Adams Sorekuongyakubu Adama School of Economics University of Cape Coast +233244368026
Adams Sorekuongyakubu Adama School of Economics University of Cape Coast +233244368026
➢Words
➢Functions 𝐐𝐃 = 𝐟 𝐏 𝐨𝐫 𝐐𝐒 = 𝐟 𝐏 𝐐𝐃 = 𝐟(𝐏, 𝐘, 𝐏𝐘 , 𝐇)
➢Linear Equations 𝐐𝐃 = 𝛂 + 𝛃𝐏
➢Tables
➢Graphs
➢Graph of two variables
➢Graphs of a Single Variable
Q P
0 10
5 9
7 8
9 7
11 6
13 5
15 4
17 3
19 2
21 1
Tools of Economic Analysis
Tools of Economic Analysis
Economic Growth Rate (Ghana only)
16
14 14.04600263
12
10
9.149799094 9.292511869
8 7.899740293
7.312525021
6 6.399912419
5.900003953
5.59999999
5.199999984 4.845756132
4 4 4.499999699 4.346819153 3.985865624
3.882704469
2
0
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Economic Behaviour-(Self Interest)
➢Why did you come to lecture today?
➢Why do people go to work?
➢Economists assume that most individuals act as if
they are motivated by self-interest and respond in
predictable ways to changing circumstances.
➢Self-interested simply means that you seek your own
personal gain.
Economic Behaviour-(Self Interest)
Resources
Scarcity
Economic Goods
Is there any such thing as free Lunch?
➢The expression “there’s no such thing as a free lunch”
clarifies the relationship between scarcity and
opportunity cost.
Marginal Thinking
➢Individual decisions are rarely straight-forward and usually
involve weighing of costs and benefits to achieve maximum
results.
➢Economist emphasize marginal thinking when the focus is on
additional or marginal choices.
➢Marginal choices involve the effects of adding or subtracting
from the current situation.
➢Marginal Change: describe small incremental adjustments to an
existing plan of action.
➢Thinking at the margin can be seen as the basic rule of rational
behaviour.
Incentives Matter
Scarcity
Command Economics/Socialism
Command Economies
➢Features:
➢Economic resources are owned by a centrally planned authority
or state ownership.
➢Central planners guide economic activities and answer the three
key questions of the economic problem.
➢Adv.
➢May improve efficiency and fairness in allocation of resources.
➢Disadv.
➢a poorly functioning government can destroy incentives, lead to
corruption, and result in the waste of a society’s resources.
Market economies
➢Features:
➢Private ownership of economic resources or factor of
production.
➢Minimal government intervention.
➢Economic decisions are based on market conditions or
prices.
➢Production is operated primarily for profit gains.
Market economies
➢Adv.
➢Raises the standard of living of people by allowing individuals to
earn income and enjoy life.
➢Profit motives provides an incentive for entrepreneurs to take risks
to organize factor of production.
➢Profit motives leads to innovations in knowledge and information
which further lead to economic development.
➢Disadv.
➢it favours those whose have acquired factors of production are able
to exploit workers.
➢it leads to social and economic inequalities.
Mixed Economies
15 A
B
14
12 C
D
J
9
Q E
5
F
0 1 2 3 4 5 Rice
Cocoa
15 A
B
14
12 C
D
9
Q E
5
F
0 1 2 3 4 5 Rice
The Production Possibilities Frontier/Curve
➢The PPC indicates that the opportunity cost that an
economy faces increases along the PPC.
➢This is because some resources are better suited for the
production of some goods than to the production of other
goods.
➢Why is the PPC not a straight line?
➢This is because the PPC curve tells us about the increasing
opportunity cost that the an economy is faced with.
➢Thus the Principle of Increasing Opportunity Cost applies
with the PPC
The principle of increasing opportunity cost
➢It states that opportunity costs increase the more you
concentrate on an activity. In order to get more of
something, one must give up ever increasing quantities of
something else.
➢Negative Slope and Opportunity Cost: The slope of the PPF
is negative. Because a society’s choices are limited by
available resources and existing technology, when those
resources are fully and efficiently employed, it can
produce more capital goods only by reducing production
of consumer goods.
Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT)
Higher Investment,
Greater Economic Lower Investment, less
Growth Economic Growth
Kg
0 Cg
Cocoa
A’
B’
15 A
B C’
14
12 C
D
D ’
9
Q E E’
5
F F’
0 1 2 3 4 5 Rice
Technological Change & Growth
A
15
B’
14
B
C’
12 C
D D’
9
Q E E’
5
F F’
Rice
0 1 2 3 4 5
Growth, Scarcity, Efficiency and Equity.
➢Substitution Effect
➢Unlimited wants/scarce resources
➢When the price of a good falls, consumers substitute that good for
other goods, which become relatively more expensive.
➢Reverse also holds true
➢Income Effect
➢Money income: is simply the number of Cedis received per period
➢Real income: your income measured in terms of what it can buy.
➢A fall in the price of a good increases consumers’ real income making
consumers more able to purchase goods; for a normal good, the
quantity demanded increases.
Demand Curve
GH₵12
A curve showing the relation
GH₵10
between the price of a good
GH₵7 and the quantity demanded.
GH₵4
GH₵2
0 180 Q
45 100 130 200
Shifts In Demand Versus Movements Along A Demand Curve
B
₵6
₵5 A
Demand
0
75 100 Quantity
A shift (change) in the demand curve
A graphical representation of the effect of changes in other determinants of
demand rather than changes in a commodity’s own price. And these factors are
Consumer’s income
Price of other related commodities
Taste and preference of the consumer
Consumers’ expectation of future prices
Season and weather
Types of Goods Demanded
Complementary goods: Two goods are known as complements goods when they
are jointly consumed or demanded. With complement goods as quantity demand
for one increases, quantity demanded for the other increases as well. A change in
the price of one good affect not only the quantity demanded of that good but also
the quantity demanded of its complement. For example, Car and vehicle are jointly
demanded. Also tennis and racket are jointly demanded. Usually in a demand
equation, the coefficient of the prices of complementary goods carry the same
signs.
Types of Goods Demanded
Substitute goods: Two goods are known as substitute goods if the two goods satisfy
the same or similar needs or desires. With substitutes goods, as the quantity
demanded for one increases, demand for the other decreases. A rise in the price of
one goods increases quantity demanded of the other because it becomes relatively
cheaper to buy than the other. These goods could be close substitutes or perfect
substitutes. Example, Coca Cola and Pepsi are substitute goods. Usually in a
demand equation, the coefficient of the prices of substitutes goods carry different
signs.
Types of Goods Demanded
Normal good refers to any good who quantity demanded changes in the same
direction with a given change in income. That is, as income rises, quantity
demanded rises and vice versa. Example of a normal good is ‘good food’. Usually
in a demand equation, the coefficient of the income variable is positive.
Inferior goods refers to goods for which less is demanded as income rises. They are
inversely related to income. Usually in a demand equation, the coefficient of the
income variable is negative
Types of Goods Demanded
Neutral goods refers to goods whose demand do not change as income change.
Example salt.
Giffen goods refer to goods whose quantity demanded increases as price increases
and vice-versa. Giffen goods have an upward sloping demand curve.
Number of Price of Related
Buyers Goods
Income
Supply?
Shifts in Demand vs. Movement Along the Demand Curve
₵1
D1 D2
75 100
Market vs Individual Demand
15
+
15
= 15
10 10 10
D2
D1 D1
4 5 2 8 6 13
Demand Function
➢The function describes how much of a good will be
purchased at different prices taking into
consideration other determinants of demand.
➢𝐐𝐝𝐱 = 𝐟(𝐏𝐱 , 𝐏𝐲 , 𝐌, 𝐓, 𝐇)
➢𝐐𝐝𝐱 = 𝛂𝟎 + 𝛂𝟏 𝐏𝐱 , +𝛂𝟐 𝐏𝐲 , +𝛂𝟑 𝐌, +𝛂𝟒 𝐓, +𝛂𝟓 𝐇
➢ An economic consultant for Microsoft Corporation
recently provided the firm’s marketing manager with
this estimate of the demand function for the firm’s
product:
➢𝐐𝐝𝐱 = 𝟏𝟐𝟎𝟎 − 𝟑𝐏𝐱 + 𝟒𝐏𝐲 − 𝐌 + 𝟐𝐀 𝐱
Demand Function
➢Where 𝐝
𝐐𝐱 represents the amount consumed of good
X, 𝐏𝐱 is the price of good X, 𝐏𝐲 is the price of good Y, M
is income and 𝐀 𝐱 represents the amount of
advertising spent on good X.
➢Suppose good X sells for GH¢20 per unit, good Y sells
for GH¢15 per unit, the company utilizes 2,000 units
of advertising, and consumer income is GH¢10,000.
How much of good X do consumers purchase? Are
goods X and Y substitutes or complements? Is good X
a normal or inferior good?
Derived demand Competitive
demand
Composite Demand
Derived demand Competitive
demand
Composite Demand
Demand Function
Try Work
Suppose the price of commodity X is GH¢35.00 per unit, the price of good Y is
GH¢25.00 per unit, and the income of the consumer is GH¢8,000.00. How much of
good X will this consumers purchase?
Are goods X and Y substitutes or complements goods?
Is good X a normal or inferior good?
What will be the new quantity demanded if price falls to GH¢35.00
Supply
Quantity
Market Supply Curve
➢It is curve which shows the various quantities of
a commodity which all producers are willing to
produce and sell at different prices at a given
Price Price
period of time.
Supply Supply
Price Supply
6 6
6
5 5
5
16 25 Quantity 36 55 Quantity
20 30 Quantity
Change in Quantity Supplied
➢Movement along the supply curve is
caused by changes in the price of
the commodity when all other
factors are held constant. ₵6 B
➢It is also known as change in
quantity supplied. ₵4 A
➢That change in quantity supplied
occurs as a result of change in price
holding all other factors constant. 100 150
Change in Supplied
➢What happens when to supply all other factors
are not constant?
➢Thus, changes in other determinants of supply
other than price would cause the supply curve to
shift.
➢What are these determinants
Change in Supplied
➢What happens when to supply all other factors
are not constant?
➢Thus, changes in other determinants of supply
other than price would cause the supply curve to
shift.
➢What are these determinants
STATE OF
PRICE OF
TECHNOLOG
RELATED GOODS
Y
SUPPLY PRODUCER
COST OF INPUTS DETERMINANTS EXPECTATIONS
NUMBER OF GOVERNMENT
PRODUCERS POLICY
The supply Function
Equals
Quantity Supplied D
Q
150
(The Walrasian Price Adjustment)
D S
Surplus
PH
Pe
PL
Shortage
S D
Q0 Qe Q2 Q
(The Marshallian Quantity Adjustment)
D S
P1
PS1
Pe
P2
Ps2
S D
Q1 Qe Q2 Q
(IS there a Unique Equilibrium)
We1
P1 E1
S
D
D 0
Q1 Q2
Le2 Le1 L QUANTITY
P
Shift
EFFECTS in Demand
OF Curve
CHANGES IN DEMAND AND
ShiftSUPPLY ON EQUILIBRIUM
in Supply Curve
D1 P S
D S
D
P1
P0
P0
P1
D1
S D S D
Q0 Q1 Q2 Q Q0 Q1 Q2 Q
SIMULTANEOUS INCREASE IN BOTH DEMAND AND SUPPLY
P P S
D1 D1
D S D
P0 P0
P1
D1 D1
S D S D
Q0 Q1 Q Q0 Q1 Q
Simultaneous Increase In Both Demand And Supply
D1 S
P
D
P1
P0
D1
S D
Q0 Q1 Q
Increase In Demand But A Decrease In Supply
P P S
D1 D1
D S D
P1
P1
P0 P0
D1 D1
S D S D
Q0 Q Q1 Q0 Q
Increase In Demand But A Decrease In Supply
D1
P
D S
P1
P0
D1
S D
Q0 Q1 Q
ELASTICITIES
Elasticities
➢If a rock band increases the price it charges for
concert tickets, what impact will that have on
ticket sales?
➢More precisely, will ticket sales fall a little or a
lot?
➢Will the band make more money by lowering the
price or by raising the price?
Elasticities
➢The law of demand establishes that quantity
demanded changes inversely with changes in
price, ceteris paribus.
➢But how much does quantity demanded change?
➢This is very important to understand for many
economic issues.
➢This is what the price elasticity of demand is
designed to answer.
Elasticities
➢Think of price elasticity like an elastic rubber
band.
➢When small price changes greatly affect, or
“stretch,” quantity demanded, the demand is
elastic, much like a very stretchy rubber band.
➢When large price changes can’t “stretch”
demand, however, then demand is inelastic, more
like a very stiff rubber band.
Elasticities
➢The price elasticity of demand measures how responsive
quantity demanded is to a price change.
➢The price elasticity of demand is defined as the
percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the
percentage change in price.
𝐏𝐞𝐫𝐜𝐞𝐧𝐭𝐚𝐠𝐞 𝐜𝐡𝐚𝐧𝐠𝐞 𝐢𝐧 𝐪𝐮𝐚𝐧𝐭𝐢𝐭𝐲 𝐝𝐞𝐦𝐚𝐧𝐝𝐞𝐝
𝐏𝐄𝐃 =
𝐏𝐞𝐫𝐜𝐞𝐧𝐭𝐚𝐠𝐞 𝐜𝐡𝐚𝐧𝐠𝐞 𝐢𝐧 𝐩𝐫𝐢𝐜𝐞
𝚫𝐐 𝐏
𝐨𝐫 𝐏𝐄𝐃 = ×
𝚫𝐏 𝐐
Elasticities
Good A Original New % Change Elasticity
Good B
Price 5 6 20%
Elasticities
➢Inelastic demand when 𝐞𝐩 < 𝟏
➢Fairly elastic when 1< 𝐞𝐩 < ∞
➢Unitary elastic demand when 𝐞𝐩 = 𝟏
➢Perfectly inelastic demand when 𝐞𝐩 =
𝟎
➢Infinitely elastic demand when 𝐞𝐩 = ∞
Graphical Illustration Of Point Elasticity Of Demand
A
P1
𝜟𝑷
P2 B
C
𝜟𝑸
0 Q1 Q2 D’ Q
𝚫𝐏 = 𝐂𝐀; 𝚫𝐐 = 𝐂𝐁, ; 𝐏 = 𝐐𝟏 𝐀; 𝐐 = 𝟎𝐐𝟏
𝚫𝐐 𝐏
𝐛𝐮𝐭 𝐞𝐩 = ×
𝚫𝐏 𝐐
𝐂𝐁 𝐐𝟏 𝐀
⇒ 𝐞𝐩 = ×
𝐂𝐀 𝟎𝐐𝟏
𝐂𝐁
➢The first term in the equation = reciprocal of the
𝐂𝐀
slope of the straight line –DD’
➢Straight line has a constant slope, hence the value of
𝐂𝐁
is the same at any point on the demand curve
𝐂𝐀
𝐐𝟏 𝐀
The second term - thus the price-quantity ratio- are
𝟎𝐐𝟏
𝟎
coordinates of poi (l intercept (D’)- =𝟎
𝟎𝐃′
➢Thus the numerical value of the price-quantity ratios
varies from infinity to zero. The value of 𝐞𝐩 thus depends
on the point on the demand curve
P 𝒆𝒑 = ∞
𝒆𝒑 > 𝟏
𝒆𝒑 = 𝟏
𝒆𝒑 < 𝟏
𝒆𝒑 =0
0 Q
ARC Elasticity
➢Used when price changes are relatively high.
𝐏𝟏 + 𝐏𝟐ൗ
𝚫𝐐 𝟐
𝐞𝐩(𝐚𝐫𝐜) = ×
𝚫𝐏 𝐐𝟏 + 𝐐𝟐ൗ
𝟐
𝚫𝐐 𝐏𝟏 +𝐏𝟐 𝟐
𝐞𝐩(𝐚𝐫𝐜) = × ×
𝚫𝐏 𝟐 𝐐𝟏 +𝐐𝟐
𝚫𝐐 𝐏𝟏 +𝐏𝟐
𝐞𝐩(𝐚𝐫𝐜) = ×
𝚫𝐏 𝐐𝟏 +𝐐𝟐
The arc elasticity measures the average price
elasticity
Demand And Total Revenue
➢Once the market demand for various goods and services
are known, it becomes quite easy to estimate the revenue
that firms are likely to obtain.
➢This is because total consumer spending is equivalent to
total business receipts or revenue from sales.
➢Total consumer spending TCS:
➢𝐓𝐂𝐒 = 𝐏 × 𝐐 = 𝐓𝐑
➢If the market demand is linear the total-revenue curve
will be a curve which initially slopes upwards, reaches a
maximum and then starts declining.
Price Elasticity and Revenue
➢The total revenue can be computed by multiplying
price by the corresponding quantity. E.g 𝐓𝐑𝟏 = 𝐏𝟏 ∗
𝟎𝐐𝟏
➢The Marginal revenue is of particular interest in this
analysis.
➢Marginal Revenue is the change in TR that occurs as a
result of selling an additional unit of the commodity.
➢The slope of the TR curve gives us the MR
TR
𝑻𝑹
P
D 𝒆𝒑 = ∞
P2 A 𝒆𝒑 > 𝟏
P1 B 𝒆𝒑 = 𝟏
P3 C 𝒆𝒑 < 𝟏
D’ 𝒆𝒑 =0
Q2 Q1 Q3 Q
𝑴𝑹
Marginal Revenue
𝐓𝐑 And
= 𝐏𝐐 Price Elasticity
𝐛𝐮𝐭 𝐏 = 𝐟 𝐐
hence 𝐓𝐑 = 𝐏𝐐 = 𝐟 𝐐 𝐐
To get the MR, we differentiate TR using the Product Rule
𝐝𝐓𝐑 𝐝𝐐 𝐝𝐏
=𝐏 +𝐐
𝐝𝐐 𝐝𝐐 𝐝𝐐
𝐝𝐏
𝐌𝐑 = 𝐏 + 𝐐
𝐝𝐐
𝐝𝐐 𝐏
𝐛𝐮𝐭 𝐞𝐩 = − ×
𝐝𝐏 𝐐
𝐐
Multiply both sides by −
𝐏
𝐐 𝐝𝐐 𝐏 𝐐
− 𝐞𝐩 = − × ×−
𝐏 𝐝𝐏 𝐐 𝐏
𝐐 𝐝𝐐
− 𝐞𝐩 =
𝐏 𝐝𝐏
𝐏 𝐝𝐏
Rearranging − =
𝐞𝐩 𝐐 𝐝𝐐
𝐝𝐏
Substituting into MR
𝐝𝐐
𝐝𝐏
𝐌𝐑 = 𝐏 + 𝐐
𝐝𝐐
𝐏
=𝐏−𝐐
𝐞𝐩 𝐐
The two Qs will cancel out
𝐏
𝐌𝐑 = 𝐏 −
𝐞𝐩
𝟏
𝐌𝐑 = 𝐏 𝟏 −
𝐞𝐩
Marginal Revenue And Price Elasticity
We noted that when the demand curve is falling
the TR curve initially rises, reaches a maximum
and then starts declining.
Thus
If 𝐞𝐩 > 𝟏 ⇒ the total revenue curve has a positive
slope- thus is still increasing and has not reached
maximum point
Marginal Revenue And Price Elasticity
If 𝐞𝐩 = 𝟏 ⇒ the TR curve reaches maximum level,
because at this point the slope of MR=0
𝟏
𝑷 > 𝟎 𝐚𝐧𝐝 𝟏 − = 𝟎 ⇒ 𝐌𝐑 = 𝟎
𝐞𝐩
Substitutes No Substitutes
Possibility of Postponement of
Purchase
Income Levels
CROSS ELASTICITY
➢Measures the extent to which Changes in the price of
one commodity is affects the quantity demanded of
another commodity
𝚫𝐐𝐱 𝐏𝐘
➢𝐄𝐱𝐲 = ×
𝚫𝐏𝐘 𝐐𝐗
➢The co-efficient of 𝐄𝐱𝐲 could either be positive or
negative depending on the type of commodity
➢If the two commodities in question are substitute it
would be positive
➢If the two commodities in question are complements
it would be negative
INCOME ELASTICITY
➢The income elasticity of demand is a measure of the
relationship between a relative change in income and
the consequent relative change in quantity
demanded, ceteris paribus.
➢Thus, measures the responsiveness of quantity
demanded to changes in income
𝚫𝐐 𝐌
𝛄= ×
𝚫𝐌 𝐐
INCOME ELASTICITY
If the income elasticity is positive, then the good in
question is a normal good because the change in
income and the change in quantity demanded move
in the same direction.
If the income elasticity is negative, then the good in
question in an inferior good because the change in
income and the change in quantity demanded move
in opposite directions.
Consumer surplus
What is it?
Willingness to pay: the maximum amount that a
buyer will pay for a good.
It measures how much the buyer values the good or
service.
The difference between what you paid, and what you
were willing and able to pay.
Consumer surplus
Buyer Willingness to Pay
James GH₵100
Jerry GH₵80
Winifred GH₵70
Gifty GH₵50
Buyers Price Quantity
Demande
Consumer surplus d
More than GH₵100 More than None
GH₵100
James GH₵81 to GH₵100 1
Jerry GH₵71 to GH₵80 2
Winifred GH₵51 to GH₵70 3
James , Jerry , GH₵50 to less 4
Winifred, Gifty
Price of
Album
Demand
0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of
Albums
Price of
Album
(a) Price = GH₵80
100
James’ consumer surplus (20)
80
70
50
Demand
0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of
Albums
(b) Price = 70
Price of
Album
100
James’ consumer surplus (20)
80
Jerry’s consumer
70 surplus (10)
Total
50 consumer
surplus ($40)
Demand
0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of
Albums
Using Demand Curve to Measure Consumer Surplus
The market demand curve depicts the various
quantities that buyers would be willing and able to
purchase at different prices.
The area below the demand curve and above the
price measures the consumer surplus in the market
The formula for consumer surplus is
given by:
P
P A
0
𝟏
𝐂𝐒 = × 𝐛𝐚𝐬𝐞 × 𝐡𝐞𝐢𝐠𝐡𝐭
𝟐
First In this case
Surplu 𝟏
P1
s
Surplus for B 𝐂𝐒 = × (𝟎 − 𝐐𝟐 ) × (𝐏𝟎 − 𝐏𝟐 )
new 𝟐∗
Additional
ConsumersSurplus 𝐐
P2
𝐂𝐒 = න 𝐟 𝐐 𝐝𝐐 − 𝐏 ∗ 𝐐∗
D 𝟎
0 Q1 Q2 Q
Producer Surplus
➢What is it?
➢The amount a seller is paid, minus the seller’s
cost.
➢It measures the benefit to sellers participating in
a market.
➢Cost: the value of everything a seller must give up
to produce a good.
The Cost of Four Possible Sellers?
Seller Cost
Akpors GH₵900
Akpordoos GH₵800
Kakporgbo GH₵600
Gbokataa GH₵500
Using Supply Curve to Measure Producer Surplus
➢Just as consumer surplus
is related to the demand
curve, producer surplus is
closely related to the
supply curve.
P
Supply
900
800
600
500
Q
1 2 3 4
Using Supply Curve to Measure Producer Surplus
➢The area below the price and above the supply
curve measures the producer surplus in a
market.
900 Total Producer surplus
800
600
500
1 2 3 4
How a Higher Price Raises Producer Surplus
➢As price rises, producer surplus increases for
two reasons:
➢Those already selling the product will receive
additional producer surplus because they are
receiving more for the product than before
➢Since the price is now higher, some new sellers
will enter the market and receive producer
surplus on these additional units of output sold
(b) Producer Surplus at Price P
Price
Additional producer Supply
surplus to initial
producers
D E
P2 F
P1 B
Initial surplus C
Producer surplus
to new producers
A
0 Q1 Q2 Quantity
The formula for Producer surplus is given by:
𝟏
= × 𝐛𝐚𝐬𝐞 × 𝐡𝐞𝐢𝐠𝐡𝐭
𝟐
In this case
𝟏
P𝐒 = × (𝟎 − 𝐐𝟐 ) × (𝐏𝟎 − 𝐏𝟐 )
𝟐
∗
𝐐
𝐏𝐒 = 𝐏 ∗ 𝐐∗ − න 𝐟 𝐐 𝐝𝐐
𝟎
THE INFLUENCE OF GOVERNMENT POLICIES ON
MARKET OUTCOMES
S Price D S
Price D
4 4
3 3
Price
2 Ceiling
2
Shortage
PF
Pe
PC Ceiling
Shortage
D
0 Qs Qe Quantity
Qd
Price controls: Price ceilings
Wasted Resources
People spend money, time and expend effort in
order to deal with the shortages caused by the
price ceiling.
You waste a lot of time looking for a good in case
of shortage, the time has it’s value! You can work
or just rest, do something better than look for a
good you’ can’t find.
Price controls: Price ceilings
Inefficiently Low Quality
Price ceilings often lead to inefficiency in that the
goods being offered are of inefficiently low quality
In case of rent controls, the landlords will not
improve the conditions of the apartments, there is
no incentive since the rental fee is low but the main
reason is that since there is a shortage, people are
willing to rent the apartment as it is, even in bad
condition!
Price controls: price ceilings
Black Markets
A black market is a market in which goods or
services are bought and sold illegally—either
because it is illegal to sell them at all or because
the prices charged are legally prohibited by a
price ceiling.
If someone for example bribes (gives extra
money) to the apartment owners he will get the
apartment, but the honest people that don’t
break the law will never find one this way!
Price Controls: Price Floor
Price Floors: a minimum price buyers are
required to pay for a good. Its a lower limit for
the price.
S Surplus S
Price D Price D
4 4
3 3
Price
2 2 Ceiling
P ST
PT
A
B E
P1
C F
PS
D
D
Q
QT Q1
Before Tax After Change
Tax
Consumer 𝐀+𝐁+𝐄 𝐀 𝐀 − (𝐀 + 𝐁 + 𝐄)
Surplus = −𝐁 − 𝐄
Producer 𝐂+𝐃+𝐅 𝐃 𝐃 − (𝐂 + 𝐃 + 𝐅)
Surplus = −𝐃 − 𝐅
Tax 0 𝐁+𝐂 B+C
Revenue
Total 𝐀+𝐁+𝐄+𝐂+𝐃+𝐅 𝐀+𝐁 (𝐀 + 𝐁 + 𝐂 + 𝐃)
Welfare + 𝐂 + 𝐃 − (𝐀 + 𝐁 + 𝐄 + 𝐂
+ 𝐃 + 𝐅) = − −𝐄 − 𝐅
Elasticity and the Size of the Deadweight Loss
The size of the deadweight loss from a tax, as
well as how the burdens are shared between
buyers and sellers, depends on the price
elasticities of supply and demand.
The less elastic the curves are, the smaller the
deadweight loss.
P ST
S
PT
P1
PS
Q
QT Q1
P
ST
S
PT
P1
PS
D
Q
QT Q1
Elasticitydifferences
Elasticity and the Size of help
can the Deadweight Loss
us understand tax
policy.
Those goods that are heavily taxed often have a
relatively inelastic demand curve in the short run.
This means that the burden falls mainly on the
buyer.
It also means that the deadweight loss to society is
smaller than if the demand curve was more
elastic.
The Welfare Effects of Subsidies
If taxes cause deadweight or welfare losses, do
subsidies create welfare gains?
Think of a subsidy as a negative tax.
The Welfare Effects of Subsidies
If taxes cause deadweight or welfare losses, do
subsidies create welfare gains?
Think of a subsidy as a negative tax.
We see that the subsidy lowers the price to the
buyer and increases the quantity exchanged.
P
S
A S1
Ps
B H
Pe G
Pd C E F
D
D
Qe Q1 Q
With No With Subsidy Impact of
Subsidy Subsidy
Deadweight Zero J
Loss
CONSUMER CHOICE THEORY
Consumer Behaviour
The theory of consumer choice examines how consumers make decisions when
they face trade trade-offs and also how they respond to changes in their
environment.
Consumers are surrounded by a great variety of goods they may want but their
ability to have whatever bundle of these goods is dependent on their financial
resources.
With the limited financial resources, consumers would have to choose the kind of
good among the many alternatives that will bring them the most satisfaction.
Consumer Behaviour
Utility is an abstract and a fundamental measure used in studying consumer
behaviour and consumers’ preferences among a wide variety of goods and services.
It refers to the satisfaction derived from the consumption of a certain quantity of a
product.
The utility a consumer derives from consuming a good determines their
willingness to pay for that good.
Consumer Behaviour
Utility is introspective and subjective. It may differ from consumer to consumer
Utility is quite distinct from ‘satisfaction’
Utility implies the potentiality of a good to satisfy the consumer whereas satisfaction is
actual realization.
Utility induces the consumer to purchase a good whereas satisfaction is the end result
from consuming a good.
Satisfaction, sometimes, may be more or less than the expected satisfaction (utility) a
consumer may perceive to derive from consuming a good.
Consumer Behaviour
Measurement of Utility
The cardinal measurement of utility was propounded by Alfred Marshall and his
followers, known as the cardinalists.
According to the cardinalists, the utility of a commodity can be quantified and thus
measured numerically.
For example, the utility derived from consuming a ball of Kenkey can be measured, say
50 utils.
Assumption of the Cardinal Utility Theory
Rationality of consumers: The cardinalists assume that consumers aim at
maximizing their utility subject to the constraint imposed by their income
Cardinal utility: The cardinalists believe that utility can be measured. The unit of
measurement is utils. Also, they assume that the amount a consumer is willing to
pay for a good reflects the utility the consumer derives.
Assumption of the Cardinal Utility Theory
Constant marginal utility of money: This implies that the satisfaction obtained from
spending more money (income ) is constant. Therefore marginal utility obtained
from spending an additional cedi is constant.
Diminishing marginal utility: This assumption implies that the utility derived from
consuming successive units of a commodity diminishes as the consumer consumes
larger quantity of the commodity.
The total utility a consumer derives depends on the quantity of goods he/she
consumers
Cardinal Utility Concepts
Total Utility (TU): It is the total satisfaction enjoyed from consuming any given
quantity of a good
Mathematically, it can be expressed as the summation of the marginal utility
derived from consuming each unit of the good to the last quantity consumed
TU= σ 𝑴𝑼 or 𝐓𝐔 = 𝒙𝒅𝑼𝑴 or 𝐓𝐔 = 𝑨𝑼 ∗ 𝑸
Cardinal Utility Concepts
Marginal Utility (MU): Refers to the extra satisfaction derived from consuming
additional units of a good
Mathematically, it is the change in the utility
𝑻𝑼
𝐴𝑼 =
𝑸
The relationship between TU,AU and MU (Utility Schedule )
𝑴𝑼𝒙
𝛌= , Thus the utility derived from spending the last cedi should be equal to the
𝑷𝒙
proportion of the MU obtained from the price of the good.
Equilibrium Condition under the behavior
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Graphical representation
P,MU
E
𝜆𝑃𝑥
𝑀𝑈𝑥
0 Qty
Xe
Equilibrium Condition Under the cardinalist’s Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
The consumer will be in equilibrium at the point where
𝑴𝑼𝒙 = 𝝀𝑷𝑿 .
