CHAPTER 1 - ECO - 2020-21 National Accounts Slides
CHAPTER 1 - ECO - 2020-21 National Accounts Slides
1. Introduction
2. Gross Domestic Product
3. The rate of inflation
4. GDP from a demand perspective
5. GDP at factor cost
6. The GDP by branches of activity
7. The Net Interior Product
8. GDP from an income perspective
9. The current account balance
10. Gross National Disposable Income
11. Gross National Savings
12. The capacity or need for financing
References
4
1. Theory
• Chapters 1 and 2 in Blanchard (2016)
2. Practice
• List of exercises in Campus Virtual
3. Indicators
• Macroeconomic indicators in Campus Virtual
1. Introduction
5
J. Andrés and R. Doménech (2020): “La era de la disrupción digital”. Ed. Deusto.
1. Introduction: GDP pc and life expectancy
J. Andrés and R. Doménech (2020): “La era de la disrupción digital”. Ed. Deusto.
1. Introduction: Consumption and productivity growth
J. Andrés and R. Doménech (2020): “La era de la disrupción digital”. Ed. Deusto.
1. Introduction: convergence
1. Introduction: convergence
2. Gross Domestic Product
15
SOME ISSUES
SUM OF APPLES AND ORANGES: value (not quantity)
Nominal GDP
Sum of final goods produced times their current price
◼ Growth due to quantity
◼ Growth due to prices
- From 1960 to 2019, nominal GDP increased 327 times, while real
GDP increased 9 times and the GDP deflator increased 327/9 =
36.3. In other words, during those 59 years on average, nominal
GDP grew at 9.8%, real GDP at 3.7% and the GDP deflator at
6.1%
- Nominal and real GDP are the same in 2010, because the data
series used is based on 2010 prices. Before 2010, nominal GDP was
growing faster than real GDP, so the GDP deflator was increasing
(there was inflation). From 2009 to 2016, nominal and real GDP
evolved very similarly, meaning that the GDP deflator varied little
or not at all (there was hardly any inflation). In 2017, 2018 and
2019, the deflator rose by 1.4%, 1.1% and 1.6%, respectively (low
inflation). As a result, nominal GDP grew more than real GDP and
the blue line became steeper than the red line.
%)
After the fall in real GDP between 2009 and 2013 associated with the Great
Financial Crisis, real GDP has recovered from 2014 to 2019, but has suffered
a sharp drop of 4.1% year-on-year in 2020:I, which will deepen in 2020:II
due to the effects of Covid-19 (data source: FUNCAS)
3. The inflation rate
We know that…
A B
p p Family expenses on A
CPIt = w A At + w B Bt , wA =
p0 p0 Total expenses
Weights
3. The inflation rate
26
In 2020:I, the GDP deflator remained the same as in 2019 (1.6%). The overall
CPI, which was 0.7% in 2019, has fallen to negative rates (-0.9% in May and -
0.3% in June 2020) basically as a result of the sharp fall in fuel prices. The
underlying CPI, which does not include energy or fresh food prices, has
remained at the same levels as in 2019 (1.1%). (data source: FUNCAS)
Double Counting
Aggregate output can be measured
by the value of final goods produced
Revenues=200 in the economy.
Wages=70
Profit=30
Revenues=100
Intermediate Wages=80
Costs=100 Profit=20
Wages=70
VA2
Profit=30
Revenues=100
Intermediate Wages=80
Costs=100 Profit=20 VA1
Intermediate Wages=80
Costs=100 Profit=20
AGGREGATE OUTPUT
Value of the final goods and services produced
by the economy in a given period.
SUM OF VALUED ADDED
Value added equals the value of a firm´s
production minus the value of the intermediate
goods it uses in production.
SUM OF INCOMES IN THE ECONOMY
Value received by the factors of production for
their participation in the process.
%)
GDPmp + Q ≡ C + G + I + Is + X
Then: Y ≡ GDPmp ≡ C + G + I + Is + (X – Q)
And research?
Types of investment
Components of the demand in GDPmp (millions of euros at current prices) for Spain
(2016-19). Last column: % /GDPmp in 2019 (in parenthesis: anual rates of variation).
2016 2017 2018 2019
FINAL CONSUMPTION 860,543 894,561 924,621 950,525 (76.3%)
(2.4) (4.0) (3.4) (2.8)
Households (C) 648,265 678,229 700,802 717,287 (57.6%)
(2.9) (4.6) (3.3) (2.3)
Public Administrations (G) 212,278 216,332 223,819 233,238 (18.7%)
(1.1) (1.9) (3.5) (4.2)
GFCF (I) 200,048 216,838 233,584 249,259 (20.0%)
(3.1) (8.4) (7.7) (6.7)
INVENTORY INV. (Is) 8,834 8,893 11,365 10,386 (0.9%)
NACIONAL DEMAND (ND) 1,069,425 1,120,292 1,169,570 1,210,170 (97.2%)
(C + G + I + Is) (2.4) (4.8) (4.4) (3.5)
In 2014-2019, real GDP (bars) grew thanks to DN (black line). In contrast, X-Q
(blue line) contributed less because X and Q grew at similar rates. The sharp
fall in GDP in 2020:I was mainly due to the fall in DN (in year-on-year rates, C
fell by 5.7% and I by 6.5%, while G grew by 3.6%). Also X-Q has made a
negative contribution of 0.3% because X has fallen by 6.5%, more than Q
(5.5%). (data source: FUNCAS)
5. GDP at factor cost
36
Example: GDPmp and GDPfc for Spain in 2019 (millions of current euros)
Example: Current account balance, dark blue line (Spain, 2019 in millions of
current euros and percentage of GDPmp)
X Q TB PI SI CAB
434,250 399,089 35,161 2,473 –12,729 24,905
(34.9%) (32.1%) (2.8%) (0.2%) (–1.0%) (2.0%)
Trade balance (X-Q) in light blue bars. (data source: FUNCAS)
10. Gross National Disposable Income
42
GNDI ≡ GDPmp + PI + SI
GDPmp PI SI GNDI
1,245,331 2,473 -12,729 1,235,075
11. Gross National Savings
43
GNS ≡ GNDI - (C + G)
GNDI C G GNS
1,235,075 717,287 233,238 284,550
12. The capacity or need for financing
44
It can be seen that the sum of gross national savings and net capital
transfers received by the Spanish economy (288,622 m. of euros) was
more than enough to finance the total investment made (259,645 m. of
euros). Consequently, the Spanish economy had a financing capacity
given by the difference (28,977 m. of euros, 2.3% of GDPmp),
satisfied by net financial flows to the rest of the world.
It can also be seen that the financing capacity or need of an economy
is equal to the sum of the current account balance (CAB) and the net
capital transfers received from the rest of the world (TRk):
Passing the consumption of the families (C) to the first member of the identity
and subtracting the total tax collection (T) in both members, we have:
Y - T - C ≡ (I + Is) + (G - Td - Ti) + (X - Q)
Adding now in both members the primary income, the secondary income and
the net capital transfers, it remains:
(Y + PI + SI) + TRk – T – C ≡ (I + Is) + (G – T) + (X – Q) + PI + SI) + TRk
We define private sector savings (S) as the magnitude remaining after this
private sector has used the income received during the productive process
(GNDI) to pay direct taxes net of transfers and indirect taxes net of subsidies
(T ≡ Td + Ti) and, in addition, make consumption expenditure (C), that is:
Thus, we obtain the capacity or need for financing of the entire economy as the
sum of the capacities or financing needs of the private sector, [(S + TRk) - (I +
Is)], and the public sector, (T - G).
12. The capacity or need for financing
49
Spain's Financing Capacity (2019) as the sum of the private sector's financing
capacity and the public sector's financing need:
28,977 ≡ [(319,745 + 4,072) – (249,259 + 10,386)] + (198,043 –
233,238)
The more general expression of the Fin. Cap. can be reformulated as:
Let us denote by national savings (NS) the sum of private savings (S) and public
savings (T-G):
NS ≡ S + (T - G).
Thus, this expression indicates that the financing capacity or need of the entire
economy is equal to national savings [NS ≡ S + (T - G)], plus net capital
transfers (TRk), minus the total investment made (I + Is).
A financing capacity (> 0) indicates that the country saves more than it invests.
A financing need (< 0) indicates that the country invests more than it saves. In
Spain (2019) we find:
The following graph presents this breakdown with quarterly data on the
Spanish economy since 2014.
12. The capacity or need for financing
53
12. The capacity or need for financing
54
Y ≡ ND + (X - Q) → X - Q ≡ Y - ND
Therefore, the trade balance, (X - Q), is the difference between GDP and
domestic demand. If GDP is higher (lower) than domestic demand, the trade
balance shows a surplus (deficit). Adding now in both members the primary
income, secondary income and net capital transfers, we find: