0% found this document useful (0 votes)
101 views

Introduction To Game Theory Problem Set #1: Jörgen Weibull

This document contains 7 problems related to game theory. Problem 1 involves finding Nash equilibria in 2x2 games. Problem 2 models public good provision as a game. Problems 3-7 involve analyzing extensive form games, normal form representations, and equilibrium concepts such as Nash and subgame perfect equilibrium.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
101 views

Introduction To Game Theory Problem Set #1: Jörgen Weibull

This document contains 7 problems related to game theory. Problem 1 involves finding Nash equilibria in 2x2 games. Problem 2 models public good provision as a game. Problems 3-7 involve analyzing extensive form games, normal form representations, and equilibrium concepts such as Nash and subgame perfect equilibrium.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 3

Introduction to Game Theory

Problem Set #1
Jörgen Weibull

1. Consider the following 2 × 2 normal-form game G, for arbitrary a, b > 0:

H T
H a, 0 0, b
T 0, b 1, 0

(i) Find all pure and mixed Nash equilibria in G.


(ii) For each pure or mixed Nash equilibrium in G, and each player, find the
player’s set of pure and mixed best replies to the equilibrium in question.
2. Two individuals, 1 and 2, contribute to a public good (say, a clean shared
kitchen) by making individual efforts x ∈ [0, 1] and y ∈ [0, 1]. The resulting
level of the public good is x + y. Individual utilities are given by

u1 (x, y) = (x + y) e−x and u2 (x, y) = (x + y) e−y

Each individual strives to maximize his or her expected utility.


(a) Game A: Suppose both effort levels are chosen simultaneously. Write
up the normal form of Game A! Is this a Euclidean game? Does it have
a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium? Find the set of pure-strategy Nash
equilibria!
(b) Game B: Suppose individual 1 first chooses her effort level, and that
this is observed by individual 2, who then chooses his effort level. Write up
the normal form of Game B! Is it a Euclidean game? Does it have a pure-
strategy Nash equilibrium? Find its unique subgame perfect equilibrium
in pure strategies!
(c) Does there exist a Nash equilibrium in Game B in which individual 2
makes effort x2 = 1/2? (Either prove than none exists or specify one such
equilibrium.)
3. Consider an n-player simultaneous game, with normal form G, in which
each player has k pure strategies, which we below will call actions.
(i) How many pure-strategy profiles does G have? How does this number
grow if k is doubled, if n is doubled?
(ii) Suppose that the game is played twice, and that all players, before
chosing their second-period action, observes the first-period action profile,
and hence can condition their second-period action upon this observation.
Let G2 be the normal form of the so-defined game. How many pure

1
strategies does each player have in G2 when n = k = 2? When n = 2 and
k = 10?
(iii) Is it true that the game G2 necessarily has at least one Nash equilib-
rium in pure strategies, for any possible assignment of Bernoulli values?
(iv) Is it true that the game G2 necessarily has at least one Nash equilib-
rium in mixed strategies, for any possible assignment of Bernoulli values?
4. Draw the extensive form for a strategic interaction in which player 1 has
a binary choice, to take action A or B, and where the interaction ends if 1
takes action A but continues if he takes action B. In the latter case, player
2 learns that 1 took action B, and player 2 then has a binary choice, to
take action C or D. If player 1 ends the game by taking action A, then
each player receives 5 euros. If player 2 ends the game by taking action C
then player 1 receives 6 euros and player 2 receives 1 euro, while if player
2 ends the game by taking action D then both players receive nothing.
(a) Suppose that each player’s payoff (that he or she strives to maximize)
is his or her monetary gain, and solve the so-defined game by backward
induction.
(b) Suppose instead that player 1 is an altruist in the sense that her payoff
is the sum of both player’s monetary gains, but player 2 is selfish and only
care about his own gain. Solve the so-defined game by backward induction.
(c) Suppose instead that player 1 is selfish and only cares about her own
monetary gain, while player 2 is spiteful against people who take action
B (1 thinks of such persons as greedy). More exactly, 1’s payoffs are as
case (a) above, while 2’s payoff is 5 if player 1 takes action A, but x − y if
player 1 takes action B, where x is 2’s monetary gain and y that of player
1. Compare the equilibrium behavior of the selfish player 1 with that of
the altruistic player 1 in (b).
5. Consider n firms competing in a product market with demand D (p) =
max {0, a − p}, for some a > 0. In stage 1 of the interaction, each firm i
selects its output level qi ∈ [0, 100], without observing other firms’ outputs.
Let Q = q1 + ... + qn . In stage 2, the market price is determined by the
equation
D (p) = Q = q1 + ... + qn
Suppose that the profit to firm i is π i = (p − ci ) qi , for some ci < a.
Suppos that each firm strives to maximize its profit.
(a) Let n = 2 and suppose that both firms’ managers are rational and that
their rationality and all the details of the game (including their costs) are
common knowledge between them (each knows this and knows that the
other knows this etc. ad infinitum). Show that this uniquely determines
their output levels, and that this coincides with the unique Nash equilib-
rium of the game.
(c) Analyze the questions in (a) but now for an arbitrary finite number n
of firms, and study how the outcome depends on n. In particular, what
happens as n → ∞?

2
6. Consider the extensive-form game Γ given below.

(5,2) (0,0) (2,0) (0,3)

l r l r

(3,1)
L R

L R

(a) Verify that Γ has perfect recall and that it has two subgames.
(b) Write up its pure-strategy normal form, as well as its quasi-reduced,
reduced normal form, and agent normal form.
(c) Prove directly that the claim in Kuhn’s Theorem holds in this game.
(That is, that there for each mixed strategy in the normal form of the
game exists a realization-equivalent behavior strategy.
(d) Find the set of pure-strategy Nash equilibria.
7. Consider a two-player finite extensive-form game of perfect information,
ΓT , defined as follows: At each decision node, the player in question has
only two choice alternatives, or moves, to go L or R. The players take
turns: first player 1 chooses between L and R, then 2 observes 1’s choice
and chooses L or R, then 1 observes 2’s choice and makes his move, etc.
until both players have made T moves each. The game thus has “length”
2T , where T is a positive integer.
(i) How many pure strategies does each of the players have in this game
when T = 2? When T = 3?
(ii) For arbitrary T ∈ N?
(iii) Let T ∈ N and suppose that the Bernoulli values in ΓT have been
drawn at random, i.i.d. and normally distributed. After the realization
of this draw, both players know all Bernoulli values. What is the prob-
ability, from the perspective of an outside observer, that the so created
game has at least one Nash equilibrium in pure strategies? What is the
probability that the game has at least one subgame perfect equilibrium in
pure strategies?

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy