Brandt - 2014 - From Divergence To Convergence
Brandt - 2014 - From Divergence To Convergence
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.52.1.45
* Brandt: University of Toronto. Ma: London School Rubie Watson, Jeffrey Williamson, Bin Wong, Tim Wright,
of Economics and Shanghai University of Finance and Se Yan, Jan Luiten van Zanden, Madeleine Zelin and par-
Economics. Rawski: University of Pittsburgh. We have ticipants in the May 2010 and September 2012 Asian
received valuable advice from many colleagues, including Historical Economics Conferences, and the January 2013
Masahiko Aoki, Timothy Brook, James Cassing, Nicolas Third Annual Conference on the Chinese Economy (in
Crafts, Wendy Dobson, Ronald A. Edwards, Joshua Fogel, Hong Kong). We would also like to thank Janet Currie and
Phil Hoffman, Ralph Huenemann, Wolfgang Keller, Peter four anonymous referees for their very helpful suggestions.
Lindert, LIU Pei, LI Bozhong, LONG Denggao, Deirdre Debin Ma acknowledges financial support from Global Price
McCloskey, Joel Mokyr, Andrew Nathan, Margaret and Income Project (http://gpih.ucdavis.edu/) funded by
Pearson, Dwight Perkins, Kenneth Pomeranz, Evelyn National Science Foundation. The usual disclaimer applies.
†
Rawski, Tirthankar Roy, Roger Sahs, Carole Shiue, Richard Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.52.1.45 to visit the
Smethurst, Paul Smith, Tuan-hwee Sng, Werner Troesken, article page and view author disclosure statement(s).
45
46 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
More recently, James Lee, LI Bozhong, deepen our insight into historical realities
Kenneth Pomeranz, R. Bin Wong, and and vice versa.
others identified as the “California school” Several specific questions will help to unify
have reshaped perspectives on the dyna- much of what follows:
mism and development of the mid-Qing
(1644–1911) economy. Pomeranz, in par- 1. Why was China unable to capitalize
ticular, sees little difference in economic on its early economic and technologi-
structure or per capita income between the cal leadership? Why did China become
most commercialized regions of China and a laggard among major global econo-
Europe prior to the British industrial revo- mies by the nineteenth century, if not
lution. With development in both regions before?
constrained by limited land, Pomeranz attri- 2. Once the Industrial Revolution was well
butes Britain’s head start in industrialization underway, a succession of countries in
to cheap coal and superior access through Europe, Asia, and the Americas fol-
its colonies to land-intensive goods, rather lowed England’s lead. Why was China
than to any advantage linked to political, slow to take advantage of economic
legal, or other institutional factors (2000). opportunities linked to the dissemina-
These bold claims have kindled intense con- tion of new technology?
troversy, sparked efforts to expand empirical 3. How do we explain the timing and
comparisons spanning Europe and Asia, and unique scale of China’s post-1978
catapulted Chinese economic history from breakthrough?
a narrow specialty to a central concern of
global historical studies.5 The first of these questions is the most
The present review6 seeks to illuminate difficult to answer. We are more optimis-
the historical antecedents of recent Chinese tic about tackling the second and the third.
dynamism, to specify the constraints that hin- We anticipate—and here we disagree with
dered the realization of China’s latent poten- the California school—that institutions will
tial prior to the start of the recent growth figure prominently in explaining both the
spurt, and to track the gradual relaxation of long delay in the onset of rapid growth and
these constraints during the course of the the mechanisms underlying China’s recent
twentieth century. Our analysis of China’s growth spurt.
current boom, as well as the modest advances We begin with a survey of the long-term
of the late nineteenth and early twentieth evolution of China’s economy. Since we
centuries, helps to clarify the nature and regard institutions as a crucial but neglected
impact of earlier constraints. In this way, factor that can contribute to understanding
we believe that recent developments can both the failures and the triumphs of China’s
economy during the past two centuries, we
then turn to an analysis of China’s modern
5 The breadth and intensity of the debate on the his- history from the perspective of political
torical comparison of economic growth between China economy. Starting with a summary of the
and the West is evident from the Economic History Net more robust stylized facts of the imperial
forum “Rethinking 18th Century China” http://eh.net/
forums/ChinaSum.html and in a debate between Andre Chinese economy, we lay out a broad ana-
Gunder Frank and David Landes at http://www.worldhis- lytic framework for analyzing the political
torycenter.org/whc/seminar/pastyears/frank-landes/Frank- economy of China’s premodern system that
Landes_01.htm
6 Previous surveys include Feuerwerker (1961, 1992), has links to China’s post-1949 system, both
King (1969), and Deng (2000). before and after the onset of the economic
48 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
reform initiatives of the late 1970s. Finally, Republic of China (PRC) approximates that
we briefly examine the growth spurt of the Qing, except for the border changes
following China’s post-1978 reforms with
in what are labeled “Xinjiang, Mongolia,
an eye to continuities, as well as departures and Manchuria.” Major rivers—the natural
from historic patterns. arteries of preindustrial commerce—flow
from west to east.
China’s economic history covers several
2. Long-Term Evolution
millennia. Although certain features of the
of China’s Economy
economic, political, and social system span
Map 1 indicates the territories con- much longer periods, our survey highlights
trolled by the Ming (1368–1644) and the far major elements during the period since the
larger dominions of the Qing (1644–1911) mid-fourteenth century encompassing the
emperors.7 The territory of today’s People’s Ming and Qing dynasties and the ensuing
7 Although the map locates Taiwan outside the Qing island between 1683 and 1895, when it passed into the
borders, the Qing exercised effective control over the hands of Japan.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 49
Republican period (1912–49), which ended The late Joseph Needham’s massive vol-
with the defeat and exile of the Nationalist umes on Science and Civilization in China
government led by CHIANG Kai-shek (summarized in Needham and Ronan 1978)
(JIANG Jieshi) and the establishment of the document the extraordinary spurt of Tang–
People’s Republic of China in 1949. Our Song innovation, including breakthroughs
objective is two-fold: to acquaint nonspecial- in gunpowder, the magnetic compass,
ist readers with key features of China’s pre- movable type, paper, and shipbuilding—
1800 economy, and to highlight broad areas improvements that commanded world-wide
of agreement among specialized researchers admiration:
that can serve as building blocks for subse- Printing, gunpowder and the compass: These
quent analysis and interpretation. three have changed the face and state of things
We preface discussion of fundamental throughout the world; the first in literature,
features of the Ming–Qing economy with a the second in warfare, the third in navigation;
brief discussion of the earlier Song era (960– whence have followed innumerable changes,
in so much that no empire, no sect, no star
1279), which is essential because specialists seems to have exerted greater power and influ-
often view Ming–Qing history in light of the ence in human affairs than these mechanical
Song era, jumping over the short-lived Yuan discoveries” (Bacon 1960).
or Mongol reign (1279–1368).
Needham’s works establish China as the
2.1 Song as the Peak? global leader in many fields of scientific and
technological endeavor until perhaps the
The Song (960–1279) and its Tang (618– fourteenth century. Why this advantage did
907) precursor brought sweeping change not lead to an industrial revolution is known
to China’s economy and society. Major new as the “Needham puzzle” (Lin 1995; Deng
developments included the formation of 2003).
institutions and structures that evolved into Deep institutional change and techno-
foundations of what historians see as “tradi- logical progress (which may be linked—see
tional” or “premodern” China: consolidation Francesca Bray 1994) had major qualitative
of political control in the emperor’s hands; a impact on the Song economy. Some schol-
tax system based on registration and assess- ars, notably Jones (1988), go further, depict-
ment of privately-held land; a merit-based ing the Southern Song (1127–1289), as an
civil service staffed by commoners rather early and remarkable episode of “intensive”
than aristocrats; and the use of written growth—meaning increases in urbaniza-
examinations to create a pool of candidates tion, marketed agricultural surplus, and the
for official appointments, accompanied by level of per capita income—that subsequent
a shift to an agricultural regime based on dynasties failed to replicate. Skinner con-
small-holder ownership and tenancy, the cludes that “levels of urbanization achieved
expansion of markets for commodities and in the most advanced regions were higher
factors, the penetration of money in com- in the medieval [i.e. Song] era than in late
mercial exchange, and the extensive devel- imperial times” (1977b, p. 28).
opment of private commerce.8 Maddison’s estimates or guess-estimates
of global economic aggregates, summarized
in table 1, reflect this “Song peak” thesis,
8 Modern scholarship in this area begins with the so-
called NAITO thesis, named after the pre-war Japanese
scholar NAIT O¯ K o
¯ n
an. Miyakawa (1955) summarizes (2004) cites an array of relevant work by Chinese, Japanese,
his thesis. Von Glahn’s review of recent monetary studies and western researchers.
50 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
Table 1
China’s Economy in Global Perspective: Angus Maddison’s Long-Term Estimates
1000 1500 1600 1700 1820 1870 1913 1950 1973 1998
Absolute values
Population 59 103 160 138 381 358 437 547 882 1,243
GDP 26.5 61.8 96 82.8 28.6 189.7 241.3 239.9 740 3,873.3
GDP per capita 450 600 600 600 600 530 552 439 839 3,117
Note: Population is in millions; GDP in billions of 1990 international dollars; per capita GDP in 1990 international
dollars.
Source: Angus Maddison (2001, Tables B-10, B18, and B-21).
of demographic behavior build on family system (1959, p. 270) and the population
genealogies and other micro-level data.9 totals that it generated.11 Coming between
Careful empirical study of China’s his- the relatively firm totals for 1400 (70 million)
torical demography begins with the work of and 1794 (310 million), the invasion from
Ho (1959), who examined the institutional China’s northeast (Manchuria) that ousted
dimensions of census taking during the Ming the Ming and established Qing rule (circa
(1368–1644) and Qing (1644–1911) dynas- 1644) resulted in significant, but unquan-
ties. The 1953 population census, the first tifiable population loss that could have
conducted by the People’s Republic of China amounted to many millions.
(PRC) and probably the most accurate to Problems multiply at the regional level. 12
that point, provides an important milepost Skinner (1987) reconstructed the arbitrary
that helps to triangulate earlier estimates. adjustments that provincial officials used
Concerns over the reliability of Ming and to update early nineteenth-century popu-
Qing census figures arise from their reliance lation reports in Sichuan province, raising
on self-reporting, the incentive for misre- concerns about other nineteenth-century
porting inherent in the use of population estimates. Skinner’s revisions, (along with
(and land) registers to assign tax obligations, earlier work by Perkins 1969), suggest a
and the incompleteness of reporting systems, population of no more than 390 million on
particularly in regions populated by ethnic the eve of the Taiping Rebellion (1851–64),
minorities. A Ming ditty captures some of or at least 40 million lower than the official
these sentiments:10 figures. This revision has important implica-
tions not only for our view of eighteenth- and
Barren soil along the river, the harvest not yet
ready nineteenth-century population growth, but,
New taxes are announced, and yet another in light of losses from the Taiping Rebellion
levy, that earlier estimates placed in excess of
Every household subdivides, trying to evade 60 million, for the early twentieth century as
them— well.13
And officials mistake the whole thing for a
growth in population!
Ho emphasizes the comprehensiveness 11 Official records, for example, show impossibly large
and broad accuracy of early Ming popula- increases of one-third between 1760 and 1775 and one-half
tion registration (circa 1400), but finds the between 1760 and 1790, perhaps because the Qianlong
emperor demanded that officials “ascertain the true pop-
remaining estimates for the Ming unten- ulation of the empire” after a 1775 regional crop failure
able. In his view, it is not until the mid-Qing, exposed the failings of previous tallies (Ho 1959, pp. 47,
(circa 1790s), and then only until the Taiping 281).
12 Ge Jianxiong et al., Zhongguo renkoushi [History
rebellion (1851–64), that we can place sub- of China’s Population], a multivolume study by historical
stantial confidence in the official reporting demographers at Fudan University, offers new estimates
that develop aggregate totals from carefully researched
regional or county figures.
9 The most important sources of microdemographic 13 Skinner’s downward revision to the 1850 population
data are for the Qing imperial family and for Banner settle- figures raises the possibility that estimates of the loss of
ments (a legacy of Manchu military organization) residing life may be too high. Independently, Peter Schran argues
in present-day Liaoning province. Both groups are domi- for a speedy recovery of population in the aftermath of
nated by ethnic minorities whose demographic behavior this shock. He finds the notion of “substantial decline” in
might differ from that of the majority Han population. China’s population between 1850 and 1873 to be “quite
Liaoning’s abnormally high land/labor ratio could also have implausible” and concludes that, “losses due to the Taiping
influenced demographic outcomes. and Nien rebellions had almost been made up” by 1873
10 Lanyang xianzhi [Lanyang county gazetteer, 1545], (1978, pp. 645–46). CAO Shuji (2001), however, argues for
with thanks to Timothy Brook. high mortality during the Taiping Rebellion.
52 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
which dominated the economy and occupied warmer climate, longer growing season, greater availability
of water, and higher multiple cropping ratios. Land rental
a majority of the labor force, provides the was also more common in the south, with estimates sug-
strongest empirical support for this perspec- gesting that tenants cultivated over one-third of farmland
tive. The agricultural economy consisted of (Buck 1930, 1937).
15 Perkins (1969, p. 16) notes substantial regional varia-
millions of small family farms, with average tion in the expansion of cultivated area and population
farm size by the eighteenth century at less (p. 18ff). One hectare is equivalent to 15 mou (p. 16).
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 53
2.2.1 Commercialization, Domestic Trade, from the Lower Yangzi northward around
Market Integration the Shandong peninsula to Tianjin, “virtually
abandoned” under the Ming, was revived
The capacity of the Ming –Qing system during the Qing period and extended north-
to ward off diminishing returns rested on ward to connect with commodity flows along
progressive intensification of agricultural the Liao River in Manchuria (XU Dixin and
rhythms, growing household and regional WU Chengming eds. 2000, p. 166). The
specialization, expanded transport systems growth of what became the large middle-
and deepening markets for commodities, Yangzi river port of Hankou (now known as
as well as the land and labor that produced Wuhan) from “a desolate sandbank” during
them. Exploiting uniquely rich documenta- the Ming era to the “hub of a trade network
tion available for Jiangnan (referring to the linking Sichuan and Shaanxi [provinces] to
southern portion of Jiangsu province, which central and south-eastern China” by 1813
occupies the heart of the Yangzi delta), LI reflects “the development of trade along the
Bozhong (2000, 2010) reviews the emer- Yangzi” River during the Qing era (XU and
gence and growth of specialized production WU 2000, p. 165; Rowe 1984).
in textiles, food processing, apparel, tobacco, Multiple studies trace the Qing deepen-
papermaking, printing, toolmaking, construc- ing of domestic commercial networks (e.g.
tion, and shipbuilding during 1550–1850. Rawski 1972, Rozman 1974), which influen-
Building on the considerable growth of tial work by Skinner (1964) showed to con-
markets and commerce recorded under the sist of nested hierarchies of marketplaces
Song (960–1279), some of which eroded differentiated according to the periodicity of
during the Mongol (Yuan) interregnum market sessions, the scale of activity, and the
(1279–1368), the Ming–Qing era witnessed array of products and services transacted that
renewed development of trade and grow- extended from the largest cities to remote
ing agricultural commercialization. Perkins villages. Increases in the number of towns
concludes that, “shipments of agricultural and markets were particularly evident in the
products out of rural areas to domestic and densely populated delta regions surrounding
foreign markets. . . probably amounted to. . . modern-day Shanghai and Guangzhou (WU
under 7–8 percent of farm output” before Chengming 2002, p. 186).
the twentieth century (1969, 119). Perkins The analysis of Qing price data for food
estimates that 30–40 percent of agricul- grains, which local governments reported
tural products were marketed during the upward on a monthly basis, reveals substan-
early 20th century (1969, 114). The implied tial price integration, most notably across
breakdown between local and long-distance localities linked by low-cost water transport
trade, with roughly one-fourth of marketed (Ch’üan and Kraus 1975). Wang concludes
farm products entering long-distance trade, that “early eighteenth-century China was, on
may approximate circumstances of earlier the whole, comparable with Europe in terms
periods. of market integration” (1992, p. 53); Shiue
Early Ming renovation of the Grand Canal and Keller (2007) confirm this, and show
facilitated the northward shipment of tribute that the Lower Yangzi area achieved greater
grain to the capital, providing a new chan-
nel for north–south trade.16 The sea route
16 The Grand Canal, initially constructed during the Sui helped to forge the unification of the subsequent Tang and
Dynasty (AD 589–616), became a main inland artery that Song empires (CH’ÜAN Han-sheng 1990).
54 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
credit at substantially lower rates by ceding to over 7 percent, fairly low by the standards
“use rights” to land in return for a loan. Once of early modern Europe. This leads scholars
the loan was repaid, the use rights were such as Chao (1986) to attribute the overall
returned. Land mortgage (diandi) contracts slow growth of cities to a low and declining
from northeast China for the 1930s indicate agricultural surplus.
implicit annual rates in the neighborhood of Rather than large urban centers, the lower
10 percent. Yangzi region developed a distinctive pattern
Lending rates differed substantially across of urban settlements, forming clusters of
regions, reflecting the often highly local market towns along the dense regional net-
nature of these markets. Surveys conducted work of rivers, creeks, and man-made canals,
during the 1930s showed modal values for with extensive geographic specialization in
annual interest costs on unsecured per- the marketing and production of agricul-
sonal loans ranged from 20–30 percent in tural and handicraft products (LIU Shijie
coastal regions like Guangdong, Fujian, and 1987). The resulting economic geography,
Zhejiang to higher figures approaching and with no clear boundaries between urban
sometimes exceeding 50 percent in poorer and rural districts or farming and nonagri-
and less commercialized provinces like cultural activity, defeats standard measures
Henan, Jilin, Suiyuan, and Ningxia (Brandt of urbanization. LI Bozhong argues that
and Hosios 2010; Peng et al. 2009). standard classification schemes may under-
A compilation tabulating three centuries estimate the degree of urbanization in the
of rural interest rates nationwide reveals lower Yangzi region, which he places at 20
no sign of the gradual decline observed in percent during mid-Qing (2000, 414). But
Western Europe.19 Myers finds that bor- these estimates, derived from nonstandard
rowing costs for rural households remained definitions, lack international comparability.
“quite constant over a period of two hundred
years” ending in the 1930s (1970, p. 243). 2.2.4 International Exchange Before 1800
Possible explanations for high Chinese rates
and limited development of financial insti- Although the bulk of demand and sales
tutions and markets comparable to those involved purely domestic transactions, there
in early modern Western Europe will be was a small but significant international
addressed later. trade. Largely confined to China’s coastal and
border regions, and periodically restricted by
2.2.3 Urbanization
the state, most of this trade was intra-Asian,
This well-developed market network with China shipping manufactures (porce-
supported increasingly dense population lain, silk) by sea to Southeast Asia and tea
settlements, particularly in prosperous, overland to Central Asia, while importing
trade-oriented regions. Authors like Rozman timber, spices, and monetary metals by sea
(1974), Skinner (1977a, 1977b), and CAO and horses from Central Asia.20
Shuji (2001, p. 829), who assign the label European explorers arriving in Asian
“urban” to settlements exceeding a fixed waters during the early sixteenth century
number of residents, derive average rates of encountered well-established networks
national urbanization ranging from 3 percent of water-borne trade connecting Chinese
merchants and vessels with the rest of Asia
19 See PENG Kaixiang et al. (2009) for China. For
Britain, see McCloskey and Nash (1984), and for Western
Europe, see Homer and Sylla (2005). 20 Deng provides a detailed account (1997, Chap. 5).
56 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
(Frank 1998). Trade with Europe rose, silver. Silver imports reflected huge pretrade
both directly and through the integration of differences in the gold price of silver between
European merchants into Asian trade net- China and the rest of the world (Flynn and
works. China’s silk, ceramics, and tea found Giraldez 1994) as well as Chinese growth and
new markets in Europe’s expanding cities commercialization described above. China
(de Vries 2008; Brook 2010). Chinese sought had limited deposits of precious m etals and,
European luxuries (window glass, clocks), after repeated misadventures with paper
metals, and fabrics (Dikötter 2006, p. 28). currency during the early Ming period (von
Aside from the effect of silver inflows, Glahn 1996), a decided preference for hard
which exerted major influence on China’s money. Von Glahn (2003) estimates that
monetary system from the sixteenth century China’s eighteenth-century silver imports
onward, the impact of international trade on may have exceeded one billion taels, repre-
Chinese prices, incomes, organization, and senting an annual inflow equal to roughly 0.2
production remained small prior to 1800; percent of GDP.23 By 1640, these flows had
these commodity flows may have exerted eliminated major crossnational differences
greater domestic impact on China’s trade in the gold price of silver; thereafter, “silver
partners. Sketchy data suggest 1 percent of continued to gravitate to the Chinese market.
GDP as a generous upper bound to China’s . . because there was a huge number of buy-
trade ratio (imports plus exports divided by ers at a relatively stable world price” (Flynn
GDP).21 Scattered evidence also indicates and Giraldez 1995, p. 433). Significant price
that overseas shipments absorbed only mod- differentials persisted, however, with respect
est shares of output from the main export to other important agricultural and nonagri-
industries.22 cultural commodities.
China’s persistent merchandise trade sur-
2.2.5 Households, Human Capital, and
plus financed massive imports of New World
Private Organizations
21 China’s Maritime Customs trade data begin in the The concept of “homo economicus,”
1850s; the first comprehensive national income estimates invented by thinkers with little knowledge
are for 1933 (Liu and Yeh 1965). Together, they suggest of Asia, fits the historical realities of Chinese
a trade ratio of 8–10 percent of GDP prior to the 1930s
Depression. Backward projection based on these trade village life. Anticipating the Wealth of
data and reasonable assumptions for GDP growth puts this Nations by two millennia, Han Fei-tzu (circa
ratio at no more than 2 percent in 1870. Since trade surely 280–233 BC) mirrors Smith’s vision of indi-
outpaced output growth during the nineteenth century, we
propose one percent of GDP as a generous upper bound vidual behavior:
for China’s pre-1800 trade ratio.
22 Gardella reports calculations by WU Chengming
in the case of workmen selling their services
indicating that tea exports amounted to 23 percent of
in sowing seeds and tilling farms, the master
total output in 1840 (1994, p. 6). Tea exports carried by would . . . give them delicious food and by
the East India Company doubled between 1786 and 1830, appropriating cash and cloth make payments
while export of Fujian tea to Russia increased by a factor
of six between 1798 and 1845 (ibid., 37–39) indicating far
smaller eighteenth-century export shares. Evidence for silk 23 Our crude calculations for the late 18th century
points in the same direction. In 1880, exports of raw and assume a population of 385 million (Perkins 1969, p. 16);
woven silk amounted to 1.17 million piculs, or 55 percent annual per capita grain consumption of 3 shi; an average
of total output (Li 1981, p. 100). For the eighteenth cen- grain price of 2 taels per shi; a consumption basket in which
tury, scattered figures imply that exports were a tiny frac- grain accounted for 40 percent of total expenditure; and
tion of the 1880 total: Li cites sources reporting that Japan 90 percent of GDP going to consumption. Average annual
imported 3,000 piculs of Chinese silk “in an exceptionally GDP then becomes (3*385*2)/(0.4*0.9) or 6,417 million
good year” and that annual shipments to Mexico, another taels. Average annual silver imports of 10 million taels then
major outlet, may have totaled 10,000 piculs (ibid. 64–65). amount to 0.16 percent of annual output. On the tael, see
A picul is a measure of weight equivalent to 60.489 kg. note 39 and section 3.4.3.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 57
for their services. Not that they love the hired levels of numeracy in the Chinese population
workmen, but that . . . by so doing they can of the nineteenth–twentieth centuries than
make the workmen till the land deeper and in countries with comparable or even slightly
pick the weed more carefully. The hired work-
men . . . speedily pick the weed and till the land. higher levels of development (Baten et al.
. . . Not that they love their master, but that . . . 2010). Widespread use of bookkeeping and
by their so doing the soup will be delicious and accounting by households, businesses, lin-
both cash and cloth will be paid to them. Thus, eage trusts, and guilds confirms the high
the master’s provisions and the workmen’s level of commercial orientation and numer-
services supplement each other as if between
them there were the compassion of father acy (Gardella 1992, Yuan and Ma 2010).
and son. However. . . they cherish self-seeking Official interactions with the rural popu-
motives (Han Fei-tzu, n.d.). lace, including the collection of land taxes
and the registration system intended to pro-
Studies of North China’s rural economy by mote public security, routinely used written
Myers (1970) and Huang (1985), of Fujian materials. A substantial publishing industry
and Hunan by Rawski (1972), and of the churned out agricultural manuals as well as
Lower Yangzi region by Huang (1990) and LI cheap editions of popular novels (Brokaw
Bozhong (1998, 2000, 2010), among others, and Chow 2005). Measures of per capita
depict a diligent, ambitious, market-oriented book supply show that Western Europe and
peasantry that responded aggressively to East Asia were the only regions of the world
opportunities for economic gain. Villagers that had mass printing in the early modern
were deeply engaged with markets: in the era (van Zanden 2009, chapter 6).
more commercialized coastal and riverine Chinese villagers deployed their knowl-
districts, many households made daily trips to edge of reading and arithmetic to eco-
local markets (Zelin 1991, p. 38). Ambitious nomic ends. There was a brisk market for
individuals could enter the world of com- cheap books containing “sample contract[s]
merce as brokers or go-betweens with no . . . forms for selling and mortgaging lands,
prior accumulation of wealth. In the absence houses, or livestock; tenancy contracts; [and]
of official restrictions on personal mobility, loan agreements” (Rawski 1979, p. 114);
peddlers and merchants were free to move agricultural handbooks discussed household
to promising locations; numerous huiguan, allocation choices in language reminiscent of
local organizations of merchants from distant modern price theory texts (Rawski 1972, pp.
places, attest to the importance of commer- 54–55). Summarizing work by Myron Cohen
cial sojourning (HE Bingdi 1966). and others, Zelin observes that “Even in
The practical environment of village life remote [Qing] villages . . . written contracts
placed a premium on literacy and numer- were used in the hiring of labor, sale and
acy, both of which reached substantial lev- rental of property, distribution of land-use
els. Historical links between education and rights, marriage and concubinage, and the
social mobility reinforced this tendency, as sale and indenture of human beings” (1994,
did popular culture. Rawski (1979) shows p. 40).
that strong household demand for education, Another striking feature of Qing rural soci-
coupled with low prices for teaching services ety is the capacity of both elites and ordinary
and for books, produced levels of literacy in villagers to construct and manage complex
Qing China that outstripped much of prein- organizations, and to adapt them to chang-
dustrial Europe. Work on age-heaping (the ing circumstances in the pursuit of economic
tendency for uneducated people to give their objectives. In addition to kinship groups,
ages in round numbers) also suggests higher some of which controlled substantial wealth,
58 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
(1973, p. 204). Elman forcefully rejects the to innovation. Such changes, if they occurred,
“scholarly consensus about the alleged failed may have arisen from fears about possible
history of science in China” (2005, p. 420). dislocation associated with technical and
Despite this more favorable assessment, he economic change, a concern that certainly
concedes that the transmission of Western figured in periodic official efforts to limit
scientific knowledge was hampered by the external trade.26
demise of the Jesuits, by the growing scien- This shifts the focus to China’s political
tific prominence of Protestant regions with institutions; specifically, to the capacity of
few links to China, and by the reluctance of the political unity that prevailed throughout
both Protestants and Catholics to translate most of Ming and Qing to choke off political
materials about the solar system or evolution competition. European cities enjoyed con-
that seemed to contradict Christian theology siderable autonomy, developing their own
(2005, pp. xxxii, xxxiii, 350). charters and civil codes. Intense competition
Lin (1995) postulates two sources of inno- between cities and states allowed individu-
vation: experience, and science-based exper- als to relocate to favorable environments—
imentation. For the former, the probability opportunities that were largely absent within
of innovation is directly related to population the unitary Ming–Qing polity (Mokyr 1990,
size. The latter, however, requires experi- chap. 9).
mentation, which Lin contends developed Historical analysis of the traditional
less fully in China than in Europe; following Chinese state and institutions has long
others, he attributes this to incentives that reflected simplistic frameworks based on
encouraged able youths to pursue Confucian Oriental despotism (Wittfogel 1957) or
education in the hope of entering the ruling class struggle (for example WANG Ya’nan
bureaucracy. 1981/2005). Recent literature partially cor-
The work of others would question the rects these limitations by emphasizing that
impact that Lin attributes to China’s system benevolent imperial rule taxed the peasantry
of Confucian education. Allen (2009), cit- lightly, protected private property rights, and
ing European experience, argues that new permitted the operation of well-established
scientific knowledge played only a modest markets in land and labor.27
role in Europe’s advance. Elvin adds that, While the traditional framework of
“Chinese technology stopped progressing Oriental despotism may be misleading and
well before basic scientific knowledge had overly pessimistic, the state—especially
become a serious obstacle” (1973, p. 298). its absolutist features and highly central-
Mokyr (2002, 2009), though, insists that ized political and fiscal regime—figures
basic science became increasingly important prominently in the formation of property
and indeed, indispensable to the second and rights, contract enforcement and incentives,
third waves of industrialization. and, therefore, in the economic dynamics
Historically, the Chinese state contrib- of imperial China. In particular, the clas-
uted to generating and diffusing innova- sic dilemma of government commitment
tions, for example in hydraulics, which may posed by North—growth requires a strong
have compensated for limited private-sector state to secure property rights, but an overly
dynamism. Mokyr (1990) argues for a major
post-Song retreat in the Chinese state’s pre-
26 See Elman
disposition toward, and contribution to, 27 Pomeranz
2005 for an alternative interpretation.
(2000) and Wong (1997) discuss factor
developing new technologies. He sees the markets and taxation; Ma (2011b) reviews traditional legal
Ming–Qing state as somewhat inhospitable institutions.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 61
heuristic model of China’s traditional politi- our model: the throne, bureaucracy, gentry,
cal economy. The result is a surprisingly and commoners. The results illuminate fun-
comprehensive framework that illuminates damental dimensions of political economy
the underpinnings of Qing stability and suc- under the Chinese imperial system.
cess, pinpoints mounting tensions and con-
3.1 Key Political Institutions
straints that gradually reduced the system’s
effectiveness, and reveals specific barriers to From the tenth century on, much of what
fundamental reform. is now regarded as China was under nearly
We focus on interactions among four key continuous unitary rule.29 Map 1 depicts the
actors: the imperial household, the bureau- borders of the Ming (1368–1644) and Qing
cracy, local elites, and the masses. The (1644–1911) empires. Although Qing military
bureaucracy refers to imperially appointed and diplomatic prowess extended their terri-
officials; focusing on the 1880s, Chang tory far beyond the boundaries of Ming rule,
[ZHANG Zhongli], tabulated 23,000 office- we assume an empire of fixed size. We also
holders—2,600 in the imperial court, posit the presence of key institutional fea-
13,000 provincial and local officials, and tures, which we take as given or exogenous:
7,000 military officers (1962, p. 38). The central and unitary imperial rule; a hierar-
local elite includes retired imperial appoin- chical, meritocratic system of staffing the
tees and graduates of provincial and metro- imperial bureaucracy; and a land-based fis-
politan civil service examinations who were cal system. We briefly examine each of these
eligible for imperial appointments but held before pursuing their larger implications.
no formal posts, as well as holders of lesser The consolidation of political control in
degrees and non-degree holders who pos- the hands of the Song emperors represents
sessed sufficient land, education, wealth or an important departure from the preceding
reputation to merit recognition as part of centuries, during which the power of the
the local (or national in the case of promi- throne was checked by a relatively autono-
nent salt merchants) elites, along with their mous imperial cabinet and by regional aris-
extended families.28 tocrats. By the beginning of Song, absolute
While all institutions are in principle power had become vested in the emperor.
endogenous, we take as given Song political Moreover, there were no institutional con-
institutions that had evolved over the previ- straints on the Emperor other than a vaguely
ous millennium and endured until the 1911 defined principle of legitimacy emanating
collapse of the Qing regime. After describ- from the so-called “mandate of heaven.” As
ing these legacies, we explain how incentives Huang explains in the context of Ming:
surrounding these institutions shaped the
behavior of the four groups that populate None of the deterrents to unlimited exercise of
imperial power—including Confucian moral-
ity, reverence for the standards set up by impe-
28 Chang tabulates the ranks of gentry, which, in his rial ancestors, public opinion, or the influence
study, includes all holders of both earned and purchased of senior statesmen—had the effect of law. If
examination degrees, at 1.09 million before (i.e. about the emperor chose to defy all these and was
1850) and 1.44 million after (i.e. about 1870) the Taiping determined to exercise his absolute power to
rebellion (1851–64). Assuming an average of five persons the full, there was no way of checking him
per gentry household, he concludes that the gentry popula- (1974, p. 7).
tion amounted to approximately 1.3 percent “of the whole
population . . . in the first half of the nineteenth century”
and to “well over seven million. . . . [or approximately]
1.9 percent of the total population” after the defeat of the 29 Ma (2012) traces the historical phases of unification
Taipings (1955, pp. 111–12, 139–41). and fragmentation in Chinese history.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 63
i mperially-appointed officials were entrusted used their elite status and the dependence
to govern far-flung regions linked only by of understaffed local administrations on
networks of slow preindustrial transport and their active cooperation as levers to reduce
communication.34 or even escape tax obligations, typically with
As imperial agents, local officials were the connivance of local officials.
expected to treat taxpaying households equi- These circumstances meant that the
tably and to provide full and honest accounts intended and actual outcome of efforts to
of tax collections. But, like governments collect land taxes differed widely. Some
everywhere, China’s bureaucracy often landowners, particularly small-holders with-
veered toward the pursuit of self-interest. out the protection of elite patrons, were
The problem was further compounded by squeezed by the collectors and ended up
limited official fiscal allocations to local gov- making payments that exceeded their statu-
ernments, which forced county magistrates tory obligation. Gentry landowners, as well as
to impose informal levies unsanctioned by commoners enjoying their patronage, might
any imperial decree simply to maintain their persuade or bribe officials to accept frac-
offices and perform their duties. Such con- tional payments rather than demanding the
ditions made it difficult for both external statutory amount.35 Officials’ need for gentry
monitors and the bureaucrats themselves to cooperation made it difficult for magistrates
separate what might be called “public-inter- to resist gentry pressures for informal tax
est malfeasance” from peculation intended relief. Finally, there was considerable rev-
to secure illicit personal gain. Officials enue leakage, as clerks, runners, and officials
employed a host of strategems to pillage siphoned public funds into private purses.
the public purse: exaggerating the severity Chinese emperors, keenly aware of these
of harvest shocks, overstating the extent of difficulties, established institutions aimed
tax arrears, colluding with local landholders at limiting the impact of agency costs.
to remove land from the tax rolls, or simply Confucian ideology, which prescribed codes
diverting public funds for their own benefit. of behavior for all social groups, including
The land tax system created sharp con- officials, acted to promote upright behavior
flicts between local officials and land-owning even in the absence of effective monitoring.
households, including local elites, who often Frequent rotation of officials, as well as the
held substantial acreage. Tax collectors often “law of avoidance,” which barred officials
bullied ordinary households, for example from serving in their home districts, aimed
by manipulating weights and measures to to direct official loyalties toward the throne.
extract payments in excess of the legal tax The Censorate, a branch of the central
obligation. The prevalence of unofficial tax bureaucracy, dispatched roving observers
farming provided ample opportunity for offi- to serve as the emperor’s eyes and ears by
cials to appropriate revenues for their private reporting official malfeasance directly to the
benefit. Commoners resisted such imposi- throne.
tions (and also sought to escape taxation)
through violent tax resistance and by ally-
ing themselves with local gentry. The gentry 35 Kuhn describes how rural elites “undertook to pay
their neighbors’ taxes by proxy and fend off the tax agents’
extortion” in return for fees (2002, pp. 81–82) and docu-
34 Prior to the advent of railways, travel from the capi- ments the Qing government’s inability to suppress this ille-
tal to Shenyang required 30 days, to Xi’an or Wuhan 50 gal practice, primarily because of “how little local officials
days, to Nanjing nearly 50 days, to Guangzhou 90 days, etc. were willing to do about. . . . elite meddling in the tax sys-
(Whitney 1970, p. 47). tem” (ibid., 90–91).
66 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
Table 2
Tax Revenues in China, 1085–1776 (in Shi of Rice)
Per capita Per capita Total taxes Per capita Index
land tax indirect taxes tax burden (1085 = 100)
Notes: An extensive discussion by Ch’üan and Kraus (175, pp. 79–98) concludes that “the likely weight of an imperial
shih (shi) of milled rice in the eighteenth century was about 185 pounds” (p. 98).
Source: Data compiled by Guanglin Liu (2005), p. 90.
a small official bureaucracy, and a corre- per capita tax collections fell steadily: by
spondingly limited scope of nonmilitary 1850, per capita revenue was less than half
activities financed from the public purse. the level for 1700. Nominal revenues rose
The rulers’ long time horizons pushed in the sharply in the late nineteenth century, but
same direction.38 the increase was modest in real terms. The
After rising during the early years as the share of government revenue in total output
new Qing dynasty reestablished order, for- during Qing was also low: Yeh-chien Wang
mal tax revenue expressed in silver taels finds that late nineteenth-century land taxes
remained fairly constant between 1700 and represented 2–4 percent of the produce of
1850, averaging around 36 million silver taels the land in most areas, although they may
annually, of which approximately 70 percent have consumed a larger share in the pros-
came from taxes on land.39 With stable rev- perous Yangzi delta region. Total govern-
enue and substantial population growth, ment revenue from all sources amounted
to roughly 2.4 percent of net national prod-
38 In a dynamic setting, we could represent the policy uct in 1908 (Wang 1973, pp. 80, 128, 133),
objective as maximizing the discounted present value of suggesting that tax revenues remained well
the imperial household’s welfare, implying an important below five percent of total output through-
role for the imperial time horizon. The more dynastic
the emperor’s view, the longer the time horizon and thus out the Qing period.
the lower the discount rate used in these calculations. In Historical compilations summarized in
Olson’s (1982) framework based on the analogy of station- table 2 indicate that tax revenues under the
ary and roving banditry, extending the ruler’s time horizon
would make the throne’s interests more encompassing and Song and Ming dynasties exceeded those in
less predatory, thereby contributing to a “virtuous equilib- the Qing period, both in aggregate and in per
rium” of low extraction and high mass welfare.
39 The Qing monetary system included multiple silver
capita terms (Liu 2005). While the Song fig-
taels, which typically represented 35–40 grams of pure sil- ures are subject to considerable uncertainty,
ver. The term tael refers to traditional measures of mon- the ordering implied by these data matches
etary silver. The kuping tael used in Qing government information on the size of Chinese armies
accounts, for example, was a bookkeeping currency con-
sisting of 37.5 grams of pure silver. For details, see King during the three dynasties (IWAI Shigeki
(1965) and Kann (1975). 2004, p. 33).
68 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
30,000 – – 25
27,500 –
25,000 –
– 20
22,500 – Nominal expenditure (in 10,000 silver taels)
Real expenditure (in 10,000 shi of rice)
20,000 – Per capita real expenditure (right side scale)
Kilograms of rice
17,500 – – 15
15,000 –
12,500 – – 10
10,000 –
7,500 –
– 5
5,000 –
2,500 –
0 | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | | 0
61 1
11
91
43
41
40
39
42
03
66
12
18 8
93
52
44
1 8
18 849
17 2
62
46
08
84
45
25
47
18 5
18 –6
3
4
8
–7
19
17
18
18
18
18
19
17
18
18
18
16
18
18
16
16
18
19
18
18
50
Sources: See Ma (2011a); fiscal data are from IWAI Shegeki (2004, p. 37) and HAMASHITA Takeshi (2006,
p. 73); population from Angus Maddison (2007); grain prices are from Yeh-chien Wang (1992).
Figure 1 displays trends in nominal, real, per capita revenues of the leading European
and per capita fiscal expenditure during the states, expressed in grams of silver, were
Qing dynasty. Nominal expenditure showed 15–40 times comparable figures for Qing
little fluctuation for approximately 200 years China. England’s revenue actually surpassed
beginning in the early eighteenth century. the comparable figure for the immensely
Population growth and inflation produced larger and more populous Qing Empire! Per
an early decline in real and per capita expen- capita revenues, which remained roughly
diture, followed by trendless fluctuation constant over long periods under the Qing,
during the first half of the nineteenth cen- tended to increase elsewhere. Expressing
tury. All three nominal measures rose dur- the tax burden in terms of the number of
ing the final half-century of Qing rule, with days an unskilled urban laborer would have
per capita expenditure in the early twentieth to work in order to earn the equivalent of the
century regaining levels recorded during the average individual tax payment provides an
initial period of Qing rule. alternative view of the Qing empire’s modest
Comparative data shown in table 3 dem- fiscal capacity.
onstrate the Qing dynasty’s limited fiscal Limited revenues and the prospect
capacity. During the late eighteenth century, that adding officials could undermine
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 69
Table 3
Qing Central Government Annual Revenue in International Comparison
Panel C: Per capita revenue expressed in days’ wages for unskilled urban workers
China Ottoman Russia France Spain England Dutch R*
Notes: One Chinese silver tael = 37 grams of silver. For per capita revenue in days of urban unskilled wages, figures
for 1650–59 and 1700–09 are used to represent 1650–99 and 1700–49 respectively. The averages of data for 1750–59
and for 1780–89 are used to represent 1750–1799 for all countries except Russia, China and 19th century England.
Data are from Karaman and Pamuk (2010), with thanks to Kıvanç Karaman and Sevket Pamuk for sharing their
underlying data sets.
Nominal wages for Russia are 1 and 2.52 grams of silver for 1700–1725 and 1772–1774 respectively from data
supplied by Boris Mironov listed on http://gpih.ucdavis.edu/files/Wages_Moscow_1613-1871.xls. We thank Peter
Lindert and Steven Nafziger for the Russian data.
Nominal wages for Beijing used to represent China come from Robert C. Allen et al. 2011.
*Dutch Republic
Source: see Debin Ma 2011a as detailed above.
a dministrative effectiveness meant that the official hierarchy, hardly changed after Han
size of the bureaucracy lagged far behind (206 BC–220 AD) times. Despite a vastly
the growth of population. Indeed, the num- larger population and territory, Qing China
ber of counties (xian), units ruled by magis- had only 1,360 counties compared to 1,230
trates who occupied the lowest rung of the under the Song (Skinner 1977b, p. 19).
70 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
Limitations on the size of the bureaucracy quotas—“a gigantic concession to local gen-
help explain why the imperial administra- try and landlords” (Richards 2003, p. 124).
tion never penetrated below the county Kangxi’s successor, Yongzheng (r. 1722–35)
level. With a near-static administrative struc- sought to incorporate informal taxes and sur-
ture, population growth meant that average charges into the formal tax base in an effort
county populations during Qing reached a to restrain local corruption and stem the
large multiple of comparable Song figures. leakage of resources from the public purse.
This increased the administrative burden Here again, top-down imperial reform failed
facing local magistrates and magnified their to overcome resistance from below, now
dependence on the cooperation of local from local magistrates who valued the dis-
gentry, which in turn reinforced the pres- cretion (and opportunities for rent extrac-
sures mandating a low-tax regime, as efforts tion) associated with the traditional system.
to increase taxes would place local officials Since informal local revenues were essential
in direct conflict with the same elites whose to local governance, the information asym-
support was essential to managing local metry surrounding these revenues protected
affairs and preserving social order. them from extraction by higher-level officials
A nineteenth-century example from (Zelin 1984, chap. 7, Ma 2011a).
Xinhui, Guangdong illustrates the helpless- Under these circumstances, well-informed
ness of local officials in the absence of gentry emperors who understood the dangers of
cooperation. When the Qing state imposed excess tax demands on commoners, as well
likin (lijin) taxes on domestic trade, the local as the revenue leakage arising from official
palm-leaf guild raised no objection. But this peculation and gentry manipulation, might
seemingly obscure group blocked subse- reasonably conclude that raising the rate of
quent efforts to increase the tax rate: land taxes was not a practical option. Given
the limited size of the imperial household
When the guild resisted . . . there was nothing
the magistrate could do but request a waiver and the throne’s desire for dynastic longev-
[exempting the guild from the higher likin ity, imperial ideology evolved toward fixing a
rates]. . . . He was unable to survey the palm- revenue target rather than maximum extrac-
growing areas to tax them directly, because the tion for normal years (in the absence of har-
guild and its supporters refused to cooperate. vest failure or external crisis), an outcome
He was unable to muster community support.
. . . when he called a meeting of local gentry . . . famously encapsulated in the Kangxi emper-
no one came (Mann 1987, p. 130). or’s 1712 proclamation freezing nominal land
taxes in perpetuity (Ma 2011a).
Similar conditions existed elsewhere.
3.3.2 Limited State Capacity
While bearing the emperor’s imprimatur,
local magistrates were lone outsiders facing Like all revenue-constrained premodern
tightly-knit communities that often included empires, Qing public spending was lim-
several hundred thousand residents. The ited to programs that addressed fundamen-
inescapable reality of gentry power emerges tal issues of external and internal security.
most strikingly from the decision of the Expenditures on the military and border
Kangxi emperor (r. 1662–1722), among the defenses protected the largely sedentary
strongest Qing rulers, to abandon a pro- agrarian populace. The central government’s
posed empire-wide cadastral survey in the outlays on civilian public goods focused on
face of elite resistance. The outcome was measures intended to stabilize and increase
continued use of obsolete Ming land regis- agricultural productivity—for example
ters coupled with a permanent freeze on tax investments in water control and irrigation.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 71
The state operated a network of granaries the focus of the central government as “reg-
in an effort to limit price fluctuations and istering and checking the actions of various
stave off famine; this program may explain provincial administrations [rather] than . . .
why increases in grain prices following assuming a direct initiative in the con-
Chinese crop failures were “moderate” (20– duct of affairs” (Mayers and Playfair 1897,
70 percent) in comparison with “the worst pp. 21–22). Kwan finds that the Board of
European famines where prices doubled, Revenue, which bore major responsibility
tripled, or quadrupled” (Li 2007, 247; also for managing the imperial salt monopoly,
see Perdue 1987 and Will and Wong 1991). was “primarily a transmission center of docu-
Such programs contributed to mass wel- ments and repository for ledgers . . . [that]
fare and thus supported the longevity of the rarely initiated policy” (2001, p. 32). King
imperial system. They also relied on local notes that even in the monetary sphere,
contributions, highlighting both the need for a central government responsibility, “the
magistrates to secure elite cooperation and Board of Revenue could not be the source of
the difficulty of reconstructing a complete a coherent monetary policy. It had no power
picture of government revenues. Perdue to inspect the quality of provincial coins. . . .
(1987) shows how Qing officials worked with It could comment on provincial memorials
local gentry to expand irrigation and flood only if they were referred to the Board. . . .”
control in Hunan province. Similar arrange- (1969, p. 34). Strauss (1998) aptly summa-
ments led to the construction and main- rizes the key goal of the Qing central admin-
tenance of major projects that delivered istration as “system maintenance rather than
large-scale economic benefits for centuries: maximal efficiency” (p. 14).
the Grand Canal, spanning a north–south
3.3.3 De Facto or Informal Private Property
route over 1,000 miles in length between
Rights
Hangzhou and Beijing, completed during
the seventh century (Leonard 1996); and This focus on stability and dynastic lon-
Dujiangyan, an even older project located in gevity encouraged emperors toward prag-
the western province of Sichuan, that clev- matism, rather than absolutism. Late Tang
erly combines flood control with irrigation reforms that shifted emperors’ main source
(Needham 1971, 288–96). of tax revenue from labor to land prompted
To guard against external threats, the the state to relinquish its theoretical control
Qing, like previous dynasties, employed a of land tenure and support the emergence
mixture of attack, defense, and diplomacy. of the de facto family-based owner–tenant
Perdue (1996, 2005) shows how Qing offi- system of private landholding and household
cials harnessed mercantile interests to equip cultivation that dominated the economy
and supply extended military campaigns in of imperial China for the next millennium.
the Empire’s remote western borderlands. Such processes of bottom-up institutional
The same logistic capabilities enabled Qing innovation—visible both in Tang and in
armies to cross the Himalayas and force the shift from collectives to the household
Nepal’s fierce Gurkhas to recognize Manchu responsibility system during the 1970s—
overlordship. involved the tacit acquiescence of rulers who
China’s large size, limited revenues, long chose to overlook widespread infringements
communication lines, and small bureau- of existing rules.
cracy influenced the nature, as well as the The emerging private land ownership
scale and scope, of official activity. A late rights included residual claimancy; the right
nineteenth-century commentator described to rent, sell, or mortgage; and the right to
72 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
bequest. Recognition of these rights allowed a ctivity (Skinner 1977b, pp. 24–25—note the
private owners, rather than the state, to obvious parallel with China’s recent reform
capture the benefits associated with rising experience).
productivity, land reclamation, and popula- De facto or informal property rights in
tion growth. If households became unable to both land and commerce evolved within a
farm their plots or chose to shift occupations, unitary hierarchical empire without the rep-
the opportunity to sell or rent land use rights resentative institutions, independent cities,
allowed them to capture the returns to their or autonomous legal agents that appeared in
investment in the land. Western Europe.
The Tang reforms encouraged the devel-
3.3.4 Informal Taxation
opment of increasingly deep and sophisti-
and Rent Extraction
cated markets for land in which layers of
ownership and user rights could be pur- Land taxes collected from rural commu-
chased, sold, rented, mortgaged, and divid- nities were mostly remitted to higher levels
ed.40 Ownership of a single plot could be of government. Zelin estimates that county
vested in separate parties endowed with magistrates retained approximately one-fifth
rights over the surface and subsurface of official land tax collections to meet local
respectively—the so-called yitian liangzhu needs (1984, p. 27). Much of the retained
(two lords to a field) or yitian sanzhu (three funds went to fulfill imperially-mandated
lords to a field) systems: rights that could outlays, for example provisioning military
then be sold, leased, or used as collateral. forces and maintaining imperial relay sta-
Tenants, as well as owners, could freely tions. What remained was not sufficient to
exchange their access rights. The multiplicity operate government offices, pay the mag-
and divisibility of rights to land helped ordi- istrate’s salary, and support the required
nary villagers to maintain their livelihoods in complement of secretaries, clerks, runners,
an inherently risky environment. They also and personal servants.41 This reflects both
gave rise to complex arrangements: LONG the state’s limited fiscal resources and the
Denggao (2010) reports a single plot of land center’s deliberate effort to limit the growth
with over 100 separate owners, some with of local power bases by constraining locally
shares as small as 1/608. available fiscal resources.
Commerce experienced a similar transfor- To make ends meet, subnational officials
mation under the Tang, as earlier systems, relied on informal or extralegal surcharges.
“of administered trade became increas- Informal taxation, which was “an established
ingly arduous and expensive to enforce . . . practice in the mid-eighteenth century as it
a process of trial and error . . . punctuated was necessary for keeping public administra-
by the periodic re-imposition of controls . . . tion at work” (Wang 1973, p. 72), blurred
[led to] a general withdrawal by government the distinction between legitimate and
from the minute regulation of commercial
affairs” and a notable expansion of privately
established markets and private mercantile 41 Ch’ü indicates that county-level governments
employed several hundred (and in some cases, several
thousand) clerks, several hundred (and in some cases, over
1,000) “runners” (i.e. messengers, guards, policemen and
40 Land transactions were often recorded in writ- other menial employees), and 10–30 personal aides (1962,
ten documents, many of which survive in libraries and pp. 39, 56, 59, 77). Some of these personnel received sal-
archives. MURAMATSU Y u ¯ j i (1966) and ZHANG Deyi et aries from the magistrate; others received no salary, but
al. (2009) provide examples of documents recording land imposed irregular fees on citizens who sought access to
transactions. official services.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 73
corrupt official behavior, and thus compli- for public administration often led to the
cated efforts to detect and deter the diver- privatization of public services.43
sion and embezzlement of public funds. The In a world of rising population, static overall
weak financial position of local governments and declining per capita revenues restricted
increased the dependence of magistrates on the center’s capacity to mobilize resources,
local elites, who either to implement new administrative ini-
tiatives or to meet national emergencies.
played a crucial role here by helping the mag-
istrate with his duties; from the maintenance
Although Qing ideology celebrated the bene-
of water conservancy works to the organization ficial welfare consequences of a “small state,”
of local defense corps. . . . the magistrate, as a we cannot determine whether this reflected
non-native of the region where he held office, the rulers’ initial belief or represents a ratio-
was to a certain extent dependent on the local nalization of unavoidable realities. Limited
elite’s advice in carrying out his magisterial
duties, as well as on their support in the lead-
revenue and the lack of fiscal provision for
ership of local people. . . . In “reward” for its local governance obliged emperors to accept
“efforts,” the local elite was in turn also in a substantial financial abuse, relying on ideol-
position to enjoy certain tax exemptions, and ogy and occasional severe punishments to
moreover, to falsify land registers and popula- deter extreme behavior.44
tion reports, or, even, to appropriate tax rev-
enue which normally would have passed to the
The ubiquity of irregular taxation explains
state (Zurndorfer 1989, pg. 3). the apparent contradiction between the low
rates reflected in the receipts of the Board
Zelin itemizes these informal revenue of Revenue (see tables 2 and 3 above) and
sources, which ranged from the levying of the popular image of Ming and Qing as
surcharges, manipulation of weights, mea- rapacious regimes. The Kangxi-era gover-
sures, and currency conversion in tax collec- nor-general of Shaanxi and Gansu placed
tion, falsifying reports, shifting funds across extralegal surcharges at 40–50 percent of the
fiscal years, and concealing tax revenue from official tax quota (Zelin 1984, p. 73). Wang
commerce and from newly reclaimed land to argues that such imposts were less severe, at
extracting contributions and donations from least in 1753, a year for which the historical
local farmers and merchants. She chronicles record is particularly rich; Wang concludes
an episode in eighteenth-century Jiangsu that “ non-statutory surcharges amounted to
province in which an investigating magis- as much as the statutory ones, which gen-
trate discovered widespread embezzlement erally ranged from 10 to 15 percent of the
of official funds: “there was not a prefecture, [authorized tax] quota” (1973, p. 69).
chou or hsien [county] in the region in which Information about the overall incomes of
[secret records providing a true picture of officeholders provides added perspective
land ownership and tax payments] . . . were
not compiled” (1984, p. 240).42 Provincial
43 Ch’ü (1962) offers a vivid portrayal of county clerks
officials solicited gifts from their bureau-
extracting bribes with the threat of delaying legal cases
cratic subordinates and skimmed funds by submitted, runners demanding “chain-release money”
inflating the cost of official purchases (1984, from the families of accused criminals who might other-
pp.46–71). Reliance on informal local taxa- wise be chained or tortured, retaining part of the goods
recovered from thieves, or sometimes resorting to outright
tion and the employment of unofficial staff extortion of wealthy residents. The porters who guarded
magistrates’ offices expected tips for accepting documents
or warrants.
44 Ho describes the use of selective capital punishment
42 Ho (1967) reports similar practices in early to control Qing officialdom (1962, 293–95). The People’s
twentieth-century Hebei province. Republic employs similar tactics.
74 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
on the impact of the tax system. While esti- official hierarchy, while remaining subject
mates of unrecorded payments are always to imperial discretion. This is exactly what
hazardous, the carefully documented work we observe. Under imperial rule, as in the
of Chang [ZHANG Zhongli] concludes that PRC, the Chinese system views legal pro-
the total incomes (including receipts from cesses as a subsidiary function of the admin-
landholding and other nonofficial activi- istrative hierarchy. In China, as in Rome, the
ties) accruing to imperial appointees dur- emperor was the source of law. The Tang
ing the 1880s may have amounted to twenty dynasty established an elaborate and system-
times the official payments associated with atic criminal code that was largely retained
their positions and that gentry households, by its successors. Modifications arose pri-
while comprising roughly two percent of marily from occasional imperial interven-
the population, received 24 percent of tions that extended or contravened existing
national income, enjoying per capita dis- codes; such actions constituted new laws or
posable incomes approximately 17.7 times substatutes that served as precedents for
the average for commoners (1962, pp. 326– subsequent decisions (SHIGA et al. pp. 12,
29). Chang also finds that informal income 120–21; SU Yegong 2000, chap. 9).
obtained by subprovincial officeholders alone Legal outcomes reflected ideological
approached 60 million silver taels, equivalent orthodoxy and social privilege. The punish-
to three-quarters of the central government’s ment inflicted upon a son for attacking his
recorded annual revenue of 80 million taels father or a wife for injuring her husband was
during the 1880s (1962, 40, 42, 328). more severe than if the roles were reversed.
Chang’s figures, however crude, reveal Trials of officials or gentry members could
the capacity of officials at all levels to extract only be conducted by officials with higher
wealth from the private sector and help to administrative rank; such prosecutions usu-
explain the huge vested interest of Chinese ally occurred only after the accused was
elites embedded in what was, after all, a demoted or stripped of his official rank, an
conquest dynasty led by the descendants of arrangement mirrored in China’s current
Manchu invaders whom most Chinese per- justice system, which imposes internal party
ceived as “barbarians.” discipline in advance of criminal prosecu-
tions. The imperial system was far from arbi-
3.3.5 Law, Economic Security,
trary. Criminal verdicts followed elaborate
and Patronage
penal codes and were subject to mandatory
Formation and disposition of property review; capital cases received the emperor’s
rights are closely linked to the legal system, personal scrutiny (Ma 2011b).
which, as in any nation, exerted substantial While county magistrates also ruled on
influence over Ming–Qing economic activ- civil and commercial, as well as criminal
ity. Chinese emperors, faced with the task of matters, broad swathes of economic and
maintaining stability while seeking to govern social life were governed by private custom,
a vast land mass with a tiny corps of officials, with disputes adjudicated and sanctions
required sufficient flexibility to strike quickly imposed by family, clan, and village elders,
and powerfully at potential nodes of counter- by local gentry, and by mercantile asso-
vailing power—aside from the gentry, who, ciations (e.g. Chen and Myers 1978, 1996).
as noted earlier, were indispensable bul- Unlike Western Europe, where autono-
warks of the status quo. mous legal professionals contributed to the
In the legal sphere, these requirements formalization of private customs and rules
point to a system that is controlled by the and the specification of property rights, the
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 75
right to sell salt was farmed out to those mer- rotect him from predatory local government
p
chants who were financially able to pay the functionaries. In return, the patron received
expressions of gratitude and loyalty on which
salt gabelle [tax] in advance” (1954, pp. 142, he built a stock of political capital (1996,
136). Observing the late nineteenth century, p. 183)
Mann finds a “familiar historical pattern . . .
[in which] local trade organizations began Similarly, Mann finds that “marketers and
to purchase the right to collect [recently traders unprotected by patronage or family
imposed] lijin taxes from their own members connections were vulnerable to harassment
by . . . paying tax quotas in advance” (1987, and extortion” (1987, p. 62).
p. 111). Faure goes on to observe that, “Ming and
Such arrangements equipped mercan- Ch’ing [Qing] local as well as long-distance
tile groups with substantial control of their trade was conducted under extensive patron-
trades—at least within the territories admin- age networks just as rural life was” (1996, p.
istered by cooperating officials. Mercantile 93). By emphasizing the ubiquity of “trading
groups typically allowed newcomers to under patronage” but also observing that,
enter their business, provided that they “ . . . Ming and Ch’ing markets were rela-
observed collectively-agreed rules, which tively open . . . because the patrons com-
might include provisions related to cur- peted” (1989/1996, p. 95), Faure offers a
rency, weights and measures, product qual- bridge between competing visions that ana-
ity, apprenticeship, wages, piece rates, and, lyze economic processes during the impe-
of course, tax payments. rial era in terms of competitive markets
Mercantile leaders—the so-called “head (e.g. Myers 1980, Myers and Wang 2002) or,
merchants”—wielded considerable power: alternatively, in terms of rivalry among gen-
their special status enabled ready access to try and official predators for opportunities to
officials; they could enact and enforce rules extract resources from hapless commoners
and sanction nonconforming members with (e.g. Feuerwerker 1958; Huang 1985, 1990).
fines or even expulsion from the officially- As we shall see, the idea that genuine, but
recognized trade body—the commercial limited or incomplete property rights lead to
equivalent of capital punishment. Thus in what might reasonably be termed a “patron-
the salt trade, “merchant chiefs and head age economy” makes sense not only for the
merchants formed a powerful ruling clique. Ming–Qing era, but for contemporary China
. . . [that] exerted powerful control over dis- as well.
tribution and sale of salt” (Ho 1954, pp. 138,
3.4 The Long-Run Political Equilibrium
141).
Relationships within these networks, Starting with the simplest of assump-
including within families and lineages, often tions—the emperor rules his large domains
took the form of patron–client ties rather with a nonhereditary bureaucracy selected
than transactions among equals. Faure by competitive examination, employing the
quotes Duara’s study of twentieth-century land tax as the primary source of fiscal reve-
North China: nue—we derive implications that accurately
depict major aspects of the actual Ming–
In a society where neither the market nor the Qing regime. The following observations
state fully regulated economic relationships, summarize the long-run properties of both
the individual peasant (or village household)
was often dependent on a powerful local fig-
the “model” and, we believe, of the system
ure . . . to ensure the fulfillment of a contract, that existed prior to the nineteenth-century
to provide access to the market . . . and to escalation of western imperial pressure.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 77
3.4.1 Mutual Reinforcement between of formal and informal influence and power.
Ideology and Incentives, between Public office was the most important source
de Facto and de Jure Political of prestige and wealth. At the same time,
and Economic Power money was essential to finance the long
preparation needed to pass the civil service
The combination of status, power, and high examinations: during 1834/35, 81 percent of
incomes available to examination graduates, provincial examination graduates and 93 per-
official appointees, and their families pro- cent of successful palace examination candi-
vided incumbent elites and ambitious com- dates were over 24 years of age; over half of
moners with powerful incentives to seek the palace graduates and nearly 40 percent
advancement within the imperial system by of the provincial degree winners were over
investing in Confucian education for bright 35 years (Elman 2000, pp. 704, 706). Ho
sons in the hope that they might earn exami- notes that “the children of salt merchants
nation degrees. The frequency with which probably received the best schooling in the
poor households sought schooling for sons empire,” which enabled a group of fewer
who, while eligible to compete, had no realis- than 300 families to produce 139 palace
tic chance of achieving examination success, degreeholders and 208 provincial exami-
reflected both the practical benefit of literacy nation graduates between 1646 and 1802
in a society permeated by written documents (1954, p. 162). This cross-fertilization of eco-
and the long-term impact of Confucian ide- nomic resources, status, and political power
ology, which accorded respect and status to represented both a bulwark of stability and a
men whose educational attainments, how- formidable obstacle to reform.
ever modest, exceeded the local norm.
3.4.2 Stability, Resilience,
The result was a remarkable consistency
and Path Dependency
of objectives, incentives, and mobility strate-
gies across social strata. Rich and poor, elites The institutional arrangements described
and commoners, farmers and craftsmen, all above demonstrated great strength, resil-
invested in education and relied on educa- ience, and stability throughout the Ming–
tional attainment to promote both social Qing era, supporting the enormous expansion
standing and economic gain. In this fashion, of territory and population depicted in table 1
generations of Chinese strengthened an ide- and map 1 in an increasingly commercialized
ology that associated leadership with edu- but primarily agrarian economy.
cational attainment and exalted hard work The dynastic regime demonstrated a
and thrift as the proper route to upward capacity not only to withstand shocks but
mobility through training, discipline, and also to restore stability in the wake of poten-
self-cultivation. tially destabilizing disasters. The devastating
Recent efforts by Acemoglu and others Taiping rebellion (1851–64), which exposed
to investigate the institutional backdrop of the weakness of Qing rulers, was sup-
long-term economic growth emphasize links pressed by regional leaders who possessed
between de jure power arising from legal the highest-level Civil Service examination
provisions and other formal institutions and degrees. These men mobilized troops and
de facto influence attributable to custom, funds in their home provinces and defeated
wealth, and other informal arrangements the rebel armies. The victorious generals, all
(Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2005; of whom were Han Chinese, then restored
Acemoglu and Robinson 2012). Imperial control to the throne, even though it was
China displayed extreme interpenetration occupied by the non-Chinese descendants
78 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
of Manchu invaders. They also contributed The Qing monetary system revolved
prominently to the Tongzhi Restoration around two core elements: officially minted
(1861–75), a joint Manchu–Chinese effort to copper cash, often joined in “strings” of up
restore stability and prosperity by revitalizing to 1,000, mediated retail transactions, while
orthodox Confucian ideology, reconstruct- wholesale trade and large transactions relied
ing the traditional low-tax fiscal regime, and on a mixture of silver “shoes” (shoe-shaped
restoring regular civil service examinations. ingots cast by private firms), bits of silver bul-
This episode demonstrates how a com- lion, and, as European trade expanded, an
mon ideology and close alignment of incen- array of imported silver coins from Europe,
tives among the imperial household and the Americas, and Japan.46 The exchange
overlapping bureaucratic, scholarly, com- rate between copper and silver, theoretically
mercial, and landed elites created a tight constant at 1000 standard cash per silver tael,
web of vested interests that, once estab- varied widely over time, across regions, and
lished, proved extremely difficult to dis- among different trades.
lodge. Unfortunately, the same forces that In the face of such monetary complexity,
promoted stability also militated against local elites, guilds and mercantile groups
reforms that might threaten the standing, sought to reduce currency risk by establish-
the incomes, or the future prospects of inter- ing and enforcing uniform local monetary
locking socio-economic leadership groups standards. These efforts, aimed at reducing
that dominated the imperial polity. transaction costs for particular groups and
districts, gave rise to a maze of exchange rates
3.4.3 Limited Monetary
linking multiple varieties of silver ingots,
and Financial Development
coins and bits, copper cash, bills issued by
The Qing economy operated under a merchants and financiers, and bookkeeping
bimetallic copper–silver monetary standard currencies established in various localities
with no regular issue of official paper cur- and trades.47 The resulting system imposed
rency and no long-lived government debt a regime of high transaction costs result-
or other financial instruments. This arrange- ing from unstable exchange rates, from the
ment, which imposed high transaction costs expense of shifting assets from one currency
throughout the economy, reflected the to another, and, for large transactions, from
absolutist nature of political authority, which the need to hire specialists to mediate the
was not limited by the sort of checks and fulfillment of payment obligations.
balances that gradually emerged in leading The limited extent of property rights and
European states prior to the British indus- the arbitrary nature of the underlying legal
trial revolution. system seem to account for the restricted
The absence of checks and balances led to development of financial instruments.
the ironic result that China, which pioneered Unlike Holland or England, there was no
the use of printed paper currency during the formal market for public debt. The absence
Song dynasty (960–1279), reverted to a sys- of credible financial instruments restrained
tem built around low-denomination copper state capacity and rendered the traditional
tokens and uncoined silver because repeated
episodes of official mismanagement evi-
dently eroded the private sector’s trust in 46 Standard works on monetary history include Kann
government monies as a store of wealth 1975, King 1965, and Peng 1958.
47 An early twentieth century report enumerated more
or even as a medium of exchange for large than one hundred tael bookkeeping units (DAI Jianbin
transactions (Ma 2013). 2007, pp. 58–79).
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 79
state prone to fiscal predation or confisca- (1962, p. 25). In China, such inspira-
tion in times of crisis (CHEN Feng 1992, tion came only in the twentieth century.
chapter 7; Ma 2013). De facto governmen- Even the most progressive Qing reform-
tal borrowing (or extraction) took the form ers, men who supported the expansion
of advance collection of taxes, forced loans of factories and rail transport, failed to
from merchants, and sale of official titles comprehend the potential of intensive
and positions. Formalized public debt began growth to raise productivity and living
only during the latter half of the nineteenth standards.
century, when the bargaining power of lend- • Lack of fiscal capacity. Perkins
ers (particularly Western bankers and gov- describes Qing public finances the
ernments) was reinforced by extraterritorial last half of the nineteenth century as
privilege or Western consular and military “almost unbelievably weak” (1967,
presence (ZHOU Yumin 2000, pp. 277–87, p. 492). Available data indicate that
Ma 2013). the share of Qing GDP that reached
Insecure property rights and the lack of government coffers in the seventeenth
institutional restraint on imperial power and eighteenth centuries was not much
produced a domestic economy in which higher. Comparisons in table 3 show
only land was suitable for long-term pas- that Qing revenue shares were consis-
sive wealthholding. We see no emergence tently smaller than in leading European
of tradable long-lived financial instruments states.
and, indeed, no scope for financial transac- • Lack of administrative structure.
tions beyond spot exchanges in the absence Modern economic growth leans heavily
of personal links. The general absence of on the capacity of the state to formulate
impersonal financial arrangements contin- and implement policies that support and
ued well into the late nineteenth-century encourage development. Contemporary
treaty port era, when “much share capital and retrospective accounts agree that
was raised through private connections” such capacity was notably lacking in the
(Faure 2006, p. 52). Qing empire, which Strauss describes
as a “presiding state. . . . [that] was usu-
3.4.4 How the Imperial System
ally content to reign and loosely regu-
Constrained Growth
late rather than vigorously rule” (1998,
Despite its formidable economic achieve- p. 12).
ments, the imperial systems were designed in • Patronage economy. Although pri-
the ideological framework of the seventeenth vate ownership figured prominently in
and eighteenth centuries and ultimately pre- China’s imperial economy, the absence
vented China from moving rapidly to capi- of legal protection against official abro-
talize on new opportunities arising from the gation of property rights obliged private
industrial revolution in Great Britain. Five owners to seek protective alliances with
items stand out: incumbent officials and local power
holders. The rise of widely dispersed
• Lack of vision. Gerschenkron empha- patronage structures across different
sized the importance of ideology as a sectors of the economy obstructed inno-
driver of modern economic growth in vation and also encouraged widespread
follower nations: “in a backward country corruption.
the great and sudden industrialization • Interlocking elite interests. Under
effort calls for a New Deal in emotions” China’s imperial system, the interests
80 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
of the imperial household, the bureau- The challenge from Western imperial-
cracy, and the intellectual, commercial, ism represented a watershed in Chinese
and landed elites were closely aligned history—a novel threat unlike China’s tradi-
and reinforced by a combination of de tional nemesis of land-based invasion across
jure and de facto economic and political her northern frontier. Europe’s rising power
power. This tight web of interests con- threatened the economic, political, institu-
tributed to the system’s longevity, but tional, and ideological underpinnings of the
also strengthened its capacity to resist Qing empire. The turbulent period from
changes that threatened the wealth, roughly 1800 to 1949 helps to illuminate the
power and status of these dominant dynamics of the Ming–Qing system, demon-
groups. strating its resilience while simultaneously
revealing institutional obstacles to economic
We now turn to the long and painful pro- change highlighted in our political economy
cess of pushing back these barriers. analysis.
Prior to 1800, European trade with China
was a lopsided affair dominated by the
4. Turbulent Century: China Confronts
exchange of Chinese commodity exports,
the Industrial Revolution, 1840–1939
notably tea and silk, for silver coin and bul-
lion shipped from the Americas. British
4.1 China’s Opening, 1840–95
merchants, frustrated by the limitations of
The stability of the imperial equilibrium the “Canton system,” which, from 1757, had
hinged on its capacity to thwart internal and restricted European trade49 to that city (now
external threats. Although China’s Qing rul- known as Guangzhou), urged London to
ers, leaders of a seminomadic group with ori- demand wider access to the China market,
gins along China’s northeastern frontier, were initially with little success.
unusually adept at expanding and defending British and Indian traders made a com-
China’s land borders through a combination mercial breakthrough by discovering a ready
of diplomacy and force, the nineteenth cen- Chinese market for India-grown opium.
tury brought a notable acceleration of politi- Believing the ensuing shift in China’s trade
cal and economic change arising from both balance from surplus to deficit and the
internal and external pressures. reversal of long-standing silver inflows were
Beginning with the White Lotus (1796– linked to rising opium imports,50 a disturbed
1804), a series of domestic rebellions cul- Qing court dispatched a high official, LIN
minating with the vast Taiping uprising Zexu, to extirpate the Canton opium trade.
(1851–64) both reflected and contributed to
the erosion of the Qing regime. The simul- evidence of low temperatures and declining rainfall; Man-
taneous upsurge of European military and houng Lin cites contemporary accounts suggesting that sil-
diplomatic pressure along China’s maritime ver outflows during the first half of the nineteenth century
reduced China’s stock of monetary silver by 7–19 percent
frontier—accentuated by falling terms of (2006, pp. 83–85).
trade, unfavorable weather trends, and the 49 The Canton system did not affect trade with Asian
reversal of long-standing silver inflows,— partners, which involved a number of port cities.
50 Recent research has questioned the link between ris-
inflicted further shocks.48 ing opium imports and silver exports during the nineteenth
century, citing other potential sources for the reversal of
silver imports, including the rising gold price of silver,
48 Williamson (2011, pp. 33–34) concludes that China’s declining domestic demand for silver, as well as a break-
external terms of trade fell by 85 percent between 1796 down in the Spanish Peso Standard. See Lin (2006) and
and 1821; Zhang et al. 2007 and Li (2007, pp. 27–30) cite Irigoin (2009).
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 81
When he did so, the British merchants that it was ideology and institutions, rather
sought London’s protection from what they than resource limitations, that imposed bind-
regarded as an illegitimate seizure of mer- ing constraints on China’s growth prospects
cantile property. The result, fuelled by both before and after the start of the treaty
British visions of a vast China market, was port system. As we will see, the insertion
the Opium War of 1839–42.51 British arms of a treaty port economy in the traditional
forced the Qing to accept the Treaty of Chinese empire represented initially what
Nanking (1842), which ceded Hong Kong seemed like a small rupture to a giant closed
to the British, forced the Qing to accept a political system that would only grow over
regime of virtual free trade, and initiated the time to tear at the foundation of traditional
“treaty port” system by opening five Chinese China’s long run political equilibrium.
ports to British merchants. This agreement,
4.2 Change and Resistance to Change,
which set the tone of China’s international
1840–95
economic relations during the century prior
to the Pacific War, subsequently expanded to
4.2.1 Political Accommodation and
include dozens of treaty ports where foreign
Institutional Change to 1895
residents were protected by extraterritorial-
ity at the expense of Chinese sovereignty.52 The new era marked by China’s forced
While these innovations initiated a long opening began disastrously for the Qing,
adjustment process that eventually resulted which barely survived the devastating
in substantial economic advance, the initial Taiping Rebellion (1850–64). Confucian
pace of change was slow. China’s response elites based in Hunan and Anhui provinces
to the treaty system poses difficulties for mobilized funds, assembled regional armies,
Pomeranz’ (2000) reliance on access to and led successful campaigns to defeat the
cheap coal and other land-intensive goods Taiping armies. As noted above, the “Tongzhi
to explain Britain’s unique economic suc- Restoration” (1861–75) engineered a recov-
cess and the consequent “great divergence” ery through the revitalization of traditional
between European and Asian incomes. If institutions. The likin (lijin) tax, levied on
these were the key obstacles to Chinese eco- internal trade to help fund the anti-Taiping
nomic expansion, the nineteenth century effort, developed into an important compo-
treaty system—which allowed unlimited and nent within China’s fiscal system. Along with
virtually duty-free importation of mining new taxes on seaborne international trade col-
equipment as well as coal and other land- lected by the foreign-administered Imperial
intensive products—along with the gradual Maritime Customs, an arrangement forced
increase in migration of Chinese farmers on the Qing by European pressure, the likin
into the fertile and sparsely populated plains system began to restructure the Chinese fis-
of Manchuria should have provided a major cal regime. By 1908, the long-dominant land
impetus to Chinese growth. The absence of tax had declined to 35 percent of officially
any such outcome lends credence to our view recorded revenue (Wang 1973, p. 80).
The rise of commercial taxation, which
51 Johnson cites multiple descriptions of the large scale
became de facto local revenue following
of Shanghai’s domestic trade prior to the Opium War, the suppression of the Taipings, reflected a
including references to “forests of masts” and suggestions process of fiscal as well as political decentral-
that Shanghai’s trade volume surpassed London’s during ization visible throughout Chinese history fol-
the 1830s (1993, pp. 175–76).
52 So and Myers (2011) examine the treaty port lowing major rebellions or invasions (ZHOU
economy. Zhenghe 2009). Aided by newly acquired
82 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
fiscal resources, regional bureaucrats such port system, which opened a growing list of
as LI Hongzhang (1823–1901) and ZHANG ports to European commerce while restrict-
Zhidong (1837–1909) sponsored the Self- ing Chinese tariffs to a modest 5 percent.
Strengthening movement (1860–94), a pro- China’s Maritime Customs data show the
gram that aimed to expand Chinese military volume of exports doubling and imports ris-
strength by developing a small number of ing by 77 percent between 1870 and 1895.53
Western-style, capital-intensive enterprises Despite its modest scale, trade gradually
financed by the state and directed by presti- aligned major domestic commodity prices
gious officials with impeccable academic cre- with international markets throughout the
dentials. Although these enterprises, which Pacific Basin. Brandt’s discovery that, start-
included arsenals, factories, and shipyards, ing in the late 1880s, domestic prices for rice,
were fraught with inefficiency and corrup- wheat, and cotton moved in close harmony
tion, they did record modest achievements with market shifts throughout the Pacific
(Kuo and Liu 1978). The Jiangnan Arsenal, basin demonstrates that several decades
located in Shanghai, impressed Japanese of unfettered trade forged unprecedented
visitors in 1873. Japanese reformers initially global links with vast swathes of China’s
relied on Chinese translations of European economy (1985, 1989). By the late 1880s,
scientific treatises (Elman 2005, p. 411). millions of villagers inhabiting the Yangzi riv-
China’s Hanyeping steelworks began pro- er’s drainage area who grew, bought, or sold
duction five years ahead of Japan’s Yawata rice, or worked for or traded with partners
complex. who engaged in those activities, had become
Despite these innovations, traditional unwitting participants in far-flung networks
thinking dominated, representing, as aptly of international commerce, influencing and
suggested by the title of Wright’s classic being influenced by distant producers, con-
book (1962), the last stand of Chinese con- sumers, and traders of rice.
servatism. In contrast to the concurrent The treaty system accelerated the arrival
Meiji reform in Japan, there was no effort to of new technologies, initially to the treaty
overhaul the regime’s fundamentals. There ports themselves, which, in both the
was no modern constitution or commercial nineteenth- and twentieth-century versions
law, and no reform of the currency system. of expanded links to global markets, became
Railroads were prohibited and steamships staging points for the domestic diffusion of
were restricted to the Yangzi and other major technology. The development of manufac-
rivers; (Wright 1962, SUZUKI Tom o ¯ 1992). turing, however, fell far short of the potential
Perkins (1967) concluded that “If the impe- surrounding the expanded inflow of goods,
rial government of China was an obstacle to technology, and knowledge during the latter
industrialization, it was more because of what half of the nineteenth century.
it did not do than because of harmful efforts Attempts by Chinese and European entre-
which it did undertake. . . . The real problem preneurs to capitalize on opportunities linked
was that although the . . . government . . . to new technologies and trade arrange-
did take a number of positive steps they were ments encountered powerful resistance. The
few and feeble” (1967, pp. 491–92).
53 Figures come from the Nankai quantity indexes of
4.2.2 Economic Change and Its Limits: The
export and import reproduced in Hsiao (1974), p. 274.
Partial Unraveling of Key Institutions Keller, Li, and Shiue (2010, 2011, and 2012) have begun to
systematically exploit the trade data covering 1860s–1949
Expansion of China’s international trade compiled by China’s Maritime Customs agency and sum-
was the most obvious effect of the treaty marized in Hsiao’s volume.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 83
By the early eighteenth century. . . groups of all Chinese trade guilds are alike in inter-
transport workers had become organized into fering with every detail of business and
84 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
4.4.1 Institutional Restructuring and State the 1919 Versailles Treaty56 expanded into
Building in a Time of Instability a broad attack on traditional culture. While
some reformers railed against the inability
While historians continue to study China’s of Confucian thinking to encompass sci-
failed experiment with parliamentary gov- ence or democracy, others joined a 1921
ernment and local self-rule during the first Shanghai conclave that established China’s
four decades of the twentieth century, the Communist Party.
so-called “Warlord era” that followed the Both the privileges and autonomy of
Qing dynasty’s 1911 collapse recalls the polit- treaty ports, especially the largest of them,
ical fragmentation commonly observed dur- Shanghai, strengthened in this time of weak-
ing dynastic interregnums. One researcher ened central rule. Although tinged with for-
counts 140 conflicts involving more than eign privilege and racial discrimination, the
1,300 rival militarists between 1911 and steadfast upholding of freedom of speech
1928 (Billingsley 1988, p. 24). Through and association in the treaty ports fostered
much of the 1910s and 1920s, the self-styled an explosive growth of chambers of com-
national government in Beijing lacked both merce and associations of bankers, lawyers,
revenue and authority. Along with the loss of and accountants, most notably in Shanghai
the power of personnel appointment at the (Xu 2001). Relative peace, stability and rule
province and county levels, fiscal decentral- of law also nurtured the first generation of
ization placed the Beijing administration on Shanghai industrial tycoons, including the
life support from foreign loans collateralized Rong brothers (textiles and flour milling),
by revenues from the Western-controlled LIU Hongshen (matches) and the Jian broth-
(and efficiently managed) bureaucracies ers (tobacco), all of whom operated outside
charged with collecting customs and salt the traditional bureaucratic patronage sys-
taxes (Strauss 1998, Iwai 2004). tem. The legal and jurisdictional autonomy
As had often occurred in China’s past, frag- of Shanghai’s International Settlement shel-
mentation and prolonged weakness at the tered the local branch of Bank of China
center offered opportunities for experimen- from the predatory attempts of the fiscally-
tation with new ideas and institutions that strapped Beijing government (Ma 2011c).
would later reshape the long-term trajec- The result was a unique symbiosis between
tory of Chinese history. Despite the political Chinese entrepreneurs and foreign-con-
chaos, the first three decades of the twenti- trolled treaty ports that flourished despite
eth century brought an interlude of cultural the social discrimination that the expatri-
enlightenment that Bergere (1989) identi- ate communities inflicted on their Chinese
fied as the “golden age of the Chinese bour- neighbors and business partners (Coble
geoisie.” New concepts such as democracy, Jr. 2003). The benefits of rule of law were
science, and self-government, new styles of widely recognized; as one observer noted in
Chinese writing, literature, and academic 1917:
scholarship, new generations of politicians,
scholars, and entrepreneurs, and new sys- The Chinese residing in the International
tems of education achieved growing promi- Settlement have numbered 800,000. Although
nence in the new environment of patriotism
and nationalism (Furth 1983, Kuhn 1986, 56 China, which supplied over 100,000 noncombatant
and Sun 1986). In the face of increasingly workers to support British and French forces in Europe,
expected the Versailles settlement to include the return
aggressive Western and Japanese penetra- of German concessions in Shandong province. Instead,
tion, student-led demonstrations against Article 156 of the treaty awarded these territories to Japan.
88 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
they are unspeakably low in knowledge and much in evidence. In Tianjin, “Guild bosses
[education] level, under the influence of British . . . opposed the efforts of some merchants to
custom, their habit of following the law is supe- introduce motor vehicles. . . . threatened to
rior to [Chinese in] the interior. . . . [whose]
officials bully the people and the people dare kill the general manager of the factory [that
not resort to the law, whereas the residents in had purchased trucks, so that] the factory
the Settlement all know that detaining people had to turn control of transport back to the
without warrant is kidnapping, and a kidnap- guild” (Hershatter 1986, p. 134).
per, whether an official or a commoner, would The establishment of the K uomintang-led
be punished (cited in Xu 2001, p. 41).
Nanjing government in 1927 marked a step
Nonetheless, overall political uncertainty to recentralize state power. The regime
across China in this period presented the mounted a vigorous effort to establish admin-
reverse side of the North paradox: “a govern- istrative structures that could formulate and
ment too weak to be a threat . . . [is also] too implement developmental policies. Strauss
weak to enforce its writ and provide a stable finds that these efforts “coalesced in a number
political and legal environment” (Kirby 1995, of important pockets of Republican govern-
p. 50). China’s 1904 Company Law is a case ment” (1997, p. 340). These state-building
in point. This measure, which introduced efforts drew on the model of China’s
limited liability and aimed to provide uni- Western-controlled Maritime Customs and
versal and formal property rights to Chinese Salt Inspectorate, organizations that dem-
businesses through company registration, onstrated the potential of efficient, honest,
attracted few registrants apart from banks transparent, apolitical bureaucracies led by
and other large, officially-backed enter- expatriates but largely operated by Chinese
prises (Kirby 1995). In an environment of personnel (Strauss 1998, chap. 3). The
political uncertainty and civil unrest, formal Ministry of Finance, setting out to emulate
registration was widely viewed as a danger- the Salt Inspectorate, which it absorbed in
ous recipe for public exposure of private 1927/28, hired “personnel who were experi-
assets. When Guangdong lineage-based enced, competent, and hard-working,” often
firms sought Hong Kong registration under turning to “open civil service examination
British common law, their objective was nei- as the preferred method of recruitment” as
ther to secure limited liability nor to attract “new departments and sections were cre-
outside capital, but rather to obtain shelter ated” during the 1930s (Strauss 1998, p. 187).
from official predation rampant in the city of The Nanjing government pursued genu-
Canton wracked by rebellion and revolutions ine tax reforms. After restoring China’s tariff
(Chung 2010). autonomy in 1928 (KUBO T o ¯ r u 2005), the
Most Chinese entrepreneurs operated regime sought to impose standard domes-
outside the formal sphere, drawing on long- tic taxes in place of the likin system, which
standing traditions of private contracting was encrusted with tax farming, extralegal
and social networking to help resolve issues fees, and ad hoc imposts (Iwai 2004, pp.
of information asymmetry and contractual 381–85). At the same time, CHIANG Kai-
disputes. Family firms and lineage or rela- shek [JIANG Jieshi], the Nanjing regime’s
tion-based partnerships dominated (Zelin strongman, used traditional tactics to extract
2009).57 The old patronage system remained resources from urban businesses. CHIANG
enlisted Shanghai’s criminal underworld to
57 Foreign-owned treaty port firms shared the Chinese
pressure enterprises located in Shanghai’s
penchant for recruiting on the basis of family or regional foreign-controlled concessions, leading to
links (Rawski 1969, pp. 464–65). confrontations with prominent Shanghai
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 89
capitalists and eroding the rule of law within of global cotton piece goods (ILO 1937,
the treaty port (Coble 1986, p. xi). vol. 1, pp. 57–58).58
China’s improving economic prospects
4.4.2 The Onset of Modern Economic
attracted trade and investment. China’s for-
Growth
eign trade rose to a peak of more than two
China’s first wave of industrialization percent of global trade flows in the late 1920s,
occurred amidst political uncertainty. a level that was not regained until the 1990s
Following the 1896 treaty settlement, activ- (Lardy 1994, p. 2). Remer calculated that,
ity in mining and manufacturing accelerated between 1902 and 1931, inflows of foreign
sharply from its tiny initial base. Output of direct investment grew at annual rates of 8.3,
modern industry (i.e. excluding handicrafts) 5 and 4.3 percent in Shanghai, Manchuria
showed double-digit real growth during and the rest of China (1968, p. 73). By 1938,
1912–36, in spite of political instability and China’s stock of inward foreign investment
the impact of the Great Depression (Chang amounted to US$2.6 billion—more than
1969). Factory production clustered in two any other underdeveloped region except
regions: the lower Yangzi area, where both for the Indian subcontinent and Argentina
foreign and Chinese entrepreneurs pursued (Hou 1965, p. 98). Although estimates of
industrial ventures in and around Shanghai, pre-war capital flows often blur the distinc-
and the northeast or Manchurian region, tion between direct and portfolio holdings,
where Japanese initiatives predominated it is evident that China played a considerable
(Lieu 1936; Schumpeter 1940; Mansh ¯
u
role in global capital flows. The 1938 figure
kaihatsu 1964-65; Ma 2008). World War I, of US$2.6 billion for China’s stock of for-
which weakened competitive pressure from eign investments amounts to 8.4 percent of
European imports, spurred the expansion of worldwide stocks of outward foreign invest-
domestic manufacturing in the absence of ment; China received 17.5 percent of out-
tariff autonomy. bound foreign direct investment in that year
As in other nations, factory production (Twomey 2000, pp. 32, 35)—compared with
initially focused on textiles, food processing, 2.1 percent of inward FDI in 2001 (Velde
and other consumer products. The growth 2006, Table 2).
of consumer industries spurred new private Domestic investment expanded rapidly.
initiatives in machinery, chemicals, cement, “Modern-oriented” fixed investment (calcu-
mining, electricity, and metallurgy. Official lated from domestic absorption of cement,
efforts (including semiofficial Japanese activ- steel, and machinery) grew at an average rate
ity in Manchuria) promoted the growth of of 8.1 percent during 1903–36, outpacing
mining, metallurgy, and arms manufacture Japanese gross domestic fixed capital forma-
(Rawski 1975; 1989, chap. 2). Foreign inves- tion in mining, manufacturing, construction,
tors dominated the early stages of China’s and facilitating industries, which advanced
modern industrialization, but Chinese at an annual rate of 5.0 percent. Defying
entrepreneurs quickly came to the fore, so the effects of the Great Depression and
that Chinese-owned companies produced political tumult, economy-wide gross fixed
73 percent of China’s 1933 factory output
(Rawski 1989, p. 74). In some sectors, the 58 Hong Kong’s prominence in the textile sector during
scale of operation became substantial: by the early postwar decades followed the arrival of Shanghai
1935, textile mills in China produced 8 per- textile entrepreneurs, who diverted shipments of imported
equipment to Hong Kong as Communist prospects for vic-
cent the world’s cotton yarn (more than tory in China’s civil war advanced during the late 1940s.
Germany, France, or Italy) and 2.8 percent See Ma 2008.
90 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
investment exceeded ten percent of aggre- regional specialties like cotton, fruit, sesame,
gate output during 1931–36 (Rawski 1989, peanuts, and tobacco (Liang 1982, chap. 5).
pp. 251, 261), with direct foreign investment A particularly sweeping transformation
contributing at least one-eighth and perhaps occurred in money and banking. China’s
more.59 Republican era inherited a pre-modern mon-
Transport development also supported etary system that mixted silver bullion, coins,
economic expansion. China’s growing rail- copper cash, and private notes. However,
way network, although much smaller than from the early 20th century, minted sil-
India’s, was particularly important. As the ver dollars, including a rising proportion of
length of track grew from 364 kilometers domestic coinage, gradually replaced silver
in 1894 to over 21,000 by 1937, newly con- taels even in rural areas.60 Meanwhile, a
structed north–south lines slashed economic simultaneous shift toward widespread use of
distances across a landscape dominated banknotes convertible into silver on demand
by rivers flowing from west to east (YAN under China’s free banking version of a sil-
Zhongping et al. 1955, p. 180). Completion ver standard delivered even larger benefits.
of railway and telegraph connections link- Beginning in the early 1920s, public accep-
ing Peking (Beijing) and the central China tance of banknotes issued by the Bank of
river port of Wuhan, for example, reduced China and the Bank of Communication,
the time needed to ship goods between these quasi-public Chinese institutions that ben-
cities, sell them, and receive the proceeds efited from the political and legal security of
from 150 to only 2–3 days (based on Whitney China’s treaty ports, grew rapidly. Innovative
1970, p. 46). Growing availability of rail arrangements that allowed smaller financial
transport encouraged coal mining, with the institutions to exchange cash and govern-
result that “falling energy costs stimulated ment bonds for notes issued by these two
new activity in a wide range of industries. . . . banks accelerated the economy-wide substi-
[including] railway workshops [and] manu- tution of bank notes for hard currency (Ma
facturers of cement, textiles, flour, cigarettes, 2013). As a result, the estimated share of
matches, chemicals” and others. Lower fuel notes and deposits in M1 money supply rose
prices also “led to the revival of native indus- from 22.3–34.6 percent in 1910 to a mini-
tries which had earlier languished because mum of 40.4 percent in 1925 and 83.2 per-
of the high cost of fuel” (Rawski 1989, cent in 1936 (Rawski 1989, p. 157) following
pp. 224–25; Wright 1984, p. 46). Railway the Nanjing government’s shift to a fiduciary
transport also stimulated further commer- currency in 1935 (Shiroyama 2008; Brandt
cialization of agriculture, raising farmers’ and Sargent 1989). By the 1930s, the nation-
terms of trade and boosting production of wide branch network of Chinese modern
banks extended to over 500 localities; some
banks began to experiment with loans to
59 Rawski places average annual gross domestic fixed
farmers as well as merchants and industrial-
capital formation during 1931–36 at 3 billion 1933 yuan
(1989, p. 260). Remer (1968, p. 83) estimates that China’s ists (Rawski 1989, pp. 136, 152).
