The Meiji Restoration
The Meiji Restoration
What
light do they throw on the nature of the Meiji Restoration?
The rule of the Tokugawa Shgunate lasted in Japan from 1603 and 1868.
The Tokugawa Shogunate had come to power in 1603, after a period of
complete feudal anarchy. This period represented an extremely rigid
social structure, isolationist policies and a traditional belief system.
Most policies were geared towards freezing society into a conservative
feudal mould. This attitude probably stemmed from the traditional form
of governance and social norms and maybe an insecurity regarding
power and the Tokugawa hold over it. In many respects Japan before
1868 was similar to China, especially in terms of its insular attitude,
emphasis on indigenous traditions and perception of the west. However
both were to follow very different paths in the coming times, something
in which the Meiji Restoration played a crucial role.
The defeat of the Tokugawa bakufan gave impetus to the demand for the
return of the monarch to actual power and the beginning of ‘Meiji Ishin’
or the Meiji restoration. It is significant that this has been called a
‘restoration’ and not a revolution or a movement. The term ‘Ishin’, in
addition to change connotes renewal and new beginnings of all things.
The rebels did not claim to bring any new concepts but were only
bringing back power to the Emperor – Emperor Meiji. Symbolic of the
aspirations which were to be fulfilled, imperial oracles had proclaimed
that the young emperor’s reign would take the name Meiji, the era of
‘Enlightened Rule’.
The ‘restoration’ of the young emperor Meiji in 1867-68 was a little
more than a coup d’etat. A relatively small band of insurgents had
toppled the Tukugawa bakufu. They stated their intent to restore direct
imperial rule, but this was not likely to occur. Political contenders at
that time feared that the rebels from Satsuma and Choshu would simply
form a new bakufu and use the name of the emperor to rule from a
narrow base of power. If we compare the situation of 1869 in any
aspect – political, economic, social, cultural – to that of just a decade
later, the changes are breathtaking and fully merit the term revolution.
The leaders of the new Meiji government in 1868 were thrilled at the
ease and speed with which they overcame the Tokugawa. The young
Samurais of the Satsum and Choshu clans came to wield power, and in
the process of reconstruction were significantly helped by the
merchants. Propelled by the fear of foreign or domestic resistance and
discontent with the old regime, they generated an ambitious agenda,
through a process of trial and error, aiming to build a new sort of
national power. These Samurai believed in a traditional revival of the
imperial system while a radically new approach with regard to
economy, society and polity would be followed.
The period from the Meiji Restoration till around 1885 can be seen as a
period of transition. Let us now examine the significant changes that the
Meiji Restoration brought about in the areas of society, economy, polity,
military, education etc. in order to promote the ultimate central goal of
promoting industrialization in Japan.
One of the more pressing matters for those who had driven the
Tokugawa Shogunate from power was to create a centralized political
structure that would permit them to exercise authority effectively
throughout the country. Soon after, in 1868 the Constitution known as
the Seitaisho was promulgated, according to which all authority was
vested in the Dajokan or the Grand Council of State. The Dajokan proved
to be a very efficient form of revolutionary government; it wore the
badge of tradition while concentrating all power in the hands of a small
number of men who could implement their policies through their own
ministries.
This system persisted until 1885 when the Meiji leaders inaugurated a
cabinet system moulded explicitly along European lines. At the head of
the government was a Prime Minister. He presided over a cabinet that
ran the bureaucratic agencies – the several ministries – of the Japanese
state. In the early years the ministerial staff was recruited mainly by
personal connections from the rank of Satsuma and Choshu samurai and
their allies. In 1887 it began a system of Civil Service examinations.
From this point on, performance in this examination became the
primary qualification for service in the prestigious ranks of the
ministries of the imperial state.
But the Meiji leaders realized that these reforms were mostly makeshift.
These leaders were willing to create representative political bodies –
probably influenced by their success in the west. The whole Samurai
class had come to be well-educated and wanted a degree of
participation in the government. 1873 onwards, the emergence of
political interest groups and parties demanding people’s rights gained
strength. However, it was not before 1886 that actual work of drafting a
constitution and its supporting legislation got underway.
In 1872 a law was enacted which swept away the prohibition against
the sale in perpetuity in land, the government policy of buying up
common lands, the freedom of occupation and in the choice of crop
testify to the revolutionary victory of the right to private ownership in
land. On July 28, 1873 the Land Tax Reform Law was introduced
designed by Okubo Toshimichi. According to this law, the government
gave certificates of ownership to individuals who farmed specific plots
of land and assigned a monetary value to the holdings. The tax rate was
fixed at 3 percent of the land’s value to be paid annually in cash by the
legal owner. With this system government revenues were stabilized the
Meiji tax receipts were made roughly equivalent to the total land taxes
collected before 1868. The commutation of the land tax into a money tax
collected on a national uniform scale indicates a new tax relationship,
namely the impersonal cash nexus between government and governed
replacing the old irregular tax collected in kind according to the crop.
While standardizing the tax rate brought welcome reductions to some,
at the same time it increased the burdens on others leading to
widespread discontent and opposition. In some regions, recalcitrant
peasants objected violently to plans to dismiss local officials, revise the
taxation system, and conscript an army. In the end the Meiji regime
changed its policy, cutting the land tax by nearly 20 percent in 1877, and
dispatching its police forces to quell protests where necessary.
