Soft Currency Economics II Warren Mosler
Soft Currency Economics II Warren Mosler
Copyright
Preface
Statement of Purpose
Fiat Money
Lead Accounting
More on Why Lead Accounting is Unworkable – Inelasticity for Loan Demand
How the Government Spends and Borrows as Much as it Does Without Causing
Hyperinflation
Taxation
Foreign Trade
Conclusion
Other Books
By Warren Mosler
All Rights Reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced in any form or
by any means, including scanning, photocopying, or otherwise without prior
written permission of the copyright holder.
Fiat Money
Lead Accounting
How the Government Spends and Borrows as Much as it Does Without Causing Hyperinflation
Foreign Trade
Conclusion
Mosler had Spaventa validate and confirm his thinking that the market had
the pricing all wrong. This lead to very successful trades for Mosler, what he
referred to a “free 2%” return, and at the same time educated Spaventa that Italy
(this was prior to the Euro) could not go bankrupt unless it wanted to, and thus
Italy did not have to succumb to the pressure from the IMF to implement austerity
programs.
It is often said that history repeats itself. Twenty years after the Italian
Epiphany, Italy is once again experiencing financial difficulties and there is once
again a discussion of the potential for default. One major difference exists today
compared to the early 1990s and that is the monetary system that existed in the
1990s no longer applies. Today, Italy no longer has its own free trading fiat
currency that it can issue to pay government expenditures. Instead, Italy now has
to borrow Euros to fund expenditures and it is the European Central Bank (ECB),
not the Italian Central Bank, which can provide the economic remedy.
1. A tax credit bond, which is a bond that in the case of nonpayment can
be used directly for the payment of taxes;
The “Free Lunch” possibility totally preoccupied me. The reward for turning
this into a risk free spread was immense. So I started brainstorming the issue with
my partners. We knew no nation had ever defaulted on its own currency when it
was not legally convertible into gold or anything else. There was a time when
nations issued securities that were convertible into gold. That era, however, ended
for good in 1971 when President Nixon took us off the gold standard
internationally (the same year I got my BA from U-Conn) and we entered the era of
floating exchange rates and non-convertible currencies.
While some people still think that the America dollar is backed by the gold
in Fort Knox, which is not the case. If you take a $10 bill to the Treasury
Department and demand gold for it, they won’t give it to you because they simply
are not legally allowed to do so, even if they wanted to. They will give you two $5
bills or ten $1 bills, but forget about getting any gold.
Historically, government defaults came only with the likes of gold standards,
fixed exchange rates, external currency debt, and indexed domestic debt. But why
was that? The answer generally given was “because they can always print the
money.” Fair enough, but there were no defaults (lots of inflation but no defaults)
and no one ever did “print the money,” so I needed a better reason before
committing millions of our investors funds.
A few days later when talking to our research analyst, Tom Shulke, it came
to me. I said, “Tom, if we buy securities from the Fed or Treasury, functionally
there is no difference. We send the funds to the same place (the Federal Reserve)
and we own the same thing, a Treasury security, which is nothing more than
account at the Fed that pays interest.”
So functionally it has to all be the same. Yet presumably the Treasury sells
securities to fund expenditures, while when the Fed sells securities, it’s a “reserve
drain” to “offset operating factors” and manage the fed funds rate. Yet they have to
be functionally the same - it’s all just a glorified reserve drain! Many of my
colleagues in the world of hedge fund management were intrigued by the profit
potential that might exist in the 2% free lunch that the Government of Italy was
offering us. Maurice Samuels, then a portfolio manager at Harvard Management,
immediately got on board, and set up meetings for us in Rome with officials of the
Italian government to discuss these issues.
Maurice and I were soon on a plane to Rome. Shortly after landing, we were
meeting with Professor Luigi Spaventa, a senior official of the Italian Government’s
Treasury Department. (I recall telling Maurice to duck as we entered the room. He
looked up and started to laugh. The opening was maybe twenty feet high. “That’s
so you could enter this room in Roman times carrying a spear,” he replied.)
Professor Spaventa was sitting behind an elegant desk. He was wearing a three-
piece suit, and smoking one of those curled pipes. The image of the great English
economist John Maynard Keynes, whose work was at the center of much economic
policy discussion for so many years, came to mind. Professor Spaventa was Italian,
but he spoke English with a British accent, furthering the Keynesian imagery.
After we exchanged greetings, I opened with a question that got right to the
core of the reason for our trip. “Professor Spaventa, this is a rhetorical question,
but why is Italy issuing Treasury securities? Is it to get lira to spend, or is it to
prevent the lira interbank rate falling to zero from your target rate of 12%?” I could
tell that Professor Spaventa was at first puzzled by the questions. He was probably
expecting us to question when we would get our withholding tax back. The Italian
Treasury Department was way behind on making their payments. They had only
two people assigned to the task of remitting the withheld funds to foreign holders
of Italian bonds, and one of these two was a woman on maternity leave.
I said nothing, giving him more time to consider the question. A few seconds
later he jumped up out of his seat proclaiming “Yes! And the International
Monetary Fund is making us act pro cyclical!” My question had led to the
realization that the IMF was making the Italian Government tighten policy due to a
default risk that did not exist.
Our meeting, originally planned to last for only twenty minutes, went on for
two hours. The good Professor began inviting his associates in nearby offices to
join us to hear the good news, and instantly the cappuccino was flowing like
water. The dark cloud of default had been lifted. This was time for celebration!
Italy did not default, nor was there ever any solvency risk. Insolvency is
never an issue with non-convertible currency and floating exchange rates. We
knew that, and now the Italian Government also understood this and was unlikely
to “do something stupid,” such as proclaiming a default when there was no actual
financial reason to do so. Over the next few years, our funds and happy clients
made well over $100 million in profits on these transactions, and we may have
saved the Italian Government as well. The awareness of how currencies function
operationally inspired this book and hopefully will soon save the world from itself.
Gloom and doom were everywhere. News anchor David Brinkley suggested
that the nation needed to declare bankruptcy and get it over with. Ross Perot’s
popularity was on the rise with his fiscal responsibility theme. Perot actually
became one of the most successful 3rd party candidates in history by promising to
balance the budget. (His rising popularity was cut short only when he claimed the
Viet Cong were stalking his daughter’s wedding in Texas.)
With my new understanding, I was keenly aware of the risks to the welfare
of our nation. I knew that the larger federal deficits was what was fixing the
broken economy, but I watched helplessly as our mainstream leaders and the
entire media clamored for fiscal responsibility (lower deficits) and were prolonging
the agony.
It was then that I began conceiving the academic paper that would become
Soft Currency Economics. I discussed it with my previous boss, Ned Janotta, at
William Blair.
The essence of the political process is coming to terms with the inherent
trade-offs we face in a world of limited resources and unlimited wants. The idea
that people can improve their lives by depriving themselves of surplus goods and
services contradicts both common sense and any respectable economic theory.
When there are widespread unemployed resources as there are today in the United
States, the trade-off costs are often minimal, yet mistakenly deemed unaffordable.
Interest groups from both ends of the political spectrum have rallied around
various plans designed to reduce the deficit. Popular opinion takes for granted that
a balanced budget yields net economic benefits only to be exceeded by paying off
the debt. The Clinton administration claims a lower 1994 deficit as one of its
highest achievements. All new programs must be paid for with either tax revenue
or spending cuts. Revenue neutral has become synonymous with fiscal
responsibility.
The deficit doves and deficit hawks who debate the consequences of fiscal
policy both accept traditional perceptions of federal borrowing. Both sides of the
argument accept the premise that the federal government borrows money to fund
expenditures. They differ only in their analysis of the deficit's effects. For example,
doves may argue that since the budget does not discern between capital
investment and consumption expenditures, the deficit is overstated. Or, that since
we are primarily borrowing from ourselves, the burden is overstated. But even if
policy makers are convinced that the current deficit is a relatively minor problem,
the possibility that a certain fiscal policy initiative might inadvertently result in a
high deficit, or that we may owe the money to foreigners, imposes a high risk. It is
believed that federal deficits undermine the financial integrity of the nation.
The validity of the current thinking about the federal budget deficit and the
federal debt will be challenged in a way that supersedes both the hawks and the
doves. Once we realize that the deficit can present no financial risk, it will be
evident that spending programs should be evaluated on their real economic
benefits, and weighed against their real economic costs. Similarly, a meaningful
analysis of tax changes evaluates their impact on the economy, not the impact on
the deficit. It will also be shown that taxed advantaged savings incentives are
creating a need for deficit spending.
The discussion will begin with an explanation of fiat money, and outline key
elements of the operation of the banking system. The following points will be
brought into focus:
In 1971 the Nixon administration abandoned the gold standard and adopted
a fiat monetary system, substantially altering what looked like the same currency.
Under a fiat monetary system, money is an accepted medium of exchange only
because the government requires it for tax payments.
Government fiat money necessarily means that federal spending need not be
based on revenue. The federal government has no more money at its disposal
when the federal budget is in surplus, than when the budget is in deficit. Total
federal expense is whatever the federal government chooses it to be. There is no
inherent financial limit. The amount of federal spending, taxing and borrowing
influence inflation, interest rates, capital formation, and other real economic
phenomena, but the amount of money available to the federal government is
independent of tax revenues and independent of federal debt. Consequently, the
concept of a federal trust fund under a fiat monetary system is an anachronism.
The government is no more able to spend money when there is a trust fund than
when no such fund exists. The only financial constraints, under a fiat monetary
system, are self-imposed.
To illustrate the nature of federal debt under a fiat monetary system, the
model of family currency can be taken a step further. Suppose the parent offers to
pay overnight interest on the outstanding business cards (payable in more
business cards). The children might want to hold on to some cards to use among
themselves for convenience. Extra cards not needed overnight for inter-sibling
transactions would probably be deposited with the parent. That is, the parent
would have borrowed back some of the business cards from the children. The
business card deposits are the national debt that the parent owes.
In the U. S., the 12 members of the Federal Open Market Committee decide
on the overnight interest rate. That, along with what Congress decides to spend,
tax, and borrow (that is, pay interest on the untaxed spending), determines the
value of the money and, in general, regulates the economy.
Federal borrowing and taxation were once part of the process of managing
the Treasury's gold reserves. Unfortunately, discussions about monetary
economics and the U. S. banking system still rely on many of the relationships
observed and understood during the time when the U. S. monetary regime
operated under a gold standard, a system in which arguably the government was
required to tax or borrow sufficient revenue to fund government spending. Some of
the old models are still useful in accurately explaining the mechanics of the
banking system. Others have outlived their usefulness and have led to misleading
constructs. Two such vestiges of the gold standard are the role of bank reserves
(including the money multiplier) and the concept of monetization. An examination
of the workings of the market for bank reserves reveals the essential concepts.
(Additional monetary history and a more detailed explanation are provided in the
appendix).
The Fed defines the method that banks are required to use in computing
deposits and reserve requirements. The period which a depository institution's
average daily reserves must meet or exceed its specified required reserves is called
the reserve maintenance period. The period in which the deposits on which
reserves are based are measured is the reserve computation period. The reserve
accounting method was amended in 1968 and again in 1984 but neither change
altered the Fed's role in the market for reserves.
Under both CRA and LRA the Fed must provide enough reserves to meet the
known requirements, either through open market operations or through the
discount window. If banks were left on their own to obtain more reserves no
amount of interbank lending would be able to create the necessary reserves.
Interbank lending changes the location of the reserves but the amount of reserves
in the entire banking system remains the same. For example, suppose the total
reserve requirement for the banking system was $60 billion at the close of
business today but only $55 billion of reserves were held by the entire banking
system. Unless the Fed provides the additional $5 billion in reserves, at least one
bank will fail to meet its reserve requirement. The Federal Reserve is, and can only
be, the follower, not the leader when it adjusts reserve balances in the banking
system.
Bank managers generally neither know nor care about the aggregate level of
reserves in the banking system. Bank lending decisions are affected by the price of
reserves, not by reserve positions. If the spread between the rate of return on an
asset and the fed funds rate is wide enough, even a bank deficient in reserves will
purchase the asset and cover the cash needed by purchasing (borrowing) money in
the funds market. This fact is clearly demonstrated by many large banks when
they consistently purchase more money in the fed funds market than their entire
level of required reserves. These banks would actually have negative reserve levels
if not for fed funds purchases i.e. borrowing money to be held as reserves.
If the Fed should want to increase the money supply, devotees of the money
multiplier model (including numerous Nobel Prize winners) would have the Fed
purchase securities. When the Fed buys securities reserves are added to the
system. However, the money multiplier model fails to recognize that the added
reserves in excess of required reserves drive the funds rate to zero, since reserve
requirements do not change until the following accounting period. That forces the
Fed to sell securities, i.e., drain the excess reserves just added, to maintain the
funds rate above zero.
If, on the other hand, the Fed wants to decrease money supply, taking
reserves out of the system when there are no excess reserves places some banks at
risk of not meeting their reserve requirements. The Fed has no choice but to add
reserves back into the banking system, to keep the funds rate from going,
theoretically, to infinity.
In either case, the money supply remains unchanged by the Fed's action.
The multiplier is properly thought of as simply the ratio of the money supply to the
monetary base (m = M/MB). Changes in the money supply cause changes in the
monetary base, not vice versa. The money multiplier is more accurately thought of
as a divisor (MB = M/m).
Failure to recognize the fallacy of the money-multiplier model has led even
some of the most well- respected experts astray. The following points should be
obvious, but are rarely understood:
Once the Federal Reserve Board of Governors sets a fed funds rate, the Fed's
portfolio of government securities changes only because of the transactions that
are required to support the funds rate. The Fed's lack of control over the quantity
of reserves underscores the impossibility of debt monetization. The Fed is unable
to monetize the federal debt by purchasing government securities at will because
to do so would cause the funds rate to fall to zero. If the Fed purchased securities
directly from the Treasury and the Treasury then spent the money, its
expenditures would be excess reserves in the banking system. The Fed would be
forced to sell an equal amount of securities to support the fed funds target rate.
The Fed would act only as an intermediary. The Fed would be buying securities
from the Treasury and selling them to the public. No monetization would occur.
Whatever the intermediate targets of monetary policy may be, the Fed's
primary instrument for implementing policy is the federal funds rate. The fed
funds rate is influenced by open market operations. It is maintained or adjusted in
order to guide the intermediate target variable. If the Fed is using a quantity rule
(i.e., trying to determine the quantity of money), the intermediate target is a
monetary aggregate such as M1 or M2. For instance, if M2 grows faster than its
target rate the Fed may raise the fed funds rate in an effort to slow the growth rate
of M2. If M2 grows too slowly the Fed may lower the fed funds rate. If the Fed
chooses to use the value of money as its intermediate target then the fed funds
target will be set based on a price level indicator such as the price of gold or the
Spot Commodities Index. Under a price rule the price of gold, for example, is
targeted within a narrow band. The Fed raises the fed funds rate when the price
exceeds its upper limit and lowers the rate when the price falls below its lower
limit in hopes that a change in the fed funds rate returns the price of gold into the
target range.
The Treasury draws all of its checks from accounts at the Fed. The funds
are transferred from the Tax and Loan accounts to the Fed then drawn from the
Fed account to purchase goods and services or make transfer payments. Suppose
the Treasury intends to pay $500 million for a B-2 stealth bomber. The Treasury
transfers $500 million from its Tax and Loan accounts to its account at the Fed.
The commercial banks now have $500 million less in deposits and hence $500
million less reserves. At the Fed, reserves decrease by $500 million while Treasury
deposits have increased by $500 million. At this instant the increase in U. S.
Treasury deposits reduces reserves and the monetary base but when the Treasury
pays for the bomber the preceding process is reversed. U. S. Treasury deposits at
the Fed fall by $500 million and the defense contractor deposits the check received
from the Treasury in its bank, whose reserves rise by $500 million. Government
spending does not change the monetary base when reserves move simultaneously
in equal amounts and opposite directions.
Figure 3 - The Government Spends $500 million and Taxes $500 million
Figure 4 - The Government Spends $500 million and borrows $500
Federal Government Spending, Borrowing and Debt
The Fed's desire to maintain the target fed funds rate links government
spending, which adds reserves to the banking system, and government taxation
and borrowing, which drain reserves from the banking system.
The Federal Reserve does not have exclusive control of reserve balances.
Reserve balances can be affected by the Treasury itself. For example, if the
Treasury sells $100 of securities, thereby increasing the balance of its checking
account at the Fed by $100, reserves decline just as if the Fed had sold the
securities. When either government entity sells government securities reserve
balances decline. When either buys government securities (in this case the
Treasury would be retiring debt) reserves in the banking system increase. The
monetary constraints of a fed funds target dictate that the government cannot
spend money without borrowing (or taxing), nor can the government borrow (or
tax) without spending. The financial imperative is to keep the reserve market in
balance, not to acquire money to spend.
Interest Rate Maintenance Account (IRMA)
Over the course of time the total number of dollars that have been drained
from the banking system to maintain the fed funds rate is called the federal debt.
A more appropriate name would be the Interest Rate Maintenance Account (IRMA).
The IRMA is simply an accounting of the total amount of securities issued to pay
interest on untaxed money spent by the government.
Since the federal budget deficit became an issue in the early eighties the
warnings abound over the severe consequences of partaking in the supposedly
sinister practice of borrowing money from the private sector. Enough warnings
about the federal deficit have been made by Democrats, Republicans and other
patriotic Americans to fill a new wing in the Smithsonian. The following is but a
small sample:
"The national deficit is like cancer. The sooner we act to restrict it the
healthier our fiscal body will be and the more promising our future."
Senator Paul Simon (D-IL).
"...a blow to our children's living standards." The New York Times.
"...this great nation can no longer tolerate running runaway deficits
and exorbitant annual interest payments..." Senator Howell T.
Heflin, (D-AL).
The Gold System as a Basis for Reserves
The gold standard was established in the U. S. in 1834. Under a gold
standard the price of gold is set in terms of the dollar. The dollar was defined as
23.22 fine grains of gold. With 480 grains to the fine troy ounce, this was
equivalent to $20.67 per ounce. The monetary authority was then committed to
keep the mint price of gold fixed by being willing to buy or sell the gold in
unlimited amounts.
The gold standard was suspended from 1861 to 1879 due to the Civil War.
The variant which prevailed in the U. S. from 1880 to 1914 was a fractional
reserve gold coin standard. Under that standard both government issued notes
and notes issued by commercial banks (also deposits) circulated alongside gold
coins. These forms of currency were each convertible on demand into gold. Gold
reserves were held by the issuers to maintain convertibility.
In 1934 the Gold Reserve Act devalued the dollar by increasing the
monetary price of gold from $20.67 to $35.00 an ounce. The Act put the U. S. on a
limited gold bullion standard under which redemption in gold was restricted to
dollars held by foreign central banks and licensed private users.
The primary attraction of gold as a basis for a monetary system is that its
supply is limited, or at least increases slowly, whereas fiat money is limited only by
the judgments of presumably fallible people. While the gold standard provided a
stable monetary framework during much of its reign as the prevailing world
monetary standard, the gold standard itself is not immune to problems of inflation
and deflation. For example, an increase in the gold supply brought about by a
major gold strike could increase prices and disrupt financial markets.
Under gold standard rules and regulations, gold set the ultimate barrier to
the expansion of bank reserves and the supply of Federal Reserve Notes. Gold set
the upper limit to liabilities of the Federal Reserve Banks. For example, in 1963
the note and deposit liabilities of the Federal Reserve Banks could not exceed four
times their holdings of gold certificates, a special form of currency backed 100
percent by gold actually held in the Treasury vaults at Fort Knox, Kentucky. If the
total Federal Reserve Bank liabilities were $50 billion then a least $12.5 billion of
the total would have to be in gold certificates. If the Fed were to reach the upper
limit the Fed would be unable to purchase any more government securities on
balance or to increase loans to member banks. This would mean that bank
reserves could no longer increase and would even have to shrink if the public
wished to hold more currency. In this case the upper limit in the money supply
would have been reached. If a further increase in the money supply appeared
desirable the Fed had two options. First, the Federal Reserve could lower the
banks' requirements so that with the same volume of reserves banks could lend
larger sums. Second, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System could
suspend the 25 percent gold certificate reserve requirement.
The actual movement of gold into and out of the Treasury was a unique
process because of the status of gold as a monetary standard. A description of the
process of acquiring gold explains how gold certificates found their way into
Federal Reserve Banks. The term “monetize” means that the Treasury simply
creates new money when they acquire gold. When the Treasury wished to
purchase a gold brick from a gold mine they printed a gold certificate.
In the actual process of monetizing gold the Treasury buys it from a gold
mine. The gold bars are delivered to Fort Knox. The government pays by issuing a
check. The gold mine deposits the check in its commercial bank. The commercial
bank, in turn sends the check to the Federal Reserve Bank for deposit to its
reserve account there. The Reserve Bank then reduces the Treasury's balance by
the amount of the check. The original outlay by the government has increased the
gold mine's account without reducing any other private account in the commercial
banking system, and, the commercial bank has gained reserves while no other
bank has lost reserves. In effect, the Treasury's balance at the Federal Bank has
been shifted to a commercial bank. Both the money supply and commercial bank
reserves have been increased.
Note that this type of government spending which increases reserves and
the money supply is unique to the purchase of gold under a gold standard. When
the government buys anything other than gold they have to have, so to speak,
money in the bank to pay for it. The money the government spends on missiles,
cement, paper clips or the President's salary has to be raised by taxation or by
borrowing. The government, like everyone else, is prohibited from simply printing
money to pay for the things it buys. If the government assigned other commodities
the role held by gold only then would the government acquire cement or paper
clips by printing cement certificates or paper clip certificates. Everything else on
which the government spends is covered by taxes or borrowing. Therefore,
expenditures by the government from its account at the Fed are continuously
offset by receipts of taxes or borrowed funds.
Reserve Requirements, History, Rationale & Current Practice
Laws requiring banks and other depository institutions to hold a certain
fraction of their deposits in reserve, in very safe, secure, assets have been part of
the U. S. banking system since 1863, well before the establishment of the Federal
Reserve System in 1913. Prior to the existence of the Fed, reserve requirements
were thought to help ensure the liquidity of bank notes and deposits. But as bank
runs and financial panics continued periodically, it became apparent that reserve
requirements did not guarantee liquidity. The notion of reserve requirements as a
source of liquidity vanished completely upon creation of the Federal Reserve
System as lender of last resort.
Since 1913 there have been two primary roles associated with reserve
requirements: money control and a revenue source for the Treasury. The Federal
Reserve has viewed reserve requirements as a mechanism to stabilize the money
supply. The Fed has sought to set reserve requirements as part of the process of
controlling the money supply. The Fed's objective is to control the supply of
reserves. In the theory based on the gold standard an increase in the amount of
reserves provided to the banking system should be associated with an increase in
reservable deposits in an amount that is a multiple of the reserve increase. (Today,
however, banks make loans independent of their position. This critical departure
will be discussed later.)
As implied by basic tax theory, the higher the rate of taxation on the
production of any product the greater will be the price paid by the demanders of
that product and the lower will be the price received by the suppliers of that
product. Taxes introduce a wedge between prices paid and prices received.
Borrowers pay more and banks receive less for loans. A simple way in which the
Fed could eliminate the reserve tax on banks is to pay interest on the reserves. If
the Fed paid a market- based rate of interest on required reserve balances, the
reserve tax would essentially be eliminated as would the distortion of the tax on
resource allocation. In the past, proposals to pay interest on required reserve
balances have encountered resistance because they would reduce the earnings
remitted by the Fed to the Treasury.
The reserve tax has always discouraged membership in the Federal Reserve
System. To reduce the burden of the tax, legislation was enacted to allow banks to
use vault cash to satisfy their reserve requirements. This change was phased-in
beginning December 1959. At the end of 1992, 56 percent of required reserve
balances were in the form of vault cash. Despite the efforts of the Federal Reserve
System the membership declined steadily. In 1959 approximately 85 percent of all
transaction deposits were at member banks. By 1980 the portion of transaction
deposits at member banks had fallen to less than 65 percent.
Each Federal Reserve Bank's board of directors sets its discount rates
subject to approval of the Board of Governors. Since the 1950s the Fed's stated
policy discourages persistent reliance on borrowing. Borrowing from the discount
window is supposed to represent only a modest share of total reserves. The actual
amount of borrowed reserves is total reserves demanded by the banking system
minus the amount of unborrowed reserves provided by the Fed through open
market operations. Officially the Fed fashions the discount window as a safety
valve, a temporary source of resources when they are not readily available from
other sources. The discount window is simply a means of accommodating the
reserve requirements of the banking system - the same reserves provided through
open market operations but with a slightly different price and slightly different
packaging. Both the 1980 and 1990 versions of Regulation A state as a general
requirement that "Federal Reserve credit is not a substitute for capital." But all
along, fed policy has determined the amount of borrowing. To the extent that
immediate reserve needs are not provided through open market purchases they
must be provided through the discount window. In this context the window's role
is in meeting known reserve needs.
Throughout its history the Fed has used the discount window for much
more than its stated purpose. To accommodate Treasury financing needs in World
War I, the Reserve Banks were empowered to extend direct collateral loans to
member banks. Continuous borrowing year in and year out was not uncommon in
the 1920s. The availability of the discount window was expanded in 1932 by the
Emergency Relief and Construction Act. The act opened the discount window to
non-banks. It permitted the Reserve Banks to lend to individuals, partnerships
and corporations, with no other source of funds or notes eligible for discount at
member banks. The Act of June 19, 1934 authorized Reserve Banks to make
advances to established commercial or industrial enterprises for the purpose of
supplying working capital if the borrower was unable to attain assistance from the
usual sources. It is unclear whether the Act had any impact on the net amount of
lending. Essentially, Federal Reserve Banks were authorized to make loans on
behalf of the taxpayers. When a Federal Reserve Bank made a direct business loan
the loan created a new deposit in the banking system. The new deposit added
bank reserves which could be used to purchase government bonds from the Fed.
The net change to the banking system's balance sheet was an increase in deposits
matched by an increase in government securities. Reserve Banks continued to
make and co-finance working capital industrial loans until authorization to do so
was repealed by the Small Business Investment Act of 1958.
The Fed's use of the discount window has expanded to cover a wide range of
reserve needs. The frequency of borrowing from the discount window has no
explicit restrictions. The banks using the discount window are not held to any
financial strength standards. The de facto criterion for eligibility for discount loans
is simply need. Experience has consistently shown that the Fed will not allow a
bank to fail when a bank requires a loan to cover its reserve requirement. The cost
of discount borrowing may vary considerably as the discount rate changes and as
administrative costs and/or penalties change. Nevertheless, the discount window
remains accessible to any bank's reserve needs.
Member banks have reserves in the Fed which are also known as
immediately available funds since they can be transferred almost instantaneously
over Fedwire. Fedwire is the Federal Reserve's system that electronically transfers
funds and securities on its communications network. Money and securities are no
more than accounting data. A bank can access its account at its Reserve Bank to
transfer funds or securities to any other depository institution that has a Reserve
Bank account. When banks borrow fed funds they are actually borrowing deposits
from other banks. The transfer of fed funds increases the deposits at the
borrowing bank and reduces deposits at the lending bank. Most fed funds
borrowing is for one day; essentially these borrowings are one-day unsecured
loans.
Banks may obtain funds in the fed funds market to maintain their reserve
requirement. They have lines of credit with each other to enact direct transfers of
funds. Banks have been known to borrow fed funds continuously and in excess of
their reserve requirement when it is profitable to do so. Banks may borrow beyond
their reserve requirement and lend the borrowed funds at higher rates than the
cost of borrowing. The difference between a bank's cost of money and the return
on loans determines its willingness to lend. The cost of money defines the cost of
loans, and thus the demand for loans.
The Repurchase Agreements Market (Repos)
The transfer of funds is also facilitated by the market for repurchase
agreements (the repo market). Banks use repurchase agreements (RPs) to obtain
short-term funds or as a means of investing funds on a very short-term basis.
Banks are the temporary recipients of funds; other banks or the Fed may supply
funds. RPs are quite flexible; they can be issued for one day or they may be
continuing contracts. In an overnight repurchase agreement, a security, such as a
U. S. Treasury bill, is purchased from a bank which agrees to repurchase the
security at the same price plus interest the next day. In effect the 'buyer' is making
a loan to the bank.
While the trading has its eye on the funds rate the actual open market
transactions are made in the repo market. The Fed is thereby able to manage the
fed funds rate within a reasonably narrow band.
Matched Sales Purchases
Matched-sale purchase transactions (MSPs) have been used since 1966.
MSPs, also known as reverse RPs, allow the Fed to sell securities (Borrow money)
with an agreement to repurchase them (pay off the loan) within a short time. The
use of MSPs is preferred to direct sales followed later by purchases because of the
temporary nature of the market for reserves. For example, an increase in the float
that temporarily increases reserves may result when transportation facilities are
halted by a snowstorm. The excess reserves may be temporarily reduced by MSPs.
The Fed in the Repo Market
Occasionally the Fed conducts open market operations by carrying out
straight forward purchases or sales of securities, but these outright transactions
are rare. At the New York Fed's trading desk where open market operations are
executed, the desk executes outright security transactions only when it perceives a
permanent change in reserve needs. In 1992 the desk entered the market to buy
securities outright only six times.
Figure 5 - Probabilities of the Open Market Desk Daily Transactions June 1998 to December 1990
Figure 6 depicts the likelihood of the desk's use of RPs and MSPs in the repo
market. The graph also plots the probability that the desk will abstain from
participating in the market.
Figure 6 - Likelihood that the Fed’s Desk uses Repurchase and Reverse Repos
Figures 5 and 6 also shows the probability of the desk's use of RPs and
MSPs based upon the average reserve need of the banking system. Note the slight
bias of the no transaction line. The desk is somewhat more willing to allow a
reserve deficiency to persist than an equal amount of reserve excess. The presence
of the discount window as a source of reserves accounts for the desk's slightly
smaller aversion to reserve deficiency versus reserve excess.
Using the fed funds rate as its daily guide the Fed uses open market
operations continuously to stabilize the funds rate. In theory and in practice the
trading desk has an easy task. Once the desired fed funds rate has been
determined, conducting offsetting open market operations is as simple as driving a
car within the bounds of a straight, clearly marked lane. When the vehicle starts to
drift a minor adjustment is made to correct its path, if the vehicle drifts in the
opposite direction the driver uses the opposite correction.
Controlling the Fed Funds Rate
The supply of reserves consists of three parts: vault currency, reserves
supplied through fed open market transactions, and loans from the Fed's discount
window (Figure 7).
To the extent the Fed leaves the banking system short of reserves through
open market operations, banks short of reserves try to borrow from each other and
bid up the fed funds rate. As the spread between the fed funds rate and the
discount rate widens more banks will borrow from the discount window.
Borrowing from the discount window carries some administrative costs as well as
a stigma of financial weakness. Nevertheless, as the funds rate rises higher and
higher above the discount rate more banks will go to the window. Banks are, after
all, profit making businesses and the financial incentives to borrow from the
window increase as the spread between the funds rate and the discount rate
widens.
Figure 8 shows that when interest rates on fed funds rise above the
discount rate, depository institutions borrow from the Fed. In other words, the Fed
supplies the needed resources to the banking system by purchasing securities in
the open market or lending at the discount window. By adjusting the composition
of the reserves between borrowed and non-borrowed the Fed sets the spread
between the fed funds and the discount rate. The Fed uses open market operations
to adjust reserve balances so as to keep the banking system in a net borrowed
position. To reduce the spread between the fed funds rate and the discount rate
the Fed provides more unborrowed reserves through open market purchases. To
increase the spread the Fed provides fewer unborrowed reserves which require
banks to bid up the price of fed funds and borrow more heavily from the discount
window.
Open market operations are carried out by the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York under the direction of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). The
voting members of the FOMC are the seven members of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, the President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, and four of the Presidents from the other eleven Federal Reserve Banks who
serve on the FOMC on a rotational basis. The FOMC meet in Washington, D. C.
about every six weeks to assess the current economic outlook. The FOMC votes on
intermediate policy objectives and issues a directive to the trading desk manager of
open market operations in the New York Federal Reserve Bank. The directive
stipulates the target fed funds rate.
Further Discussion of Inelasticity
The fed funds rate can be very volatile because the market for reserves is
inelastic in the very short run. The banking system has no immediate way to rid
itself of excess reserves. A system-wide excess of reserves would push the funds
rate to zero. Even if banks were able to increase their volume of lending, excess
reserves would persist. Within the current accounting period each new loan
creates a deposit somewhere in the banking system, but each new loan absorbs
only a tiny fraction of the excess reserves. Furthermore, lending decisions are
generally independent of reserve needs.
The Federal Reserve can set the price of reserves but the quantity is
determined by the banking system. The market for reserves is not perfectly
inelastic because the Fed allows some spill-over in the accounting of bank reserves
from one period to the next. This practice allows banks to smooth out some of the
volatility of their reserve positions but it does not change the inelastic nature of
the market for reserves. Efforts to force the market to accept fewer loans than are
demanded would be nearly as disruptive as forcing the divers to make do with no
air. The banking system would have to reduce their outstanding loans by forcing
customers to immediately sell off assets financed through the banking system. The
senseless dislocation of assets caused by forced disintermediation makes such an
action unthinkable. Central bankers who understand the intractable nature of the
banking system's loan portfolio recognize the necessity of lagged reserve
accounting. A sensible approach to changing the money supply employs a change
in the fed funds rate to gradually bring about the desired result.
What if No One Buys the Debt
It is not possible to adequately address every question raised by "debt
phoebes". One of the most common concerns, however, clearly illustrates the
unfounded fear that arises from confusing private borrowing with public
borrowing. The question is based on an image of Uncle Sam being turned away by
lenders and being stuck without financing.
When demand is strong and sales are high businesses normally respond by
increasing output. They may also invest in additional capital equipment.
Investment in new capacity is automatically an increase in savings. Savings rises
because workers are paid to produce capital goods they cannot buy and consume.
The only other choice left is for individuals to "invest" in capital goods, either
directly or through an intermediary. An increase in investment for whatever reason
is an increase in savings; a decrease in individual spending, however, does not
cause an increase in overall investment.
The root of this paradox is the mistaken notion that savings is needed to
provide money for investment. This is not true. In the banking system, loans,
including those for business investments, create equal deposits, obviating the need
for savings as a source of money. Investment creates its own money.
Once we recognize that savings does not cause investment it follows that the
solution to high unemployment and low capacity utilization is not necessarily to
encourage more savings. In fact, taxed advantaged savings has probably caused
the private sector to desire to be a NET saver. This condition requires the public
sector to run a deficit, or face deflation.
Full Employment and Price Stability
There is a very interesting fiscal policy option that is not under
consideration, because it may result in a larger budget deficit. The Federal
government could offer a job to anyone who applies, at a fixed rate of pay, and let
the deficit float. This would result in full employment, by definition. It would also
eliminate the need for such legislation as unemployment compensation and a
minimum wage.
Once the government levies a tax, the private sector needs the
government’s money so that it can pay the tax.
A government using fiat money has pricing power that it may not
understand. The conventional understanding that the government must tax so it
can get money to spend does not apply to a fiat currency. Because the private
sector needs the government's money to meet its tax obligations, the government
can literally name its price for the money it spends. In a market economy it is only
necessary to define one price and let the market establish the rest. For this
example I am proposing to set the price of the supplementary government workers.
Given this, the secondary effects of taxes can now be considered before
deciding on the tax structure. A sales tax will inhibit transactions, as will an
income tax. This tendency to restrict trade and transactions is generally
considered a detriment. It reduces the tendency to realize the benefits of
specialization of labor and comparative advantage. Furthermore, transaction taxes
offer large rewards for successful evasion, and therefore require powerful
enforcement agencies and severe penalties. They also result in massive legal efforts
to transact without being subject to the taxes as defined by the law. Add this to
the cost of all of the record keeping necessary to be in compliance. All of these are
real economic costs of transactions taxes.
How much money one has may be less important than how much one
spends. This not a common consideration. But having money does not consume
real resources. Nor does one person's accumulation of nominal wealth preclude
another's, since the quantity of money available is infinite. Fiat money is only a tax
credit.
Prices reflect the indifference levels where buyers and sellers meet. The
market mechanism allows the participants to make their purchases and sales at
any price on which they mutually agree. Market prices tend to change
continuously. If, for example, there is a freeze in Brazil, the price of coffee may go
up. The higher price accommodates the transfer of the remaining supply of coffee
from the sellers to the buyers.
Prices going up and down can be the market allocating resources, not a
problem of inflation. Inflation is the process whereby the government causes
higher prices by creating more money either directly through deficit spending, or
indirectly by lowering interest rates or otherwise encouraging borrowing. For
example, when a shortage of goods and services causes higher prices, a
government may attempt to help its constituents to buy more by giving them more
money. Of course, a shortage means that the desired products don't exist. More
money just raises the price. When that, in turn, causes the government to further
increase the money available, an inflationary spiral has been created. The
institutionalization of this process is called indexing.
Left alone, the price of coffee, gold, or just about anything may go up, down,
or sideways. Goods and services go through cycles. One year, there may be a
record harvest and the next a disaster. Oil can be in shortage one decade, and
then in surplus the next. There could, conceivably, be years, or even decades when
the CPI grows at, say, 5% without any real inflation. There may be fewer things to
go around, with the market allocating them to the highest bidder.
If the Fed should decide to manage the economy by targeting the price of
gold, they would respond to an increase in the price of gold with higher interest
rates. The purpose would be to discourage lending, thereby reducing money
creation. In effect, the Fed would try to reduce the amount of money we all have in
order to keep the price of gold down. That may then depress the demand for all
other goods and services, even though they may be in surplus. By raising rates,
the Fed is saying that there is too much money in the economy and it is causing a
problem.
Presumably there is some advantage to targeting gold, the CPI, or any other
index, rather than leaving the money alone and letting the market adjust prices.
Interest rates can be too low and lead to excess money creation relative to the
goods and services available for sale. On the other hand, higher commodity prices
may represent the normal ebbs and flows in the markets for these items.
If there are indeed price increases due to changing supply dynamics, Fed
policy of restricting money may result in a slowdown of serious proportions which
would not have occurred if they had left interest rates alone.
Conclusion
The supposed technical and financial limits imposed by the federal budget
deficit and federal debt are a vestige of commodity money. Today's fiat currency
system has no such restrictions. The concept of a financial limit to the level of
untaxed federal spending (money creation/deficit spending) is erroneous. The
former constraints imposed by the gold standard have been gone since 1971. This
is not to say that deficit spending does not have economic consequences. It is to
say that the full range of fiscal policy options should be considered and evaluated
based on their economic impacts rather than imaginary financial restraints.
Current macroeconomic policy can center on how to more fully utilize the nation's
productive resources. True overcapacity is an easy problem to solve. We can afford
to employ idle resources.
Obsolete economic models have hindered our ability to properly address real
issues. Our attention has been directed away from issues which have real
economic effects to meaningless issues of accounting. Discussions of income,
inflation, and unemployment have been overshadowed by the national debt and
deficit. The range of possible policy actions has been needlessly restricted. Errant
thinking about the federal deficit has left policy makers unwilling to discuss any
measures which might risk an increase in the amount of federal borrowing. At the
same time they are increasing savings incentives, which create further need for
those unwanted deficits.
The major economic problems facing the United States today are not
extreme. Only a misunderstanding of money and accounting prevents Americans
from achieving a higher quality of life that is readily available.
Mosler Speech - Rome Debt Management
Conference October 26, 2012
I’ll first address what I believe is the most misunderstood question, which is
why the euro national governments debts are as high as they are. The answer
begins with the absolute fact that government debt is equal to global ‘non-
government’ accumulations of euro financial assets. For any given ‘closed sector’
the euro is a traditional case of ‘inside money’, as with a ‘giro’ or ‘clearing house.’
The only way an agent could have net euro financial assets would be for another to
be net borrowed. For every euro asset there is a euro liability. The net is always
zero.
This type of system famously can’t accommodate a net desire to save, unless
there is a provision for net financial assets to enter the sector in question. In the
case of the euro, this means the non-government sector requires government
deficit spending to satisfy its net savings desires, should there be any.
Additionally, note that all government spending is either used to pay taxes or
remains as net savings in the economy, in one form or another. And
unemployment, as defined, is the evidence that the economy does not have
sufficient euro income to pay its taxes and fulfill its net savings desires.
In the years immediately before the euro, the member nations with today’s
high debts had their own currencies. As currency issuers, whether they realized it
or not, they had no solvency issues, they set their own interest rates, and they
accommodated domestic savings desires with government deficit spending, which
allowed them to sustain growth and keep unemployment relatively low.
The point here is that high deficits were offsetting the high demand leakages
built into the institutional structures. And that requirement has not gone away, as
the traditional demand leakages remain. And note that the nation with the lowest
deficit, Luxemburg, never had its own currency, and instead market forces caused
them to fund their net financial assets with net exports.
What changed with the euro, and the ‘divorces’ from the national central
banks, was the ability to fund national deficits. The euro nation’s financial
dynamics became very much like the US states. They can no longer ‘print the
money’, and are instead revenue constrained. However, the difference is that,
unlike the US states, the euro members entered the euro with the higher debt
levels incurred when they were issuers of their currencies, not constrained by
revenues, and acting to offset demand leakages as required to sustain output and
employment.
Today, the ECB is the central bank for the euro. I often call it the ‘score
keeper’ for the euro. The ECB system spends and lends euro simply by crediting
accounts. These euro don’t ‘come from’ anywhere.
They are ‘data entry’. As Chairman Bernanke responded when asked where
the hundreds of billions of dollars lent to the banks came from: ‘...we simply use
the computer to mark up the size of the account they have with the Fed.’
In fact, any central bank, operationally, can make any size payments in its
own currency. When the ECB makes a 500 million euro securities purchase, no
one asks where the euro came from, whether it was taxpayer money, or whether
the ECB somehow borrowed it from China. Central banks are not revenue
constrained in their own currency. This puts them in the unique position of being
able to act counter cyclically during a down turn in the economy.
Conversely, the euro members, like the US states, are not financially
capable of reacting counter cyclically to increased savings desires when private
sector credit expansion fails and economies slow.
Only the ECB can, as I like to say, ‘write the check’ to allow for the provision
of the net financial assets demanded by the institutional structure, as evidenced
by the rate of unemployment and the output gap in general.
Given the state of private sector credit and net export potential, the euro
zone currently needs even higher levels of government deficit spending than
otherwise to sustain growth and employment. And only the ECB can write that
check. And yes, I realize the political difficulties this implies, the most pressing
issue being that of moral hazard.
Given the necessity of more national government debt and with only the
ECB ultimately capable of writing the check, I’ll now discuss policy options for
closing the output gap, and their associated risks.
A third option is for the ECB to make ‘cash’ distributions to the member
nations on a per capita basis of perhaps 10% of euro zone GDP annually. This
would begin a systematic reduction of member deficits towards zero over a multi-
year period. It would also have to include strict spending limits to regulate
aggregate demand. To that end, the ECB could withhold payment to violators,
which is far easier to do than imposing and collecting fines, as is the case today.
Twenty years ago I was in Rome at the finance ministry meeting with
Professor Luigi Spaventa, along with my colleague Maurice Samuels of Harvard
Management. Those, too, were dark days for Italy. Debt was over 100% of GDP,
interest rates over 12%, the global economy was weak, and Professor Rudi
Dornbusch had been making the rounds proclaiming that Italian default was
certain. I asked Professor Spaventa, rhetorically, why Italy was issuing CCT’s and
BTP’s. Was it to fund expenditures, or was it because if the treasury spent the lira,
and did not issue securities, and the Bank of Italy did not sell securities, the
overnight rate would fall to 0? There was a long pause before Professor Spaventa
answered ‘no, rates would only fall to ½% as we pay interest on reserves’
indicating full and sudden understanding that there was no default risk. He then
immediately rose with an attack on IMF conditionality. A great weight had been
lifted. The next week it was announced ‘no extraordinary measures would be taken
- all payments will be met on time” and the debt crisis receded.
Solving that debt crisis was relatively easy, as in fact there was no debt
crisis. Today the situation is both more serious and more complex. The economic
problem is that deficits are too small, while the political understanding is that
deficits are too large. And the consequential ECB funding with conditionality
translates into lower rates and higher unemployment.
I will conclude with very brief word on inflation. Just like the dollar, yen,
and pound, the euro is a simple public monopoly. And any monopolist is
necessarily price setter, not price taker.
Furthermore, a monopolist sets two prices. First is what Marshall called the
‘own rate’ which is how the monopolist’s thing exchanges for itself. For a currency
that is the interest rate set by the CB.
The second is how that thing exchanges for other goods and services. For a
currency we call that the price level. I say it this way - the price level is necessarily
a function of prices paid by the government of issue when it spends, and/or
collateral demanded when it lends.
What this means for the euro zone is that inflation control ultimately comes
down to limiting government spending by limiting selected prices member nations
are allowed to pay when they spend.
Thank you.
Other Recommended Books
Berstein, Peter L.,A Primer on Money, Banking, and Gold, Vintage Books, 1965.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,The Federal Reserve System: Purposes and
Functions, 7th Ed. (The Board 1984).
Cosimano, Thomas F. and John B. Van Huyck,"Dynamic Monetary Control and Interest Rate
Stabilization",Journal of Monetary Economics 23, 1989, pp. 53-63.
Dillard, Dudley, The Economics of John Maynard Keynes, The Theory of a Monetary Economy,
(New York: Prentice-Hall, 1948).
Feige, Edgar L., Robert McGee, "Money Supply Control and Lagged Reserve Accounting",
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 9 (November 1977), pp. 536-551.
Feinman, Joshua N., "Reserve Requirements: History, Current Practice, and Potential Reform",
Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1993, pp. 569-589.
Feinman, Joshua N., "Estimating the Open Market Desk's Daily Reaction Fraction", Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 25, No 2 (May 1993).
Henning, Charles N., Pigott, William, Scott, Robert Haney, Financial Markets and the Economy,
4th Ed., Prentice-Hall, 1984.
Knodell, Jane, "Open Market Operations: Evolution and Significance", Journal of Economic
Issues, (June 1987), pp. 691-699.
Laurent, Robert D., "Lagged Reserve Accounting and the Fed's New Operating Procedure",
Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Midyear 1982, pp. 32-44.
Manypenny, Gerald D. and Bermudez, Michael L., "The Federal Reserve Banks as Fiscal Agents
and Depositories of the United States", Federal Reserve Bulletin, October, 1992.
Mayer, Thomas, Duesenberry, James S., Aliber, Robert Z., Money, Banking, and the Economy,
2nd Ed., W.W. Norton & Company, 1984.
McDonough, William, et al, "Desk Activity for the Open Market Account", Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, Quarterly Review, Spring 1992-93, pp. 109-114.
Meyer, Lawerence H., Editor, "Improving Money Stock Control", Center for the Study of
American Business, (Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff Publishing, 1983).
Mishkin, Frederic S., The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets, 3rd Ed., Harper
Collins, 1992.
Pierce, David A.,"Money Supply Control: Reserves as the Instrument Under Lagged
Accounting”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. XXXI, No. 3 (June 1976) pp. 845-852.
Rosenbaum, Mary Susan, "Contemporaneous Reserve Accounting: The New System and Its
Implications for Monetary Policy", Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta (April
1984), pp. 46-57.
Roth, Howard L., "Federal Reserve Open Market Techniques", Economic Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City (March 1986).
Timberlake, Richard H., "Institutional Evolution of Federal Reserve Hegemony", Cato Journal,
Vol. 5, No. 3 (Winter 1986).
About the Author
What others are saying about Warren Mosler:
“I can say without hesitation that Warren Mosler has had the most profound
impact on our understanding of modern money and government budgets of
anyone I know or know of, including Nobel Prize winners, Central Bank
Directors, Ministers of Finance and full professors at Ivy League
Universities. It is no exaggeration to say that his ideas concerning economic
theory and policy are responsible for the most exciting new paradigm in
economics in the last 30 years - perhaps longer - and he has inspired more
economists to turn their attention to the real world of economic policy than
any other single individual.” DR. MATTHEW FORSTATER, PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS,
UNIVERSITY OF MISSOURI - KANSAS CITY
“Warren is one of the rare individuals who understand money and finance
and how the Treasury and the Fed really work. He receives information from
industry experts from all over the world.” WILLIAM K. BLACK, ASSOCIATE
PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS & LAW, UNIVERSITY OF MISSOURI - KANSAS CITY
-------------------------
Warren Mosler is currently the Present of Valance Co, Inc. located in St.
Croix in the US Virgin Islands, where he resides. Mosler is also Chairman and
majority shareholder of Consulier Engineering (CSLR), President and founder of
Mosler Automotive, which manufactures the MT900 sports car in Riviera Beach,
Florida; Co-Founder and Distinguished Research Associate of The Center for Full
Employment And Price Stability at the University of Missouri in Kansas City;
Senior Associate Fellow, Cambridge Center for Economic and Public Policy,
Downing College, Cambridge, UK; and Associate Fellow, University of Newcastle,
Australia.