FDI stock (which he calls “business investment”), grew by
US$1.43 billion between 1914 and 1931, or by an annual
average of US$83.9 million, which converts to 370 mil-
lion yuan or 12.3 percent of average capital formation for
1931–36. If, as seems likely, annual FDI inflows increased 60MA Junya (2008) explains how a nationwide network
between 1914 and 1931, this calculation understates the of native banks shifted both bills and silver dollars to take
share of FDI in aggregate investment. Exchange rate data advantage of differentials in dollar–tael exchange rates
are taken from Remer (1968, p. 151) and Hsiao (1974, linked to varying agricultural cycles, particularly between
p. 192). north and south China.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 91
Along with this impressive monetary sectors, including traditional finance and the
expansion came the sustained development native banks (qianzhuang), handicraft tex-
of new financial instruments and institutions. tiles, traditional water transport, and, most
Major urban centers, especially Shanghai, importantly, agriculture, which occupied
also saw the growth of new financial institu- two-thirds of GDP.
tions, namely a stock exchange and insur- Constrained by the unreliability of avail-
ance and trust companies (YAN Hongzhong able information on acreage and yields,
2012). Most notable is the growth of public Rawski appeals to indirect measures of labor
debt during the Republican era. While, dur- productivity in agriculture: wages of hired
ing the 1910s and 1920s, the bulk of the gov- farm labor and nonfarm wages available to
ernment debt came from foreign bank loans unskilled rural migrants in male (coal mining)
often securitized by governmental fiscal and female (cotton textile factories) occu-
revenues from Maritime customs and other pations that competed for farm labor. The
sources, the Nanjing decade (1927–37) saw argument is that, with ample labor mobil-
the emergence of a vibrant domestic market ity and competitive labor markets, sustained
for bonds issued by the Nationalist govern- increases in real wages paid to farm labor-
ment (Goetzmann, Ukhov, and Zhu 2007; ers, miners, and mill hands imply parallel
Yan 2012). increases in the marginal product of agricul-
These forces resulted in increased per tural labor, and therefore, in the real income
capita output and structural changes of the of the majority of self-employed farmers who
sort associated with Simon Kuznets’ concept operated independently as owners or tenants
of modern economic growth in two major (Rawski 1989, chap. 6).61
regions: the Lower Yangzi, where private These achievements occurred despite the
domestic and foreign investment in and absence of a truly national government and
around Shanghai served as the key driver (Ma the inability of the aspiring Nanjing regime
2008) and the Northeast (Manchuria), where to establish control over interior provinces
Japanese investment and eventual take- or rural areas (Eastman 1984, pp. 219, 221)
over provided key momentum (Chao 1982, or to push central revenue above 3 percent
MIZOGUCHI Toshiyuki and UMEMURA of aggregate output (Rawski 1989, p. 15).
Mataji 1988). Growth persisted in the face of multiple
More controversially, Rawski (1989) shocks: the Great Depression, falling export
argues that developments in industry, trans- demand, Japan’s severance of Manchuria in
port, and finance precipitated a nationwide 1932, rapidly rising silver prices triggered
episode of modern economic growth at by Britain’s decision to go off gold, and the
the national level during the early decades United States Silver Purchase Act of 1934.
of the twentieth century. His estimates of While debate surrounds the extent and
modern-sector growth resemble earlier significance of this early wave of economic
results (e.g. Chang 1969 for modern indus- expansion, there is little doubt about what
try). But with the modern sector accounting followed. Japan’s 1937 invasion plunged
for only 12.6 percent of GDP in 1933 (Liu China into an eight-year abyss of warfare,
and Yeh 1965, p. 89), its growth says little
about changes in aggregate output. In con- 61 Brandt (1989) makes a similar case for Central and
trast to Murphey (1977), Rawski finds that Eastern China, focusing on increasing specialization and
substantial spillovers from modern sector commercialization in the farm sector, a process that he ties
to growing openness to the international economy, favor-
activity pushed output expansion ahead of able terms of trade, and spillovers from China’s emergent
population growth in several nonmodern modern/urban sector.
92 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
followed immediately by renewed civil strife Taiwan and the People’s Republic (Kirby
between Nationalists and Communists. 1990; Bian 2005).
These conflicts took a massive toll of both Reflecting Leninist theory as well as expe-
human life and physical capital. They also rience acquired from the administration
imposed further costs arising from rampant of rural base areas during several decades
corruption, fiscal predation and hyperinfla- of intermittent civil war (Schran 1976; Lai
tion. These circumstances partly accounted 2011), the Communists came to power with
for the rise of a new regime that quickly a disciplined party hierarchy, to which they
achieved historically unprecedented cen- quickly added a vertically integrated admin-
tralization and control under a socialist istrative structure that, for the first time in
command economy. Chinese history, penetrated to the village
level.62 This system, fortified by patron-
age linked to the nomenklatura system
5. Development under the People’s
of official appointments and the officially
Republic of China
controlled distribution of scarce resources
under the new central plan, equipped the
5.1 Socialist Planning 1949–76
state with unprecedented capacity to ensure
When MAO Zedong’s victorious armies nationwide implementation of official direc-
marched into Beijing, the new regime inher- tives without relying on the cooperation of
ited a shattered economy wracked by physi- local gentry or other independent agents.
cal destruction and extreme macroeconomic Although provincial and local leaders often
instability. But unlike Mao’s vision of the adapted and distorted messages from Beijing
new nation as a “blank sheet of paper,” the to promote their own agendas, this new
intellectual and mental outlook of China structure produced a historic expansion of
in 1950 was fundamentally different from state power.
the society that British traders and diplo- The broad contours of economic change
mats had encountered a century earlier. following the establishment, in 1949, of
Growing interaction with the outside world the People’s Republic of China (PRC) and
had expanded the knowledge and broadened the reunification of China under Chinese
the intellectual horizons of elites and many Communist Party (CCP) rule are well
ordinary folk, especially in coastal regions, understood. The new government quickly
with communism as a radical manifestation implemented an orthodox mix of fiscal and
of such new departures. monetary policies to restore fiscal balance
A century of change had endowed China and quell hyperinflation, steps that helped
with a considerable, albeit unevenly dis- facilitate recovery from damage inflicted by
tributed, physical and human infrastructure twelve years of war and civil strife. Following
of modern transportation, administration, violent campaigns that expropriated the
and enterprise. The National Resources assets of urban and rural elites, the latter
Commission, “the technical and manage- through a land reform that redistributed
rial agency” set up by the Nationalists that approximately 40 percent of the agricul-
eventually employed 12,000 staffers to direct tural land (Schran 1969, p. 22; Wong 1973,
and control most of China’s industries during
the Sino–Japanese War of 1937–45, earned a
62 Liu (2005) highlights the parallel between the early
reputation for efficient, apolitical operation.
PRC and the system instituted by ZHU Yuanzhang (1328–
Former staff members figured prominently 98), the first Ming emperor; both expanded state control
in postwar economic administration in both and restricted market activity and labor mobility.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 93
p. 160; Roll 1980, chap. 4), the PRC moved accelerate the pace of development by amal-
to implement a socialist planning system gamating rural households into large-scale
loosely modeled after the Soviet Union, collective units (renmin gongshe or People’s
which supplied loans, technology, and advice Communes), and promoting rural industrial-
for China’s First Five-Year Plan (1953–57). ization. The communes proved to be a costly
China’s plan system, like its Soviet coun- failure: poor incentives for farm households,
terpart, sought to develop and expand a coupled with perverse incentives that led
self-sustaining military-industrial complex. local officials to submit false reports of bum-
This called for high rates of saving to finance per crops and encouraged higher echelons
investment skewed toward heavy industry, to demand excessive grain procurement, as
along with an elaborate planning apparatus well as massive reallocation of labor from
to capture resources and channel them into agriculture to industry inflicted an immense
high-priority investments. With most mar- famine on China’s peasantry that cost tens
kets replaced by officially mandated alloca- of millions of lives.65 Efforts to revive for-
tion of resources and outputs, the regime set ward momentum in the early 1960s met with
prices to extract savings from farmers and some success, but the economy suffered
consumers. These savings made their way to further setbacks in the mid-1960s when a
the state coffers through profit remittances political campaign known as the “Cultural
of state-owned enterprises.63 In the country- Revolution” sparked a new reversal in eco-
side, collectivization and strict controls on nomic policies and incentive mechanisms.
personal mobility through the hukou system Mixed economic outcomes characterize
of residential permits facilitated resource China’s quarter-century of socialist planning
extraction. In the cities, rationing contrib- under MAO and his colleagues. The plan era
uted to a buildup in household savings. brought notable expansion of industrial and
Despite these similarities, Chinese plan- technological capabilities, as well as major
ning was never as extensive as the Soviet improvements in literacy, school attendance,
Union’s and remained much more decen- maternal and infant survival rates, pub-
tralized (Wong 1985; Xu 2011). In con- lic health, and life expectancy. Real annual
trast to the U-form hierarchy of the Soviet GDP growth officially reported at roughly
Union, the Chinese economy resembled an 6 percent (aggregate) and 4 percent in per
M-form, with a large number of relatively capita terms66 surpassed gains in India, and
self-sufficient provinces and prefectures other populous low-income nations, often by
(Donnithorne 1972; Maskin, Qian, and Xu large margins (Morawetz 1978).
2000).64
Starting in 1958, China distanced itself
from Moscow’s political leadership and eco- 65 On official incentives, see Kung and Chen (2011).
nomic strategy, as MAO Zedong sought to Discovery of new materials has tended to raise estimates
of famine deaths. Work by Ashton et al. (1984) and Peng
(1987), based on census data, suggests excess mortality
63 The ratio of fiscal revenue to national product, which between 20–30 million. Dikötter’s recent review “puts the
never reached 10 percent during the Qing or Republican number of premature deaths at a minimum of 45 million”
eras, averaged more than 25 percent between 1952 and (2010, p. 325).
1977. (Compendium 2010, p. 18). 66 These official figures for 1953–78, based on what
64 Using terminology derived from studies of corporate the Chinese call “comparable prices,” are from China’s
structures by Alfred Chandler and others, Maskin, Qian, National Bureau of Statistics (NBS 2007, p. 7). Use of 2000
and Xu (2000) describe Chinese industrial structures as prices, which avoids upward bias inherent in plan prices
“M-form”—i.e. analogous to multi-divisional corporations, assigned during the 1950s, results in average annual growth
which they contrast with “U-form” (resembling unitary of 4.4 percent for real GDP during 1952–78 (Perkins and
corporations) structures observed in Soviet industry. Rawski 2008, p. 839).
94 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
left cynical and demoralized following two Trust and Investment Corporation
decades of hunger and instability. (CITIC)—“the investment arm of the
Chinese state,”—and eventually appointed
5.2.1 The Role of Political Change
to the ceremonial post of Vice President,
China’s initial decade and a half of reform epitomized this change (Economist 2005).
rested on important political changes that Of particular importance was a new system
interacted with economic initiatives to facili- of performance evaluation for subnational
tate the economy’s gradual shift toward officials based on quantitative algorithms that
market-influenced outcomes. assigned major weight to local GDP growth
Recognizing that improved living stan- (Whiting 2001). Facilitated by China’s
dards were central to reestablishing political M-form hierarchy, these policies are widely
legitimacy, China’s ruling Communist Party viewed as having inspired tournament-like
shifted its objectives toward greater empha- competition among county and provincial
sis on economic growth, particularly at the leaders, who recognized that accelerated
intensive margin. At the same time, the party economic growth would bring recognition
shifted its objectives away from the “ideologi- and promotion, and made strenuous efforts
cal correctness” that had turned descendants to ramp up local economies (Li and Zhou
of landlords, businessmen, and noncom- 2005).71
munist political leaders into pariahs and The new vertical alignment of incentives
elevated “red” enthusiasm over “expertise” spanning the CCP leadership, local and
derived from knowledge and experience. regional officials, and ordinary Chinese—
The CCP also revised its own internal most of whom stood to benefit from rapid
structure to emphasize governance based economic growth—reduced the agency costs
on formal procedures rather than, as under inherent in any system of governance in a
MAO, the personal inclinations of top lead- nation of China’s size. It also strengthened
ers. Xu refers to the early years of reform as the capacity of China’s government and party
a “watershed period in which the CCP began leaders to shape the behavior of lower-level
to transform itself from a ‘personality-ruled officials assigned to implement the center’s
party’” into what Shirk (1993) describes as policy decisions (Naughton 2011).
“a system governed by rules, clear lines of Under the PRC’s authoritarian political
authority, and collective decision making system, the Party defines policy objectives.
institutions” (2011, p. 1090). The changes In doing so, leaders depend on a system of
included personnel policies meant to elevate policy experimentation with deep historical
objective criteria over seniority or personal roots—both during the pre-1949 experi-
ties as the chief determinants of appoint- ence in Communist-controlled base areas,
ments and promotions. and, at greater remove, during the imperial
Elite recruitment reflected this shift, as era, when local experimentation gave birth
both government and party welcome new to the nationally implemented likin (lijin) tax
graduates of China’s universities follow- on domestic trade during the second half of
ing the revival of merit-based admissions in the nineteenth century.72 Heilmann traces
1977. Elite recruitment gradually encom-
passed entrepreneurs and other former
pariahs: the rehabilitation of RONG Yiren, a 71 Montinola, Qian, and Weingast provide examples of
trickle, and then a torrent of capital inflows plant insisted that he did not know the unit
as local governments raced to attract top cost of the products coming off his assembly
international companies. Following an initial line, telling visitors that, “our job is to pro-
focus on export production, China’s ongoing duce sewing machines; costs are the con-
economic expansion sharpened the interest cern of the general company office” (1982
of multinational firms in China’s domestic interviews).
market as well. This enabled Chinese offi- China’s reformers, dissatisfied with the
cials to hone their strategy of offering market passivity of firms that were intended to lead
access in exchange for large-scale technology China’s economy, set out to “enliven” state-
transfers to the foreign firms’ domestic sup- owned industry by injecting new incentives,
pliers and joint venture partners. flexibility, and technology.76 Neither privatiza-
As a result, China, formerly among the most tion nor bankruptcy was considered. Instead,
isolated economies, moved rapidly to rejoin managers of state enterprises were granted
the global system of exchange. Between 1978 modestly expanded autonomy. Funding was
and 1993, official data show a rise in China’s shifted from government grants to loans
trade ratio from 9.7 to 31.9 percent along from newly established state banks. Hints of
with rising inflows of foreign investment. a labor market began to appear: retirees and
workers with special skills concluded infor-
Enlivening state enterprises. Between mal moonlighting arrangements. A new class
1955 and 1978, the number of industrial of “contract” workers emerged without the
enterprises increased from 125,000 to lifetime job security promised to incumbent
348,000, output rose by a factor of 10, and workers in state-owned enterprises.
factory employment expanded from 5.9 to Rather than transferring profits (and
61 million workers. In 1978, state-owned losses) to the state, firms could now keep
enterprises contributed 77.6 percent of a share of their profits and deploy them
industrial production, with the remain- to upgrade equipment, pay bonuses, or
der coming from collective firms, most improve workers’ housing. To supply nascent
controlled by local governments or state- markets, firms were allowed to find their
owned firms.75 Most firms, most managers, own outlets for production that exceeded
and many workers had no market-economy plan quotas, which in China tended to be
experience. Enterprises carried out instruc- considerably below actual capacity. In 1984,
tions. Pricing, advertising, marketing, prod- a new “dual track policy” institutionalized
uct selection, and responding to market these initiatives, partitioning most commod-
developments played no role in day-to-day ity markets into plan and market compo-
operations. Observations from 1982 regard- nents. This horizontal bifurcation represents
ing two manufacturers of sewing machines a genuine policy innovation, retaining the
illustrate prereform circumstances. When tax/subsidy elements implicit in plan alloca-
a visitor suggested that the work force at a tions of inputs and outputs, while revealing
Guangzhou factory was three times the nec- current information about marginal costs to
essary size, the manager agreed, but asked, agents throughout the economy.77
“if we did not employ them, where would
they go?” The manager of a large Shanghai
76 Accounts of initial reforms affecting state-owned
industry include Naughton (1995) and Steinfeld (1998).
75 Data in this paragraph are from Chen (1967, pp. 77 Under modest assumptions, this regime approaches
182, 475); Industry 2000, p. 21; Compendium 2010, p. 40; Paul Samuelson’s vision of a market system with initial
Yearbook (1991, p. 96). lump-sum transfers.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 99
of reform produced no substantial group the late 1980s/early 1990s, ensured that the
of losers—a rare outcome in episodes of gains from rapid growth were more widely
substantial socio-economic change (Lau,
shared than would otherwise have occurred
Qian, and Roland 2000). Income inequality (Brandt and Zhu 2000).
retreated during the first reform decade,
5.2.4 Political and Economic Change
as rural reform success eroded the gap
since the mid-1990s
between rural and (much higher) urban
incomes (Ravallion and Chen 2007). The Despite more than a decade of rapid eco-
early reforms mainly affected resource flows: nomic expansion, China reached a critical
adjustments of stocks in the form of layoffs, juncture during the early 1990s. Growth had
bankruptcy, or privatization were notably become increasingly cyclical, with successive
absent. periods of liberalization and reform accom-
Reforms such as the dual-track system, panied by rising inflation along with acceler-
which protected the nominal value of long- ating growth. Soft budget constraints in the
standing economic rents, stand out in this state sector saddled the state-owned banks
regard. In addition, potential reform losers with non-performing loans that may have
often became its strongest advocates and exceeded one-half of their asset portfolios
beneficiaries. Dissolution of collective farm- (Brandt and Zhu 2007). Central government
ing undermined the power and perquisites fiscal revenue fell to twenty percent of rev-
of rural leaders, but simultaneously endowed enue collected by all levels of government,
them with new opportunities to turn politi- and only 3 percent of GDP. Many of these
cal networks into economic assets by form- problems reflected one central issue: the
ing new businesses or taking over former drag on an increasingly liberalized economy
commune and brigade enterprises. Similarly, arising from bloated, plodding, and inef-
the retreat from planning encouraged wide- ficient state-owned enterprises burdened
spread commercialization of government with surplus workers, weak management, lax
agencies, partly in response to the fiscal labor and financial discipline, rising losses,
squeeze described earlier, which enabled and overdue debts.
government officials to turn what began as Urban unrest culminating in the June
a reduction in their authority into economic 1989 crackdown in Beijing and other cities,
gain. combined with the subsequent fall of the
Of equal or perhaps greater importance Berlin Wall and collapse of the Soviet Union
in preserving stability was massive resource confronted China’s leaders with a profound
redistribution from China’s rapidly grow- crisis of legitimacy. Following initial moves
ing and dynamic nonstate sector to the to roll back previous reform efforts, DENG
sluggish state sector. Wages and employ- Xiaoping’s Southern Tour of 1992 revived the
ment in the lagging state sector continued momentum of market-leaning reform, pav-
to grow because of ongoing injections of ing the way for the CCP’s 1993 decision to
credit through China’s state controlled finan- adopt the long-term objective of building a
cial system. Limited channels for deploying “socialist market economy.” This surprisingly
China’s rapidly rising savings—a product of explicit document proposed a long-term
financial repression—meant that much of objective of limiting government’s economic
the increase in savings ended up in China’s role to macroeconomic control; prudential
state-run banks, which in turn recycled them regulation of such matters as competition,
to state-linked firms and institutions. These social safety nets, health, and environment;
flows, which exceeded 10 percent of GDP by and strategic planning, with other choices to
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 101
reflect the outcome of market p rocesses.79 industrial parks to attract overseas and
The 1993 decision led to a succession of domestic investors, loosened restric-
fresh reform initiatives, including tions on overseas travel and study for its
own citizens, encouraged Chinese firms
• A sweeping fiscal overhaul that sharply to invest overseas, and extended legal,
increased the center’s fiscal strength tax, and regulatory changes initially
(Wong and Bird 2008). restricted to special economic zones and
• Comprehensive restructuring of the coastal regions throughout the domestic
enterprise sector, including the fur- economy.
loughing and eventual dismissal of tens • Major efforts to expand domestic market
of millions of redundant state sector orientation, including extensive priva-
employees, substantial privatization of tization and deregulation of domestic
both state and collective enterprises, trade and transportation, a major roll-
along with further reforms—including back of official involvement in pricing
virtual elimination of planned allocation and allocation of both commodities and
of materials—that sharply increased the labor, and a rapid increase in the share
market orientation of the remaining of private business in output and espe-
government-linked firms.80 cially employment, backed by new con-
• Financial reorganization that tightened stitutional and legal provisions affirming
central control, strengthened the central the legitimacy of private ownership and
bank, injected new assets, and removed the state’s responsibility to protect pri-
nonperforming loans from the balance vate (along with state and collective)
sheets of state-owned banks, increased property.
the banks’ commercial orientation, and
reduced the power of provincial and The new reform efforts were far more sys-
local officials to influence lending deci- tematic than earlier initiatives. They were
sions (Allen, Qian, and Qian 2008; Yi also far more aggressive, including measures
2010). that imposed substantial costs on large and
• Broad embrace of globalization that potentially powerful groups, such as urban
transformed China into a major par- state sector workers and state enterprises
ticipant in global flows of commodities, inundated with competition from imports
capital, and technology (Branstetter following steep reductions in trade barriers.
and Lardy 2008). To this end, China They also appear to have had the desired
reduced tariffs and other trade barri- effects. Productivity growth in the state non-
ers in advance of its 2001 entry into agricultural sector during 1998–2007 was as
the World Trade organization, estab- high as that in the nonstate sector (Brandt
lished numerous economic zones and and Zhu 2010). Analysis of enterprise-level
total factor productivity (TFP) results shows
steep improvement in state-sector perfor-
79 The text of this decision is available at http://www. mance. In 1998, the average gap between
gov.cn/gongbao/shuju/1993/gwyb199328.pdf, pp. 1286 TFP levels in state-owned and (more pro-
1303 (Chinese version) and China Daily, Supplement,
November 17, 1993 (English translation). Qian and Wu ductive) nonstate firms in 425 manufacturing
explain the background and impact of this document subsectors was nearly 30 percent. By 2007,
(2003, pp. 35–42).
80 On labor issues, see Rawski 2006 and Cai 2010. On
this gap had largely disappeared. (Brandt
state enterprise reform, see Holz 2003; Garnaut, Song, and et al., in progress). Aggregate TFP growth
Tenev 2005; Yusuf, Nabeshima, and Perkins 2006. during 1998–2007 surpassed growth rates
102 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
of urbanization. Chinese producers and con- To understand the long delay in China’s
sumers are increasingly engaged with sophis- response to the new landscape of modern
ticated technologies like smart phones and economic growth that unfolded during the
high-speed trains. Formerly state-controlled ninettenth and twentieth centuries, this
and internationally isolated, China’s economy essay has focused on ideology and institu-
once again reflects the deep and expand- tional constraints. We view the trajectory
ing influence of domestic and global market of China’s twentieth century economy as a
forces. gradual and ongoing process of rolling back
old and new institutional barriers obstruct-
6.2 Linking China’s Economy with the Past:
ing prosperity and growth. We begin by com-
Continuities and Departures
paring the Qing imperial regime with the
China’s growth spurt has stimulated efforts reform-era People’s Republic. 82
to define a “Chinese model” of growth, or
6.2.1 Major Institutional Continuities
to establish a “Beijing consensus” of devel-
opment-enhancing policies (e.g. Hsu, Wu, Our review reveals substantial areas of
and Zhao 2011). Such thinking assumes institutional continuity linking China’s past
that China’s economic, political, and social and present.
circumstances sufficiently resemble prevail-
ing conditions in other low-income nations, Authoritarian system. Major ele-
so that application of Chinese policies may ments of institutional continuity begin with
produce something akin to recent Chinese China’s authoritarian political system. In
outcomes. But the deep historical roots the People’s Republic, as under Qing rule,
surrounding important features of China’s self-perpetuating elites exercise supreme
current institutions and the central role of authority with no formal checks and bal-
China’s unusual legacy of human capital ances. Although the Qing memorial sys-
undermine this approach. tem and the Communist Party’s practice of
We attribute China’s recent economic suc- democratic centralism provide avenues for
cess to a combination of beneficial historic lower ranking-individuals to influence policy
legacies, recent and past accumulations outcomes, decisions emanating from the
of capital, skill, and policy expertise, and throne or politburo are final. Despite the
important economic and political changes growing influence of international norms
that facilitated the realization of old and new
potentials. Despite the success of China’s
imperial system in absorbing vast population 82 These challenges are evident in Fukuyama’s recent
increases, the administrative, organizational, work, which showcases imperial China as the prototype
of an empire with strong state capacity. While recogniz-
and entrepreneurial skills, commercial and ing issues such as corruption, Fukuyama largely neglects
transport networks, and other developmen- the patrimonial nature and inherent weakness of the Qing
tally promising resources visible in the Qing political system as well as efforts to engage in modern state
building from the beginning of the twentieth century. To
economy proved incapable of generating a explain why high-speed growth occurred only after 1978,
rapid and effective response to new opportu- Fukuyama resorts to a more cultural explanation: “What
nities arising from the British industrial revo- China did not have was the spirit of maximization that
economists assume is a universal human trait.” He goes on
lution. If historic accumulation of resources to claim that, “It is far likelier that cultural attitudes towards
and capabilities deserves recognition as an science, learning, and innovation explain why China did so
important contributor to China’s recent poorly in the global economic race in previous centuries,
and is doing so well at the present, rather than any funda-
growth, why does China’s boom begin only mental defect in political institutions” (2011, pp. 316–17).
in the late 1970s? We disagree on both points.
104 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
and practices and the façade of a separate fees, local leaders turned the power of emi-
and independent legal structure, China’s nent domain into a new source of revenue
tradition of strong official control over the by commandeering farmland with nominal
administration of law and justice, especially compensation and reselling it for business
over politically sensitive cases, remains use at much higher prices.
intact. Today, as in the past, the top echelon
of political leaders often decides matters Economic decentralization and local
behind closed doors that, in other societies, experimentation. Both Qing and the
might be determined by legislative action, People’s Republic combine centralization of
legal codes or judicial verdicts. political authority with relatively decentral-
ized economies. The Qing economy was a de
Personnel, agency and central–local facto market system with private ownership.
tensions. To implement central policies, During the prereform decades under the
both the Qing and the People’s Republic People’s Republic, China’s planned economy,
rely on centrally-managed, merit-based per- though patterned after the Soviet example,
sonnel systems. The Confucian approach was far less centralized than the USSR’s,
emphasizing “rule of (properly trained, with provincial and local governments con-
selected and motivated) men” rather than trolling numerous state-owned enterprises
“rule of law” prevails. Both systems rely on and managing substantial resource flows.
a combination of ideology and oversight Reforms have increased these decentraliz-
to limit the inevitable agency costs associ- ing tendencies, albeit within the context of
ated with granting substantial autonomy to a largely market economy in which the state
lower-level officials, whose career prospects sector generates less than 30 percent of GDP
depend more on outcomes than on adher- (Brandt and Zhu 2010).
ence to carefully prescribed procedures. Chinese governments consistently pref-
With imperfect monitoring, we observe ace major policy initiatives with local experi-
similar agency problems today as under the ments, which form “an essential part of the
Qing. Like the Qing, the current regime has central decision-making process” in China
implemented vigorous measures to curb today (Xu 2011, p. 1079). Experimentation
what the center views as corrupt diversion of continues: in October 2011, four sub-national
tax payments intended for the central trea- jurisdictions were authorized to issue provin-
sury. The reform efforts of the Yongzheng cial or municipal bonds (http://english/caijing/
emperor (r. 1678–1735) failed to dent “infor- com/cn/2011-10-25/110916003.html).
mal networks of local power and influence” or
to eliminate “the tax evasion and tax farming Education, human capital and entre-
that [had] decreased the level of remittances” preneurship. The historical legacy of
to the central treasury (Zelin 1984, p. 307). national civil-service examinations designed
These tensions persist: Shue observes that to support the imperial administration
rural administration in the PRC both before helped to make pursuit of education a hall-
and after the start of reform “perpetuated mark of Chinese society throughout the
the contained but unrelenting central–local past millennium. It also promoted remark-
struggle characteristic of imperial politics” able cultural homogeneity across China’s
(1988, p. 114). Local governments continue vast landscape. Even though PRC empha-
to resist Beijing’s efforts to limit the scale of sis on basic education has delivered notable
taxation and fee collection. When the center improvements in school attendance and
eliminated agricultural taxes and rural school other dimensions of human development,
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 105
stocks of human c apital accumulated before migrants to Thailand, many of whom “came
1949 figure prominently in recent economic . . . almost straight from the farm,” quickly
gains. Reflecting long-standing cultural val- came to dominate Thailand’s domestic and
ues, three decades of negative financial international commerce. In contrast to Thai
returns for graduates,83 school closures and natives, Skinner comments that Chinese
suspension of merit-based admissions during migrants hailed from “a grimly Malthusian
the Cultural Revolution (roughly 1966–76), setting where thrift and industry were essen-
and persecution of intellectuals did not deter tial for survival.” Ideology reinforced this
millions of Chinese families from emphasiz- divergence: Chinese struggled for wealth to
ing learning and study. Restoration of univer- preserve family and lineage continuity, while
sity entrance examinations in 1977 attracted Thai norms frowned on “excessive concern
swarms of self-taught candidates. for . . . material advancement.” Differences
The legacy of human capital extends in proverbs tell the story: for the Chinese,
beyond reverence for education. The room “Money can do all things,” but for the Thai,
allowed for small private plots and rural “Do not long for more than your own share”
markets under collective agriculture helped (1957, pp. 97, 92, 93, 95).
to preserve commercial instincts in the A century later, Chinese migrants display
Chinese countryside, which in turn contrib- similar capabilities in Italian city of Prato:
uted to the boom that followed the restora- Chinese laborers, first a few immigrants, then
tion of household farming. Rapid expansion tens of thousands. . . . transformed the textile
of production, employment, and exports hub into a low-end garment manufacturing
in millions of “township and village enter- capital—enriching many, stoking resentment
prises” relied on China’s deep reserves of and prompting recent crackdowns. . . . [A local
industrialist commented that] The Chinese are
rural management capability, highlighting very clever. They’re not like other immigrants.
what Wright has termed China’s historic . . . [Reporters noted that] what seems to gall
“abundance of small-time entrepreneurs” some Italians most is that the Chinese are
(1984, p. 325). Comparisons across time and beating them at their own game—tax evasion
space draw attention to the coherence and and brilliant ways of navigating Italy’s notori-
ously complex bureaucracy—and have created
potential of this organizational repertoire. a thriving, if largely underground, new sector
Rawski (2011a) and others have remarked while many Prato businesses have gone under
that China’s post-1978 boom drew heavily (Donadio 2010).
on an informal revival of traditional com-
mercial mechanisms that several decades of Alignment of Incentives. The Qing
Communist regulation and propaganda had achieved considerable success in aligning
endeavored to suppress. incentives among the throne, the bureau-
The economic success of Chinese migrants cracy, the gentry, and the masses—all of
illustrates the economic potential of these whom sought prosperity and stability. The
cultural elements. Nineteenth-century plan era, during which the state called on
ordinary Chinese to suppress their desire for
better living standards for the sake of “build-
83 According to HOU Fengyun, “large-scale wage
ing socialism,” emerges as a historical anom-
reductions for high-level mental workers” occurred in
1957, 1959, and 1961, and “mental workers . . . were aly. Following the death of MAO Zedong,
mostly excluded” from wage increases in 1959, 1961, 1963 reform policies restored the traditional unity
and 1971. Hou describes 1976–90 as an era of “no payoff of objectives, with leaders, officials, and
to education.” Apparently referring to the late 1980s, Hou
notes that average monthly pay in universities was RMB 57 populace all pursuing, this time not just eco-
less than in the food and drink sector (1999, pp. 181–85). nomic security, but also growth.
106 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
Patronage economy and income with data from the widely studied China
inequality. Today, as in imperial times, the Household Income Project (CHIP) survey,
absence of legal checks on official power Sicular (2011) shows China’s Gini coeffi-
and the consequent uncertainty surround- cient for household income distribution ris-
ing property rights compels individuals and ing from 0.40 in 1988—no different from its
businesses to seek the patronage of pow- estimated value during the 1930s (Brandt
erful individuals or agencies, typically by and Sands 1992, p. 205)—to 0.47 in 1995 and
offering gifts, services, or cash in exchange 2002 and then to 0.50 in 2007, with house-
for enhanced security and preferential treat- holds in the top decile receiving 34.5 percent
ment. In both systems, protection seekers of 2007 incomes. Since the CHIP data appear
devote substantial resources to construct- to exclude the highest income earners and
ing alliances with incumbent powerholders, are unlikely to incorporate “hidden income,”
promising young officials, or well-connected which Wang and Woo (2011, table 7) place at
individuals.84 There is also a “top-down” ele- approximately two-thirds of the convention-
ment in which official policy nurtures and ally reported total for 2008, a full accounting
protects flows of rents that strengthen the would surely push the Gini coefficient well
adherence of elite beneficiaries to existing above 0.50, placing China’s income distribu-
power structures. Insiders at every level reap tion among the world’s most unequal. Since
large benefits: a typical account describes an Wang and Woo find that inclusion of “hid-
urban housing official whose family accu- den incomes” more than triples the earn-
mulated “as many as thirty-one houses” ings of households in the highest income
(AN Baijie 2013). In this case, as in Kuhn’s group, (2011, Table 6), it seems entirely pos-
account of an episode from the 1840s, the sible that the share of top earners in China
miscreants “operated their business right out today matches or even exceeds comparable
of government offices” (2002, p. 90). outcomes of gentry elites during the 1880s,
Once in place, these patronage struc- when Chang (ZHANG Zhongli) estimates
tures are self-reinforcing and therefore that 2 percent of the population received
extremely difficult to dislodge. Just as the 24 percent of overall income (1962, p. 327).
Kangxi emperor failed to overcome gentry
resistance to a nationwide cadastral survey, 6.2.2 Key institutional departures
recent efforts by China’s current leaders “to under the PRC
narrow the vast gap between China’s rich
and poor” have foundered after encounter- Vision/objectives. Like many of their
ing “formidable opponents” in the shape of British contemporaries (McCloskey 2010,
“hugely profitable state-owned companies” chapter 10), China’s Qing emperors failed
that fiercely resist proposals to limit salaries, to recognize the enormous potential returns
reduce their market power, or increase their associated with the Industrial Revolution.
contributions to state coffers (Davis 2012). But even if the Qing had grasped the long-
These structures contribute to high and term prospects arising from steam engines,
rising levels of income inequality. Working railways, and other new technologies, con-
cerns that unleashing such forces might
disrupt the delicate balance of power and
84 Recent revelations about the family finances of alignment of interests that supported their
prominent PRC officials echo historical accounts, for continued rulership might have discour-
example in GAO Yang’s account of links between the
nineteenth-century scholar official Zuo Zongtang and the aged them from pursuing new economic
merchant–banker Hu Guangyong (1993). opportunities.
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 107
Mao’s China built a military industrial elite recruitment that include multiple chan-
complex strong enough to resist external nels of education, wealth or connections.
military threats, completing a century-long Along with globalization, urbanization and
effort that originated with the Qing self- industrialization, opportunities for eco-
strengthening movement. This achievement, nomic gains have greatly widened, absorbing
however, imposed huge costs on China’s peo- potential regime opponents into elite ranks
ple. DENG Xiaoping’s famous observations (Dickson 2008) and assisting official efforts
that “to get rich is glorious” and “it does not to marginalize dissident groups.
matter if a cat is black or white as long as it
catches mice,” summarized his determina- State capacity. Building on experience
tion to harness Chinese energies to elevate accumulated in the administration of iso-
living standards, as well as national strength. lated rural areas during China’s protracted
This expansion of national goals motivated civil war and in the civil war itself, the PRC
pragmatic policies of economic opening and demonstrated unprecedented capacity to
expansion to generate economic growth, formulate, implement, and monitor nation-
which, under China’s post-1978 reform wide policy initiatives that, for the first time
administration, was “seen as a life and death in Chinese history, penetrated directly to the
matter for the regime” (Xu 2011, p. 1088). village level. Campaigns to expand school
Indeed, the capacity to deliver economic attendance, reduce infant mortality, attack
growth and high living standards has become “rightists,” and force villagers into collectives
a key source of legitimacy for Communist demonstrated the reach of these new mech-
rule in the reform era. anisms. Following the post-1978 restoration
of individual incentives and the associated
Elite recruitment and absorption of shift toward more market-oriented policies,
newly emerging interests. During the often built upon local experimentation, these
Ming–Qing era, elite status derived from structures enabled a scaling up of efforts
examination success, which required can- that were essential to delivering economic
didates and their families to undertake growth.
prolonged educational investments. Qing Enhanced capabilities have endowed the
gentry resisted efforts to open the door to state with unprecedented leverage over
newcomers whose nontraditional mobil- resources. Vast foreign exchange reserves,
ity paths threatened to devalue traditional official control over the financial system,
Confucian education (Mosk 2011). They sweeping privatization of urban housing and
did so with good reason, as the abolition of of state-owned and TVE assets, and wide-
the traditional examination system (1905) spread confiscation and reassignment of
and the collapse of the Qing dynasty (1911) farmland all illustrate newfound state power,
produced a rapid decline in the financial often exercised through local government
payoff to Confucian learning. By the late agencies, to accumulate and allocate assets
1920s, the returns to “modern” education on an immense scale, partly to promote
had far surpassed the financial benefit from growth and efficiency, but also to benefit
Confucian learning among employees of the powerholders in ways that widen inequality
Tianjin–Pukou railway (Yuchtman 2010). and may even retard economic development.
Following the MAO years, which enforced
even stricter ideological limits on its politi- Globalization. Foreign military power
cal elites and actively persecuted excluded compelled the partial opening of China’s
groups, the reform-era PRC has broadened nineteenth-century economy. Qing elites
108 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
sought to limit foreign activity; individual source of more than three-fourths of China’s
foreigners, as well as their products and reform-era increase in per capita output
technologies, faced powerful informal (Zhu 2012, Table 1); at the micro level, lead-
opposition by local gentry. China’s initial ing international firms in a growing range
reform policies resembled those of their of industries find themselves facing intense
Qing predecessors, confining foreign com- pressure from rising Chinese competitors.
merce to a few localities. But over time, Amidst its unprecedented growth spurt,
Chinese reform deepened, leading to the China’s economy remains hugely inefficient.
gradual dismantling of the fundamen- Improved performance among state firms
tal institutional structure of the planned has not closed the huge gap in the returns
economy. The prolonged era of peace and to capital favoring the non-state sectors
order in the last few decades—a sharp con- (Brandt and Zhu 2010). Even in manufactur-
trast with China’s Republican era (1912– ing, the leading source of rising productiv-
49) marked by two world wars, Japanese ity, Hsieh and Klenow (2009) find enormous
aggression, and protracted civil strife— inefficiency in the allocation of labor and
provided time and space for gradual reform. capital among firms within n arrowly-defined
The peaceful and prosperous rise of Japan subsectors (see also Brandt, Van Biesebroeck,
and several smaller East Asian economies and Zhang 2012). Large-scale misalloca-
offered powerful models of export-oriented tion arises from systematic policy distortions
success. Following their lead, China’s favoring state-connected entities and urban
reforms have moved the PRC from extreme residents, the survival of plan remnants in
isolation to global engagement, achieving an increasingly marketized economy, and
trade ratios that dwarf those of other major persistent adherence to widely discred-
economies,85 absorbing large inflows of for- ited industrial policies. Perhaps the central
eign investment, and, most recently, emerg- source of inefficiency is a political system
ing as a substantial originator of outbound that uses control over resources, especially
foreign direct investment.86 land and credit, to maintain patronage net-
works and mobilize support for aspiring
6.3 Unfinished Business, leaders. A central aspect of these inefficien-
Uncertain Prospects cies is the redistribution of income and assets
(land, urban housing, and market power) to
As China’s long boom approaches the regime insiders, often at the expense of the
end of its fourth decade, a new leadership economy’s most dynamic sectors.
group has inherited a powerful, yet deeply Widespread agreement about the
flawed, economy. Despite nagging ques- strengths and weaknesses of the pres-
tions about the reliability of official data, the ent system conceals divergent expecta-
reality of immense growth and dynamism is tions about China’s economic prospects.
beyond doubt. At the macro level, academic Assuming domestic political stability and
studies identify productivity growth as the continued access to overseas markets,
Perkins and Rawski (2008) anticipate that
85 Official data for 2009–11 show annual trade ratios of
China can maintain real annual growth
44.2, 50.2 and 50.0 percent (Yearbook 2012, pp. 44, 234). in the 6–8 percent range to 2025. Others
86 In 2012, China’s outbound overseas direct investment question the assumption of political sta-
reached $77.2 billion, while incoming FDI amounted to bility. Citing evidence of corruption, pre-
$111.7 billion (see http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/business/
2013-01/16/content_16125737.htm and http://www.cnbc. dation, and rent seeking, Pei argues that
com/id/100382634 2012 ). “the economic costs of ensuring the CCP’s
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 109
in order to preserve and increase cohesion Thus far, the momentum of China’s long
within the ruling groups and their associates boom, buoyed by high levels of personal sav-
and supporters. The institutional structures ing, has pushed aside these costs and other
surrounding the selection, approval, financ- seemingly daunting obstacles. External
ing, and execution of investment represent a events, especially the advance of globaliza-
major arena for such activity. tion, with the attendant expansion of over-
Access to investment opportunities, credit, seas markets, international supply chains,
and land are routinely used to buttress the and transnational flows of capital and tech-
current regime and its allies. Official approval nology, have provided enormous benefits.
(pizhun), an essential step in business for- Most important, perhaps, is the robust devel-
mation and expansion, may be reserved for opment of China’s nonstate economy, where
well-connected insiders, especially in sectors steep expansion of productivity and retained
promising high profits. China’s state-owned earnings has sustained rapid growth despite
banks specialize in lending to favored cli- the distortions, graft, and rent seeking that
ents, particularly state-owned enterprises, bedevil the public sector.
at below-market rates and with lax repay- Today, as in the mid-1990s, costs and pres-
ment provisions. Allocation of land is simi- sures appear to be on the rise. Economic
larly tilted in favor of official associates and rebalancing and management of corruption
clients. As in imperial times, the patronage represent areas where the state has failed to
economy is much in evidence: relatives and attain its own widely advertised objectives.
associates of top leaders readily parlay per- In both instances, policy failure may reflect a
sonal connections into lucrative business clash between publicly-stated objectives and
positions. As in the past, private entrepre- the inner workings of China’s elite politics
neurs invest in informal security umbrellas and patronage economy. Although Beijing
to deflect arbitrary disruption of commercial has vowed to lessen the economy’s depen-
activity.88 dence on exports and investment since the
Although this system is not without advan- late 1990s, the GDP share of fixed invest-
tages—as when China’s government, by ment, already at unprecedented levels, con-
ordering state-owned banks to dispense tinues to rise. Recent infrastructure failures,
massive loans, achieved a V-shaped recovery such as the 2011 high-speed train disaster,
following the 2008 financial crisis, the cost highlight the costs of a system that combines
of such arrangements, although difficult to massive investment with rampant corrup-
specify, is surely high. India’s economy, which tion. Objections from state-run companies,
is no paragon of efficiency, has approached which constitute “some of the most formi-
Chinese growth rates despite investing a dable opponents of change,” apparently
far smaller fraction of GDP. Pouring cheap stymied a major effort by the outgoing HU
credit into the state sector increases financial Jintao-WEN Jiabao administration to “nar-
risk, fuels outsized seasonal fluctuations, ele- row the vast gap between China’s rich and
vates capital intensity, contributes to sluggish poor” and thus spur the growth of consump-
job creation, and aggravates long-standing tion (Davis 2012).
unemployment problems (Rawski 2002). Repeated announcements of anticorrup-
tion drives—most recently in the form of
experiments requiring local officials in sev-
88 A typical description notes that “the price that private
eral Guangdong districts to divulge their
entrepreneurs had to pay to ensure political protection was
in the form of de facto extortion on the part of cadres“ (Tsai personal assets (ZHENG Caixiong 2011),
2002, p. 128). have produced no visible results: China’s
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 111
score in Transparency International’s corrup- • If, as is widely argued both within and
tion perceptions index was the same in 2010 outside China (e.g. World Bank 2012),
as in 2001, as was its relative position: better continued dynamism will require sub-
than India or Russia, but worse than Turkey stantial reform, is China’s current politi-
or Brazil. cal equilibrium sufficiently flexible to
Inability to implement policy changes withstand large-scale dissolution of rents
advanced by top leaders raises the possibil- that might accompany a steep reduc-
ity that China has moved from a flexible and tion in the share of credit reserved for
effective system of “authoritarian resilience” government projects and state-owned
(Nathan 2003) to a new stage in which clashes enterprises? Or a no-holds-barred effort
among inner-party factions and powerful to uproot corruption such as Hong
interest groups obstruct efforts to address Kong accomplished during the 1970s
widely-recognized difficulties (Li 2012). (Manion 2004)?
Equally noteworthy is growing evidence • China’s government channels growing
of disaffection among successful participants resource flows to pursue strategic eco-
in the Chinese system, many of whom are nomic objectives, including long lists of
reportedly moving funds offshore (Frangos, specific products (e.g. large-scale pas-
Orlik, and Wei 2012) and considering over- senger aircraft and engines) and technol-
seas migration. “You can feel the anxiety of ogies (e.g. nuclear power generation).
the ultra-wealthy and even of the political Will state management of resource and
elite. They feel there’s no security for their development resources generate ineffi-
wealth or possessions, and that their assets ciency and distortions on the same scale
could be taken away at any time. Nobody feels that is evident in state-influenced alloca-
protected against the system anymore.” 89 tion of financial resources? Might such
These observations raise a series of distortions, together with the conse-
questions: quences of graft and rent seeking, limit
resource flows available to dynamic sec-
• Can the current institutional struc- tors of China’s economy, with negative
ture continue to support rapid growth consequences for aggregate productiv-
as population aging, a declining labor ity growth?
force, and rebalancing efforts lower • Could the outsized returns available to
household saving rates? As rising wages individuals and enterprises connected
erode long-standing comparative advan- to China’s power elite spark a diversion
tage in labor-intensive industries? As of talent from innovation and enterprise
technological advance eliminates easy into politics and rent seeking, with neg-
gains from absorbing imported equip- ative consequences for incentives and
ment and manufacturing processes? hence for economic performance?
As limited enforcement of intellectual
property rights inflicts growing damage Such concerns are not new. Writing in the
on domestic innovators and discourages mid-1990s, two prominent China specialists
FDI? If international recession and expressed doubts about the system’s viability.
protectionism slow the growth of world Naughton wrote that
trade?
The political system is simply not adequate to
89 Anderliniand Waldmeir 2011, quoting an informant cope with the challenges that confront it. The
whom they describe as a “publishing and fashion mogul.” dysfunctional political system might p revent
112 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
the Chinese people from quickly building While striving to avoid this error, we must
the kind of future system they would prefer; also recognize that, as is painfully evident
it might even jeopardize the achievements of from Japan’s recent history, past success can-
recent decades (1995, p. 310).
not guarantee the future efficacy of institu-
Lardy concluded his 1998 study by empha- tional structures.
sizing the long-run importance of Careful historical study must figure promi-
nently in serious efforts to grapple with these
. . . restructuring the banking system, particu- and many other issues surrounding the his-
larly eventually allowing the emergence of pri-
vate banks. . . . [even though this] will require toric path and future prospects for China’s
the state and the party to surrender a great economy. This review reveals powerful com-
deal of economic and political power. . . . In the plementarities between efforts to fathom the
long run . . . delay is an almost certain path to structures and mechanisms undergirding
a lower pace of economic growth, a declining China’s recent economic advance and studies
rate of job creation, and thus an even greater
challenge to political stability (pp. 221–22). of China’s imperial past. Our survey demon-
strates the insights that historical study can
These deeply knowledgeable authors (and bring to the analysis of contemporary affairs.
many others) underestimated the strength Several years of struggling to comprehend an
of China’s unconventional system. Although immense body of historical scholarship has
there was no political reform, no major finan- reinforced our conviction that contemporary
cial restructuring, no reduction in the domi- developments can also provide fresh per-
nance of China’s big four state-owned banks, spectives for addressing the vast storehouse
and no retreat from state–party control over of materials on the history of what once was
financial institutions and resources, China’s and soon will become the world’s largest
economy has continued its powerful advance national economy.
in the face of major shocks from the Asian
financial crisis of the late 1990s and the 2008 References
global financial crash. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Rob-
China’s recent trajectory demonstrates the inson. 2005. “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause
capacity of a dynamic economy to prosper of Long-Run Growth.” In Handbook of Economic
Growth: Volume 1A, edited by Philippe Aghion and
despite heavy burdens. China’s boom, like Steven N. Durlauf, 385–472. Amsterdam and San
earlier growth spurts in Japan and Korea, Diego: Elsevier, North-Holland.
confirms the wisdom of Schumpeter, who Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2012.
Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosper-
insisted that static efficiency was neither nec- ity, and Poverty. New York: Random House, Crown
essary nor sufficient for long-run dynamism Publishers.
(1942, p. 83). It is equally true, however, that Allen, Franklin, Jun Qian, and Meijun Qian. 2008. “Chi-
na’s Financial System: Past, Present, and Future.” In
changing circumstances may undermine the China’s Great Economic Transformation, edited by
effectiveness of institutional structures. As Loren Brandt and Thomas G. Rawski, 506–68. Cam-
we have seen, the institutions of China’s Qing bridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Allen, Robert C. 2009. The British Industrial Revo-
dynasty supported immense demographic lution in Global Perspective. Cambridge and New
and geographic expansion, but proved inca- York: Cambridge University Press.
pable of responding constructively to new Allen, Robert C., Jean-Pascal Bassino, Debin Ma,
Christine Moll-Murata, and Jan Luiten van Zanden.
challenges arising from nineteenth-century 2011. “Wages, Prices, and Living Standards in China,
globalization. 1738–1925: In Comparison with Europe, Japan, and
With the aid of hindsight, we can see that India.” Economic History Review 64: 8–38.
An, Baijie. 2013. “Official Whose Family Owns
pessimistic predictions of the 1990s failed 31 Houses Arrested.” China Daily, January 15.
to comprehend China’s dynamic potential. Anderlini, Jamil, and Patti Waldmeir. 2011. “Chinese
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 113
Doubt the Road Ahead.” Financial Times, Novem- Brandt, Loren, and Thomas G. Rawski. 2008. “China’s
ber 5, 4. Great Economic Transformation.” In China’s Great
Ashton, Basil, Kenneth Hill, Alan Piazza, and Robin Economic Transformation, edited by Loren Brandt
Zeitz. 1984. “Famine in China, 1958–61.” Population and Thomas G. Rawski, 1–26. Cambridge and New
and Development Review 10 (4): 613–45. York: Cambridge University Press.
Bacon, Francis. 1960. The New Organon and Related Brandt, Loren, and Barbara Sands. 1992. “Land Con-
Writings. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill. centration and Income Distribution in Republican
Bardhan, Pranab, and Dilip Mookherjee, eds. 2006. China.” In Chinese History in Economic Perspec-
Decentralization and Local Governance in Devel- tive, edited by Thomas G. Rawski and Lillian M. Li,
oping Countries: A Comparative Perspective. Cam- 179–206. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of
bridge and London: MIT Press. California Press.
Baten, Joerg, Debin Ma, Stephen Morgan, and Qing Brandt, Loren, and Thomas J. Sargent. 1989. “Inter-
Wang. 2010. “Evolution of Living Standards and preting New Evidence about China and U.S. Silver
Human Capital in China in the 18–20th Centuries: Purchases.” Journal of Monetary Economics 23 (1):
Evidences from Real Wages, Age-Heaping, and 31–51.
Anthropometrics.” Explorations in Economic History Brandt, Loren, Donghyun Park, Johannes Van Biese-
47 (3): 347–59. broeck, Wenkui Zhang, and Yifan Zhang. Forthcom-
Beal, Edwin George. 1958. The Origin of Likin, 1853– ing. “The Evolving Behavior of China’s State Owned
1864. Cambridge, Mass.: Chinese Economic and Enterprises.”
Political Studies, Harvard University. Brandt, Loren, Johannes Van Biesebroeck, and Yifan
Bergère, Marie-Claire. 1989. The Golden Age of the Zhang. 2012. “Creative Accounting or Creative
Chinese Bourgeoisie 1911–1937. Cambridge and Destruction? Firm-Level Productivity Growth in
London: Cambridge University Press. Chinese Manufacturing.” Journal of Development
Berliner, Joseph S. 1976. The Innovation Decision in Economics 97 (2): 339–51.
Soviet Industry. Cambridge, Mass. and London: Brandt, Loren, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2000. “Redistribu-
MIT Press. tion in a Decentralized Economy: Growth and Infla-
Bian, Morris L. 2005. The Making of the State Enter- tion in China under Reform.” Journal of Political
prise System in Modern China: The Dynamics of Economy 108 (2): 422–39.
Institutional Change. Cambridge and London: Har- Brandt, Loren, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2007. “China’s
vard University Press. Banking Sector and Economic Growth.” In China’s
Billingsley, Phil. 1988. Bandits in Republican China. Financial Transition at a Crossroads, edited by
Stanford: Stanford University Press. Charles W. Calomiris, 86–136. New York: Columbia
Boserup, Ester. 1965. The Conditions of Agricultural University Press.
Growth: The Economics of Agrarian Change under Brandt, Loren, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2010 “Accounting
Population Pressure. New York: Aldine. for China’s Growth.” University of Toronto Depart-
Bourgon, Jerome. 2002. “Uncivil Dialogue: Law and ment of Economics Working Paper 394.
Custom Did Not Merge into Civil Law under the Branstetter, Lee, and Nicholas R. Lardy. 2008. “China’s
Qing.” Late Imperial China 23 (1): 50–90. Embrace of Globalization.” In China’s Great Eco-
Bramall, Chris. 1989. Living Standards in Sichuan, nomic Transformation, edited by Loren Brandt and
1931–1978. London: Contemporary China Institute. Thomas G. Rawski, 633–82. Cambridge and New
Bramall, Chris. 2000. Sources of Chinese Economic York: Cambridge University Press.
Growth, 1978–1996. Oxford and New York: Oxford Brokaw, Cynthia J., and Kai-wing Chow, eds. 2005.
University Press. Printing and Book Culture in Late Imperial China.
Bramall, Chris. 2009. Chinese Economic Develop- Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California
ment. London and New York: Taylor and Francis, Press.
Routledge. Brook, Timothy. 1999. The Confusions of Pleasure:
Brandt, Loren. 1985. “Chinese Agriculture and the Commerce and Culture in Ming China. Berkeley and
International Economy, 1870–1930s: A Reassess- Los Angeles: University of California Press.
ment.” Explorations in Economic History 22 (2): Brook, Timothy. 2010. The Troubled Empire: China in
168–93. the Yuan and Ming Dynasties. Cambridge and Lon-
Brandt, Loren. 1989. Commercialization and Agri- don: Harvard University Press, Belknap Press.
cultural Development: Central and Eastern China, Brown, Shannon R. 1978. “The Partially Opened Door:
1870–1937. Cambridge; New York and Melbourne: Limitations on Economic Change in China in the
Cambridge University Press. 1860s.” Modern Asian Studies 12 (2): 177–92.
Brandt, Loren, and Arthur J. Hosios. 1996. “Credit, Brown, Shannon R. 1979a. “The Ewo Filature: A Study
Incentives, and Reputation: A Hedonic Analysis in the Transfer of Technology to China in the 19th
of Contractual Wage Profiles.” Journal of Political Century.” Technology and Culture 20 (3): 550–68.
Economy 104 (6): 1172–1226. Brown, Shannon R. 1979b. “The Transfer of Technol-
Brandt, Loren, and Arthur J. Hosios. 2010. “Interest- ogy to China in the Nineteenth Century: The Role
Free Loans between Villagers.” Economic Develop- of Direct Foreign Investment.” Journal of Economic
ment and Cultural Change 58 (2): 345–72. History 39 (1): 181–97.
114 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
Buck, John Lossing. 1930. Chinese Farm Economy: odern China.” Paper presented at Asian Historical
M
A Study of 2866 Farms in Seventeen Localities and Economics Conference, Tsinghua University, May.
Seven Provinces in China. Chicago: University of Chow, Gregory C. 2002. China’s Economic Transfor-
Chicago Press. mation. Malden, Mass. and Oxford: Blackwell.
Buck, John Lossing. 1937. Land Utilization in China: Ch’ü, T’ung-tsu. 1962. Local Government in China
A Study of 16,786 Farms in 168 Localities, and under the Ch’ing. Cambridge and London: Harvard
38,256 Farm Families in Twenty-Two Provinces in University East Asia Center.
China, 1929–1933. Shanghai: Commercial Press. Ch’üan, Han-sheng. 1990. Research on Chinese Eco-
Burgess, John Stewart. 1966. The Guilds of Peking. Tai- nomic History, Volume 1. Taipei: Taoshan Publishers.
pei: Cheng-wen Publishing Co, 1928. Ch’üan, Han-sheng, and Richard A. Kraus. 1975. Mid-
Cai, Fang. 2010. “Labor Market Development and Ch’ing Rice Markets and Trade: An Essay in Price
Expansion of Rural and Urban Employment.” In History. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University East
Transforming the Chinese Economy, edited by Fang Asian Research Center.
Cai, 85–114. Leiden and Boston: Brill. Chung, Stephanie Po-Yin. 2010. “Chinese Tong as Brit-
Cao, Shuji. 2001. History of China’s Population: Qing ish Trust: Institutional Collisions and Legal Disputes
Era (In Chinese). Shanghai: Fudan daxue chubanshe. in Urban Hong Kong, 1860s–1880s.” Modern Asian
Cha, Dong-Se, Kwang Suk Kim, and Dwight H. Per- Studies 44 (6): 1409–32.
kins. 1997. The Korean Economy 1945–1995: Perfor- Coble, Parks M., Jr. 1986. The Shanghai Capitalists and
mance and Vision for the 21st Century. Seoul: Korea the Nationalist Government, 1927–1937, Second edi-
Development Institute. tion. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Council
Chan, Anita, Richard Madsen, and Jonathan Unger. on East Asian Studies.
1992. Chen Village under Mao and Deng, Second Coble, Parks M., Jr. 2003. Chinese Capitalists in
edition. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of Japan’s New Order: The Occupied Lower Yangzi,
California Press. 1937–1945. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of
Chan, Wellington K. K. 1977. Merchants, Mandarins, California Press.
and Modern Enterprise in Late Ch’ing China. Cam- Compendium. 2010. China Compendium of Statistics
bridge: Harvard University East Asian Research 1949–2008 (In Chinese). Beijing: China Statistics
Center. Press.
Chang, Chung-li [Zhang Zhongli]. 1955. The Chinese Dai, Jianbin. 2007. History of Silver Taels in Modern
Gentry: Studies on Their Role in Nineteenth-Century China (In Chinese). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue
Chinese Society. Seattle: University of Washington chubanshe.
Press. Davis, Bob. 2012. “China Tries to Shut Rising Income
Chang, Chung-li [Zhang Zhongli]. 1962. The Income of Gap.” Wall Street Journal, December 10, A14.
the Chinese Gentry. Seattle: University of Washing- Deng, Gang [Kent G. Deng]. 1997. Chinese Maritime
ton Press. Activities and Socioeconomic Development c. 2100
Chang, John K. 1969. Industrial Development in Pre- B.C.–1900 A.D. Westport, Ct.: Greenwood Press.
Communist China. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Deng, Jianpeng. 2006. The Poverty of Property
Company. Rights—Studies on Traditional Chinese Civil Law
Chao, Kang. 1982. The Economic Development of Man- (In Chinese). Beijing: Falu chubanshe.
churia: The Rise of a Frontier Economy. Ann Arbor: Deng, Kent G. 2000. “A Critical Survey of Recent
University of Michigan Center for Chinese Studies. Research in Chinese Economic History.” Economic
Chao, Kang. 1986. Man and Land in Chinese History: History Review 53 (1): 1–28.
An Economic Analysis. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford Deng, Kent G. 2003. “Development and Its Deadlock
University Press. in Imperial China, 221 B.C.–1840 A.D.” Economic
Chen, Feng. 1992. A Study on Qing Military Expendi- Development and Cultural Change 51 (2): 479–522.
ture (In Chinese). Wuhan: Wuhan University Press. de Vries, Jan. 2008. The Industrious Revolution: Con-
Chen, Fu-mei Chang, and Ramon H. Myers. 1978. sumer Behavior and the Household Economy, 1650
“Customary Law and the Economic Growth of China to the Present. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge
during the Ch’ing Period.” Ch’ing-shih wen-t’i 3 (10): University Press.
4–27. Dickson, Bruce J. 2008. Wealth into Power: The Com-
Chen, Fu-mei Chang, and Ramon H. Myers. 1996. munist Party’s Embrace of China’s Private Sector.
“Coping with Transaction Costs: The Case of Mer- Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University
chant Associations in the Ch’ing Period.” In Chi- Press.
nese Business Enterprise: Critical Perspectives on Dikötter, Frank. 2006. Exotic Commodities: Modern
Business and Management, Volume 2, edited by Objects and Everyday Life in China. New York:
Rajeswary Ampalavanar Brown, 252–74. London and Columbia University Press.
New York: Routledge, 1989. Dikötter, Frank. 2010. Mao’s Great Famine: The His-
Chen, Nai-Ruenn. 1967. Chinese Economic Statistics: tory of China’s Most Devastating Catastrophe, 1958–
A Handbook for Mainland China. Chicago: Aldine. 62. New York: Walker and Co.
Chen, Zhiwu, Kaixiang Peng, and Weiping Yuan. Donadio, Rachel. 2010. “Chinese Remake the
2010. “Robbery, Social Order, and Interest Rates in ‘Made in Italy’ Fashion Label.” New York Times,
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 115
He, Bingdi [Ping-ti Ho]. 1966. Historical Survey of Huang, Philip C. C. 1990. The Peasant Family and
China’s Landsmannschaften (In Chinese). Taipei: Rural Development in the Yangzi Delta, 1350–1988.
Xuesheng shuji. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Heilmann, Sebastian. 2008. “From Local Experiments Huang, Ray. 1974. Taxation and Governmental Finance
to National Policy: The Origins of China’s Distinctive in Sixteenth-Century Ming China. Cambridge and
Policy Process.” China Journal 59: 1–30. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Heilmann, Sebastian, and Elizabeth J. Perry, eds. 2011. Industry. 2000. 50-Year Compendium of Statistics on
Mao’s Invisible Hand: The Political Foundations of China’s Industry, Transport, and Energy 1949–1999
Adaptive Governance in China. Cambridge: Harvard (In Chinese). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
University Asia Center. International Labor Office. 1937. The World Textile
Hershatter, Gail. 1986. The Workers of Tianjin, 1900– Industry: Economic and Social Problems. 2 Volumes.
1949. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Geneva: International Labor Office.
Ho, Franklin L. 1967. “The Reminiscences of Ho Lien Irigoin, Alejandra. 2009. “The End of a Silver Era:
(Franklin L. Ho) as Told to Crystal Lorch Seidman.” The Consequences of the Breakdown of the Span-
Unpublished. ish Peso Standard in China and the United States,
Ho, Ping-ti. 1954. “The Salt Merchants of Yang-Chou: 1780s–1850s.” Journal of World History 20 (2):
A Study of Commercial Capitalism in Eighteenth- 207–44.
Century China.” Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies Ishikawa, Shigeru. 1983. “China’s Economic Growth
17 (1–2): 130–68. since 1949—An Assessment.” China Quarterly 94:
Ho, Ping-ti. 1956. “Early-Ripening Rice in Chinese 242–81.
History.” Economic History Review 9 (2): 200–218. Iwai, Shigeki. 2004. A Study of China’s Early Modern
Ho, Ping-ti. 1959. Studies on the Population of China, Fiscal History (In Japanese). Kyoto: Kyoto University
1368–1953. Cambridge and London: Harvard Uni- Press.
versity Press. Jin, Guantao, and Qingfeng Liu. 2011. The Transforma-
Ho, Ping-ti. 1962. The Ladder of Success in Imperial tion of Chinese Society (1840–1956): The Fate of Its
China: Aspects of Social Mobility, 1368–1911. New Ultrastable Structure in Modern Times (In Chinese).
York: Columbia University Press. Beijing: China Law Press.
Holz, Carsten A. 2003. China’s Industrial State-Owned Johnson, Linda Cooke. 1993. “Shanghai: An Emerging
Enterprises: Between Profitability and Bankruptcy. Jiangnan Port, 1683–1840.” In Cities of Jiangnan in
Singapore; River Edge, N.J. and London: World Late Imperial China, edited by Linda Cooke John-
Scientific. son, 151–81. Albany: State University of New York
Homer, Sidney, and Richard Sylla. 2005. A History of Press.
Interest Rates, Fourth edition. Hoboken, N.J.: Wiley. Kann, Eduard. 1975. The Currencies of China: An
Hou, Chi-ming. 1965. Foreign Investment and Eco- Investigation of Silver and Gold Transactions Affect-
nomic Development in China, 1840–1937. Cam- ing China: With a Section on Copper. New York:
bridge and London: Harvard University Press. AMS Press.
Hou, Fengyun. 1999. Formation and Present Circum- Karaman, K. Kivanç, and Şevket Pamuk. 2010. “Otto-
stances of Human Capital in China (In Chinese). man State Finances in European Perspective, 1500–
Beijing: Jingji kexue chubanshe. 1914.” Journal of Economic History 70 (3): 593–629.
Hsiao, Liang-lin. 1974. China’s Foreign Trade Statis- Keller, Wolfgang, Ben Li, and Carol H. Shiue. 2010.
tics, 1864–1949. Cambridge: Harvard University “China’s Foreign Trade: Perspectives from the Past
East Asian Research Center. 150 Years.” Unpublished.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallo- Keller, Wolfgang, Ben Li, and Carol H. Shiue. 2011.
cation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” “The Evolution of Domestic Trade Flows When For-
Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1403–48. eign Trade Is Liberalized: Evidence from the Chi-
Hsu, S. Philip, Yu-Shan Wu, and Suisheng Zhao, eds. nese Maritime Customs Service.” Unpublished.
2011. In Search of China’s Development Model: Keller, Wolfgang, Ben Li, and Carol H. Shiue. 2012.
Beyond the Beijing Consensus. London and New “Shanghai’s Trade, China’s Growth: Continu-
York: Taylor and Francis, Routledge. ity, Recovery, and Change since the Opium War.”
Hsueh, Li-min, Chen-kuo Hsu, and Dwight H. Perkins. National Bureau of Economic Research Working
2001. Industrialization and the State: The Changing Paper 17754.
Role of the Taiwan Government in the Economy, King, Frank H. H. 1965. Money and Monetary Policy
1945–1998. Cambridge: Harvard Institute for Inter- in China, 1845–1895. Cambridge: Harvard Univer-
national Development. sity Press.
