrors increases the likelihood that
consumers attribute service outcomes to themselves, rather than to the
service provider. As a result, unfavourable outcomes create less expressed
dissatisfaction. The downside of the phenomenon is that favourable
outcomes also lead to less expressed satisfaction. Self-awareness is the key
driving factor here: cues that increase self-awareness (e.g. the small talk of
a sales person centred on the customer) make self-attributions more likely.
The effect is shown both in experimental scenarios in a lab setting and in
real-life shopping situations. Interestingly, it also operates for the evaluation
of past experiences. A limiting condition is that consumers have to bear
some responsibility for the negative outcome (e.g. returning or exchanging
previously purchased items).
Exercise 9.2 Your experience
The apparently fresh Brie is acrid, the new vacuum cleaner blocks or the waiter in an
expensive restaurant is unhelpful – here the dissatisfactions arise because we expected a better
experience. Conversely, we may be pleasantly surprised and satisfied when expectations are
surpassed, such as when the roads are unusually clear, the fruit in supermarkets is ripe or the
plane arrives early.
Think back to the last time you were surprised by your experience as a consumer. Did the
surprise make you satisfied, dissatisfied or neither? How would you explain what happened?
What is the first reason that comes to mind and who was responsible? Are there other possible
reasons? Why did you come up with the first one first?
Availability
According to the availability heuristic, vivid events are more easily brought
to mind than routine occurrences and, in addition, these vivid events are
judged more probable than they are in reality (see Chapter 8). Folkes (1988)
gives an interesting example of how this can work. She asked people who
were approaching the escalators to their apartment in a six-storey building
how often the escalators broke down. The escalators only went to the fourth
floor so that those who lived on the fifth and sixth floors always had to
climb the stairs for the last part of their ascent. These people estimated that
the escalators broke down less often than the people who used the first four
floors, for whom an escalator failure (leading to the unusual event of
climbing the stairs) was more vivid. The distinctiveness of a product failure
raises its vividness, and the availability heuristic raises the perceived
likelihood that it will occur again (Chapter 8). This, in turn, raises
dissatisfaction. The supplier should, therefore, try to make failures less
distinctive. For example, if customers are occupied in some way when
service quality is reduced, they may form a less distinct memory of the poor
performance.
Causal Inferences
Weiner (1980, 1990) has examined the explanations given for success and
failure and has suggested three causal dimensions that are relevant to
consumer response: stability, locus of causality and controllability. Stability
occurs when the cause can be consistently attributed to a particular person
or feature of the environment; locus of causality relates to whether the
purchaser, the supplier or some other party is seen to be at fault; and
controllability reflects the ability of an agent to intervene and change
outcomes. An unstable negative event may not trigger negative attributions
by consumers; for example, an out-of-stock item may be seen as
exceptional (unstable) and unlikely to be repeated. It is, therefore, better for
a seller if the cause of their failure is seen as unstable by the customer. By
contrast, it is better to have stability in product success since this
encourages continued usage. Folkes (1984) suggests that, when failure is
perceived to be stable, a consumer will prefer to have a refund for a product
failure since a replacement carries the same risk as the original; if the
failure is seen as unstable, consumers will be more willing to accept a
replacement. The perception of stability may vary across customer
segments. Bolton (1998) examined defection from the service supplier as a
consequence of the failure of a mobile phone network. If the customer was
long-term, the failure was offset against past good performance and seen as
unstable, so the customer was disinclined to defect. Recent customers who
lacked this experience were more likely to see the failure as stable, blame
the supplier, and defect.
What are you going to say to customers? Consider the attributions they will make and the
response they will want. What are the customer expectations and how can you manage these so
that the failure is more acceptable? What compensation should you give, if any?
Section 3: Measuring Satisfaction and Service
Quality
Satisfaction and service quality are usually measured through surveys.
Surveys have the advantage of being easy to administer, direct, clear in their
purpose and high in face validity. Many measurement instruments are based
on the disconfirmation paradigm.
Satisfaction
Satisfaction with a product is experienced by a customer or an ex-customer.
In this respect, it is more restricted than the attitude to the product and
assessments of quality, which may be given by anyone, customer or not.
However, satisfaction with the product is an attitude; people are satisfied for
reasons that can be measured, as reported in Chapter 7, and they will give
an overall satisfaction like the global attitude described in the theory of
planned behaviour. This overall satisfaction can be measured by a question
such as:
Here, the latter two items are relative to two different comparators:
expectations and the ideal. For practical purposes, the ACSI is the average
of responses to the three items, though Fornell and his associates use
different weights for specific predictions. When a firm markets several
brands, a composite ACSI score for the firm can be derived from the scores
for each brand. The ACSI items are part of a larger set of questions that
cover complaints, loyalty, expectations, value and quality.
Box 9.2 The American Consumer
Satisfaction Items
1. Please consider all your experiences to date with your main supermarket. Using a
ten-point scale on which ‘1’ means ‘very dissatisfied’ and ‘10’ means ‘very
satisfied’, how satisfied or dissatisfied are you with your supermarket overall?
2. To what extent has your main supermarket fallen short of your expectations or
exceeded your expectations? Using a ten-point scale on which ‘1’ now means ‘falls
short of your expectations’ and ‘10’ means ‘exceeds your expectations’, to what
extent has your supermarket fallen short of or exceeded your expectations?
3. Forget your main supermarket for the moment. Now imagine an ideal supermarket.
How well do you think your supermarket compares with that ideal supermarket?
Please use a ten-point scale on which ‘1’ means ‘not very close to the ideal’ and
‘10’ means ‘very close to the ideal’.
Note: the ACSI methodology was developed in Sweden as the Swedish Consumer
Satisfaction Barometer. Now the method is used in many countries. Other countries that
have adopted ACSI methodology include Barbados, Brazil, China, Colombia, India,
Kuwait, Malaysia, Portugal, Saudi Arabia, Serbia, South Africa, South Korea, Turkey,
and Singapore and the UK.
Parasuraman, Zeithaml and Berry (1988) showed that these 22 items could
be allocated to five dimensions – tangibles, reliability, responsiveness,
assurance (knowledge and courtesy of employees and their ability to inspire
trust and confidence) and empathy (caring and individual attention to
customers). However, the five-factor structure has not been well supported;
Cronin and Taylor (1992) found only one general factor.
2. Combined item:
Day (1984) and Singh and Howell (1985) have noted that complaining is
affected by how people explain product failure, their expectation of redress and
the likely time-cost and effort involved. Research on complaining needs to take
account of all the possible reasons that people might have for this behaviour.
We can cover these reasons by using Ajzen’s (1985, 1991) theory of planned
behaviour, as discussed in Chapter 7. This deals with three types of influence:
There is evidence that customers who are retained when they complain after a
service failure may be more satisfied than they would be without the failure.
This is called the service recovery paradox (SRP). One explanation is that, if
customers appreciate the efforts of the company to satisfy their concerns, they
may recommend it more and be more inclined to repurchase. Examples of SRP
were found by TARP (1979) and Gilly and Gelb (1982), but Solnick and
Hemenway (1992) found that those who complained about health provision
were over four times more likely to defect than those who did not. More
patronage after complaint may occur because the complaint handling resolved
the customer’s dissatisfaction and exceeded expectation, but it is also possible
that those who intend to remain with the supplier complain because they want
to benefit from any changes resulting from their complaining.
Magnini et al. (2007) used role-play studies to investigate the SRP. They found
that the effect occurred when the failure was not severe, the firm had not failed
the customer before, the cause of the failure was seen as unstable and the
customer believed that the company had little control over the failure. In a
meta-analysis, De Matos et al. (2007) found a significant SRP effect for
satisfaction but not for repurchase intention or word of mouth.
It appears that dissatisfaction with waiting can affect the total service
experience: the longer the wait, the lower the evaluation of the whole service
(Feinberg, Widdows and Steidle, 1996; Katz, Larson and Larson, 1991; Taylor,
1994; Tom and Lucey, 1995). Organizations may not see delay in the same way
as their customers. Feinberg and Smith (1989) found that the customer at the
checkout thought the average delay was 5.6 minutes when the staff thought it
was 3.2; the actual time was 4.7 minutes.
It is likely that people are less bothered by delay when it is expected (Maister,
1985). Supporting this, an experiment on bank queues by Clemmer and
Schneider (1989) showed that the more unexpected the delay, the more it was
disliked. This suggests that we can identify two types of dissatisfaction with
delay: a low involvement discontent when the delay is predicted and a high
involvement disconfirmation effect when it is unanticipated. As delays get
more common, they also become more predictable and, paradoxically,
consumers may put up with them more easily. This may be why Taylor (1994)
did not find that common delays were associated with significantly more
irritation.
People also tolerate a wait better if they know how long it is. The provision of
delay information is standard for airlines, and many bus and train service
providers display boards reporting the wait before the next train or bus arrives.
In some countries, mobile phone apps can be used to find out when the next
bus will arrive. Predictability seems much appreciated by consumers; for
instance, phone queues are tolerated better when delay information is provided.
People are less irritated by delay if they are occupied in some way. One
example here is the way in which Disneyland entertains its queues with
costumed characters; another is the provision of mirrors in places where people
have to wait, for example at lifts. Taylor (1995) used two groups in an
experiment to test the effect of occupying people when they had to wait. Both
groups were delayed by 10 minutes but only one was allowed activities to
offset the delay. In this study, the evaluation of the service was reduced by
delay but the reduction in evaluation was less when people were occupied. The
principle of occupying waiting customers also applies for download delays on
the Internet, where waiting times are not counted in minutes but seconds.
Providing additional visual content during a search and download makes the
wait feel shorter and reduces negative affect towards the wait. However, for
short waits, providing this additional content actually makes the wait feel
longer (Hong, Hess and Hardin, 2013). Taylor’s work also suggested that, if the
service provider was thought to have control, customers assessed the service
more negatively. This is consistent with Weiner’s (1980, 1990) suggestion that
people become more irritated when they believe that the service provider has
control of the situation. Cheng and Tsai (2014) confirm that mentioning that a
delay is due to ‘uncontrollable circumstances’ reduces perceived waiting time
during train delays.
Studies by Dubé-Rioux, Schmitt and Leclerc (1989) show that when delay
occurs at the beginning or end of a process, in their example a restaurant meal,
it was evaluated more negatively than mid-process delays. It was better for
waiters to take the order, and then impose the delay, than to wait before taking
the order. However, it is not always clear when a service starts and finishes. For
example, delays to air travel occur when going to the airport, at check-in,
baggage check, passport control, the departure lounge, in the plane before take-
off, before landing, at baggage reclaim, and again at passport control and
customs. People may think of this sequence as a number of services or just one,
and the way they regard it may affect how they tolerate delay at different
points.
In a study by East, Lomax and Willson (1991), respondents were asked whom
they held responsible when they were delayed at the checkout of a
supermarket. Table 9.2 shows that more of the people who blamed
management disliked waiting. The investigations of delay in post offices,
building societies and banks gave very similar results. We see from the
bracketed numbers in Table 9.2 that few people are self-blaming; they are
much more likely to blame other customers than themselves. This is consistent
with the actor–observer bias (Jones and Nisbett, 1972) – that an actor tends to
see others as choosing and therefore responsible for their behaviour, while the
actor sees the same behaviour in himself as caused by the situation (e.g.
circumstances or other people).
When serious delays occur, managers may receive much of the blame. Often,
the cause is accidental or brought about by other service providers on whom
the firm had relied. This suggests that management needs to distinguish
between the cause of the delay and responsibility for its consequences. Staff
should clearly accept responsibility for remedying a problem, but it will help if,
when appropriate, they can explain that they did not create the problem. For
example, the cause of an aircraft take-off delay may be that a service company
has failed to deliver airline food on time, a mechanical fault has been revealed
by standard checks before take-off, bad weather has delayed the plane’s arrival,
or airport congestion is worse than normal. In all these cases, timely
announcements may help to deflect blame.
Queues can be organized as either multiple-line or single-line. Sometimes it is
possible to use a queuing ticket system, which allows people to conduct other
business while they wait. The relative attraction of these three systems was
tested by East et al. (1992) in their investigation of bank and building society
use (see Table 9.3). The single-line queuing system is much preferred to
queuing at each counter, despite the fact that this introduces a slight delay as
customers make their way to a vacant counter. The advantages of single-line
systems are twofold: delays are approximately equal and therefore fair and they
are more predictable since excessive delays at one counter will not affect
waiting time much when there are several counters in use. A single-line system
seems particularly useful when the start of a service is imminent, for example
in train stations where there is a danger of missing the train. Work by Pruyn
and Smidts (1993) indicates that, although people may prefer the single line,
the queuing system is of less consequence than the duration of delay and the
quality of the waiting environment.
Box 9.5 Delay management
Research on the response to delay helps us to understand how to manage this service problem
better. There are three approaches:
Consumers are contented when products meet positive expectations and are
discontented with goods and services that show expected weaknesses, but
this fulfilment of expectations normally produces little arousal and,
therefore, little ‘exit’ or ‘voice’ by the customer. Much research has focused
on those occasions where product performance surprises the consumer (the
disconfirmation model). Surprise is arousing and causes more behavioural
response and, therefore, more potential impact on profit. There is some
variation in the way researchers describe the detail of the disconfirmation
model but there is agreement that the discrepancy between expectation and
perception is the main focus; expectations and perceptions may have
additional direct effects on dis/satisfaction. In addition, researchers now
recognize an interpretative phase in which consumers’ explanations of their
experience may modify their responses to it.
Price decreases are often temporary, in the form of sales promotions. Access to scanner
data has given researchers the opportunity to develop sophisticated quantitative models to
evaluate promotion effectiveness. Combining a price cut with additional promotional
activities, such as in-store displays and advertising features, may have a synergistic effect.
Promotions usually have large short-term effects on sales, but there is doubt about their
long-term effectiveness and contribution to profit. Customization of promotions, to adapt
them to the characteristics and purchase habits of individual consumers or consumer
segments, seems to hold promise – for example, Waitrose’s ‘Pick Your Own Offers’.
However, initial results show that customization is not necessarily more profitable
compared to mass promotions, especially in ‘bricks-and-mortar’ retailing.
Section 1: Consumer Response to Price
Reference Prices
A price is rarely treated in isolation: prices become informative by relating
them to other prices, a phenomenon studied under the heading of reference
price. A price in combination with a reference price, whether accurate or
not, allows a consumer to decide if it is better to buy here and now or to
wait and buy elsewhere. When a product is cheaper than expected, it is
more likely to be purchased and vice versa.
Interestingly, most research on reference price does not ask consumers for
their reference prices directly but instead derives them from choice models
estimated on panel data (Winer, 1986). These models include as explanatory
variables not only the elements of the marketing mix, including price, but
also a reference price term. This term captures the difference between the
current price of the product and some mathematical function of past prices
(in the case of IRP) or currently observable other prices (in the case of
ERP). The fact that this difference variable helps explain choice better,
when compared to a model with just the price variable, is taken as evidence
that consumers make comparisons with reference prices. The wide
availability of individual-level scanner data has permitted an extremely
productive stream of research in this area (see the review in Mazumdar, Raj
and Sinha, 2005).
Although most research examines ERP and IRP as defined above, a number
of alternative definitions of reference price have been proposed. People may
compare with the price they usually pay, would like to pay or the price they
expect to pay, given the expected evolution of prices, or the price they
regard as fair. Winer (1988) even proposed eight different possible
definitions of price reference. Another qualification is that it is possible that
instead of holding precise reference price points, consumers actually have
price zones in mind. Kalyanaram and Little (1994) therefore estimate a
‘latitude of acceptance’ around the reference price. This is a zone in which
the consumer is indifferent to deviations between the observed price and the
reference price. As with most reference price models, they also find the
asymmetric price effect predicted by prospect theory (see Chapter 8), with
stronger negative responses to price increases than positive responses to
price decreases.
Exercise 10.1 Your price knowledge
Keep the till receipt for one of your trips to the supermarket. When you get home unpack your
products, and without looking at your receipt, write down the prices you paid. Indicate each
time whether you think you remember the price accurately or whether you are just making an
estimate. Also indicate how accurate you think you are (very accurate, rather accurate, not
accurate). Score your responses according to whether they are exactly right, within 10 per cent
or outside this range. Compare your results with others.
1. How easy or difficult was it to determine whether your knowledge is directly drawn
from memory? In other words, how good is your introspective access to the cognitive
processes you use to answer the questions?
2. Is there any evidence that frequently bought items are better remembered?
3. Do you have other hypotheses about why you remembered some prices better than other
ones?
4. How can these hypotheses be tested in a study?
5. Are students more or less likely to remember prices compared to other consumers? Why
is that?
Price Memory
If consumers use IRP to assess the attractiveness of an offer, it is interesting
to verify how accurate their knowledge of prices is. Dickson and Sawyer
(1990) found that less than half of US shoppers could give the correct price
for the item that they had just put into their shopping trolley. They mention
in their article that marketing executives and academics who attended
presentations of this study were surprised by how imperfect shoppers’
attention to, and retention of, price information was at the point of purchase.
Nevertheless, the finding was corroborated by Le Boutillier, Le Boutillier
and Neslin (1994) for coffee, but not for soda, where 71 per cent could
recall the exact price they paid. Still, using the same interviewing
procedure, Wakefield and Inman (1993) reported the percentages of
corrected responses ranging from 52 to 78 per cent for four product
categories.
These results from in-the-aisle price knowledge surveys have received two
types of reactions from the research community. Some researchers consider
that they bring reference price findings into question, because price
knowledge is much lower than most researchers intuitively expected
(Kalyanaram and Winer, 1995). A second type of reaction concerns the
interpretation of results. The Dickson and Sawyer results are often
interpreted as indications that price memory is poor. Vanhuele and Drèze
(2002) point out that what may be measured in these in-the-aisle surveys is
short-term memory, not long-term price memory.
Inferences about product quality from price are not always easy to make
even when there is clear covariation. De Langhe et al. (2014) examine the
case where the evidence is asymmetric in strength. For some product
categories, low prices consistently lead to low quality but higher prices are
associated with varying quality. Consumers in this case tend to overestimate
the quality of high-end products. The opposite occurs when there is a strong
correlation at the high end but not the low end; consumers then
underestimate the quality of the low-end products.
Combining this review with that on reference price, we see that price can
influence acceptability through a comparison with reference prices that
highlight the economic sacrifice or through quality inferences. This gives us
the model shown in Figure 10.1. Notice that, as price rises, the acceptability
of the product is raised by the price–quality relationship but reduced by the
comparison against reference prices. Normally, we expect the reference price
effect to be stronger since otherwise sales would rise with increase in price,
which is not usually observed. In a series of experiments, Bornemann and
Homburg (2011) showed that when consumers evaluate a product for
consumption in the distant future, the price–quality relationship receives
more weight, while for consumption in the near future price is instead
interpreted as a sacrifice (for example, participants in the experiments had to
imagine the launch of an electronic book reader that would be available in
the university book store in two days or six months).
Pick with a friend a couple of flying destinations that are served by a low-cost carrier (like
Ryanair, EasyJet or Virgin Blue). Agree on a departure date and hour and check the prices of
your flights a couple of times over the next week. Do prices change? By how much and in
which direction? Why do they change? Under what conditions would you find it acceptable if
your friend found a lower price than you for a given flight? What if you both logged on at the
same time and got a different price quote?
Bolton, Warlop and Alba (2003) examine, in ten different studies, how
information about prices, profits and costs influences consumer perceptions
of price fairness. They show that consumers underestimate inflationary
trends, even when provided with explicit quantitative information, and
therefore overestimate the profits that sellers are drawing from price
increases. When comparing the price of the same product in different types
of stores (such as a department store versus a discount store), they tend to
attribute price differences to different profit motives instead of to different
cost levels. Some marketing strategies are considered unfair, even when
they are not under the store’s control. When they are given information
about the cost structure of a firm, consumers tend to focus on the cost of
goods sold and ignore other cost categories. In conclusion, unfavourable
comparisons seem to dominate: consumers apparently have a tendency to
believe that the selling price of a good (or service) is substantially higher
than its fair price.
Framing of Price and Price Reductions
Sometimes prices can be presented in different ways in order to make them
look more attractive, a practice that is referred to as ‘framing’. Likewise,
temporary price reductions can be presented in different formats, such as
‘up to 50% off’, ‘30–50% off’ or ‘buy two get one free’. Rationally
speaking, consumers should be indifferent to different frames that result in
the same cost. However, Chapter 8 showed how framing can affect people’s
judgements. The frequency of use of price framing suggests that it is an
effective pricing tool.
Promotions can take many forms but promotional campaigns are usually
short-lived (see Box 10.3). The distinction has to be made between
promotions offered by retailers and manufacturers to consumers, and trade
promotions offered by manufacturers to retailers. Examples of trade
promotions are co-op advertising funds and display allowances. The retailer
may or may not pass on cost savings to the consumer (called the ‘pass-
through’).
Box 10.3 Types of promotion
Direct price reduction – also known as ‘discounts’ or, in the USA, as ‘deals’.
Couponing – refers to the distribution of certificates that can be redeemed for a
discount when purchasing.
Rebates or cashback – price refunds that can only be obtained after the purchase
by mailing an application, for instance.
Display – refers to a special in-store display that attracts attention.
Feature advertising – refers to stand- alone circulars, also known as flyers, that
consumers receive in their postbox. This is a form of cooperative advertising in
which manufacturers pay retailers to feature their products.
Games and contests.
Multibuy – for example, three for the price of two.
Extra quantity – for example, 10 per cent extra length on a chocolate bar.
Bonus offers – buy product X and get product Y free.
Much of our evidence on sales promotions comes from the USA, where
marketing practices are rather different from those applying in Europe. In
the USA, we find that:
Analyse the moves of the two players. Were there alternatives? Under what conditions is there
an interest in this type of escalation and for whom? What would you do next if you were
Sainsbury?
Sources of Extra Sales
Observing a promotional sales spike or bump does not necessarily mean the
promotion was effective. Whether a sales promotion is beneficial, from a
managerial perspective, depends on whether the additional sales can be
attributed to brand switching (usually good news for the manufacturer, but
the retailer’s evaluation depends on the relative margins of the competing
brands), category expansion effects (even better news, both for
manufacturer and retailer) or purchase acceleration and stockpiling (usually
mixed news because this can be considered as ‘borrowing’ sales from the
future). Researchers therefore have built sophisticated econometric models
to decompose the promotional bump into these three sources of sales.
Initial results were conflicting, with some researchers finding that most
promotional sales volume comes from brand switchers (e.g. Gupta, 1988;
Totten and Block, 1987) and others observing that category expansion is a
more important source of additional sales (e.g. Chintagunta, 1993). One
possible explanation of the contrasting findings is product category
differences. When comparing category expansion, brand switching and
purchase acceleration, Pauwels, Hanssens and Siddarth (2002) found a
breakdown of 66/11/23 for a storable product (canned soup) and 58/39/3 for
a perishable product (yoghurt). Van Heerde, Leeflang and Wittink (2004)
found that each source contributes to about one-third of the sales bump on
average; they used four products, two from an American and two from a
Dutch data set.
Some consumers may buy and consume a discounted brand more with no
effect on later consumption.
Some buyers may switch brands or maintain a raised consumption after
trying a brand on promotion.
Some regular consumers may accelerate purchase and stockpile a brand
on a deal; as a result, they may buy less later. This requires more planning
than is usually found among consumers of frequently purchased goods.
The availability of scanner data has made research on the carryover effect more
feasible and the overall picture shows little carryover effect. The most
comprehensive study in this area is by Ehrenberg, Hammond and Goodhardt
(1994a), using panel data from Britain, Germany, America and Japan on 25
established grocery products. The researchers identified 175 sales peaks of 25
per cent or more for different brands in these product fields and compared sales
levels before and after these promotional episodes. The procedure excluded
cases where the sales pattern was irregular either before or after the peak.
The overall outcome of this study was a sales increase of 1 per cent which is
effectively no effect. A check was made by measuring the repeat buying rates
for the 8-week period after the peak; the average was 43 per cent – almost the
same as the 44 per cent inferred from NBD theory (see Chapter 4) which
showed that buying was stationary in the post-promotion period. Differences
between countries were small and there was no evidence that categories
showed a consistent movement when data were available on the same category
from more than one country.
There are four bases for concern about promotional activity. The first comes
from reference price research. Promotional prices may become integrated in
the reference price and consumers therefore start perceiving the normal,
non-promoted price as high (Kalwani and Yim, 1990). In an interesting
twist to this effect, Palmeira and Srivastava (2013) show that when an
additional product (e.g. a ring) is offered as a promotion along with a
purchase (e.g. a necklace), it is better to give it for free than to charge a low
promoted price. This practice makes it less likely that the value of the free
item is considered and it is therefore not devalued in the eye of the
customer. A second basis for concern about promotional activity comes
from attribution theory, suggesting that consumers make causal attributions
of promotional events; they wonder why the brand is promoted.
Lichtenstein and Bearden (1989), for instance, concluded that consumers’
reactions are more positive when they think that a promotion aims to attract
customers, as opposed to when they think the promotion’s objective is to
get rid of unwanted goods. Third, customers may see the lower price as
evidence of poorer quality. Finally, frequent promotions may condition
consumers to only buy on deal. Bolton (1989) and Raju (1992), for
instance, observed that sales spikes are smaller when promotions are more
frequent.
A1 = S/Tλ
Wee and Pearce (1985) found that Huff’s model was well supported and
that the exponent, λ, was approximately 2, as Reilly hypothesized. Huff’s
approach includes all the possible shopping centres, although in practice a
consumer might rule many of these out. Wee and Pearce modified Huff’s
model and used only the shopping centres that the shopper considered. With
this adjustment predictions were better, but even the improved model gave
an R2 of only 0.25, showing that much of location preference remained
unexplained. This is hardly surprising since a gravity model cannot take
account of the detail of a particular shopping environment or of the exact
way in which information is processed. For example, Foxall and Hackett
(1992) found that stores that were located at path junctions were better
remembered. One use of gravity models is to calculate the loss of trade that
would occur in existing stores if a new store were opened in a particular
location.
Because shoppers are attracted to retail centres, retail growth also happens
at these centres. Central place theory (Christaller, 1933; Losch, 1939) uses
the importance of a centre and the economic distance as basic concepts to
explain how centres develop and how retail units tend to cluster together,
with each taking advantage of the custom generated by the others.
Businesses in the same field can benefit from proximity since together they
increase the total custom. We can find examples of this effect in most cities;
one example is the concentration of restaurants in particular locations (see
Box 11.1).
Box 11.1 Retail clusters
Some quite small locations can become specialists in a particular field. In the ancient
Shropshire town of Ludlow, a number of restaurants gained entry to the Michelin Guide
and more high quality restaurants then joined them. People can take a long weekend in
Ludlow and eat excellent cuisine. As a result, Ludlow may draw gourmets from great
distances. A similar effect is found in Ireland, at Kinsale, which is a hub for award-
winning restaurants.
Store Preferences
Gravity models and central place theory provide explanations of retail
attractiveness at an aggregate level. At an individual level, we can ask about
the shoppers’ preferences for store types and assemble the reasons given for
using stores. We can also investigate when the stores are used, and how
frequently. Complete Exercise 11.1 on your personal use of supermarkets.
Exercise 11.1 Supermarket use
Which supermarket do you use most? What is the main reason for this? Do you have a regular
day and time of day for doing your shopping? Many people do have regular times – why do
you think this is so? Would you say that you were loyal to your main supermarket? What does
this mean?
Sources: Consumer Research Unit, Kingston University, UK; Debra Perkins, Florida Memorial
University, USA; Phil Gendall, Otago University, New Zealand
We see that, in the economic conditions of 2015, getting good value is
important for the main shopping trip since ‘value for money’, together with
‘low prices’ and ‘in-store promotion’, account for 87 choices out of 200.
Convenient location gets only 24 out of 200 for the main store, while range and
quality criteria combined get 51 out of 200. We should be wary about a direct
comparison between Table 11.1 and Figure 11.1 because of the different
methods used for gathering data, but if we compare top-line findings it appears
that in 2015, compared with earlier data, low prices were considerably more
important, location much the same and quality/range somewhat less. In the UK,
a rise in the deep-discounting stores, Aldi and Lidl, has been one consequence
of this focus on price. In the UK, the big four – Tesco, Asda, Sainsbury’s and
Morrisons – accounted for 75 per cent of all grocery sales in 2010, according to
the Kantar Worldpanel reported in The Guardian (2011). By August 2015, the
share of the big four had fallen to 72 per cent, while the deep discounters had
gained substantially and accounted for 11.5 percent. Over this period, margins
were squeezed as supermarkets fought to retain share. Nielsen also reported on
convenience or ‘top-up’ stores; compared with the main shopping store choice,
location was much more important, and value for money, range and quality less
so.
Figure 11.1 Which factors are most important when choosing where to do your
shopping? (Two reasons selected, data supplied by Nielsen, 2015)
Shopping Trip Patterns
The previous section outlined the reasons shoppers give for their choice of
store. However, it is important to understand not just why and where people
shop but also how often and when. While consumers go shopping for a great
variety of goods, researchers have mostly studied grocery shopping (partly
because of the wealth of detailed data available from consumer panels).
Households tend to have a routine of supermarket shopping that often includes
one weekly main trip and one or more top-up trips. In the USA, McKay (1973),
Frisbie (1980) and Kahn and Schmittlein (1989) found this pattern. In Britain,
Dunn, Reader and Wrigley (1983) also found evidence of weekly trips
supplemented by secondary trips. In recent times, the growth of convenience
stores and small-store formats among the supermarket groups has led to more
secondary trips.
The timing of shopping trips has many managerial implications, ranging from
staffing and stock management to store layout, parking requirements and the
best time to conduct in-store promotions. The store may be little used over
much of the day while, at other times, congestion and delay may reduce the
quality of service delivered. Off-peak periods are useful for staff relaxation,
cleaning, restocking, training and maintenance, as Sasser (1976) notes, but
smoothing demand remains a desirable managerial objective.
Store use varies over the year and can be affected by bad weather. It rises
before holiday periods, including the weekend, and shopping tends to be
heavier later in the week. Figure 11.2 shows the distribution of shoppers over
the week that applied in the UK in 1994 for full-time workers and others.
Figure 11.3 shows the distribution of those shoppers over the day. The figures
show that those who are employed full-time tend to shop later in the week and
later in the day. We can infer from these two distributions that those shopping
late on a Friday or on Saturday are very likely to be employed full-time. This
separation of the employment segments could be useful to store owners; if
these groups prefer different goods, both displays and in-store promotions
could be switched to take account of those preferences. Recent evidence on
daily shopping suggests that Saturday and Sunday supermarket shopping has
become somewhat heavier but that the basic pattern of shopping over the week
is unchanged (sales data are shown for 2015 in Table 11.2, last column).
Figure 11.2 Percentage of shoppers on each day by employment status (East et
al., 1994b)
This evidence shows that many shopping trips are related to factors over which
shoppers have little or no control. They cannot choose when they are paid or
when they have to collect their children from school. Because their shopping
times are often linked to such activities, they are fairly inflexible; shoppers
could shop at other times, and they reported this in the survey, but they have
good reasons for their practices and stores would have to offer substantial
inducements at off-peak times to change their customers’ shopping trip
behaviour. It is also clear that the reasons shoppers have for their habits are
relatively unchanging so that any inducements that a store might offer would
have to be sustained. Overall, these findings suggest limited scope for
redistributing demand in supermarkets.
Exercise 11.2 Analysis of store data
On the website associated with this book (www.sagepub.co.uk/east) you will find uk98, which
is the data in an SPSS format from a survey conducted in the UK. Findings from this survey
were used for this chapter. The questionnaire for the survey is supplied as su6. Use SPSS to
compare stores (question 3) in respect of comparative checkout delay, how much the store is
recommended and the relative share of requirements (questions 13, 16 and 21). Use Compare
means, means, to get the means per store.
For all stores, what factors are associated with the rating of the store? To do this, select
potential predictors and run an ordinal regression to predict the answers to question 17. Is
rating related to recommendation and share of requirement? Use a Spearman correlation to test
for this.
How strong are these findings? What alternative explanations are there for the associations you
find?
Section 2: Customer Typologies
Perhaps the most sophisticated classification of shoppers is made by the
Dunnhumby agency in their analysis of Tesco’s loyalty data. Dunnhumby
uses a selection of frequently bought products to classify customers on 30
criteria. For example, a large size of oven-ready chips will indicate
positively for budget consciousness and negatively for health consciousness
or gourmet propensity. Those who purchase organic produce indicate
another type of concern and those who buy Tesco’s own label
disproportionately may be classified as Tesco loyalists. These behaviour-
based classifications are used to ensure that coupons go to those who will
appreciate them, and new products are promoted to customers who are
likely to buy them. In an unpublished 2014 Dunnhumby survey by Julian
Highley, health-committed customers emerge as an attractive target. The
proportion of these people is increasing and they welcome supermarket
efforts to provide healthy food. They tend to be loyal and up-market and are
more responsive to strong promotions than the less health committed. As a
result, serving these customers can yield more profit. In other work,
Dunnhumby has derived the price sensitivity and profitability of customers
from their past purchases. This customer segmentation can be used to direct
promotions to those who will yield more profit and it could even be used to
change displays and promotions over the day as the proportions of different
customers change.
Nielsen (2011a) found that 30 per cent agreed strongly and 37 per cent slightly that you
could save money on groceries by buying on the Internet. However, there are drawbacks
and the Nielsen study showed that the inability to select items for oneself when buying
was the most common problem reported about Internet grocery purchase. Internet grocery
shopping is well established, particularly in the UK, but a MINTEL (2014) report found
that, although about 20 per cent of shoppers did all or most of their grocery shopping
online, this constituted only about 5 per cent of total grocery sales by value. Thus, it
seems that online grocery purchase attracts lighter buyers.
Grocery buying has been studied to see whether brand loyalty is stronger when purchase
is made on the Internet. Degeratu, Rangaswamy and Wu (2001) found that brand names
play a stronger role in choice and that fewer brand switches are made in the online
environment. Another study by Danaher, Wilson and Davis (2003) found this effect for
high market share products but the reverse for small share brands. But these studies
compare those who shop online with those who shop offline and any differences may be
due to the different abilities and interests of the two groups rather than to the channel
used. Arce and Cebollada (2006) compared the online and offline grocery purchasing of
the same people and still found less brand switching online. One explanation for this is
that, on the Web, buyers may work from a list of past purchases and take less advantage
of the discount opportunities available. As a result, they stick to the same brands and have
high loyalty. This effect may be weaker for small share brands that may be bought less
often, which would explain the finding of Danaher et al. (2003).
Heavy Shoppers
According to the ‘heavy half’ principle (Chapter 4), the heaviest 50 per cent
of buyers will make about 80 per cent of all purchases. Retailers want to
identify these heavy buyers and aim to target promotions at these shoppers
in order to recruit and retain them.
It might be thought that those who spend more would use more shops and
therefore have lower first-store loyalty, but Dunn and Wrigley (1984) and
Mason (1991) found that first-store loyalty did not change as total
expenditure in supermarkets increased. Knox and Denison (2000) found a
small positive association (r = 0.24) between store loyalty and total
spending for supermarkets but a negative relationship for other types of
retail outlet. If bigger spenders in supermarkets are more loyal, it follows
that they are doubly attractive to the retailer who gets their main custom.
Not only do they spend more but also a larger proportion of this spending
goes to their favourite store. Stores with loyalty data may be able to identify
heavy buyers directly from their spending and direct promotions to them.
(Note that loyalty data only show purchases at the single store chain but
spending in other stores may be inferred from the goods bought in the
single chain.)
Dittmar, Beattie and Friese (1995) suggested that the way in which products
are bought reflects the way in which people see themselves. These
researchers suggested that the sexes might differ in this respect. They found
that men tend to buy instrumental and leisure items impulsively, reflecting
their independence and activity, while women tend to buy symbolic and
self-expressive goods concerned with appearance and the emotional aspects
of self. Dittmar (2005) stresses that materialistic values are one key to
compulsive shopping. Those with low self-esteem can only get mood repair
from shopping if possessions have importance to them (see Figure 11.4).
Resource Constraint
The first theory of store loyalty was suggested by Charlton (1973), who
drew on earlier work by Enis and Paul (1970). In this theory, store loyalty is
the outcome of limited resources: those who lack money, time and
transport, or whose environment lacks choice (Tate, 1961), are forced to use
one store much of the time and are therefore obliged to be loyal. Carman
(1970) offered a variation of this model, suggesting that some people had
little interest in shopping and therefore did not use the choice that they had.
Such people had commitments outside the home, full-time work, little home
entertaining and a lack of interest in deals, advertising and shopping. As a
result, they were loyal to both brands and stores because they did not seek
alternatives. However, East et al. (1995) found that shoppers with different
loyalty levels gave similar ratings for the pleasantness of supermarket
shopping, which does not support Carman’s lifestyle theory.
Carman (1970), and Enis and Paul (1970), found that those with low
incomes were more loyal, so resource constraint probably did affect loyalty
at the time when the research was conducted but it is unlikely that this still
applies. Shoppers now have more choice because they have wider access to
stores through car ownership or by shopping online and they can stock
perishable groceries for long periods because of the almost universal
availability of home refrigerators and freezers.
Discretionary Loyalty
Dunn and Wrigley (1984) argued that Charlton’s negative concept of store
loyalty needed review. They suggested that some store loyalty arose from a
pattern of one-stop shopping, often in large supermarkets. We call this
discretionary store loyalty. Discretionary loyalty could be an adaptation to
being time poor and money rich. People can spend less if they use several
stores and cherry pick the bargains (leading to low loyalty) but this takes
time and effort. Those with less time and more money may choose to buy
most of what they need from one outlet because this is easier; as a result,
they will show high loyalty. Mason (1991) found that store loyalty was
higher when the housewife worked and was under 45 years of age (when
family commitments are likely to take a lot of time). Flavián, Martínez and
Polo (2001) found general support for discretionary loyalty in Spain.
However, East et al. (2000) found that neither free time nor income was
significantly related to SCR in a regression analysis covering many factors,
and this leaves some doubt about the basis of discretionary loyalty.
Incentives are very expensive. They take about 1 per cent of turnover; thus, if
the store group makes 5 per cent on turnover, the incentives reduce the margin
by 20 per cent and sales must be increased to compensate for this. Furthermore,
competitors can run loyalty schemes which may cancel out any gains. In an
effort to reduce the effect of competitor response, some schemes, such as Air
Miles and Fly Buys, only allow one retailer in each sector. If Shell gives Air
Miles, BP, Esso and other fuel suppliers are excluded. However, competitors
can still run alternative schemes.
It is probably the information rather than the direct incentive that is the most
important aspect of loyalty schemes but researchers remain interested in the
incentive effect of loyalty cards; this is difficult to measure because other
factors may be involved. For example, Tesco took share from Sainsbury when
the loyalty scheme was introduced in 1995 but much of this change might have
happened in any case because Tesco built more stores, many of which were in
Sainsbury territory (East and Hogg, 1997). Although Tesco gained market
share, the firm’s customers did not show a disproportionate increase in loyalty
measured in aggregate as share-of-category requirement (SCR). The data in
Table 11.5 from Taylor Nelson Sofres show that in 1996, a year after the
introduction of the loyalty scheme, Tesco had a slightly greater market share
than Sainsbury in 1994, but the same SCR. Thus, Tesco’s loyalty scheme
seems to have built a customer base by gaining new customers rather than by
getting its existing customers to buy more. This seems to be the normal pattern
for share gains that was noted in Chapter 4.
Store Features
The store environment includes the amount of space employed, and the
layout, fittings, colours, aromas, sound and density of customers present.
There are some standard display features used by stores that affect the
impression given by the store. For example, discount stores may sell out of
cases to emphasize low prices, shopping centres create central areas with
entertaining features, and fashion shops use music that suits the age and
taste of their clientele. These features help to define the store offering and to
differentiate it from that of other stores (and from sellers on the Internet). In
this way, store design and the display of goods have parallels with
advertising and packaging.
Exercise 11.3 Assessing atmospheric features
Describe a shop which you find attractive and stimulating. What is the basis for this? How are
space, colour, sound and odour used? Do these environmental features affect your spending in
the store?
Another study by Yalch and Spangenberg (2000) showed that music could
raise sales in a department store. The music had to be appropriate for each
department; for example, music in departments with younger customers had
to be played at high volume. Other work has looked at the way different
stimuli work together. For example, Mattila and Wirtz (2001) showed that,
when music and scent were similar in terms of arousing properties
(congruent), the evaluation of the environment increased. In another
example, a ‘Christmas’ scent raised the evaluation of the store environment
only when accompanied by Christmas music (Spangenberg, Grohmann and
Sprott, 2005). Bosmans (2007) also found that scents that were congruent
with the product had a powerful influence on evaluations. Morrison et al.
(2011) show that the arousal induced by music and aroma results in
increased pleasure levels, which in turn positively influences shopper
behaviours, including time and money spend, approach behaviour, and
satisfaction with the shopping experience. Madzharov, Block and Morrin
(2015) found that ambient scents affect consumers’ spatial perceptions and
feelings of power, along with product preference and enhanced purchasing
behaviour. These effects probably work by association between the stimulus
and the action.
Another explanation for atmospheric effects is that they affect mood which
in turn affects purchasing. Donovan and Rossiter (1982) used a classification
of mood states described by Mehrabian and Russell (1974). They found that
a store’s atmosphere produced mood effects in consumers which could affect
the time and money spent in the store. Figure 11.5 shows this stimulus →
organism → response (SOR) model with the intervening moods of pleasure
and arousal. Donovan and Rossiter expected high arousal to act with
pleasure to raise spending/time in store and with displeasure to reduce
spending/time in store. The first was supported but there were too few
unpleasant environments to test the second effect.
Smith and Sherman (1992) showed that store image was associated with
mood, which then predicted the amount of time and money spent in the
store. Mehrabian and Russell (1974) suggested that more novel and complex
environments would raise interest, and Gröppel (1993) observed that
supermarkets with high novelty and complexity levels gave more pleasure
and that customers spent more time and bought more in such stores.
Swinyard (1993) argued that only the more elaborate processing of the
highly involved consumer would be affected by mood and that this mood
change would affect shopping intentions. This was supported in a scenario-
based experiment, i.e. only the highly involved shoppers claimed that they
would modify their shopping intentions. Sharma and Stafford (2000) showed
that store design affects the persuasiveness of sales personnel, an effect that
may be mediated by mood. Eroglu, Machleit and Davis (2003) even found
support for mood effects in an online environment.
Donovan et al. (1994) reviewed research in this area. They noted weaknesses
in their earlier article and those of others. In particular, they suggested that it
was necessary to distinguish moods induced by the environment from
emotions associated with purchase. Donovan et al. conducted a further study
which avoided these problems. They found that pleasure did contribute to
time in the store and extra spending, and that arousal did reduce spending in
environments rated as unpleasant, but arousal did not increase spending
when the environment was pleasant. The increase in time without increase in
spending seems to indicate more browsing or window shopping. In some
retail sectors, window shoppers are as common as active shoppers (Nielsen,
2005) and we need to know how valuable window shoppers are: do they buy
later or encourage others to buy through word of mouth?
Crowding
A common problem in stores, banks, post offices, restaurants and other retail
services is the level of congestion or crowding. People have a complex
response to crowding and, in different contexts, may find it attractive or
aversive. Hui and Bateson (1991) found that an important factor in
determining whether crowding was liked or disliked is the control that
customers feel that they have in the situation. In Hui and Bateson’s study,
high densities of people were associated with increased control in a bar and
reduced control in a bank. People go to banks for instrumental reasons and
bars for recreation, and it seems likely that these different uses affect the
way crowding is perceived, since crowding is more likely to obstruct activity
in banks than in bars. In shops, therefore, people are likely to dislike
densities that impede action, and store designs should aim to reduce such
congestion. However, when shoppers have little to buy and their activity is
more recreational, they may enjoy store congestion. It is also likely that
people are put off when a store appears empty. Wicker (1984) has suggested
that every setting has an optimal number of occupants. For example, some
people feel reluctant to go into a near-empty restaurant. Here, people may
attribute the emptiness of the restaurant to a lack of quality.
Compulsive shoppers buy things that they do not need and may not use.
This pattern of behaviour has raised concern because of the financial
devastation that uncontrolled spending can produce. These people tend to
have low self-esteem, which is temporarily alleviated by shopping.
In this chapter, we show how consumers use WOM to choose brands in different
categories. We describe problems in researching this field, report findings on the relative
frequency of positive and negative WOM (PWOM, NWOM) and examine the
circumstances that stimulate people to give WOM. We provide evidence on the impact of
PWOM and NWOM and we explain how different factors contribute to that impact. We
describe how WOM production is related to market share, and review applications of
WOM research.
Section 1: The Nature of Word of Mouth
In Chapter 5, we described the way in which innovations are adopted by
consumers. At the centre of the adoption process is the communication of
information. A person who adopts a new idea or product must find out
about it, either through mass media (advertising, promotions, television,
radio), through personal discovery (e.g. seeing it in a shop) or from other
people (salespersons, other consumers). This chapter is concerned with the
last way of finding out, through the influence of others. Sometimes, this
occurs as observational learning when people see what others do and copy
them, but often they receive advice as word of mouth (WOM). In addition
to guiding the adoption of new products, WOM is involved in the switching
from one brand to another in established markets. Normally, WOM is
focused on conversations between consumers, where, unlike advertising,
the person giving advice usually lacks any commercial interest. This feature
of WOM is one reason why it is influential but another aspect of person-to-
person exchanges is that these are often interactive so that a receiver can
follow up and ask further questions. This helps the receiver to get the
information needed, which makes the advice more influential. WOM advice
may be received via face-to-face exchanges, telephone, text messages, mail,
email, blogs, message boards and social networking websites. WOM also
sometimes occurs as rumour (see Box 12.1).
Box 12.1 Rumour
Rumours are unverified topical beliefs that circulate between people. Early thinking about
rumour was presented by Knapp (1944) and by Allport and Postman (1947). Rumours
may be based on hope, fear or hatred and may involve claims about conspiracies or
dangers. The Internet now provides a means for the rapid circulation of rumours and
many companies have suffered from this hazard. The financial marketplace is particularly
susceptible to rumour (Kimmel, 2004). Rosnow (2001) argues that uncertainty, credibility
and personal relevance are the primary drivers of rumours, which will spread faster in
contexts of high anxiety (e.g. when investments are at risk). Kimmel and Audrain-
Pontevia (2007) found that roughly three-fifths of rumours were negative, one-fifth
positive and one-fifth neutral. They confirmed that uncertainty, credibility and importance
of the topic were the key factors in rumour transmission. For a review of research on
rumours and their influence, see Kimmel (2010).
Many of the classic studies on WOM were concerned with innovations and
new categories rather than established brands – for example, Whyte (1954)
on air conditioners, Coleman, Katz and Menzel (1957) on the prescribing of
new drugs by physicians, and Katz (1961) on new farming practices. These
really new products may produce a large amount of comment compared
with well-established products that consumers often know well. However,
sometimes brands will have new features not offered by others and then
choice may be more like the adoption of a new product. For example, a car
manufacturer may offer ‘passive keyless entry’, allowing the car to be
started while the transponder key remains in the driver’s pocket. As the
category matures and brands become more familiar, the reason for choice
may not be an innovation but some simple advantage that can be drawn to a
consumer’s attention. For example, one person might advise another about
the relative cost of mobile phone brands, or their performance in weak-
signal areas. This is useful to a prospective buyer but it does not deal with
an innovative feature of the product. In this chapter, we focus less on the
adoption of new categories and more on brands in mature categories.
Researching Word of Mouth
WOM is difficult to measure. Ideally, we would observe WOM as it occurs
and then monitor its consequences. In practice, WOM occurs too rarely for
it to be observed systematically and usually any consequences occur much
later, so that direct observation of the outcomes of WOM may be
impossible. As a result, other methods have to be used, which are reviewed
below.
Internet research usually deals with aggregate effects. We can count the
posts and obtain data on box office receipts. We may be able to predict
returns from such data but we do not know the specific influences on
individuals and how those individuals reacted, instead we have only the
collective effects. We want to understand as well as predict, and for this we
need individual-level data so that we can connect individual responses to
individual experience. Such individual-level data are obtained in
experiments and surveys.
Box 12.2 Online advice
The predictive value of online comment depends, in part, on how much this medium is
used, compared to other media. If it is only a small part of total advice on brands, it may
not be a reliable guide to sales. Surveys show that online comment remains a modest part
of the total. In 2006, Keller and Fay found that WOM was:
Face-to-face 70%
Phone 19%
Email 4%
Text message 3%
Online chat or blog 1%
Other 3%
In other surveys, the shares are similar. In 2010, the Keller Fay Group reported that 7 per
cent of WOM was offline in the USA, the UK and Australia, though this rose to 15 per
cent for the teen group in US measurements. In 2011, Keller Fay reported that, in the UK,
81 per cent of WOM was face-to-face, 10 per cent via phone and 9 per cent online
(including email, texting and social networking sites). This suggests that the Internet is
not the dominant channel for advice, though some categories such as restaurants, holidays
and hotels attract much more online comment than others, and it is likely that, in these
fields, the Internet is a more reliable guide to demand. In addition, it is possible that the
design of survey questions leads to the omission of some Internet advice. Fay (2014)
reports a market research study that found a third of referral sales were based on Internet
comment.
There are, however, some differences between Web and face-to-face advice. First, most
online advice is one-way and not interactive. Second, in many contexts, such as online
reviews or Twitter, advice from one source may be received by many others, which is
uncommon for offline advice. Third, the Web may allow a degree of deception – those
reviews on Amazon may include some that are ‘arranged’; because of this, people may be
more suspicious of positive comment on the Web than they are when it occurs face-to-
face. Fourth, offline WOM is more often between close ties whereas, on the Web, a larger
amount of weak-tie contact is likely to occur (e.g. in discussion groups or anonymous
product reviews).
Experiments
A number of experiments have examined the impact of positive and
negative information (e.g. Ahluwalia, 2002; Herr, Kardes and Kim, 1991).
The main problem here is that the artificiality of the laboratory situation
restricts generalization to naturally occurring WOM. This artificiality has
several aspects:
1. The stimulus is not like real WOM. In experiments, the ‘WOM’ is
often prepared written information rather than spontaneous exchanges
between people (e.g. Herr, Kardes and Kim, 1991). Such prepared
advice cannot be asked for, which is often a feature of real WOM, and
the advice is unlikely to be well-tailored to the needs of the receiver.
2. The response measures may be inappropriate. Experimental studies of
WOM have used attitude towards a product or brand and belief items
to measure impact (e.g. Ahluwalia, 2002); marketers are generally
more interested in the impact on purchase or purchase probability.
Experiments often rush the process by taking measures of effect
shortly after exposure to the stimulus. In natural settings, people who
receive WOM may not act on it for months. In their improved
experimental design, Christiansen and Tax (2000) delayed the
measurement of effects for a week.
3. In experiments, each participant makes an equal contribution to the
outcome. In everyday life, some people say nothing while others give a
lot of WOM.
Retrospective Surveys
In retrospective surveys, respondents have to report on their experience and
these reports may be systematically distorted by recall error. For example, if
NWOM is more easily recalled than PWOM, a measure of relative
frequency will be biased in favour of NWOM (see Box 12.3). A second
concern about surveys relates to the recruitment of the sample, which is
often based on convenience. However, problems about convenience
sampling recede as more data are gathered. If we have 20 studies using
diverse population samples and different categories, and these all show the
same pattern, we can be more confident about the findings. A further
problem arises when survey evidence is interpreted; unlike experiments, it
does not provide causal relationships so that associations between variables
may be explained in a variety of ways.
Exercise 12.1 Questionnaire on word of
mouth
Fill out this questionnaire:
3. In the last six months, how many times have you received positive advice about any
mobile phone handset?
Write in number (0, 1, 2, etc. ……)
If you answered 0, then please go to Q.9
4. The last time you received positive advice, did you ask for advice or was it just given?
Just given [1]
Asked for it [2]
5. What was your relationship to the person who last gave you positive advice?
Casual acquaintance [1]
More distant family, friend or colleague [2]
Close family, close friend or colleague [3]
7. Did the last positive advice that you received affect your handset choice or intended
handset choice?
No [1]
Yes [2]
9. In the last six months, how many times have you received negative advice about any
mobile phone handset?
Write in number (0, 1, 2, etc. ………..)
If you answered 0, then please go to Q.15
10. The last time you received negative advice, did you ask for advice or was it just given?
Just given [1]
Asked for it [2]
11. What was your relationship to the person who last gave you negative advice?
Casual acquaintance [1]
More distant family, friend or colleague [2]
Close family, close friend or colleague [3]
12. About which brand was the last negative advice received?
Please write in (Samsung, iPhone, etc.) ………………
13. Did the last negative advice received affect your handset choice or intended handset
choice?
No [1]
Yes [2]
15. In the last six months, how many times have you given negative advice about any
mobile phone handset?
Write in number (0, 1, 2, etc. ……)
If you answered 0, then please go to Q.17
16. About which brand did you last give positive advice?
Please write in (Samsung, iPhone, etc.) ………………
17. In the last six months, how many times have you given positive advice about any mobile
phone handset?
Write in number (0, 1, 2, etc. ……)
18. About which brand did you last give negative advice?
Please write in (Samsung, iPhone, etc.) ………………
The purpose of this exercise is to show how aspects of WOM may be measured in a
retrospective survey. From the responses of a group of people to these questions, it is possible
to find out:
To some extent, the problems that affect measurement in this area may be
offset by using multiple methods and measures, and a wide range of
categories. A second strategy is to estimate measurement distortions so that
errors can be corrected (Box 12.3).
Box 12.3 Measuring recall bias
East et al. (2013) measured how the volume of WOM recalled is related to the time
elapsed since the WOM was given. Respondents were asked about the volume of PWOM
and NWOM that they gave in the week after using a service such as a hotel. They were
also asked how long ago the service was used. Data on six categories were collected. It
was anticipated that people would forget more instances of WOM when the time lapse
was longer. However, there was a tendency for the recalled volume of both PWOM and
NWOM to increase with the time elapsed. When the ratio of PWOM to NWOM was
measured in relation to time lapse, there was no significant trend. This finding suggests
that ratios gathered over different periods are comparable.
Section 2: The Occurrence of Word of Mouth
How Does Word of Mouth Affect Brand Choice in
Different Categories?
WOM from others provides helpful information and this is particularly true in
the case of services that cannot be tested before a choice is made. For example,
a person who has to find a new dentist has few sources of relevant information
on a dentist’s competence. Because of this, advice from other people is
probably the best way of finding a dentist that they will be happy with. The
adviser provides a kind of second-hand experience. WOM will be less
important in the case of goods that can be inspected and tested, and when
information can be gathered from advertising or online search before buying.
This means that the need for WOM will vary between categories. It is often
said that WOM reduces risk – and this is true – but risk is highest when there is
a lack of information on a product and little opportunity to gather information
by direct experience.
In early work, WOM was credited with very large effects. Dichter (1966)
claimed that advice figured in as many as 80 per cent of brand decisions. Katz
and Lazarsfeld (1955) claimed to show that WOM was seven times as effective
as newspapers and magazines, four times as effective as personal selling and
twice as effective as radio advertising in influencing consumers to buy
products. These early studies applied more to the adoption of new categories
than to brand switching, so these claims may not tell us much about brand
choice in familiar categories. However, WOM clearly has an impact on brand
choice; Keaveney (1995) found that about 50 per cent of service provider
replacements occurred primarily through WOM. A study by East et al. (2005b)
showed that sales impact depended on the category. Table 12.1 shows the
results of this work.
People may confuse the WOM from satisfied and dissatisfied customers with WOM in
general. This may be why Silverman (2001: 134) claims that studies have shown that most
WOM is negative. To establish the ratio of all PWOM to all NWOM, we need studies on the
general occurrence of PWOM and NWOM, not just those where the WOM is based on
dis/satisfaction. Mangold, Miller and Brockway (1999) established a typology of the triggers
of word of mouth about services as judged by the receiver of WOM. East et al. (2015) used
this typology in surveys to find out what most stimulates PWOM and NWOM. The results are
shown in Table 12.2, where we can see that satisfaction (PWOM) and dissatisfaction
(NWOM) are the most important factors but that a variety of other stimuli induce WOM.
These results are for services and a study has now been done on durable goods (at the time of
writing, not yet published). The findings for durables are quite different. Advertising has the
strongest effect on PWOM and little effect on NWOM. Satisfaction is an important stimulus
of PWOM but dissatisfaction had little effect on NWOM, perhaps because modern durables
are so reliable that they rarely cause dissatisfaction.
Some products generate more WOM than others. Berger and Schwartz (2011)
point out that some categories are more interesting than others – one would
expect phone apps to get more comment than soap. Also, some products are
more visible than others because of their usage or because they are frequently
present in the environment. Such products (e.g. mobile phones) may stimulate
more WOM than those that drop from sight after use, such as films. Berger and
Schwartz found that the cued and visible products received more WOM than
interesting products with limited visibility. The latter were talked about a lot
immediately after consumption but WOM then fell away. In a field experiment,
the authors found that WOM could be increased by linking a product to a
recurrent feature of the environment. The authors also suggest that advertising
could be more effective when this sort of linkage is used. A study of the decay
in the production of WOM after product experience found wide variation
between products (East et al., 2014b).
Why is there more PWOM? One explanation may be that there are not
many negative things to say about goods and services. Mostly, people are
satisfied with what they get, according to Peterson and Wilson (1992),
whose work suggested an average 10:1 ratio of satisfied to dissatisfied
(Chapter 9). A second possibility is that PWOM is seen as more useful.
Most consumer choices are about selecting one from many brands. NWOM
may eliminate an option but this does not settle the choice if more than one
option remains. By contrast, PWOM may be used by a receiver to make a
final decision. Thus, if people are trying to help others with their advice,
saying what is good may be more constructive than saying what is bad.
How Much Do People Talk about Their Current
Brand?
East, Romaniuk and Lomax (2011) investigated whether the brand that was
referred to in PWOM and NWOM was currently used, previously used or
never used (Table 12.3). Across 15 studies, they found that, on average, 71
per cent of PWOM was about the currently used brand, 22 per cent about a
previously used brand and only 7 per cent about a never-used brand. For
NWOM, 22 per cent was about the currently used brand, 55 per cent about
a previously used brand and 22 per cent about a never-used brand.
Wangenheim (2005) also found that NWOM was often about previously
owned brands, and Winchester and Romaniuk (2008) found that, when
people expressed negative beliefs about brands, these brands were often
previously owned. Table 12.3 also shows that people are more willing to
give NWOM than PWOM on brands they have not used and this suggests
that, sometimes, brands become widely discussed because of their
deficiencies. This is a serious worry for managers. Note that the previous
work showing more PWOM than NWOM was about all the brands in a
category. Individual brands could be the object of more NWOM than
PWOM.
How Does the Occurrence of WOM Relate to the
Market Share of the Brand?
Bigger brands, with more users, will get more recommendations because, as we
see above, most recommendations are about the current main brand. As a
result, the volume of recommendation will tend to relate to market share.
NWOM on previously owned brands will reflect the market share that applied
at an earlier time, and if the market has not changed much this will
approximate to the current market share. This means that NWOM volume will
also relate to market share, but less so than PWOM because it relates to an
earlier market structure. This was tested by Uncles, East and Lomax (2010a).
They analysed data from 13 surveys and found an average correlation between
market share and PWOM volume of 0.92. This was significantly greater than
the corresponding correlation for NWOM which was 0.73.
This evidence shows that if one brand gets more PWOM than another, it is not
necessarily performing better. To do well, a brand must get more PWOM and
less NWOM than would be expected on the basis of the market-share norm.
Sometimes, new brands may get much more PWOM than their market share
warrants; for example, some unpublished evidence at Kingston University
showed that, when smart phones first arrived, iPhone was well above the norm
for PWOM and its subsequent success has vindicated this early interest.
Factors Associated with Word-of-Mouth
Production
In studies at Kingston University, we have found that the volume of
recommendation is often related to:
The relative attitude to the brand. Relative attitude is the rating of the
brand compared with other available brands and is similar to relative
satisfaction.
Whether a person was recruited to the brand by recommendation or
not. In the main, those who are recruited by recommendation tend to
give more recommendations themselves. This was found by
Wangenheim and Bayón (2004) when they investigated German utility
customers and Uncles et al. (2013). This effect is likely to depend on
the size of a person’s circle of friends. Those who interact more with
others have more opportunity both to receive and to give advice.
Related to this, Godes and Mayzlin (2004a) incentivized PWOM and
found that the extra sales that resulted were related to the size of a
person’s social circle.
Whether the communicator recommends other categories. People who
give advice across a wide range of products are called mavens (Feick
and Price, 1987).
Age. The pattern here is that people tend to give and receive less
WOM as they age, particularly when they are over 65 (East et al.,
2014a). This may depend on opportunity, since there is likely to be a
loss of social contact as people age, stop work and their children leave
home. (Factors associated with age are covered in more detail in
Chapter 6.)
Whether a brand owner has heard others recommend their brand. (We
discuss this in Section 4.)
This work on negativity bias has used measures of impact based on change
in attitude or thinking. However, in marketing, impact may be better
measured as a change in purchase or purchase propensity. People might
receive NWOM and change their attitude but not change their intention to
purchase. This could happen if, prior to the NWOM, they had zero
probability of purchase. East, Hammond and Lomax (2008) used the shift in
purchase probability to measure the impact of WOM; they showed that
positive advice has more effect if the receiver has a low likelihood of
purchase before the PWOM is received because this leaves more room for
change. Conversely, NWOM has more effect when the initial probability of
purchase is high. This applies the gap notion to intention rather than
attitude, as in the negativity bias research.
In Table 12.4, we show East et al.’s average results from 19 studies. In this
work, respondents were asked what their probability of purchase was before
and after hearing WOM, using the Juster (1966) scale (see Chapter 7). The
mean probability of purchase before WOM was 0.43 for those who received
PWOM and 0.40 for those receiving NWOM, so that there was somewhat
more ‘room for change’ in the purchasing probability for the receivers of
PWOM (0.57) than NWOM (–0.4). The impact of PWOM was
correspondingly greater in magnitude than that of NWOM (0.20 versus –
0.11). A study by Sweeney, Soutar and Mazzarol (2014) has also found that
PWOM has more effect on purchase intention than NWOM. These findings
suggest that PWOM usually has more impact than NWOM when impact is
measured as a change in intention. However, as we stated at the beginning
of this chapter, it is difficult to study WOM effects, and estimates of past
probabilities of purchase could easily be biased by selective recall. For this
reason, we should be cautious about these research findings. In a recent
article, East et al. (2016) review how impact should be measured.
What Variables Affect the Impact of WOM?
East et al. (2008) measured how six variables affected WOM impact, where
impact was measured as change in the intention to buy. These were: the
prior probability of purchase; how strongly expressed the WOM was;
whether the WOM was about the main brand; the closeness of the
communicator and receiver (that is, whether a close friend/relative or not);
whether the WOM was sought or not; and how much advice the respondent
reported giving on the category that was studied. These factors were used in
a regression analysis to predict impact. Table 12.5 shows the output from
the analysis. We see that the prior probability of choice is the most
significant factor, supporting the gap argument in the previous section. For
PWOM, the greater the prior probability, the less the change (and the
reverse for NWOM). The strength of WOM expression, a variable noted as
important by Mazzarol et al. (2007), is a strong determinant of impact.
Also, PWOM about the currently used main brand has more effect than
PWOM on other brands, while NWOM on the main brand has less impact
than NWOM on other brands. The closeness of the communicator and
whether the advice was sought are only significant for PWOM, and the
amount of WOM given by the respondent is only significant for NWOM.
Previous work has shown that close ties have more effect than distant ties
(Brown and Reingen, 1987) and that sought advice is more influential than
advice that is unsought (Bansal and Voyer, 2000; East et al., 2005a). The
weak associations shown in Table 12.5 may relate to the method of analysis.
When multiple regression is used, other variables that are associated with
both the predictor and outcome variables can assume part of the
explanation.
Such ideas may also help us understand how advertising can affect WOM. It is
known that the level of WOM on a product rises when it is advertised (Bayus,
1985; Graham and Havlena, 2007). According to Keller and Fay (2009), 20 per
cent of WOM discussions refer to paid advertising content. The ad may
increase the salience of the brand so that previously used PWOM scripts are
more likely to be expressed, or the ad may supply a script that a receiver can
repeat – this seems more likely for print and radio ads where information is
already in a verbal form that can be passed on. This suggests that ads should be
tested to see whether they do promote WOM.
Section 5: Applications of Word-of-Mouth
Research
Net Promoter Score
The Net Promoter Score (NPS) is intended to measure the number of people
who are positive about a brand/company (promoters) and the number who
are negative (detractors) (Reichheld, 2003). The score is computed by
subtracting the number of detractors from the number of promoters, as
shown in Figure 12.4. The NPS asks about the intention to recommend, but
Romaniuk, Nguyen and East (2011) found that intentions reflect the WOM
that responders have given in the recent past; apparently, when asked what
they will do, people will check on what they have done. Past behaviour is
likely to be a guide to future behaviour, and in Chapter 2 this was supported
with respect to purchase. Thus, it might be better to measure past WOM
directly rather than use a question about what responders will do.
To some extent, the best strategy depends on cost. If costs are low (as when
the Internet is used), it makes sense to target all those on a customer
database. However, the messages need to differ between current users
(responsible for most of the PWOM) and ex-users (responsible for most of
the NWOM). If costs are high, it may pay to focus on the influentials; this is
what happens when BzzAgents are given products to talk about. However,
whether all users or just influentials are targeted, there is a need for research
to find out what sort of information people pass on and what impact
different forms of information have on receivers.
Promoting Positive and Stopping Negative
Comments
A popular method of promoting PWOM from current customers is the
referral programme. This is a managed intervention designed to add to
naturally occurring PWOM. Often, there is a reward for the person making
a successful referral and sometimes an incentive for the person referred.
There is evidence that the customers acquired through such campaigns are
more valuable than those acquired by other means (Schmitt, Skiera and Van
den Bulte, 2011). Referral programmes use customer databases to
communicate with those who are likely to support a brand, but another use
of such databases is to direct information to groups who could be criticizing
the product. In Table 12.3, we showed that about one-fifth of negative
advice comes from current customers and more than half from ex-
customers and both are likely to be accessible via the database. When there
is dissatisfaction with the brand, it should be possible to design messages to
reduce it. By doing so, both NWOM and defection may be reduced.
Information, Not Hearsay
When there are widespread misunderstandings about a topic, there is a
danger that strategies will be misjudged. Many beliefs about WOM appear
to have been mistaken. It is not true that NWOM is more common than
PWOM, according to the evidence that has now accumulated, and it does
not appear that there is much evidence that NWOM has more impact. The
role of satisfaction or dissatisfaction in the genesis of WOM has probably
been over-emphasized. Nor is it generally true that long-term customers
usually recommend more than short-term customers. More research
findings are needed to displace such hearsay and to inform evidence-based
marketing strategies.
Summary
PWOM and NWOM are powerful influences on consumer choice but they
are difficult to study. Internet research deals with only a moderate fraction
of those giving advice, experimental research lacks relevance to natural
settings, and survey research is prone to bias. In the absence of good
evidence, some misunderstanding has occurred. It now appears that
dis/satisfaction, though often important, may not be needed for WOM.
Therefore, comparisons between satisfied and dissatisfied customers are
inappropriate for determining the occurrence and impact of PWOM and
NWOM.
Research evidence shows that PWOM is more common than NWOM and
that, in general, PWOM has somewhat more impact on the probability of
purchase than NWOM. Impact is related to the probability of purchase
before the WOM is received, the strength of expression of WOM, and
whether the WOM is about the current main brand or not. Those people
who are very likely to buy a brand give less weight to NWOM on this
brand, and those who are very unlikely to purchase a brand give less weight
to PWOM on it.
There is uncertainty about the process whereby influence passes through the
social structure. The two-step flow model, in which the mass media affect
opinion leaders who then pass the message on to followers, has been
criticized by Watts and Dodds (2007), who argue that influence is more
dispersed and bi-directional. One suggestion is that the WOM production of
product users is increased when they hear others recommend their brand,
and this would make influence omni-directional and more dependent on
ownership than opinion leadership. Managers, seeking to influence WOM,
may target opinion leaders or they can try to influence the whole customer
base. The best strategy depends on costs; when these are low, it is better to
target the whole customer base.
The advertising budget is allocated through media planning and this involves trade-offs
between reaching more buyers and having a greater number of exposures to a smaller
number of buyers. We review research on the frequency and concentration of ad
exposures and how these affect the impact of advertising. There is evidence that high
concentrations of ads may break through the resistance established by competitor brands.
The mechanisms by which advertising operates are complex. Sales effects resulting from
advertising appear to have two components: a short-term effect that is largely dissipated
within a few weeks, and a long-term effect which can last for more than a year but which
only occurs if there is a short-term effect. We discuss the bases for these effects. We also
introduce recent thinking that applies consumer memory theory to explain how
consumers take account of advertising.
Ads can have more effect on certain consumer segments and on certain types of brands.
We illustrate these effects and consider which segments provide most extra sales volume.
The media landscape continues to evolve, offering new ways of communicating with
consumers, while biometrics and consumer neuroscience are being increasingly promoted
as methods of evaluating advertising effectiveness. We discuss some impacts of these
changes.
Section 1: Effective Advertising
Ads may affect our knowledge and attitudes, but ultimately they must
change or reinforce behaviour if they are to be useful. In social applications,
ads can reduce accidents, increase voting rates, promote healthy eating, or
get people to report suspicious behaviour that might indicate terrorist
activity. In commercial applications, advertising can increase purchase and
subscription, or maintain purchase rates when the price goes up. Sometimes
the profit-making behaviour occurs at the end of a chain of prior actions,
and the links in this chain may be strengthened by advertising, such as by
getting consumers to go to a showroom or to check a product on the
Internet.