It is curious that such major and fundamental changes could come about
with minimum violence and resistance. There were a number of reasons
for this. Firstly, the Daimyos who had assisted in the downfall of the
Tokugawas were determined to ensure the success of the regime. And
most Daimyos also realized that resistance would only cause civil strife
which they wanted to avoid. At the same time majority of the Daimyos
were in debt and welcomed the idea of shifting this burden to the
government. Another factor in favour of the new government was that
the payment of stipends was free of any political obligations and as such
served as pensions. This was a comfortable economic settlement which
made the transition easier.
Even before the samurai had been fully dispossessed, the Meiji leaders
decided they had to renovate the military from the bottom up. In April
1871 the government created an imperial guard of just under ten
thousand samurai recruited from the restoration forces. The
conservative military leadership’s ascendancy was however short-lived.
In 1873 the government decreed a system of uniform conscription.
Beginning at the age of twenty, all males were obliged to give three
years of active service and four years on reserve status. Like the French
model, the 1873 decree noted several exemptions, for household heads,
criminals, the physically unfit, students and teachers in many prescribed
schools, and government officials. It also allowed people to buy their
way out for a huge fee of 270 yen. Japan’s army passed its first major
test when it put down a large samurai rebellion in 1877. The navy was
built up in the 1880s and 1890s. By the mid-1890s Japan’s military was
strong enough to move from the task of keeping order at home to that of
imposing its will overseas.
Western ideas had been entering Japan since the time of the Shogunate,
which had sent seven missions to the United States and Europe till
1868. The representatives of the state in these missions investigated the
institutions and cultures of the nations they visited, adding to Japan’s
fund of knowledge about the west and doing much to modify the
popular image of Americans and Europeans as uncivilized barbarians.
The floodgates to western knowledge opened wide in 1868. Within a
decade several hundred Japanese were studying in the United States
and Europe, and an even greater number of foreigners, many in the
employ of the national and prefectural governments, lived in Japan
instructing the Japanese in the finer points of western political
administration, medical practices, legal philosophies, technological
advances, and education systems. Increasingly, international
expositions provided another avenue for learning about the wonders of
the outside world. The recency of western advance suggested that Japan
should be able to bridge the gap between itself and the advanced
nations of the west if the country’s leaders acted wisely and judiciously
to acquire foreign industry, technology and learning.
In the course of appeasing the old classes, the state also created
opportunities for capital investment. Through the 1871 settlement, the
Daimyos gained in monetary terms and were therefore encouraged to
invest in new sectors such as banking and commercial enterprises. The
Daimyos came to become the commercial magnates. In the 1870s, many
Daimyos also took loans from the Chonin against government
guarantee. These loans could be repaid as government bonds. By
encouraging the accumulation of capital in this manner, the government
was encouraging the creation of a class of buyers.
The appeasement of the Samurai was not easy as they had not gotten a
very lucrative economic settlement after their dispossession. The
government decided to take over their debts as well and in addition
small loans were also offered to the Samurai. New areas for cultivation
in Japan were explored such as Hokaido and many Samurai were
encouraged to settle down in these areas. A number of Satsuma Choshu
clans were desirous of getting high positions in the police, army and
bureaucracy and the Daimyos helped them a great deal in this regard.
EH Norman also notes that while the Samurai as a class disappeared
they occupied positions in various sectors, leading to a system seeped in
Samurai ethos.
The monetary system inherited from the Tokugawa period was not
conducive to modernization. Different currencies were issued by local
governments. Depending on the area, the values of commodities were
expressed either in terms of silver or gold. The government needed to
bring uniformity in the monetary system and had to have central
control to facilitate economic growth. The monetary reform of 1871
intended to achieve all these. A uniform standard currency was
established for the country and only the central government had the
right to issue money. The decimal system with a yen as the basic unit
was adopted.
The Bank of Japan was created with the monopoly to issue notes. This
helped in the centralization of capital accumulation. The gold standard
was also adopted. A banking system on American lines was adopted to
provide loans and as many as 100 national banks were set up in the
initial decades of the Meijji regime. Soon it seems the government began
to make direct borrowings from these banks. These banks were
dominated by the already wealthy houses such as Mitsui, Mitsubishi and
Sumitomo. This banking arrangement brought them close to
government interests leading to the forging of a crucial alliance between
the two. The emergence of the future Zaibatsu class can be traced to this
relationship.
Although it was reluctant to use foreign money for these projects, it was
for a time quite anxious to import foreign people as consultants and
managers. At great expense in the 1870s the new government engaged
several thousand ‘hired foreigners’ (oyatoi gaijin) from over twenty
years. This term suggested that the foreigners brought no value beyond
detailed technical expertise. These technicians and experts offered
important advice in a wide range of economic and social endeavours.
They were handsomely paid and most received salaries at the level of
top officials in the Japanese government. Later Japanese students began
to be sent abroad for training and soon the foreign experts were ousted
leading to independence even in the sphere of expertise.
The reason for this sale seems to be that the government now felt the
need to concentrate almost entirely on strategic and military industries.
At the same time by selling these industries to their banking allies, the
government was strengthening its own support base as well. The most
plausible factor leading to this sale, however, seems to be financial.
Inflation and disruption of trade coupled with the sluggish growth of
these industries necessitated urgent fiscal measures, and a sale of the
light industries provided the immediate solution. It should however be
noted that even after the sale government interference was not reduced
and commercial and industrial enterprises continued to run under
government guidance and supervision.
The sale was successful because the initial investment in all these units
had already been made by the government. The state also offered low
tax incentives, subsidies, loans as well as cheap transportation. Initially
the sale was limited to cotton, cement, glass etc, but the few more
successful ventures, primarily coal and metal mines, were sold later in
the decade at more competitive prices.
BIBLIOGRAPHY