What Is International Trade Theory
What Is International Trade Theory
Although mercantilism is one of the oldest trade theories, it remains part of modern thinking.
Countries such as Japan, China, Singapore, Taiwan, and even Germany still favor exports and
discourage imports through a form of neo-mercantilism in which the countries promote a
combination of protectionist policies and restrictions and domestic-industry subsidies (a hidden
protectionism). Nearly every country, at one point or another, has implemented some form of
protectionist policy to guard key industries in its economy. While export-oriented companies
usually support protectionist policies that favor their industries or firms, other companies and
consumers are hurt by protectionism. Taxpayers pay for government subsidies of select exports
in the form of higher taxes. Import restrictions lead to higher prices for consumers, who pay
more for foreign-made goods or services. Free-trade advocates highlight how free trade benefits
all members of the global community, while mercantilism’s protectionist policies only benefit
select industries, at the expense of both consumers and other companies, within and outside of
the industry. (FTAs - free trade agreements)
Absolute Advantage
In 1776, Adam Smith questioned the leading mercantile theory of the time in The Wealth of
Nations. Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (London:
W. Strahan and T. Cadell, 1776). Recent versions have been edited by scholars and
economists. Smith offered a new trade theory called absolute advantage, which focused on the
ability of a country to produce a good more efficiently than another nation. Smith reasoned that
trade between countries shouldn’t be regulated or restricted by government policy or
intervention (invisible hand). He stated that trade should flow naturally according to market
forces. In a hypothetical two-country world, if Country A could produce a good cheaper or faster
(or both) than Country B, then Country A had the advantage and could focus on specializing on
producing that good. Similarly, if Country B was better at producing another good, it could focus
on specialization as well. By specialization, countries would generate efficiencies, because their
labor force would become more skilled by doing the same tasks. Production would also become
more efficient, because there would be an incentive to create faster and better production
methods to increase the specialization.
Smith’s theory reasoned that with increased efficiencies, people in both countries would benefit
and trade should be encouraged. His theory stated that a nation’s wealth shouldn’t be judged by
how much gold and silver it had but rather by the living standards of its people.
Comparative Advantage
The challenge to the absolute advantage theory was that some countries may be better at
producing both goods and, therefore, have an advantage in many areas. In contrast, another
country may not have any useful absolute advantages. To answer this challenge, David Ricardo,
an English economist, introduced the theory of comparative advantage in 1817. Ricardo
reasoned that even if Country A had the absolute advantage in the production of both products,
specialization and trade could still occur between two countries.
Comparative advantage occurs when a country cannot produce a product more efficiently than
the other country; however, it can produce that product better and more efficiently than it does
other goods. The difference between these two theories is subtle. Comparative advantage focuses
on the relative productivity differences, whereas absolute advantage looks at the absolute
productivity.
Let’s look at a simplified hypothetical example to illustrate the subtle difference between these
principles. Miranda is a Wall Street lawyer who charges $500 per hour for her legal services. It
turns out that Miranda can also type faster than the administrative assistants in her office, who
are paid $40 per hour. Even though Miranda clearly has the absolute advantage in both skill sets,
should she do both jobs? No. For every hour Miranda decides to type instead of do legal work,
she would be giving up $460 in income. Her productivity and income will be highest if she
specializes in the higher-paid legal services and hires the most qualified administrative assistant,
who can type fast, although a little slower than Miranda. By having both Miranda and her
assistant concentrate on their respective tasks, their overall productivity as a team is higher. This
is comparative advantage. A person or a country will specialize in doing what they
do relatively better. In reality, the world economy is more complex and consists of more than
two countries and products. Barriers to trade may exist, and goods must be transported, stored,
and distributed. However, this simplistic example demonstrates the basis of the comparative
advantage theory.
In addition to the four determinants of the diamond, Porter also noted that government and
chance play a part in the national competitiveness of industries. Governments can, by their
actions and policies, increase the competitiveness of firms and occasionally entire industries.
Porter’s theory, along with the other modern, firm-based theories, offers an interesting
interpretation of international trade trends. Nevertheless, they remain relatively new and
minimally tested theories.
As a result, it’s not clear that any one theory is dominant around the world. This section has
sought to highlight the basics of international trade theory to enable you to understand the
realities that face global businesses. In practice, governments and companies use a combination
of these theories to both interpret trends and develop strategy. Just as these theories have evolved
over the past five hundred years, they will continue to change and adapt as new factors impact
international trade.
EXERCISES
1. What is international trade?
2. Summarize the classical, country-based international trade theories. What are the
differences between these theories, and how did the theories evolve?
3. What are the modern, firm-based international trade theories?