Mela, Gupta and Lehmann (1997) studied the impact of brand advertising
and sales promotion on price sensitivity over an 8-year period. They
focused on a mature product where life-cycle effects were minimal and
found that reductions in brand advertising were associated with increased
price sensitivity. Most of this effect occurred among less loyal customers,
showing that this segment is an important target for brand advertising
campaigns.
HMV chief executive Simon Fox said the whole market for the final instalment of the boy
wizard’s tale would be at half price, and cited Ottakar’s, now owned by HMV, as an
example of the price to be paid for not joining in a Harry Potter price battle: ‘Not being
price competitive on the book seemed to set a perception that the store was high price.
There are very few books that have that level of publicity,’ said Mr Fox. ‘If we try to be
anything other than half price we are setting the Waterstone’s brand off as high price and
that’s something we are trying to change’.
Sales Support
The cases in the Advertising Works (UK) and Effective Advertising
(Australia) series demonstrate that advertising can increase sales. On rare
occasions, the effect is large, as in the case of Levi 501 jeans in the UK.
Here, campaigns from 1984 to 1987 raised sales 20 times (Feldwick, 1990).
But the Levi 501 case was quite exceptional. Even when the best campaigns
are reviewed, sales gains of 100 per cent or more are uncommon and tend to
go to small brands, which can sometimes increase share substantially as they
start from a lower base.
Sometimes, even static sales are an achievement if, without the advertising,
there would have been a decline. In Australia, Hahn Premium light beer
expected to lose its leading position because of a build-up of intense
competition but its campaign successfully countered the attack and the brand
even gained a little share (Effective Advertising 8, 2006). The Australian
lamb advertising corrected a long-term decline in lamb sales, so the 25 per
cent gain on sales from the start of that campaign is probably an
underestimate of the advertising achievement.
One very successful campaign in the UK was conducted by the ad agency
TBWA for Wonderbra. This ad probably drew attention because it was
puzzling. The model (Eva Herzigova) was unconventionally provocative and
the quote was mysteriously enigmatic to those unfamiliar with the work of
the film star, Mae West. The cost of the initial four-month campaign was
only £330,000 as billboards were the predominant medium used (Baker,
1995). Over a two-year period, a gain in sales of 120 per cent was achieved,
even though Wonderbra was selling above the price of many other brands.
The key to this success was almost certainly the substantial editorial
comment and word of mouth (WOM) that the advertising provoked,
including discussion of how advertising could distract drivers and cause
accidents. Although this is an extreme example, WOM is an important
secondary effect of advertising. Keller and Fay (2009) found that 32 per cent
of online WOM and 21 per cent of offline WOM referred to paid
advertising, and that this involved more recommendation than other WOM.
The Advertising Works and Effective Advertising cases have been selected
here because they are successful. Most advertising for established brands
produces far less sales response. This is illustrated in a report by Riskey
(1997) on 23 Frito-Lay ad campaigns. This study compared brand sales
when ads were running with a no-ad control condition. The study was
conducted using the BehaviorScan method of Information Resources Inc.
(IRI), which is described in more detail in Box 13.3. Twelve campaigns
showed measurable effects, and these cases produced an average sales
increase of 15 per cent.
Box 13.3 BehaviorScan
Information Resources Inc. (IRI) uses cable TV in specific towns to test ads. Households
are recruited to a panel and agree to receive television that may be modified by IRI. The
Behavior Scan technology swaps commercials so that some households receive trial ads
or extra exposures of normal ads when compared with other households. The former
allows copy tests to be conducted, the latter weight tests. Members of the panel show an
identification number when they buy groceries in town. IRI finances the scanners in the
town’s stores and downloads sales information each night from those scanners. The
system allows sales to be tied to households receiving different frequencies of
advertising.
This system permits experimental tests but suffers from some weaknesses:
Members of the household may not be watching a TV set even though it is on.
Out-of-town purchases (out-shopping) are missed.
The tests exclude trade response. National advertising may generate more retailer
stocking and competitor advertising than in the test communities.
The brands that are tested are chosen for commercial reasons and this may bias the
sampling.
There may be a ‘hothouse’ effect if panellists guess that commercials are on test
and, as a consequence, take more interest in them.
Word of mouth between test and control panellists may compromise the
experiment.
While principles for developing effective copy might help to avoid mistakes, creativity is
still required to produce ads that gain attention and engagement from the audience. By its
nature, creativity cannot be anticipated. But, after its creation, we can see features of an
ad that help to make it successful. For example, the Wonderbra campaign was noticed
because it created curiosity at a number of levels. Among these were the enigmatic and
challenging character of the model, the oddity of putting such ads on billboards, and in
the ad shown, uncertainty about the origin of captions such as ‘or are you just pleased to
see me?’ This comes from a line Mae West says to Cary Grant in the film She Done Him
Wrong. The full line is ‘Is that a pistol in your pocket, or are you just glad to see me?’
Section 2: Advertising Frequency and
Concentration
Schedules
Advertising is presented in media according to a schedule. Traditionally, for
TV, radio or print media, ad exposures may be continuous (delivered at a
steady frequency per month) or in bursts (e.g. one month on and two months
off). When the bursts are short-interval (e.g. a week), this pattern may be
called pulsing. Sometimes, a low level of advertising or drip is maintained in
the gaps between bursts. The choice of schedule should be determined
primarily by its sales impact on consumers. Continuous schedules spread the
advertising across a larger number of people but each person tends to see
fewer exposures compared with bursting. As the time for the burst is
reduced, there is more concentration (the exposures occur over a shorter
period) but fewer buyers may be reached by the ad during this reduced time.
There are good reasons why the response to exposures should be S-shaped.
An important argument is based on the idea of breakthrough, getting over a
threshold of attention so that the audience cannot miss the message
(Broadbent, 1998). An S-shaped response is also implicit in Krugman’s
(1972) three-hit theory. Krugman argued that on first exposure, viewers are
curious, on the second the meaning of the ad may become clear and they
endorse or reject the message, and on the third and subsequent exposures
they are reminded of the message again and may take action. In this
account, the second and third exposures are more effective than the first. An
influential book by Naples (1979) endorsed the three-hit theory.
Roberts’ evidence has not been corroborated by other research and it should
be closely scrutinized. First, we note that the data are gathered in Britain
where ad clutter is relatively low. This raises the possibility that stronger
effects from ad concentration might be observed in high-clutter
environments. Second, the study is restricted to groceries. Third, doubts may
be felt about the effectiveness of the control comparison used in this work
(purchases made by the same respondents when they had not been exposed
to the advertising for 28 days). However, in the absence of other evidence
Roberts’ results remain important.
Breakthrough
Breakthrough relates to the psychological concept of interference, which
occurs when learning about one concept reduces the ease with which a
related concept is processed or recalled. Thus, learning more about Brand A
interferes with the processing or recall of the competitive Brand B, and vice
versa. Breakthrough occurs when the concentration of exposure to ads for
one brand overcomes the interference set up by past learning about other
brands.
Under this model, the first few presentations of the ads may secure
additional interest and may sometimes modify thinking about a brand. This
thoughtful initial response is likely to have a substantial sales effect, when it
occurs. Once consumers become accustomed to the ad, they will no longer
give it much thought; however, a second primary effect may continue to
operate, produced by the low-involvement automatic mechanisms that help
to maintain brand awareness. Mechanisms of this sort produce weak effects
but may continue to work over many repetitions as they refresh the
associative network described in Chapter 3. This dual-process account has
some parallel in work on persuasion by Fazio (1990) and Petty and Cacioppo
(1986). Even if existing consumers of a brand do not pay much attention to a
new ad, they may still be affected by these passive low-involvement
processes.
Figure 13.3 also shows secondary processes that may occur later. These
secondary effects generally produce weak effects on sales, but because they
are sustained over long periods may contribute substantially to the total sales
benefit from advertising. Studies of the connection between primary and
secondary effects consistently show that a secondary effect occurs only
when there has been a primary effect on sales. Abraham and Lodish (1990)
reported that, if advertising tests do not show an effect after six months, they
are unlikely to show any effect later. Jones (1995a) found that no one-year
ad effect was observed if a short-term effect was not detected in the first
seven days after exposure. Riskey (1997) observed that longer-term effects
in 12 ad campaigns occurred only when there were shorter-term effects.
Lodish et al. (1995b) found no delayed effects from ads that were ineffective
in their test year. This evidence shows that any secondary effect is an
outcome of the primary effect; however, a primary effect does not guarantee
a secondary effect because it could be countered by competitor
communications.
A third effect occurs when advertising raises distribution and reduces stock-
outs so that the product is more easily purchased. More efficient stocking
may occur either because retailers anticipate demand and order more when
they are advised about forthcoming ad campaigns, or because the extra
demand from an ad campaign forces retailers to increase stock. Retailers
may maintain the higher stock level after the advertising has finished, thus
further boosting sales.
Short-Term Decay
Early studies estimated advertising half-lives on the assumption that there
was a single process of ad decay. On this basis, Broadbent (1984) claimed
that, for most brands, half-lives were in the region of 4–6 weeks. A meta-
study of 70 brands by Clarke (1976) indicated half-lives in the range of 4–
12 weeks. Subsequently, Broadbent and Fry (1995) suggested that ad decay
had both short-term and long-term components. Roberts (1999) measured
average short-term ad decay for frequently purchased brands. He found that
this fitted an exponential curve with a half-life of 16 days. This means that,
on average, an exposure loses 4.4 per cent of its sales effect each day and
72 per cent after 28 days. This rapid loss of effect has practical implications
(see Exercise 13.2).
Exercise 13.2 On which day should you
advertise?
Groceries have an uneven pattern of purchase over the week. Spending is heavier on Thursday, Friday
and Saturday when compared with Sunday, Monday, Tuesday and Wednesday. The Nielsen figures
are shown below.
Weekly UK supermarket sales by day of the week (percentage of total, supplied to us by Nielsen in
2015):
Which day should you advertise if the impact of your ads decays each day?
Long-Term Decay
Lodish and Lubetkin (1992) investigated long-term decay using IRI data on
upweight tests. In their study, 44 brands received 50–100 per cent extra
advertising during a test year and approximately half of the brands showed a
sales increase that year. Lodish and Lubetkin analysed the extra sales achieved
for these brands over the next two years, after ad spending had returned to
normal. They compared the results with a control condition where there had not
been any extra advertising. Table 13.1 shows the extra sales for the upweight
group compared to the control group. The extra sales in years 2 and 3, after the
upweight had finished, were roughly equal to the extra sales during the test year.
This work was criticized for excluding cases where there was no sales impact
from increased weight, since these cases might have shown a response in later
years, but Lodish et al. (1995b) checked and found that there was no such later
response.
Figure 13.4 How primary and secondary effects of advertising may combine
with base sales
Figure 13.4 shows both short-and long-term effects of advertising. Here, a burst
of advertising produces a short-term primary effect. The long-term secondary
effect is based on the extra sales generated by the short-term effect; it has a
smaller amplitude but lasts much longer. The combined effect sums the base
sales, the long-term and the short-term effects.
Box 13.5 New thinking on effective
advertising
Past work on effective advertising has often emphasized the measurement of aggregate
sales responses. New approaches give more emphasis to understanding consumer
memory networks. An example of such an approach is provided by Wright (2016), who
proposed a model of advertising effect based on experimental evidence about how
memory and emotion operate (this could be seen as an evolution of Figure 13.3). His
model is born of concerns that existing approaches are incomplete, over-generalize, or
have no obvious association with known brain processes. Wright suggests that effective
advertising has four requirements:
1. ‘An opportunity to see, or being present in the media to which the consumer is
exposed.’
This is the role of media planning, to maximize the opportunities to see within
the advertising budget available. The exact selection of ad placements will depend
on the advertiser’s views about effective frequency, and on the desirability of using
a variety of media platforms to create campaign synergies (Jeannes and Beal,
2012) or to achieve concentration by making use of multiple touchpoints within a
single day (e.g. morning TV, drive-time radio, outdoor advertising, digital media).
4. ‘Retrieval, so that some of the results of this mental processing are evoked at the
point of purchase, with a resultant effect on consideration and choice.’
The past processing of ad content will have no effect unless the relevant memories
(or mild emotional attachments) are brought to mind at the point of purchase. The
chances of such retrieval will be affected by the stimuli that consumers are exposed
to just before they make a purchase decision. In other words, even though
advertising is processed, it runs the risk of being lost in the vast store of consumer
memory unless it is specifically evoked. Wright comments that we know relatively
little about how past processing of advertising is evoked at the point of purchase,
and encourages more research in this area.
Wright (2016) is a critic of the exclusive use of sales response to evaluate advertising
effect. This is partly because such evaluations usually take little account of stimuli
encountered at the point of purchase and so can never provide a full explanation of
advertising effect, but also because the sales response is often relatively small in
magnitude and so easily masked by the natural variations in sales common in most
markets. Thus, Wright argues for the use of recall-based measures of advertising
effectiveness to supplement the analysis of sales response.
Exercise 13.3 Reconciling models of
advertising effectiveness
1. This chapter has discussed advertising effects such as supporting higher prices,
encouraging more sales and building distribution. Yet Wright (2016) suggests that
advertising operates through consumer memory. Discuss how a stronger presence in
consumer memory may or may not support higher prices, encourage more sales or build
distribution.
2. Other mechanisms discussed in this chapter include memory interference, social
influence and breakthrough. Discuss how this can be understood in terms of consumer
memory. That is, how can these effects be explained by the ways that advertising is
processed into memory?
Section 4: Specific Effects
Whatever the mechanisms that underlie advertising effect, the response may
be greater for some types of consumer segments or brands than for others.
Prior knowledge of these differences may offer a substantial practical
advantage to advertisers.
High and Low Loyalty Segments
Raj (1982) found the maximum sales response to advertising occurred
among those with a share-of-category requirement (SCR) loyalty of 50–70
per cent. The purchases of other brands were not much affected when the
focal brand gained – the extra sales in the 50–70 per cent loyalty group
came mainly from an increase in category volume. Tellis (1988a) also found
that ads had more sales effect on buyers with an SCR greater than 50 per
cent. Those who had not bought the brand before showed only a small
volume sales response to the advertising compared with loyal buyers.
Wood and Poltrack (2015) found that, for supermarket products, most of the
incremental revenue gained by advertising came from previous brand
buyers who had switched back to buy the advertised brand. Some of these
buyers went on to show high levels of loyalty over the subsequent year. So,
while the low-loyalty segment is an important advertising target, these
buyers do not necessarily stay low loyalty.
The factors underlying digital sharing may vary between the media. Araujo,
Neijens and Vliegenthart (2015) analysed 19,343 global brand messages
posted on Twitter over three years and found that, for Twitter, informational
cues are the primary cause of sharing. While emotional content and the use
of hashtags amplified the effects of informational cues on retweeting, they
had no detectable impact on their own. This differs from Facebook videos,
where strong emotions that cause a physiological reaction are the main
driver of viral sharing (Nelson-Field, Riebe and Newstead, 2013). However,
Araujo et al. (2015) and Nelson-Field et al. (2013) studied different
behaviours and used slightly different methods; Araujo et al. identified
emotional cues from Twitter text, whereas Nelson-Field et al. measured
emotional reactions directly. So, it is possible that variation in the factors
underlying sharing is due to differences in study methods rather than
differences in media.
Exercise 13.4 Where will new media take us?
How is advertising in new media going to develop? How is this going to affect other forms of
advertising?
At the time of writing, the changes that previously played out between TV
advertising are manifesting again in the growth of in-app advertising on
mobile devices. Fulgoni (2015) found that these new digital channels tend
to add to, rather than cannibalize, existing digital channels. That is, the rise
of mobile devices has not reduced the use of desktop computers, just as the
rise of desktop computers did not reduce TV viewing. Fulgoni noted that
advertising on mobile devices was cheaper, more effective and less affected
by clutter, leading him to recommend that media planners ensure they
include in-app ads in their ad schedules. The advantages of mobile apps will
likely erode over time as more advertisers participate in this medium, but
this does demonstrate the value that can sometimes be gained from
exploiting a new media channel. For now, mobile in-app advertising seems
to have simply added an additional medium that operates in a familiar
manner.
Section 6: Biometrics and Consumer Neuroscience
Another recent trend is the upsurge of interest in the use of biometrics (eye
tracking, heart rate, breathing, facial expression, skin conductivity) and
neuroscience (EEG or electroencephalograms and fMRI or functional
magnetic resonance imaging) to detect whether people are paying attention
to and processing ads. Some marketers believe that biometrics can directly
measure attention to ads, and that brain scans (EEG and fMRI) can reveal
whether advertisements are being processed either through encoding into
memory or by increasing the desire for products.
What does this mean for marketing? It is consistent with the theories of
Wright (2016) in that it shows the importance of recognition (demonstrating
that the ad is processed into memory), while activation of the Ventral
Stratium is consistent with establishment of a somatic marker that yields an
ongoing mild emotional attachment to the advertised brand.
As with all such studies, the work of Venkatraman et al. (2015) is limited by
sampling and by the context of their research. Venkatraman’s method also
analyses all 30 seconds of a TV ad together, whereas methods such as
biometrics and EEG can track the reactions to individual scenes at
particular points within an ad. The more detailed tracking of viewer
reactions provided by biometrics and EEG offers opportunities to assist
copy development, as advertisers may be able to use these methods to
choose which scenes to insert at particular points within an ad.
So, as work in this area continues, other results may well emerge.
Exercise 13.5 Personal reflection on
advertising effects
When you next sit with a housemate and see a TV advertisement for a bank, ask that person (i)
if they recognize the advertisement (i.e. whether they remember seeing it before), (ii) whether
they like it, and (iii) whether it makes them more likely to use that bank. On the following day,
reflect on the advertisement yourself and think about whether the advertised bank easily comes
to mind, and whether you have a mild emotional attachment to that bank, or to any bank.
Summary
Commercial advertising targets behaviours that affect profit, such as
purchase and rental. Social advertising may target behaviours such as
smoking and dangerous driving. The benefit from commercial advertising
occurs through more sales, greater margins or lower costs; however, it will
only work if it is processed into memory in some way, either consciously or
subconsciously. Ad campaigns usually have quite small effects on sales that
are hard to detect in the short term; in large markets, the payback on
advertising can nonetheless be many times the expenditure.
We present a model in which ads may have two sorts of primary effect: one
is thoughtful, and the effect is quite strong if it occurs; the other is
automatic and weak. Thoughtful processes occur early in the sequence of ad
exposures if they occur at all; automatic mechanisms can occur at each
exposure so ads can continue to have some effect for a long period. Wright
(2016) proposes a third mechanism – mild emotional attachment; this
differs from other automatic mechanisms as it arises from a different brain
process. The result is to establish a somatic marker that overlays other
memories, rather than simply adding further weak associations between
existing memories.
While low-loyalty and light buyers show less individual volume response to
advertising, the large number of these buyers ensures that these segments
provide more sales gain. Advertising is effective at reaching light and non-
buyers and contrasts with direct marketing, which is better when there is a
need to focus on a particular segment of existing buyers. In their reaction to
television advertising, light viewers are more responsive than heavy
viewers.
Aaker, J.L. and Williams, P. (1998) Empathy versus pride: the influence of
emotional appeals across cultures, Journal of Consumer Research, 25(3),
241–61.
Abraham, M.M. and Lodish, L.M. (1990) Getting the most out of
advertising and promotion, Harvard Business Review, 68(3), 50–60.
Adams, H.F. (1916) Advertising and its Mental Laws, New York:
Macmillan.
Ahmad, R. (2002) The older or ageing customer in the UK: are they really
different? International Journal of Market Research, 44(3), 337–60.
Aksoy, L., Cooil, B., Groening, C., Keiningham, T. and Yalçın, A. (2008)
The long-term stock market valuation of customer satisfaction, Journal of
Marketing, 72(4), 105–22.
Alexander, V., Tripp, S. and Zak, P.J. (2015) Preliminary evidence for the
neurophysiologic effects of online coupons: changes in oxytocin, stress,
and mood, Psychology & Marketing, 32(9), 977–86.
Allenby, G.M. and Ginter, J.L. (1995) The effects of in-store displays and
feature advertising on consideration sets, International Journal of
Research in Marketing, 12(1), 67–80.
Allport, G.W. (1935) Attitudes. In C. Murchison (ed.), A Handbook of
Social Psychology, Worcester, MA: Clark University Press, 798–844.
Anderson, E.W. and Mansi, S.A. (2009) Does customer satisfaction matter
to investors? Findings from the bond market, Journal of Marketing
Research, 46(5), 703–14.
Anglin, L.K., Stuenkel, J.K. and Lepisto, L.R. (1994) The effect of stress on
price sensitivity and comparison shopping. In C.T. Allen and D.R. John
(eds), Advances in Consumer Research, 21, 126–31.
Arce, M. and Cebollada, J. (2006) The role of loyalty in online and offline
shopping behaviour: an empirical application to the grocery industry,
Conference Proceedings of the European Marketing Academy, Athens.
Areni, C.S. and Kim, D. (1993) The influence of background music on
shopping behavior: classical versus top-forty music in a wine store. In L.
McAlister and M.L. Rothschild (eds), Advances in Consumer Research,
20, 336–40.
Armstrong, J.S., Du, R., Green, J. and Graefe, A. (2016) Predictive validity
of evidence-based principles: an application of the index method,
European Journal of Marketing, 50.
Ataman, M.B., Mela, C.F. and Van Heerde, H.J. (2008) Building brands,
Marketing Science, 27(6), 1036–54.
Ataman, M.B., Van Heerde, H.J. and Mela, C.F. (2010) The long-term
effect of marketing strategy on brand sales, Journal of Marketing
Research, 47(5), 866–82.
Babin, B.J., Hardesty, D.M. and Suter, T.A. (2003) Color and shopping
intentions: the intervening effect of price fairness and perceived affect,
Journal of Business Research, 56(7), 541–51.
Bagozzi, R.P. (1981) Attitudes, intentions and behavior: a test of some key
hypotheses, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 41(4), 607–27.
Baldinger, A.L. and Rubinson, J. (1996) Brand loyalty: the link between
attitude and behavior, Journal of Advertising Research, 36(6), 22–34.
Baldwin, M.W. and Holmes, J.G. (1987) Salient private audiences and
awareness of the self, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,
52(6), 1087–98.
Bargh, J.A., Chaiken, S., Govender, R. and Pratto, F. (1992) The generality
of the automatic activation effect, Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 62(6), 893–912.
Bass, F.M. (1969) A new product growth model for consumer durables,
Management Science, 15(5), 215–27.
Bass, F.M., Jeuland, A.P. and Wright, G.P. (1976) Equilibrium stochastic
choice and market penetration theories: derivation and comparisons,
Management Science, 22(10), 1051–63.
Bayus, B.L. (1985) Word of mouth: the indirect effects of marketing efforts,
Journal of Advertising Research, 25(3), 31–9.
Beales, H.J., Mazis, M.B., Salop, S.C. and Staelin, R. (1981) Consumer
search and public policy, Journal of Consumer Research, 8(1), 11–22.
Beatty, S.E. and Smith, S.M. (1987) External search effort: an investigation
across several product categories, Journal of Consumer Research, 14(1),
83–95.
Bellizzi, J.A., Crowley, A.E. and Hasty, R.E. (1983) The effects of color in
store design, Journal of Retailing, 59(1), 21–44.
Berger, J. and Iyengar, R. (2012) How interest shapes word of mouth over
different channels, available at
http://rady.ucsd.edu/faculty/seminars/papers/berger.pdf
Berger, J. and Schwartz, E.M. (2011) What drives immediate and ongoing
word of mouth? Journal of Marketing Research, 48(Oct.), 869–80.
Berthon, P., Pitt, L., Parent, M. and Berthon, J.-P. (2009) Aesthetics and
ephemerality: observing andpreserving the luxury brand, California
Management Review, 52, 45–66.
Biel, A.L. (1991) The brandscape: converting brand image into equity,
Admap, October, 41–6.
Bijmolt, T.H.A., van Heerde, H.J. and Pieters, R.G.M. (2005) New
empirical generalizations on the determinants of price elasticity, Journal
of Marketing Research, 42(2), 141–56.
Bird, M., Channon, C. and Ehrenberg, A.S.C. (1970) Brand image and
brand usage, Journal of Marketing Research, 7, 307–14.
Bitner, M.J., Booms, B.H. and Tetreault, M.S. (1990) The service
encounter: diagnosing favourable and unfavourable incidents, Journal of
Marketing, 54(1), 71–84.
Blackett, T., Boad, B., Cowper, P. and Kumar, S. (1999) The future of co-
branding. In Co-Branding, pp. 113–23. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Blair, M.H. and Rabuck, M.J. (1998) Advertising wearin and wearout: ten
years later – more empirical evidence and successful practice, Journal of
Advertising Research, 38(5), 7–18.
Blattberg, R.C., Briesch, R. and Fox, E.J. (1995) How promotions work,
Marketing Science, 14(3), G122–32.
Broadbent, S. and Fry, T. (1995) Adstock modelling for the long term,
Journal of the Market Research Society, 37(4), 385–403.
Broadbent, T. (2000) Advertising Works 11, Henley-on-Thames: Institute of
Practitioners in Advertising, World Advertising Research Centre
(WARC).
Brown, J.J. and Reingen, P.H. (1987) Social ties and word-of-mouth referral
behavior, Journal of Consumer Research, 14(3), 350–62.
Brown, J.R. and Dant, R.P. (2009) The theoretical domains of retailing
research: a retrospective, Journal of Retailing, 85(2), 113–28.
Burke, R.R. and Srull, T.K. (1988) Competitive interference and consumer
memory for advertising, Journal of Consumer Research, 15(1), 55–68.
Buzzell, R.D. and Gale, B.T. (1987) The PIMS Principles: Linking Strategy
to Performance, New York: The Free Press.
Buzzell, R.D., Quelch, J.A. and Salmon, W.J. (1991) The costly bargain of
trade promotion, Harvard Business Review, 68(2), 141–9.
Caplovitz, D. (1967) The Poor Pay More, 2nd edition, New York: The Free
Press.
Castensen, L.L., Isaakowitz, D.M. and Charles, S.T. (1999) Taking time
seriously: a theory of socioemotional selectivity, American Psychologist,
54(March), 165–81.
Chan, H., Wan, L.C. and Sin, L.M. (2009) The contrasting effects of culture
on consumer tolerance: interpersonal face and impersonal fate, Journal of
Consumer Research, 36(2), 292–304.
Chandon, P., Morwitz, V.G. and Reinartz, W.J. (2005) Do intentions really
predict behavior? Self-generated validity effects in survey research,
Journal of Marketing, 69(2), 1–14.
Cheng, Y. and Tsai, Y. (2014) Train delay and perceived wait time:
passengers’ perspective, Transport Reviews, 34(6), 710–29.
Clare, J.E. and Kiser, C.V. (1951) Preference for children of a given sex in
relation to fertility. In P.K. Whelpton and C.V. Kiser (eds), Social and
Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility, New York: Milbank Memorial
Fund, 621–73.
Cole, C., Laurent, G., Drolet, A., Ebert, J., Gutchess, A., Lambert-
Pandraud, R., et al. (2008) Decision making and brand choice by older
consumers, Marketing Letters, 19(3/4), 355–65.
Cole, C.A. and Houston, M.J. (1987) Encoding and media effects on
consumer learning deficiencies in the elderly, Journal of Marketing
Research, 24(1), 55–63.
Coleman, J., Katz, E. and Menzel, H. (1957) The diffusion of an innovation
among physicians, Sociometry, 20(4), 253–70.
Collins, M., Beal, V. and Barwise, P. (2003) Channel use among multi-
channel viewers: patterns in TV viewing, Report 15 for Corporate
Sponsors, Adelaide, Australia: Ehrenberg-Bass Institute for Marketing
Science.
Conner, M., Lawton, R., Parker, D., Chorlton, K., Manstead, A.S.R. and
Stradling, S. (2007) Application of the theory of planned behaviour to the
prediction of objectively assessed breaking of posted speed limits, British
Journal of Psychology, 98(3), 429–53.
Coulter, K.S. and Coulter, R.A. (2005) Size does matter: the effects of
magnitude representation congruency on price perceptions and purchase
likelihood, Journal of Consumer Psychology, 15(1), 64–76.
Coulter, K.S. and Coulter, R.A. (2013) Small sounds, big deals: phonetic
symbolism effects in pricing, Journal of Consumer Research, S224–37.
Cox, K.K. (1970) The effect of shelf space upon sales of branded products,
Journal of Marketing Research, 7(1), 55–8.
Crocker, J., Fiske, S.T. and Taylor, S.E. (1984) Schematic bases of belief
change. In J.R. Eiser (ed.), Attitudinal Judgement, New York: Springer-
Verlag.
Cronin, J.J., Jr and Taylor, S.A. (1992) Measuring service quality: a re-
examination and extension, Journal of Marketing, 56(3), 55–68.
Cross, S.E. and Madson, L. (1997) Models of the self: self-construals and
gender, Psychological Bulletin, 122(1), 5–37.
Cunningham, R.M. (1956) Brand loyalty: what, where, how much? Harvard
Business Review, 34 (Jan./Feb.), 116–28.
Curhan, R.C. (1972) The relationship between shelf space and unit sales in
supermarkets, Journal of Marketing Research, 9(4), 406–12.
Dacin, P.A. and Smith, D.C. (1993) The effect of adding products to a brand
on consumers’ evaluations of new brand extensions. In L. McAlister and
M.L. Rothschild (eds), Advances in Consumer Research, 20, 594–8.
Dall’Olmo Riley, F.D., Pina, J.M. and Bravo, R. (2015) The role of
perceived value in vertical brand extensions of luxury and premium
brands, Journal of Marketing Management, 31(7–8), 881–913.
Damasio, A.R. (1994) Descartes’ Error: Emotion, Reason, and the Human
Brain, New York: Avon.
Davidson, A.R. and Jaccard, J.J. (1975) Population psychology: a new look
at an old problem, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 31,
1073–82.
Davis, F.D. (1989) Perceived usefulness, perceived ease of use, and user
acceptance of information technology, MIS Quarterly, 13(3), 319–39.
Dawar, N. and Anderson, P.F. (1993) Determining the Order and Direction
of Multiple Brand Extensions, INSEAD Working Paper 93/17/MKT.
Dawes, J., Mundt, K. and Sharp, B. (2009) Consideration sets for financial
services brands, Journal of Financial Services Marketing, 14, 190–202.
Day, D., Gan, B., Gendall, P. and Esslemont, D. (1991) Predicting purchase
behaviour, Marketing Bulletin, 2(May), 18–30.
DelVecchio, D., Henard, D.H. and Freling, T.H. (2006) The effect of sales
promotion on post-promotion brand preference: a meta-analysis, Journal
of Retailing, 82(3), 203–14.
DeSarbo, W.S., Huff, L., Rolandelli, M.M. and Choi, J. (1994) On the
measurement of perceived service quality. In R.T. Rust and R.L. Oliver
(eds), Service Quality: New Directions in Theory and Practice, London:
Sage, 201–22.
Dickson, P.R. and Sawyer, A.G. (1990) The price knowledge and search of
supermarket shoppers, Journal of Marketing, 54(3), 42–54.
Dinner, I.M., Van Heerde, H.J. and Neslin, S.A. (2014) Driving online and
offline sales: the cross-channel effects of traditional, online display, and
paid search advertising, Journal of Marketing Research, 51(5), 527–45.
Dittmar, H. (2005) Compulsive buying: a growing concern? An
examination of gender, age, and endorsement of materialistic values as
predictors, British Journal of Psychology, 96(4), 467–91.
Dittmar, H., Beattie, J. and Friese, S. (1995) Gender identity and material
symbols: objects and decision considerations in impulse purchases,
Journal of Economic Psychology, 16(3), 491–512.
Drèze, X. and Nunes J.C. (2009) Feeling superior: the impact of loyalty
program structure on consumers’ perception of status, Journal of
Consumer Research, 35(6), 890–905.
Drèze, X. and Nunes, J. (2011) Recurring goals and learning: the impact of
successful reward attainment on purchase behavior, Journal of Marketing
Research, 48(2), 268–81.
Drèze, X., Hoch, S.J. and Purk, M.E. (1994) Shelf management and space
elasticity, Journal of Retailing, 70(4), 301–26.
Driesener, C. and Romaniuk, J. (2006) Comparing methods of brand image
measurement, International Journal of Market Research, 48(6), 681–98.
Drolet, A., Schwarz, N. and Yoon, C. (eds) (2010) The Aging Consumer:
Perspectives from Psychology and Economics, New York: Routledge,
Taylor and Francis Group, Ch. 4.
Du, R.Y. and Kamakura, W.A. (2011) Measuring contagion in the diffusion
of consumer packaged goods, Journal of Marketing Research, 68(Feb.),
28–47.
Dunn, R.S. and Wrigley, N. (1984) Store loyalty for grocery products: an
empirical study, Area, 16(4), 307–14.
Eagly, A.H. and Chaiken, S. (2005) Attitude research in the 21st century:
the current state of knowledge. In D. Albarracín, B.T. Johnson and M.P.
Zanna (eds), The Handbook of Attitudes, Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum, 743–
67.
East, R., Grandcolas, U., Dall’Olmo Riley, F.D. and Lomax, W. (2012)
Reasons for switching service providers, Australasian Marketing Journal,
20(2), 164–70.
East, R., Hammond, K. and Gendall, P. (2006) Fact and fallacy in retention
marketing, Journal of Marketing Management, 22(1–2), 5–23.
East, R., Hammond, K., Harris, P. and Lomax, W. (2000) First-store loyalty
and retention, Journal of Marketing Management, 16(4), 307–25.
East, R., Hammond, K., Lomax, W. and Robinson, H. (2005b) What is the
effect of a recommendation? Marketing Review, 5(2), 145–57.
East, R., Hammond, K.A. and Wright, M. (2007) The relative incidence of
positive and negative word of mouth: a multi-category study,
International Journal of Research in Marketing, 24(2), 175–84.
East, R., Lomax, W. and Willson, G. (1991) Factors associated with service
delay in supermarkets and post offices, Journal of Consumer Satisfaction,
Dissatisfaction and Complaining Behaviour, 4, 123–8.
East, R., Lomax, W., Willson, G. and Harris, P. (1992) Demand Over Time:
Attitudes, Knowledge and Habits that Affect When Customers Use
Banks and Building Societies, Working Paper, Kingston Business School.
East, R., Lomax, W., Willson, G. and Harris, P. (1994) Decision making and
habit in shopping times, European Journal of Marketing, 28(4), 56–71.
East, R., Romaniuk, J. and Lomax, W. (2011) The NPS and the ACSI: a
critique and an alternative metric, International Journal of Market
Research, 53(3), 327–46.
East, R., Uncles, M. and Lomax, W. (2014a) Hear nothing, do nothing: the
role of word of mouth in the decision making of older consumers, Journal
of Marketing Management, 30(7/8), 786–801.
East, R., Uncles, M., Romaniuk, J. and Dall’Olmo Riley, F. (2015) Factors
associated with the production of word of mouth, International Journal of
Marketing Research, 57(3), 439–58.
East, R., Uncles, M., Romaniuk, J. and Lomax, W. (2016) Measuring the
impact of positive and negative word of mouth: a reappraisal,
Australasian Marketing Journal, 24(1), 54–58.
Ehrenberg, A.S.C., Hammond, K.A. and Goodhardt, G.J. (1994a) The after-
effects of price-related consumer promotions, Journal of Advertising
Research, 34(4), 11–21.
Elliott, R., Jobber, D. and Sharp, J. (1995) Using the theory of reasoned
action to understand organizational behaviour: the role of belief salience,
British Journal of Social Psychology, 34(2), 161–72.
Enis, B.M. and Paul, G.W. (1970) Store loyalty as a basis for marketing
segmentation, Journal of Retailing, 46(3), 42–56.
Ennew, C.T. and Binks, M.R. (1996) The impact of service quality and
service characteristics on customer retention: small businesses and their
banks in the UK, British Journal of Management, 7, 219–30.
Eroglu, S.A., Machleit, K.A. and Davis, L.M. (2003) Empirically testing a
model of online store atmospherics and shopper responses, Psychology
and Marketing, 20(2), 139–50.
Faber, R.J. and O’Guinn, T.C. (1988) Compulsive consumption and credit
abuse, Journal of Consumer Policy, 11, 97–109.
Faber, R.J. and O’Guinn, T.C. (1992) A clinical screener for compulsive
buying, Journal of Consumer Research, 19(3), 459–69.
Fader, P.S., Hardie, B.G.S. and Huang, C.Y. (2004) A dynamic changepoint
model for new product sales forecasting, Marketing Science, 23(1), 50–
65.
Farris, P.W. and Reibstein, D.J. (1991) How prices, ad expenditures, and
profits are linked, Harvard Business Review, 57(6), 173–84.
Fazio, R.H., Powell, M.C. and Herr, P.M. (1983) Toward a process model
of the attitude–behavior relation: accessing one’s attitude upon mere
observation of the attitude object, Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 44, 723–35.
Feick, L.F. and Price, L.L. (1987) The market maven: a diffuser of
marketplace information, Journal of Marketing, 51(1), 83–97.
Feinberg, R.A. and Smith, P. (1989) Misperceptions of time in the sales
transaction. In T. Srull (ed.), Advances in Consumer Research, 16, 56–8.
Fiske, S.T. (1980) Attention and weight in person perception: the impact of
negative and extreme behavior, Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 38(6), 889–906.
Folkes, V.S. (1988) The availability heuristic and perceived risk, Journal of
Consumer Research, 15(1), 13–23.
Folkes, V.S., Koletsky, S. and Graham, J.L. (1987) A field study of causal
inferences and consumer reaction: the view from the airport, Journal of
Consumer Research, 13(4), 534–9.
Fornell, C., Johnson, M.D., Anderson, E.W., Cha, J. and Bryant, B.E.
(1996) The American Customer Satisfaction Index: nature, purpose, and
findings, Journal of Marketing, 60(4), 7–18.
Fornell, C., Mithas, S., Morgeson, F.V., III and Krishnan, M.S. (2006)
Customer satisfaction and stock prices: high returns, low risks, Journal of
Marketing, 70(1), 3–14.
Fournier, S., Dobscha, S. and Mick, D.G. (1998) Preventing the premature
death of relationship marketing, Harvard Business Review, Jan./Feb., 42–
51.
Fourt, L.A. and Woodlock, J.W. (1960) Early prediction of market success
for new grocery products, Journal of Marketing, 25(2), 31–8.
Foxall, G. and Hackett, P.M.W. (1992) Consumers’ perception of micro-
retail location: wayfinding and cognitive mapping in planned and organic
shopping environments, International Review of Retail, Distribution and
Consumer Research, 2(3), 309–27.
Fulgoni, G.M. (1987) The role of advertising: is there one? Admap, 262,
54–7.
Fulgoni, G.M. (2015) The rise of the digital omnivore: what it means for
advertisers, publishers and developers, Journal of Advertising Research,
55(2), 115–19.
Gardner, A.G. and Levy, S.J. (1955) The product and the brand, Harvard
Business Review, 33(Mar.–Apr.), 33–9.
Garretson, J.A. and Burton, S. (2003) Highly coupon and sale prone
consumers: benefits beyond price savings, Journal of Advertising
Research, 43(2), 162–72.
Giebelhausen, M., Robinson, S. and Cronin, J.J. (2011) Worth waiting for:
increasing satisfaction by making consumers wait, Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science, 39(6), 889–905.
Goldenberg, J., Libai, B., Moldovan, S. and Muller, E. (2007) The NPV of
bad news, International Journal of Research in Marketing, 24(3), 186–
200.
Goodey, C. and East, R. (2008) Testing the market maven concept, Journal
of Marketing Management, 24(3/4), 265–82.
Green, P.E. and Krieger, A.M. (2002) What’s right with conjoint analysis?
Marketing Research, 14(1), 24–7.
Green, P.E., Krieger, A.M. and Wind, Y. (2001) Thirty years of conjoint
analysis: reflections and prospects, Interfaces, 31(3), S56–73.
Gruca, T.S. and Rego, L.L. (2005) Customer satisfaction, cash flow and
shareholder value, Journal of Marketing, 69(3), 115–30.
Guardian, The (2011) Supermarkets: changing market share, 16 August.
Available at www.guardian.co.uk/business/2011/aug/16/supermarkets-
market-share-kantar
Gupta, S. (1988) Impact of sales promotions on when, what, and how much
to buy, Journal of Marketing Research, 25(4), 342–55.
Gupta, S., Lehmann, D.R. and Stuart, J.A. (2004) Valuing customers,
Journal of Marketing Research, 41(1), 7–18.
Gupta, S., Van Heerde, H.J. and Wittink, D.R. (2003) Is 75% of the sales
promotion bump due to brand switching? No, only 33% is, Journal of
Marketing Research, 40(4), 481–91.
Hallberg, G. (1996) All Consumers Are Not Created Equal, Hoboken, NJ:
John Wiley & Sons.
Hamilton, W., East, R. and Kalafatis, S. (1997) The measurement and utility
of brand price elasticities, Journal of Marketing Management, 13(4),
285–98.
Hammond, K.A. and Ehrenberg, A.S.C. (1995) Heavy buyers: how many
do you have? How important are they? In M. Bergardaà (ed.), Marketing
Today and for the 21st Century. 24th EMAC Conference Proceedings,
Essec, Paris, 1651–6.
Hanssens, D.M., Parsons, L.J. and Schultz, R.L. (2001) Market Response
Models: Econometric and Time Series Analysis, 2nd edition, Dordrecht:
Kluwer Academic.
Hardie, B.G.S., Johnson, E.J. and Fader, P.S. (1993) Modeling loss aversion
and reference dependence effects on brand choice, Marketing Science,
12(4), 378–95.
Harnett, N., Kennedy, R., Sharp, B. and Greenacre, L. (2016) Creative that
sells: how advertising execution affects sales, Journal of Advertising,
45(1), 102–12.
Harrison, A.A. (1968) Response competition, frequency, exploratory
behavior and liking, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 9(4),
363–8.
Hartman, C.L., Price, L.L. and Duncan, C.P. (1990) Consumer evaluation of
franchise extension products. In M.E. Goldberg, G. Gorn and R. Pollay
(eds), Advances in Consumer Research, 17, 110–27.
Hartnett, M. (2006) Coupons still king, Frozen Food Age, Oct., 55(3), p. 41.
Helson, H. (1964) Adaptation Level Theory, New York: Harper & Row.
Heskett, J.L., Sasser, W.E., Jr and Schlesinger, L.A. (1997) The Service
Profit Chain, New York: The Free Press.
Hoch, S.J., Drèze, X. and Purk, M.E. (1994) EDLP, Hi-Lo, and margin
arithmetic, Journal of Marketing, 58(4), 16–28.
Hong, W., Hess, T.J. and Hardin, A. (2013) When filling the wait makes it
feel longer: a paradigm shift perspective for managing online delay, MIS
Quarterly, 37(2), 383–A9.
Howard, J.A. and Sheth, J.N. (1969) The Theory of Buyer Behavior, New
York: Wiley.
Huff, D.L. (1981) Retail location theory. In R.W. Stampfl and E.C.
Hirschman (eds), Theory in Retailing: Traditional and Non-Traditional
Sources, Chicago: American Marketing Association, 108–21.
Hui, M.K. and Bateson, J.E.G. (1991) Perceived control and the effects of
crowding and consumer choice on the service experience, Journal of
Consumer Research, 18(2), 174–84.
Iacobucci, D., Grayson, K.A. and Omstrom, A.L. (1994) The calculus of
service quality and customer satisfaction: theoretical and empirical
differentiation and integration, in T.A. Swartz, D.E. Bowen and S.W.
Brown (eds), Advances in Services Marketing and Management, Vol. 3,
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1–68.
Inman, J.J., McAlister, L. and Hoyer, W.D. (1990) Promotion signal: proxy
for a price cut? Journal of Consumer Research, 17(1), 74–82.
Jin, L., He, Y. and Zhang, Y. (2014) How power states influence
consumers’ perceptions of price unfairness, Journal of Consumer
Research, 40(5), 818–33.
Jones, E.E. and Nisbett, R.E. (1972) The actor and observer: divergent
perceptions of the causes of behavior. In E.E. Jones, D.E. Kanouse, H.H.
Kelley, R.E. Nisbett, S. Valins and B. Weiner (eds), Attribution:
Perceiving the Causes of Behavior, Morristown, NJ: General Learning
Press, 79–94.
Jones, J.P. (1995a) When Ads Work: New Proof that Advertising Triggers
Sales, New York: Lexington Books.
Jones, J.P. (1995b) Single source research begins to fulfill its promise,
Journal of Advertising Research, 35(3), 9–16.
Jones, T.O. and Sasser, W.E. (1995) Why satisfied customers defect,
Harvard Business Review, Nov.–Dec., 88–99.
Kahn, B.E. and McAlister, L. (1997) Grocery Revolution: The New Focus
on the Consumer, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Kahn, B.E., Morrison, D.G. and Wright, G.P. (1986) Aggregating individual
purchases to the household level, Marketing Science, 5(3), 260–8.
Kalafatis, S., Ledden, L., Riley, D. and Singh, J. (2016) The added value of
brand alliances in higher education, Journal of Business Research (e-
pub), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2016.01.028
Kalafatis, S., Remizova, N., Riley, D. and Singh, J. (2012) The differential
impact of brand equity on B2B co-branding, Journal of Business &
Industrial Marketing, 27(8), 623–34.
Kalafatis, S., Riley, D. and Singh, J. (2014) Context effects in the
evaluation of business-to-business brand alliances, Industrial Marketing
Management, 43(2), 322–34.
Kardes, F.R., Cronley, M.L., Kellaris, J.J. and Posanac, S.S. (2004) The role
of selective information processing in price-quality inference, Journal of
Consumer Research, 31(2), 368–74.
Katz, E. (1961) The social itinerary of technical change: two studies on the
diffusion of innovation, Human Organization, 20(Summer), 70–82.
Katz, E. and Lazarsfeld, P.F. (1955) Personal Influence, Glencoe, IL: The
Free Press.
Kau, A.K. and Ehrenberg, A.S.C. (1984) Patterns of store choice, Journal of
Marketing Research, 21(4), 399–409.
Keller, K.L. and Aaker, D.A. (1992) The effects of sequential introduction
of brand extensions, Journal of Marketing Research, 29(1), 35–52.
Keller, K.L. and Lehmann, D.R. (2006) Brands and branding: research
findings and future priorities, Marketing Science, 25(6), 740–59.
Koran, L.M., Faber, R.J., Aboujaoude, E., Large, M.D. and Serpe, R.T.
(2006) Estimated prevalence of compulsive buying behavior in the
United States, American Journal of Psychiatry, 163(10), 1806–12.
Kordupleski, R.E., Rust, R.T. and Zahoric, A.J. (1993) Why improving
quality does not improve retention (or whatever happened to
marketing?), California Management Review, Spring, 82–95.
Kotzan, J.A. and Evanson, R.V. (1969) Responsiveness of drug store sales
to shelf space allocations, Journal of Marketing Research, 6(4), 465–9.
Kumar, N., Scheer, L.K. and Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M. (1995) The effects of
supplier fairness on vulnerable resellers, Journal of Marketing Research,
32(1), 54–65.
Labrecque, L.I., Patrick, V.M. and Milne, G.R. (2013) The marketers’
prismatic palette: a review of color research and future directions,
Psychology & Marketing, 30(2), 187–202.
LaTour, S.A. and Peat, N.C. (1979) Conceptual and methodological issues
in consumer satisfaction research. In W.L. Wilkie (ed.), Advances in
Consumer Research, 6, 431–7.
Leclerc, F., Schmitt, B.H. and Dubé, L. (1995) Waiting time and decision
making: is time like money? Journal of Consumer Research, 22(1), 110–
19.
Lee, L. and Tsai, C.I. (2014) How price promotions influence postpurchase
consumption experience over time, Journal of Consumer Research, 40(5),
943–59.
Leenheer, J., van Heerde, H.J., Bijmolt, T.H.A. and Smidts, A. (2007) Do
loyalty programs really enhance behavioral loyalty? An empirical
analysis accounting for self-selecting members, International Journal of
Research in Marketing, 24(1), 31–47.
Lees, G. and Wright, M. (2012) Does the duplication of viewing law apply
to radio listening? European Journal of Marketing, 47(3–4), 674–85.
Lees, G.J., Garland, B.R. and Wright, M.J. (2007) Switching banks: old
bank gone but not forgotten, Journal of Financial Services Marketing,
12(2), 146–56.
Les Échos (2004) Étendre sa marque, un pari souvent gagnat. No. 19301, 7
December, 15. Available at
http://archives.lesechos.fr/archives/2004/LesEchos/19301-50-ECH.htm
Lichtenstein, S., Slovic, P., Fischoff, B., Lyman, M. and Combs, B. (1978)
Judged frequency of lethal events, Journal of Experimental Psychology:
Human Learning and Memory, 4, 551–78.
Liu, Y. (2006) Word of mouth for movies: its dynamics and influence on
box office revenue, Journal of Marketing, 70(3), 74–89.
Liyin, J., Yanqun, H. and Ying, Z. (2014) How power states influence
consumers’ perceptions of price unfairness, Journal of Consumer
Research, 40(5), 818–33.
Lodish, L.M., Abraham, M., Kalmansen, S., Livelsberger, J., Lubetkin, B.,
Richardson, B. and Stevens, M.E. (1995a) How TV advertising works: a
meta-analysis of 389 real-world split cable TV advertising experiments,
Journal of Marketing Research, 32(2), 125–39.
Lomax, W., Hammond, K., Clemente, M. and East, R. (1996) New entrants
in a mature market: an empirical study of the detergent market, Journal of
Marketing Management, 12(4), 281–95.
Madden, T.J., Ellen, P.S. and Ajzen, I. (1992) A comparison of the theory of
planned behavior and the theory of reasoned action, Personality and
Social Psychology Bulletin, 18(1), 3–9.
Madzharov, A.V., Block, L.G. and Morrin, M. (2015) The cool scent of
power: effects of ambient scent on consumer preferences and choice
behaviour, Journal of Marketing, 79(1), 83–96.
Mägi, A.W. (2003) Share of wallet in retailing: the effects of customer
satisfaction loyalty cards and shopper characteristics, Journal of
Retailing, 79(2), 97–106.
Magnini, V.P., Ford, J.B., Markowski, E.P. and Honeycut, E.D., Jr (2007)
The service recovery paradox: justifiable theory or smouldering myth,
Journal of Services Marketing, 21(3), 213–24.
Mahajan, V., Muller, E. and Bass, F.M. (1990) New product diffusion
models in marketing: a review and directions for research, Journal of
Marketing, 54(1), 1–26.
Malafi, T.N., Cini, M.A., Taub, S.L. and Bertolami, J. (1993) Social
influence and the decision to complain: investigations on the role of
advice, Journal of Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction and
Complaining Behavior, 6, 81–9.
Manning, K.C. and Sprott, D.E. (2009) Price endings, left-digit effects, and
choice, Journal of Consumer Research, 36(2), 328–35.
Marcel, J. (1976) Unconscious reading: experiments on people who do not
know they are reading. Paper presented at the British Association for the
Advancement of Science, Lancaster, UK, 1–8 September.
Marx, K. (1930/1867) Capital, Vols 1, 2 and 3, London: J.M. Dent & Sons.
Mazumdar, T., Raj, S.P. and Sinha, I. (2005) Reference price research:
review and propositions, Journal of Marketing, 69(4), 84–102.
McPhee, W.N. (1963) Formal Theories of Mass Behavior, Glencoe, IL: The
Free Press.
Mela, C.F., Gupta, S. and Lehmann, D.R. (1997) The long-term impact of
promotion and advertising on consumer choice, Journal of Marketing
Research, 34(2), 248–61.
Melnyk, V., van Osselaer, S.M.J. and Bijmolt, T.H.A. (2009) Are women
more loyal customers than men? Gender differences in loyalty to firms
and individual service providers, Journal of Marketing, 73(4), 82–96.
Michon, R., Chebat, J.-C. and Turley, L.W. (2005) Mall atmospherics: the
interaction effects of the mall environment on shopping behaviour,
Journal of Business Research, 58(5), 576–83.
Mittal, V., Ross, W.T. and Baldasare, P.M. (1998) The asymmetric impact
of negative and positive attribute-level performance on overall
satisfaction and repurchase intentions, Journal of Marketing, 62(1), 33–
47.