Hu, Angang. 2010. “Government Transformation and King, Frank H. H. 1969. A Concise Economic History
Public Finance.” In Transforming the Chinese Econ- of Modern China (1840–1961). New York: Praeger.
omy, edited by Fang Cai, 149–99. Leiden and Bos- Kirby, William C. 1984. Germany and Republican
ton: Brill. China. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Huang, Philip C. C. 1985. The Peasant Economy and Kirby, William C. 1990. “Continuity and Change in
Social Change in North China. Stanford: Stanford Modern China: Economic Planning on the Mainland
University Press. and on Taiwan, 1943–1958.” Australian Journal of
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 117
Institution in a Changing Society. Ann Arbor: Chinese Landlordism in Late Ch’ing and Early
University of Michigan Center for Chinese Studies. epublican Kiangnan.” Bulletin of the School of Ori-
R
McElderry, Andrea Lee. 1995. “Securing Trust and Sta- ental and African Studies 29 (3): 566–99.
bility: Chinese Finance in the Late Nineteenth Cen- Murphey, Rhoads. 1977. The Outsiders: The Western
tury.” In Chinese Business Enterprise in Asia, edited Experience in India and China. Ann Arbor: Univer-
by Rajeswary Ampalavanar Brown, 27–44. London sity of Michigan Press.
and New York: Routledge. Myers, Ramon H. 1970. The Chinese Peasant Economy:
McGeary, Kevin, 2012. “Guangdong Province Chooses Agricultural Development in Hopei and Shantung,
3 Areas to Pilot Anti-corruption Measures amid 1890–1949. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Deep Mistrust.” http://www.thenanfang.com/blog/ Myers, Ramon H. 1980. The Chinese Economy: Past
guangdong-province-chooses-3-areas-to-pilot-anti- and Present. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth.
corruption-measures-amid-deep-mistrust/. Myers, Ramon H., and Yeh-chien Wang. 2002. “Eco-
Miyakawa, Hisayuki. 1955. “An Outline of the Naito nomic Developments, 1644–1800.” In The Cam-
Hypothesis and Its Effects on Japanese Studies of bridge History of China: Volume 9, Part 1: The
China.” Far Eastern Quarterly 14 (4): 533–52. Ch’ing Dynasty to 1800, edited by Willard J. Peter-
Miyazaki, Ichisada. 1976. China’s Examination Hell: son, 563–646. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge
The Civil Service Examinations of Imperial China. University Press.
New York and Tokyo: Weatherhill. Nakamura, James I., and Matao Miyamoto. 1982.
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki, and Mataji Umemura. 1988. “Social Structure and Population Change: A Com-
Economic Statistics of Japan’s Former Colonies: parative Study of Tokugawa Japan and Ch’ing China.”
Estimation and Analysis (In Japanese). Tokyo: Toyo Economic Development and Cultural Change 30 (2):
Keizai Shinposha. 229–69.
Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Lever of Riches: Technologi- Nathan, Andrew J. 2003. “Authoritarian Resilience.”
cal Creativity and Economic Progress. Oxford; New Journal of Democracy 14 (1): 6–17.
York; Toronto and Melbourne: Oxford University National Bureau of Statistics of China. 2007. Data of
Press. Gross Domestic Product of China 1952–2004 (In
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Chinese). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton and Naughton, Barry. 1995. Growing Out of the Plan: Chi-
Oxford: Princeton University Press. nese Economic Reform, 1978–1993. Cambridge; New
Mokyr, Joel. 2009. The Enlightened Economy: An Eco- York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press.
nomic History of Britain 1700–1850. New Haven Naughton, Barry. 2007. The Chinese Economy: Tran-
and London: Yale University Press. sitions and Growth. Cambridge and London: MIT
Moll-Murata, Christine. 2008. “Chinese Guilds from Press.
the Seventeenth to the Twentieth Centuries: An Naughton, Barry. 2008. “A Political Economy of Chi-
Overview.” International Review of Social History 53 na’s Economic Transition.” In China’s Great Eco-
(Supplement): 213–47. nomic Transformation, edited by Loren Brandt and
Montinola, Gabriella, Yingyi Qian, and Barry R. Wein- Thomas G. Rawski, 91–135. Cambridge and New
gast. 1995. “Federalism, Chinese Style: The Political York: Cambridge University Press.
Basis for Economic Success in China.” World Politics Naughton, Barry. 2011. “Inside and Outside: The Mod-
48 (1): 50–81. ernized Hierarchy that Runs China.” Paper prepared
Morawetz, David. 1978. Twenty-Five Years of Eco- for Legal Order, the State, and Economic Develop-
nomic Development, 1950–1975. Baltimore: Johns ment Conference, Florence, Italy, September 29–
Hopkins University Press. October 1.
Morck, Randall, and Fan Yang. 2011. “The Rise and Needham, Joseph. 1971. Science and Civilisation in
Fall of the Rishengchang Bank Model: Limiting China: Volume 4: Physics and Physical Technology:
Shareholder Influence to Attract Capital.” In Origins Part III: Civil Engineering and Nautics. Cambridge
of Shareholder Advocacy, edited by Jonathan G. S. and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Koppell, 187–214. London: Palgrave Macmillan. Needham, Joseph, and Colin A. Ronan. 1978. The
Morse, Hosea Ballou. 1932. The Gilds of China: With Shorter Science and Civilisation in China: An
an Account of the Gild Merchant of Co-Hong of Can- Abridgement of Joseph Needham’s Original Text.
ton, Second edition. New York: Longmans, Green, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University
and Co. Press.
Mosk, Carl. 2011. Traps Embraced or Escaped: Elites Negishi, Tadashi. 1951. The _ Guilds of Shanghai (In
in the Economic Development of Modern Japan Japanese). Tokyo:. Nihon hyo r onsha.
and China. Hackensack, N.J. and London: World North, Douglass C. 1994. “Economic Performance
Scientific. through Time.” American Economic Review 84 (3):
Motono, Eiichi. 2000. Conflict and Cooperation in 359–68.
Sino–British Business, 1860–1911: The Impact of the North, Douglass C., and Robert Paul Thomas. 1973.
Pro-British Commercial Network in Shanghai. New The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic
York: St. Martin’s Press, Palgrave Macmillan. History. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge Uni-
Muramatsu, Yuji. 1966. “A Documentary Study of versity Press.
120 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
North, Douglass C., John Joseph Wallis, and Barry Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press.
R. Weingast. 2009. Violence and Social Orders: A Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The Great Divergence:
Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World
Human History. Cambridge and New York: Cam- Economy. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton Univer-
bridge University Press. sity Press.
Ohkawa, Kazushi, and Henry Rosovsky. 1973. Japanese Qi, Xia. 1999. General Economic History of China:
Economic Growth: Trend Acceleration in the Twen- Song Dynasty (In Chinese). Beijing: Jingji ribao
tieth Century. Stanford: Stanford University Press. chubanshe.
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Qi, Xia. 2009. Economic History of Song (In Chinese).
Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. Beijing: Zhonghua shuju.
New Haven and London: Yale University Press. Qian, Mu. 1966. The Gains and Losses of Chinese Dynas-
¯ sawa, Masaaki. 1996. On the Social History of Agri-
O tic Politics (In Chinese). Hong Kong: Da Zhongguo.
culture During the Tang–Song Transformation (In Qian, Yingyi. 2000. “The Process of China’s Market
Japanese). Tokyo: Kyuko Shoin. Transition (1978–1998): The Evolutionary, Histori-
Pearson, Margaret M. 2011. “Variety Within and With- cal, and Comparative Perspectives.” Journal of Insti-
out: The Political Economy of Chinese Regulation.” tutional and Theoretical Economics 156 (1): 151–71.
In Beyond the Middle Kingdom: Comparative Per- Qian, Yingyi, and Jinglian Wu. 2003. “China’s Transition
spectives on China’s Capitalist Transformation, to a Market Economy: How Far Across the River?”
edited by Scott Kennedy, 25–43. Stanford: Stanford In How Far across the River? Chinese Policy Reform
University Press. at the Millennium, edited by Nicholas C. Hope, Den-
Pei, Minxin. 2006. China’s Trapped Transition: The nis Tao Yang and Mu Yang Li, 31–63. Stanford: Stan-
Limits of Developmental Autocracy. Cambridge and ford University Press.
London: Harvard University Press. Ravallion, Martin, and Shaohua Chen. 2007. “China’s
Peng, Kaixiang, Zhiwu Chen, Weiping Yuan, and Huin- (Uneven) Progress against Poverty.” Journal of
ing Cao. 2009. “Shallow Water and Heavy Boat: Mar- Development Economics 82 (1): 1–42.
ket Mechanism in Modern Chinese Rural Credit” Rawski, Evelyn Sakakida. 1972. Agricultural Change
(In Chinese). In The Evolution of Chinese Industry, and the Peasant Economy of South China. Cam-
Commerce and Finance, an International Sympo- bridge and London: Harvard University Press.
sium, edited by Qiugen Liu and Debin Ma, 117–46. Rawski, Evelyn Sakakida. 1979. Education and Popular
Shijiazhuang, China: Hebei University Press. Literacy in Ch’ing China. Ann Arbor: University of
Peng, Xinwei. 1958. History of Money in China (In Michigan Press.
Chinese). Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe. Rawski, Thomas G. 1969. “Chinese Dominance of
Peng, Xizhe. 1987. “Demographic Consequences of the Treaty Port Commerce and Its Implications, 1860–
Great Leap Forward in China’s Provinces.” Popula- 1875.” Explorations in Economic History 7 (1–2):
tion and Development Review 13 (4): 639–70. 451–73.
Perdue, Peter C. 1987. Exhausting the Earth: State and Rawski, Thomas G. 1975. “The Growth of Producer
Peasant in Hunan 1500–1850. Cambridge: Harvard Industries, 1900–1971.” In China’s Modern Economy
University Council on East Asian Studies. in Historical Perspective, edited by Dwight H. Per-
Perdue, Peter C. 1996. “Military Mobilization in Seven- kins, 203–34. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
teenth and Eighteenth-Century China, Russia, and Rawski, Thomas G. 1980. China’s Transition to Indus-
Mongolia.” Modern Asian Studies 30 (4): 757–93. trialism: Producer Goods and Economic Devel-
Perdue, Peter C. 2005. China Marches West: The Qing opment in the Twentieth Century. Ann Arbor:
Conquest of Central Eurasia. Cambridge and Lon- University of Michigan Press.
don: Harvard University Press, Belknap Press. Rawski, Thomas G. 1982. “The Simple Arithmetic of
Perkins, Dwight H. 1967. “Government as an Obstacle Income Distribution in China.” Keizai Kenky ¯ [Eco-
u
to Industrialization: The Case of Nineteenth-Century nomic Research] 33 (1): 12–26.
China.” Journal of Economic History 27 (4): 478–92. Rawski, Thomas G. 1989. Economic Growth in Prewar
Perkins, Dwight H. 1969. Agricultural Development in China. Berkeley and Oxford: University of California
China 1368–1968. Chicago: Aldine. Press.
Perkins, Dwight H. 1995. “The Transition from Central Rawski, Thomas G. 2002. “Will Investment Behavior
Planning: East Asia’s Experience.” In Social Capabil- Constrain China’s Growth?” China Economic Review
ity and Long-Term Economic Growth, edited by Bon 13 (4): 361–72.
Ho Koo and Dwight H. Perkins, 221–41. New York: Rawski, Thomas G. 2006. “Recent Developments in
St. Martin’s Press; London: Macmillan Press. China’s Labor Economy.” In Restructuring China:
Perkins, Dwight H., and Thomas G. Rawski. 2008. Party, State, and Society after the Reform and Open
“Forecasting China’s Economic Growth to 2025.” In Door, edited by Katsuji Nakagane and Tomoyuku
China’s Great Economic Transformation, edited by Kojima, 16–47. Tokyo: Toyo Bunko.
Loren Brandt and Thomas G. Rawski, 829–86. Cam- Rawski, Thomas G. 2007. “Social Capabilities and Chi-
bridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. nese Economic Growth.” In Social Change in Con-
Perry, Elizabeth J., and Merle Goldman, eds. 2007. temporary China: C. K. Yang and the Concept of
Grassroots Political Reform in Contemporary China. Institutional Diffusion, edited by Wenfang Tang and
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 121
Burkart Holzner, 89–103. Pittsburgh: University of Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and
Pittsburgh Press. Democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers.
Rawski, Thomas G. 2011a “Human Resources and Chi- Shiga, Shuzo, Hiroaki Terada, Mio Kishimoto, and
na’s Long Economic Boom.” Asia Policy 12: 33–78. Susumu Fuma. 1998. Civil Trials and Civil Contracts
Rawski, Thomas G. 2011b. “Is China’s Development in Ming and Qing China (In Chinese), edited by
Success Transferable?” In Reform and Development Yaxin Wang and Zhiping Liang. Beijing: Law Press.
in China: What Can China Offer to the Develop- Shih, Victor, Christopher Adolph, and Mingxing Liu.
ing World?, edited by Ho-Mou Wu and Yang Yao, 2012. “Getting Ahead in the Communist Party:
320–48. London and New York: Taylor and Francis, Explaining the Advancement of Central Commit-
Routledge. tee Members in China.” American Political Science
Rawski, Thomas G., and Robert W. Mead. 1998. “On Review 106 (1): 166–87.
the Trail of China’s Phantom Farmers.” World Devel- Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic
opment 26 (5): 767–81. Reform in China. Berkeley and Oxford: University of
Remer, Charles F. 1968. Foreign Investments in China. California Press.
New York: Howard Fertig, 1933. Shiroyama, Tomoko. 2008. China during the Great
Reynolds, Douglas R. 1993. China, 1898–1912: The Depression: Market, State, and the World Economy,
Xinzheng Revolution and Japan. Cambridge: Har- 1929–1937. Cambridge and London: Harvard Uni-
vard University Council on East Asian Studies. versity Asia Center.
Richards, John F. 2003. The Unending Frontier: An Shiue, Carol H., and Wolfgang Keller. 2007. “Markets
Environmental History of the Early Modern World. in China and Europe on the Eve of the Industrial
Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Revolution.” American Economic Review 97 (4):
Press. 1189–1216.
Riskin, Carl. 1987. China’s Political Economy: The Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1998. The
Quest for Development since 1949. Oxford; New Grabbing Hand: Government Pathologies and Their
York; Toronto and Melbourne: Oxford University Cures. Cambridge and London: Harvard University
Press. Press.
Roll, Charles Robert. 1980. The Distribution of Rural Shue, Vivienne. 1988. The Reach of the State: Sketches
Incomes in China: A Comparison of the 1930s and of the Chinese Body Politic. Stanford: Stanford Uni-
the 1950s. New York: Garland. versity Press.
Romer, Paul. 1993. “Idea Gaps and Object Gaps in Sicular, Terry. 2011. “Inequality in China: Recent
Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Eco- Trends.” Paper presented at “Will China Fall into a
nomics 32 (3): 543–73. Middle Income Trap? Growth, Inequality and Future
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent, and R. Bin Wong. 2011. Instability” conference, Stanford, December 6.
Before and Beyond Divergence: The Politics of Eco- Skinner, G. William. 1957. Chinese Society in Thailand:
nomic Change in China and Europe. Cambridge and An Analytical History. Ithaca: Cornell University
London: Harvard University Press. Press.
Rowe, William T. 1984. Hankow: Commerce and Soci- Skinner, G. William. 1964. Marketing and Social Struc-
ety in a Chinese City, 1796–1889. Stanford: Stanford ture in Rural China. Ann Arbor: Association for
University Press. Asian Studies.
Rowe, William T. 1992. “Ming-Qing Guilds.” Ming Skinner, G. William. 1977a. “Cities and the Hierar-
Qing yanjiu: 47–60. chy of Local Systems.” In The City in Late Imperial
Rozman, Gilbert. 1974. Urban Networks in Ch’ing China, edited by G. William Skinner, 275–351. Stan-
China and Tokugawa Japan. Princeton and London: ford: Stanford University Press.
Princeton University Press. Skinner, G. William. 1977b. “Introduction: Urban
Sait o
¯ , Osamu. 2002. “Historical Demography of Tra- Development in Imperial China.” In The City in
ditional China” (In Japanese). Shakai keizai shigaku Late Imperial China, edited by G. William Skinner,
(Research in Socio-economic History) 68 (2): 87–100. 3–32. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Schran, Peter. 1969. The Development of Chinese Agri- Skinner, G. William. 1987. “Sichuan’s Population in the
culture, 1950–1959. Urbana: University of Illinois Nineteenth Century: Lessons from Disaggregated
Press. Data.” Late Imperial China 8 (1): 1–79.
Schran, Peter. 1976. Guerrilla Economy: The Develop- Smith, Thomas C. 1959. The Agrarian Origins of Mod-
ment of the Shensi–Kansu–Ninghsia Border Region, ern Japan. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
1937–1945. Albany: State University of New York Smith, Thomas C. 1988. Native Sources of Japanese
Press. Industrialization, 1750–1920. Berkeley, Calif. and
Schran, Peter. 1978. “China’s Demographic Evolution London: University of California Press.
1850–1953 Reconsidered.” China Quarterly 75: Sng, Tuan-hwee. 2010. “Size and Dynastic Decline:
639–46. The Principal–Agent Problem in Late Imperial
Schumpeter, Elizabeth B., ed. 1940. The Industrial- China 1700–1850.” Unpublished.
ization of Japan and Manchukuo, 1930–1940: Pop- So, Billy K. L., and Ramon H. Myers. 2011. The Treaty
ulation, Raw Materials, and Industry. New York: Port Economy in Modern China: Empirical Studies
Macmillan. of Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
122 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LII (March 2014)
Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Arturo Giráldez, and Richard von Glahn, 187–206.
Press. Aldershot, U.K. and Burlington, Vt.: Ashgate.
Sommer, Matthew H. 2010. “Abortion in Late Imperial von Glahn, Richard. 2004. “Revisiting the Song Mon-
China: Routine Birth Control or Crisis Intervention.” etary Revolution: A Review Essay.” International
Late Imperial China 31 (2): 97–165. Journal of Asian Studies 1 (1): 159–78.
Spegele, Brian. 2012. “China Ousts Provincial Official Wagner, Donald B. 2001. “The Administration of the
amid Crackdown.” Wall Street Journal, Decem- Iron Industry in Eleventh-Century China.” Journal
ber 13, A11. of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 44
Steinfeld, Edward S. 1998. Forging Reform in China: (2): 175–97.
The Fate of State-Owned Industry. Cambridge and Wagner, Donald B. 2008. Science and Civilisation in
New York: Cambridge University Press. China: Volume 5 Part 11: Ferrous Metallurgy. Cam-
Strauss, Julia C. 1997. “The Evolution of Republican bridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Government.” China Quarterly 150: 329–51. Wang, Dong. 2005. China’s Unequal Treaties: Narrat-
Strauss, Julia C. 1998. Strong Institutions in Weak Poli- ing National History. Lanham, Md.: Rowman and
ties: State Building in Republican China, 1927–1940. Littlefield, Lexington Books.
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press, Clar- Wang, Xiaolu, and Wing Thye Woo. 2011. “The Size
endon Press. and Distribution of Hidden Household Income in
Su, Yegong. 2000. Ming Qing Legal Codes and Statutes China.” Asian Economic Papers 10 (1): 1–26.
(In Chinese). Beijing: China Law University Press. Wang, Ya’nan. 1981/2005. The Politics of Chinese
Sudo, Yoshiyuki. 1962. Studies on Song Dynasty Eco- Bureaucracy (In Chinese). Beijing: Zhongguo shehui
nomic History (In Chinese). Tokyo: Tokyo daigaku kexue chubanshe.
shuppankai. Wang, Yeh-chien. 1973. Land Taxation in Imperial
Sun, E-tu Zen. 1986. “The Growth of the Academic China, 1750–1911. Cambridge and London: Harvard
Community 1912–1949.” In The Cambridge History University Press.
of China: Volume 13: Republican China 1912–1949: Wang, Yeh-chien. 1992. “Secular Trends of Rice Prices
Part 2, edited by Denis Twitchett and John K. Fair- in the Yangzi Delta, 1638–1935.” In Chinese His-
bank, 361–420. Cambridge and New York: Cam- tory in Economic Perspective, edited by Thomas G.
bridge University Press. Rawski and Lillian M. Li, 35–68. Berkeley and Los
Suzuki, Tom o.
¯ 1992. The Self-Strengthening Move- Angeles: University of California Press.
ment: Industrialization in the Late 19th-Century Weber, Max. 1951. The Religion of China: Confucian-
China (In Chinese). Tokyo: Ky ¯ Shoin.
ko
u ism and Taoism. New York: Free Press.
Tawney, R. H. 1932. Land and Labour in China. New Whiting, Susan H. 2001. Power and Wealth in Rural
York: Harcourt, Brace, and Company. China: The Political Economy of Institutional
The Economist. 2005. “Rong Yiren.” http://www. Change. Cambridge; New York and Melbourne:
economist.com/node/5107693. Cambridge University Press.
Tirole, Jean. 1986. “Hierarchies and Bureaucracies: On Whitney, Joseph B. R. 1970. China: Area, Administra-
the Role of Collusion in Organizations.” Journal of tion, and Nation Building. Chicago: University of
Law, Economics, and Organization 2 (2): 181–214. Chicago Press.
Tsai, Kellee S. 2002. Back-Alley Banking: Private Will, Pierre-Etienne, and R. Bin Wong. 1991. Nour-
Entrepreneurs in China. Ithaca and London: Cornell ish the People: The State Civilian Granary System in
University Press. China, 1650–1850. Ann Arbor: University of Michi-
Tu, Wei-ming, ed. 1996. Confucian Traditions in East gan Center for Chinese Studies.
Asian Modernity: Moral Education and Economic Williamson, Jeffrey G. 2011. Trade and Poverty: When
Culture in Japan and the Four Mini-Dragons. Cam- the Third World Fell Behind. Cambridge, Mass. and
bridge and London: Harvard University Press. London: MIT Press.
Twomey, Michael J. 2000. A Century of Foreign Invest- Wittfogel, Karl A. 1957. Oriental Despotism: A Com-
ment in the Third World. New York: Taylor and Fran- parative Study of Total Power. New Haven and Lon-
cis, Routledge. don: Yale University Press, 1976.
Van Zanden, Jan Luiten. 2009. The Long Road to the Wong, Christine P. W. 1985. “Material Allocation and
Industrial Revolution: The European Economy in a Decentralization: Impact of the Local Sector on
Global Perspective, 1000–1800. Leiden: Brill. Industrial Reform.” In The Political Economy of
Velde, Dirk Willem te. 2006. “Foreign Direct Invest- Reform in Post-Mao China, edited by Elizabeth J.
ment and Development: An Historical Perspective.” Perry and Christine P. W. Wong, 253–78. Cambridge,
http://www.odi.org.uk/resources/docs/850.pdf. Mass., and London: Harvard University Council on
von Glahn, Richard. 1996. Fountain of Fortune: Money East Asian Studies.
and Monetary Policy in China, 1000–1700. Berkeley Wong, Christine P. W., and Richard M. Bird. 2008.
and London: University of California Press. “China’s Fiscal System: A Work in Progress.” In
von Glahn, Richard. 2003. “Money Use in China and China’s Great Economic Transformation, edited by
Changing Patterns of Global Trade in Monetary Met- Loren Brandt and Thomas G. Rawski, 429–66. Cam-
als, 1500–1800.” In Global Connections and Mone- bridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.
tary History, 1470–1800, edited by Dennis O. Flynn, Wong, John. 1973. Land Reform in the People’s
Brandt, Ma, and Rawski: From Divergence to Convergence 123