The corresponding quantity consumed is Xe
Equilibrium Condition Under the cardinalist’s Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Effect of a price a change on the equilibrium
P,MU
𝑒1
𝜆𝑃3
𝑒0
𝜆𝑃𝑥
𝑒2
𝜆𝑃2
𝑀𝑈𝑥
0 X1 X X2
Equilibrium Condition Under the cardinalist’s Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Effect of a price a change on the equilibrium
From the diagram the consumer is in equilibrium at point e where
𝑴𝑼𝒙 = 𝝀𝑷𝒙
Assuming price of good X increases from 𝑷𝒙 to 𝑷𝒙𝟏 , then the consumer can no longer be in a
state of equilibrium at point e because 𝑴𝑼𝒙 < 𝝀𝑷𝒙 . To restore equilibrium, the consumer has to
consume less of good X (Less than X units which is X1).
Equilibrium Condition Under the cardinalist’s Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Effect of a price a change on the equilibrium.
Per the law of diminishing marginal utility, the more units consumed, the lesser the
MU and the less units consumed, then higher the MU. Therefore the consumer will
derive a higher MU from consuming less units. Equilibrium will be restored at
point e1.
Assuming price falls to P2
There will be disequilibrium (𝑴𝑼𝒙 < 𝝀𝑷𝒙 ). For equilibrium to be restored, the
consumer has to consume more units of good X
Equilibrium Condition under the Cardinalist's Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Effect of a price a change on the equilibrium
Quantity consumed increases to X2. As more unit good X is being consumed, the
MU derived falls (per the law of diminishing marginal utility) and equilibrium is
restored at point e2.
Derivation of the Demand Curve under the Cardinalist's Approach
The analysis used to explain the effect of a price change on the equilibrium condition is used to
derive the demand curve.
P,MU
𝑒1
𝜆𝑃3
𝑒0
𝜆𝑃𝑥
𝑒2
𝜆𝑃2
𝑀𝑈𝑥
0 X1 X X2
Equi-marginal Utility
In reality, household consume multiple goods concomitantly.
𝑴𝑼𝒙
The equilibrium condition for the single commodity case (𝛌 = )
𝑷𝒙
does not hold
The principles of equi-marginal utility is then adopted to explain how consumers
maximize the utility they derive from consuming each good given their income
constraints and prices of the commodities in question.
Equi-marginal Utility
The principles or law of equi-marginal utility states that consumers will distribute
their income among the goods in such a way that the marginal utility derived from
the last cedi spent on each good is equal
Mathematically
𝑴𝑼𝒙 𝑴𝑼𝒚 𝑴𝑼𝒛
= =……. , Where X to Z are different commodities consumed. For the
𝑷𝒙 𝑷𝒚 𝑷𝒛
sake of easy analysis the principle will be restricted to two goods X and Y
Example, Px=4 Py=3, Income = GHS 34
Quantity
1 22 27 5.5 9
2 20 24 5 8
3 18 21 4.5 7
4 16 18 4 6
5 14 15 3.5 5
6 12 12 3 4
7 10 9 2.5 3
Given the equilibrium condition as
𝑴𝑼𝒙 𝑴𝑼𝒚
= , the consumer has three alternative bundles to choose from two goods.
𝑷𝒙 𝑷𝒚
Nonetheless, the consumer is constrained by his/her income and the price of the
two of goods. The consumer can only consume less or equal to his/her budget
The budget constraint of the consumer is given by
PxX+PyY=Income
Cont’
Alternative 1
The consumer can consume 2 units of good X and 5 units of good Y. The total
expenditure will be 4(2)+3(5)=GHS23.00
GHS23.00<GHS34.00
The consumer’s expenditure is lesser than his/her income
Alternative 2
The consumer can consume 4 units of good X and 6 units of good Y. The total
expenditure will 4(4)+3(6)=GHS34
GHS=34.00=34.00, consumer’s expenditure equal to his/her income
Cont’
Alternative 3
The consumer can consume 6 units of good x and 7 units of good y. The total
expenditure will be 4(6)+3(7)=GHS45
GHS45>GHS34.00
Hence expenditure larger than income
Conclusion
Given the equilibrium condition and the budget constraints of the consumer, this
consumer will choose alternative 3. Thus s/he wull consume 4 units of good x and
6 units of good y. This bundle gives the consumer the maximum utility give his/her
budget constraint
Cont’
Why not Option 1 or 3
The consumer does not choose alternative 1 although it meets the two conditions
because the consumer is rational. S/he has the objective of maximizing his/her
utility. The surplus (money left) can be used to buy more of each good which will
give the consumer a higher utility than what s/he derives from consuming the
bundles in alternative 1.
The consumer does not choose alternative 3 although it give the consumer the
highest level of satisfaction. This is because the consumer is constrained by their
income and so cannot buy the bundle of goods offered in alternative 3
Marginal Utility and the Elasticity of Demand
If, as the quantity consumed of a good increase, marginal utility decreases quickly,
the demand for the good is inelastic.
If, as the quantity consumed of a good increases, MU decreases slowly, the demand
for that good is elastic.
Quantity
Example Px=4 and Py=4.5, Income =GHS34.00
1 22 27 5.5 6
2 20 24 5 5.33
3 18 21 4.5 4.6
4 16 18 4 4
5 14 15 3.5 3.33
6 12 12 3 2.67
7 10 9 2.5 2
THE FIRM
𝑻𝑷
𝑨𝑷 = ,
𝑳
Marginal Product refers to the change in output that arises from an additional unit of
input employed
0 100 - 0 - 100 - -
1 100 100 50 50 150 150 50
2 100 50 80 40 180 90 30
3 100 33.33 100 33.33 200 66.67 20
4 100 25 110 27.50 210 52.50 10
5 100 20 130 26 230 46 20
Sunk Cost refers to cost incurred in the past that cannot be changed by current
decisions and therefore cannot be recovered.
Costs In The Short Run
Long Run Total Cost : In the long run, all factors of production are varied. There is
no fixed input so no fixed costs are incurred. Unlike the short run where total cost
is the summation of the total fixed cost and the total variable cost, the long run
total cost is equal to the long run total variable cost.
The long run average total cost curve shows the lowest unit cost at which the firm
can produce any given level of output.
Costs In The Short Run
The long run average total cost curve
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Economies of scale are cost advantages firms experience or enjoy in the long run in
the form of lower average cost as production increases in the long run.
Production becomes efficient because the cost of production can be spread over a
larger amount of goods.
The factors giving rise to economies of scale are be broadly grouped
internal factors
external factors
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Internal Economies of Scale are factors resulting from the firms’ decisions and
actions. They include:
Technical or technological economies of scale
Managerial economies of scale
Monopsony power
Network economies of scale
Bulk purchasing
External economies of scale are factors that are external to a firm but within the
same industry that bring cost benefit to a firm.
They usually are industry-wide decision and activities external to the firm.
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Examples of external economies of scale include
Infrastructure economies of scale
Specialization and division of labour
Tax incentives
Innovation and research
Access to raw materials from different firms for free or at lesser costs
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Diseconomies of Scale are costs disadvantages that firms experience in the form of
higher average cost as they increase production in the long run.
That is, as production rises, the average cost of production also rises.
Firms become worse off than they were in the short run.
The sources of diseconomies of scale are also group into internal diseconomies of
scale and external diseconomies of scale.
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Internal and External sources of Diseconomies of Scale
Managerial diseconomies
Higher input prices
Marketing diseconomies
Low morale
MARKETS
A market refers to the interaction between firms and buyers to facilitate the
transaction or exchange of goods and services.
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Perfectly Competitive Market also known as Competitive Market or PCM refers
to a market with many buyers and sellers trading identical products so that each
buyer and seller is a price taker.
Features
There are many sellers and many buyers
Homogenous and identical goods
No barriers to entry into or exit from the market
Perfect information between buyers and sellers
Both sellers and buyers are price takers
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Nature of Curves
Because producers are price takers, a firms revenue is proportional to the units of
goods it produces.
Under the PCM, the price of the good is equal to the average revenue as well as the
marginal revenue.
P=AR=MR is a horizontal curve because price is constant
A firm in the PCM maximizes profit by producing the quantity at which its
marginal cost is equal to its marginal revenue.
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Nature of Curves
Mathematically,
𝑻𝑹 = 𝑷 ∗ 𝑸
𝑻𝑹
𝑨𝑹 =
𝑸
𝑷∗𝑸
𝑨𝑹 =
𝑸
𝑨𝑹 = 𝑷
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Nature of Curves
Mathematically,
𝑻𝑹 = 𝑷 ∗ 𝑸
𝒅𝑻𝑹
M𝑹 =
𝒅𝑸
𝒅𝑷𝑸
𝑴𝑹 =
𝒅𝑸
P=MR=AR
0 Qnty
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Demand Curve
However, the market demand is downward sloping.
P=MR=AR
0 Qnty
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Profit Maximization
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Profit Maximizing Condition
Profit is maximized at the point where the MR curve in equal to the MC curve,
that is a necessary condition.
From the Curve, although MR=MC at point D, the firm is encouraged to increase
the output produced. This is because, with the additional goods produced, the
firm’s marginal revenue exceeds its marginal cost until the point E.
Beyond point E, the firm incurs a higher cost more than the revenue it earn from
producing the good. The firm is therefore encouraged to reduce the units of its
output.
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Profit maximizing Condition
This is because when the firm reduces its output, the marginal cost saved will be higher than the
marginal revenue lost
Point E is the profit maximizing point. The firm is encouraged to produce Q units at point E
because that will give it the maximum profit. The firm’s MR=MC.
The profit maximizing output level is produced at the point where the MC=MR but the MC cuts
the MR curve from below
Perfectly Competitive Markets
AR=DD
0
MR
Monopoly: The Price Maker
Profit Maximization of the Monopolist
AR/P/MR
MC
B
P
0 AR=DD
MR
Q
Monopoly: The Price Maker
Profit Maximization of the Monopolist
A monopolist maximizes profits by choosing the quantity at which MR equal MC at
point A
It then uses the demand curve to find the price that will induce consumers to buy
that quantity Point B
The profit of a monopolist is equal the its total revenue minus the total cost
𝝅 = 𝑻𝑹 − 𝑻𝑪
Monopoly: The Price Maker
The Monopolist and Welfare
The monopolist charges a higher price than the price in the perfect competitive
market
The monopolist produces lesser units of a good than the output level in the perfect
competitive market.
The monopolist enjoys a greater producer surplus than producers in the perfect
competitive market
Consumers in the perfect competitive market enjoy greater consumer surplus than
consumers in the monopoly market.
Monopoly: The Price Maker
The Monopolist and Welfare
There is inefficiency in the monopoly market.
Resources are not allocated efficiently.
Consumers are worse off because of the higher price which has been set by the
monopolist and/or the limited units of output produced.
Welfare loss
The surplus of consumers is transferred to the producer
The market welfare loss is indicated by the deadweight loss
Monopoly: The Price Maker
The Monopolist and Welfare