Mohr, L.A. and Bitner, M.J. (1995) The role of employee effort in
satisfaction with service transactions, Journal of Business Research,
32(3), 239–52.
Monroe, K.B. and Lee, A.V. (1999) Remembering versus knowing: issues
in buyers’ processing of price information, Journal of the Academy of
Marketing Science, 27(2), 207–25.
Morgan, N.A. and Rego, L.L. (2006) The value of different customer
satisfaction and loyalty metrics in predicting business performance,
Marketing Science, 25(5), 426–39.
Morin, S., Dubé, L. and Chebat, J.-C. (2007) The role of pleasant music in
servicescapes: a test of the dual model of environmental perception,
Journal of Retailing, 83(1), 115–30.
Morrison, D. and Schmittlein, D.C. (1988) Generalizing the NBD model for
customer purchases: what are the implications and is it worth the effort?
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 6(2), 145–66.
Morrison, M., Gan, S., Dubelaar, C. and Oppewal, H. (2011) In-store music
and aroma influences on shopper behavior and satisfaction, Journal of
Business Research, 64(6), 558–64.
Narisetti, R. (1997) Move to drop coupons puts Procter & Gamble in sticky
PR situation, Wall Street Journal, 17 April, 1, A10.
Neslin, S.A. and Clarke, D.G. (1987) Relating the brand use profile of
coupon redeemers to brand and coupon characteristics, Journal of
Advertising Research, 27(1), 23–32.
Neslin, S.A. and Stone, L.G.S. (1996) Consumer inventory sensitivity and
the postpromotion dip, Marketing Letters, 7(1), 77–94.
Nielsen (2005) Retail Pocket Book, 2006. Oxford: WARC and AC Nielsen.
North, A.C., Hargreaves, D.J. and Hargreaves, J.J. (2004) The uses of
music in everyday life, Music Perception, 22(1), 41–77.
Nunes, J.C. and Drèze, X. (2006) The endowed progress effect: how
artificial advancement increases effort, Journal of Consumer Research,
32(4), 504–12.
Osgood, J.F., Suci, G.J. and Tannenbaum, P.H. (1957) The Measurement of
Meaning, Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press.
Parasuraman, A., Berry, L.L. and Zeithaml, V.A. (1991) Refinement and
reassessment of the SERVQUAL scale, Journal of Retailing, 67(4), 420–
50.
Pauwels, K., Hanssens, D.M. and Siddarth, S. (2002) The long-term effects
of price promotions on category incidence, brand choice, and purchase
quantity, Journal of Marketing Research, 39(4), 421–39.
Pere, V. and Dawes, J. (2012) The persistence of excess brand loyalty over
multiple years, Marketing Letters, 23(1), 163–75.
Petty, R.E. and Cacioppo, J.Y. (1986) The elaboration likelihood model of
persuasion. In L. Berkowitz (ed.), Advances in Experimental Social
Psychology, 19, New York: Academic Press.
Pieters, R. and Warlop, L. (1999) Visual attention during brand choice: the
impact of time pressure and task motivation, International Journal of
Research in Marketing, 16(1), 1–16.
Pritchard, M.P., Havitz, M.E. and Howard, D.R. (1999) Analyzing the
commitment–loyalty link in service contexts, Journal of the Academy of
Marketing Science, 27(3), 333–48.
Raj, S.P. (1982) The effects of advertising on high and low loyalty
segments, Journal of Advertising Research, 9(1), 77–89.
Raju, J. and Zhang, Z.J. (2010) Smart Pricing, Upper Saddle River, NJ:
Pearson Prentice Hall.
Randall, D.M. and Wolff, J.A. (1994) The time interval in the intention–
behaviour relationship, British Journal of Social Psychology, 33(4), 405–
18.
Rao, A.R. and Monroe, K.R. (1989) The effect of price, brand name, and
store name on buyers’ perceptions of product quality: an integrative
review, Journal of Marketing Research, 26(3), 351–58.
Reichheld, F.F. (with Teal, T.) (1996b) The Loyalty Effect, Boston: Harvard
Business School Publications.
Reichheld, F.F. (2003) The one number you need to grow, Harvard Business
Review, 81(12), 46–54.
Reichheld, F.F. and Sasser, W.E. (1990) Zero defections: quality comes to
services, Harvard Business Review, 68(5), Sept.–Oct., 105–11.
Reilly, W.J. (1929) Methods for the Study of Retail Relationships, Austin,
TX: Bureau of Business Research Studies in Marketing, No. 4.
Riebe, E., Wright, M., Stern, P. and Sharp, B. (2014) How to grow a brand:
retain or acquire customers? Journal of Business Research, 67(5), 990–7.
Rogers, E.M. (1962) Diffusion of Innovations, 1st edition, New York: The
Free Press.
Rogers, E.M. (2003) Diffusion of Innovations, 5th edition, New York: The
Free Press.
Rokeach, M.J. (1973) The Nature of Human Values, New York: The Free
Press.
Ryan, B. and Gross, N.C. (1943) The diffusion of hybrid seed corn in two
Iowa communities, Rural Sociology, 8, 15–24, as cited in E.M. Rogers
(2003) Diffusion of Innovations, 5th edition, New York: The Free Press.
Saegert, S.C. and Jellison, J.M. (1970) Effects of initial level of response
competition and frequency of exposure on liking and exploratory
behavior, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 16(3), 553–8.
Sasser, W.E. (1976) Match supply and demand in the service industry,
Harvard Business Review, 54(6), 133–8.
Sattler, H., Völckner, F., Riediger, C. and Ringle, C.M. (2010) The impact
of brand extension success drivers on brand extension price premiums,
International Journal of Research in Marketing, 27(4), 319–28.
Scherhorn, G., Reisch, L.A. and Raab, G. (1990) Addictive buying in West
Germany: an empirical study, Journal of Consumer Policy, 13, 355–87.
Schindler, R.M. and Kirby, P.N. (1997) Patterns of rightmost digits used in
advertised prices: implications for nine-ending effects, Journal of
Consumer Research, 24(2), 192–201.
Schmitt, P., Skiera, B. and Van den Bulte, C. (2011) Referral programs and
customer value, Journal of Marketing, 75(1), 46–59.
Schmittlein, D.C., Bemmaor, A.C. and Morrison, D.G. (1985) Why does
the NBD model work? Robustness in representing product purchases,
brand purchases and imperfectly recorded purchases, Marketing Science,
4(3), 255–66.
Schmittlein, D.C., Cooper, L.G. and Morrison, D.G. (1993) Truth in
concentration in the land of (80/20) laws, Marketing Science, 12(2), 167–
83.
Seawright, K.K. and Sampson, S.E. (2007) A video method for empirically
studying wait-perception bias, Journal of Operations Management, 25(5),
1055–66.
Sharp, B., Beal, V. and Collins, M. (2009) Television: back to the future,
Journal of Advertising Research, 49(2), 211–19.
Sharp, B., Wright, M.J. and Goodhardt, G.J. (2002) Purchase loyalty is
polarised into either repertoire or subscription patterns, Australasian
Marketing Journal, 10(3), 7–20.
Shogren, J.F., Shin, S.Y., Hayes, D.J. and Kliebenstein, J.B. (1994)
Resolving differences in willingness to pay and willingness to accept,
American Economic Review, 84(1), 255–70.
Shukla, P., Singh, J. and Banerjee, M.(2015) They are not all same:
variations in Asian consumers’ value perceptions of luxury brands,
Marketing Letters, 26(3), 265–78.
Simcock, P., Sudbury, L. and Wright, G. (2006) Age, perceived risk and
satisfaction in consumer decision making: a review and extension,
Journal of Marketing Management, 22(3), 355–77.
Simon, C.J. and Sullivan, M.W. (1993) The measurement and determinants
of brand equity: a financial approach, Marketing Science, 12(1), 28–52.
Simon, J.L. (1979) What do Zielske’s real data show about pulsing? Journal
of Marketing Research, 16(3), 415–20.
Simon, J.L. and Arndt, J. (1980) The shape of the advertising response
function, Journal of Advertising Research, 20(4), 11–28.
Singh, J., Dall’Olmo Riley, F., Hand, C. and Maeda, M. (2012) Measuring
brand choice in older customers in Japan, International Journal of Market
Research, 54(3), 347–68.
Singh, J., Scriven, J., Clemente, M., Lomax, W. and Wright, M. (2012) New
brand extensions: patterns of success and failure, Journal of Advertising
Research, 52(2), 234–42.
Skowronski, J.J. and Carlston, D.E. (1989) Negativity and extremity biases
in impression formation: a review of explanations, Psychological
Bulletin, 105(1), 131–42.
Smith, D.C. and Park, C.W. (1992) The effects of brand extensions on
market share and advertising efficiency, Journal of Marketing Research,
29(3), 296–313.
Spence, C., Puccinelli, N.M., Grewal, D. and Roggeveen, A.L. (2014) Store
atmospherics: a multisensory perspective, Psychology & Marketing,
31(7), 472–88.
Swan, J.E. and Trawick, I.F. (1980) Satisfaction related to predicted versus
desired expectations. In H.K. Hunt and R.L. Day (eds), Refining
Concepts and Measures of Consumer Satisfaction and Complaining
Behavior, Bloomington, IN: School of Business, Indiana University, 7–
12.
Tate, R.S. (1961) The supermarket battle for store loyalty, Journal of
Marketing, 25(6), 8–13.
Tauber, E.M. (1981) Brand franchise extension: new product benefits from
existing brand names, Business Horizons, 24, 36–41.
Taylor, S. (1994) Waiting for service: the relationship between delays and
evaluations of service, Journal of Marketing, 58(2), 56–69.
Taylor, S. (1995) The effects of filled waiting time and service provider
control over the delay on evaluations of service, Journal of the Academy
of Marketing Science, 23(1), 38–48.
Tellis, G.J. and Wernerfelt, B. (1987) Competitive price and quality under
asymmetric information, Marketing Science, 6(3), 240–54.
Thomas, M. and Morwitz, V. (2005) Penny wise and pound foolish: the left-
digit effect in price cognition, Journal of Consumer Research, 32(1), 54–
64.
Totten, J.C. and Block, M.P. (1987) Analyzing Sales Promotion: Text and
Cases, Chicago: Commerce Communications Inc.
Triandis, H.C. (1989) Self and social behavior in differing cultural contexts,
Psychological Review, 96, 506–20.
Triandis, H.C. (2004) The many dimensions of culture, Academy of
Management Executive, 18(1), 88–93.
Trinh, G., Rungie, C., Wright, M., Driesener, C. and Dawes, J. (2014)
Predicting future purchases with the Poisson log-normal model,
Marketing Letters, 25(2), 219–34.
Tuttle, B. (2013) The 5 big mistakes that led to Ron Johnson’s ouster at JC
Penney,Time Magazine, April. Available at
http://business.time.com/2013/04/09/the-5-big-mistakes-that-led-to-ron-
johnsons-ouster-at-jc-penney/
Uncles, M., East, R. and Lomax, W. (2010a) Market share is correlated with
word-of-mouth volume, Australasian Marketing Journal, 18(3), 145–50.
Uncles, M., East, R. and Lomax, W. (2013) Good customers: the value of
customers by mode of acquisition, Australasian Marketing Journal, 21(2),
119–25.
Uncles, M., Kennedy, R., Nenyz-Thiel, M., Singh, J. and Kwok, S. (2012)
User profiles for competing brands seldom differ: re-examining the
evidence, Journal of Advertising Research, 52(2), 252–61.
Uncles, M.D. and Ehrenberg, A.S.C. (1990) The buying of packaged goods
at US retail chains, Journal of Retailing, 66(3), 278–96.
Usunier, J.C. and Lee, J. (2011) Marketing Across Cultures, 5th edition,
Harlow: Pearson.
Van der Plight, J. and van Schie, E.C.M. (1990) Frames of reference,
judgement and preference. In W. Stroebe and M. Hewstone (eds),
European Review of Social Psychology, 1, Chichester: Wiley & Sons,
61–80.
van Heerde, H.J., Leeflang, P.S.H. and Wittink, D.R. (2004) Decomposing
the sales promotion bump with store data, Marketing Science, 23(3),
317–34.
Vanhuele, M. (1994) Mere exposure and the cognitive-affective debate
revisited. In C.T. Allen and D.R. John (eds), Advances in Consumer
Research, 21, 264–9.
Varan, D., Lang, A., Barwise, P., Weber, R. and Bellman, S. (2015) How
reliable are neuromarketers’ measures of advertising effectiveness? Data
from ongoing research holds no common truth among vendors, Journal of
Advertising Research, 55(June), 176–91.
Vargo, S.L. and Lusch, R.F. (2004) Evolving to a new dominant logic for
marketing, Journal of Marketing, 68(1), 1–17.
Venkatraman, V., Dimoka, A., Pavlou, P.A., Vo, K., Hampton, W.,
Bollinger, B.B., et al. (2015) Predicting advertising success beyond
traditional measures: new insights from neurophysiological methods and
market response modeling, Journal of Marketing Research, 52(4), 436–
52.
Verhoef, P.C. (2003) Understanding the effect of customer relationship
management efforts on customer retention and customer share
development, Journal of Marketing, 67(Oct.), 30–45.
Verhoef, P.C., Franses, P.H. and Hoekstra, J.C. (2002) The effect of
relational constructs on customer referrals and number of services
purchased from a multiservice provider: does age of relationship matter?
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 30(3), 202–16.
Viscusi, W.K. (1984) The lulling effect: the impact of child resistant
packaging on aspirin and analgesic ingestions, American Economic
Review, 74(2), 324–7.
Wadhwa, M. and Kuangjie, Z. (2015) This number just feels right: the
impact of roundedness of price numbers on product evaluations, Journal
of Consumer Research, 41(5), 1172–85.
Wakefield, K.L. and Inman, J.J. (1993) Who are the price vigilantes? An
investigation of differentiating characteristics influencing price
information processing, Journal of Retailing, 69(2), 216–34.
Watts, D.J. and Dodds, P.S. (2007) Influentials, networks, and public
opinion formation, Journal of Consumer Research, 34(Dec.), 441–58.
Whyte, W.H. (1954) The web of word of mouth, Fortune, 50(Nov.), 140.
Wilbur, K.C. and Farris, P.W. (2014) Distribution and market share,Journal
of Retailing, 90(2), 154–67.
Wood, L.A. and Poltrack, D.F. (2015) Measuring the long-term effects of
advertising: Nielsen-CBS study uses single-source data to reassess the
‘two-times’multiplier, Journal of Advertising Research, 55(2), 123–31.
Xia, L., Monroe, K.B. and Cox, J.L. (2004) The price is unfair! A
conceptual framework of price fairness perceptions, Journal of
Marketing, 68(4), 1–15.
Yalch, R. and Spangenberg, E. (2000) Using store music for retail zoning: a
field experiment. In L. McAlister and M.L. Rothschild (eds), Advances
in Consumer Research, 20, 632–6.
Zajonc, R.B. and Rajecki, D.W. (1969) Exposure and affect: a field
experiment, Psychonomic Science, 17, 216–17.
Zeithaml, V.A. (2000) Service quality, profitability, and the economic worth
of customers: what we know and what we need to learn, Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science, 28(1), 67–85.
Zettelmeyer, F., Morton, F.S. and Silva-Risso, J. (2006) How the Internet
lowers prices: evidence from matched survey and auto transaction data,
Journal of Marketing Research, 43(2), 168–81.
Zhang, H., Sung, J., Liu, F. and Knight, J.G. (2014) Be rational or be
emotional: advertising appeals, services types and consumer responses,
European Journal of Marketing, 48(11/12), 2105–26.
Zhang, J., Beatty, S.E. and Walsh, G. (2008) Review and future directions
of cross-cultural consumer services research, Journal of Business
Research, 61(3), 211–24.
Habel, C., 76
habit model, 6–7, 12–13
habits, 32–33, 240
Hackett, P.M.W., 227
Hamilton, W., 277
Hammond, K., 37
Hanssens, D.M., 281–282, 289
Hardie, B.G.S., 204
Hargreaves Lansdown, 8
Harnett, N., 282
Harrison, A.A., 159, 160
Hartman, C.L., 59
Heath, R., 291
Heath, T.B., 57
heavy-half principle, 71–73
heavy shoppers, 237, 293–294
Heilman, C.M., 223
Hellman’s, 51–52
Helson, H., 204
Hemenway, D., 194
Hennig-Thurau, T., 42, 262
heuristics, 163–166
Hi-Lo strategy, 217
Higgins, M., 35
Highley, J., 235
Hirschman, A.O., 179, 193
Hoch, S.J, 217
Hofstede, G., 113–114, 115–117, 115, 117, 121
Hogg, A., 38
Holden, S.J.S., 59, 60
Holmes, J.G., 153
Homburg, C., 207
Horsky, D., 288
Howard, J.A., 183
Howell, R., 193
Huff, D.L., 227
Hui, M.K., 122, 246
Hunt, H.K., 32–33
imitation, 104
individualism–collectivism, 115–116, 115, 120–122
influentials, 22
Information Resources Inc. (IRI), 28–29, 218–219, 280–281, 284, 289
Inman, J.J., 206, 219
innovation
models of, 98–107, 99, 102, 105, 107
national cultural differences and, 121
word of mouth and, 249–250
innovators, 100
intention, 146–150
Interbrand Group, 64n1
internal reference prices (IRP), 204–205
Internet
advertising effect and, 295–297
complaining and, 192–193, 193
customized promotions and, 223–224
decision-making and, 14–15, 15
delays and, 195–196
loyalty and, 236–237
price experiments and, 210
word of mouth and, 251–253, 295
investment, 173–174
involvement, 6
iPhone, 48, 48
Isherwood, B.C., 142, 143
Iyengar, R., 262