Anti Competitive Agreements
Anti Competitive Agreements
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to National Law School of
India Review
I. Introduction
Horizontal Agreements
Vertical Agreements
Relevant Market
Penalties
Leniency
A. General Matters
B. Horizontal Agreements
C. Vertical Agreements
IV. Conclusion
32
I. Introduction
This article focuses on Section 3 of the Competition Act which sets out th
substantive prohibitions on anti-competitive agreements. Part I of this articl
provides an overview of Section 3 of the Competition Act and highlights certa
differences between the provisions of the Competition Act and the competit
regulation framework of the European Union. Part II analyses certain key orde
of the CCI on issues relevant to Section 3 of the Competition Act.
33
Horizontal Agreements
34
Vertical Agreements
The Competition Act sets out two separate standards for assessment of
whether an agreement is anti-competitive: first, it stipulates that certain horizontal
35
Relevant Market
10 § 2(t), Competition Act defines relevant product market as "a market comprising al
those products or services which are regarded as interchangeable or substitutable by
the consumer, by reason of characteristics of the products or services, their prices and
intended use."
11 § 2(t), Competition Act defines relevant geographic market as "a market comprising t
area in which the conditions of competition for supply of goods or provision of service
or demand of goods or services are distinctly homogenous and can be distinguishe
from the conditions prevailing in the neighbouring areeis."
36
products. The factors to be taken into account when determining of the relevant
geographic market include local specification requirements, adequate distribution
facilities, transport costs, and consumer preferences.
Penalties
The CCI has indicated that it will consider any aggravating or mitigating
factors when determining the appropriate level of monetary penalty for
infringement of the Competition Act.12 It has also indicated that it may consider
the establishment of an effective compliance programme as a relevant factor in
determining the quantum of fines.13
The Competition Act does not provide for criminal sanctions for individuals
participating in anti-competitive agreements (including cartels).
Leniency
12 See 1 13.5 of the CCI's decision in Belaire Owner's Association v. DLF Limited and
HUD A, [2011] 104 CLA 398 [Competition Commission of India].
13 See generally , Q.5 in CCI's Advocacy Booklet, Competition Compliance Program for
Enterprises available at http://www.cci.gov.in/images/media/Advocacy/CCP2012.pdf
(Last Accessed on February 20, 2013).
14 Regulation 3(1) of the Leniency regulations state that to obtain the benefit of leniency
under the Leniency Regulations, the applicant must satisfy certain conditions,
including: (a) ceasing further participation in the cartel; (b) providing vital disclosure
in respect of the cartel; (c) fully and continuously cooperating with the CCI and
providing all relevant information as required by it; and (d) not concealing, destroying
or manipulating relevant documents or evidence.
37
A. General Matters
A large number of the CCI's initial orders under Section 3 of the Competition
Act were dismissals of complaints filed with the CCI on the basis that the facts of
such complaints did not constitute a prima facie case under the Competition Act.
Several of such complaints were based upon an incorrect understanding of the scope
of the Competition Act, and included individual commercial disputes, complaints
under the MRTP Act and ordinary consumer complaints. The CCI clarified through
its orders that such matters did not fall within the scope of the Competition Act,
and the complainanťs remedy lay with other regulators.15
While these initial orders did not go far to elucidate the CCI's view of the
substantial prohibitions under Sections 3 and 4 of the Competition Act, they
15 For instance, the CCI dismissed several complaints relating to "unfair terms" of
contracts under § 4 of the Competition Act. § 4 prohibits the abuse of dominant
positions, including by imposition of unfair or discriminatory conditions and prices in
the purchase or sale of goods and services by a dominant enterprise or group. A large
number of complaints filed with the CCI against "unfair terms" of contracts cited no
evidence of dominance of the party imposing such unfair terms.
38
In this regard, the CCI has clarified that it is not empowered to grant damages
for tortious liability for harassment, mental agony and torture.16
Sectoral Overlap
16 M/s Abir Infrastructure Private Limited, v. M/s Emaar MGF Land Limited, 2012
CompLR 13 (CCI) [Competition Commission of India].
17 M/s Royal Energy v. M/s Indian Oil, MRTP Case No. 1/28 (C-97/2009/DGIR), at 1 7.10
at page 16, decided on 9 May, 2012 [Competition Commission of India].
39
In the case of Neeraj Malhotra v. North Delhi Power Ltd. & Ors, 18 a
alleged that the three electricity distribution companies in Delhi were
dominant position by installing meters that ran faster than the legitima
not permitting consumers to install meters of their own choice. Th
alleged that this resulted in foreclosure of markets for meters, cart
among the electricity distribution companies and an unfair and dis
price determination based on faulty meters. The CCI referred to the Delh
Regulatory Commission (the "DERC") for its view in relation to th
of the CCI to examine matters in the complaint. The DERC responde
while the CCI was not the correct forum to decide matters relating to th
tariff under the Electricity Act, 2003 and related legislations, issues
competition could be examined by the CCI. On the basis of the DER
CCI proceeded to deal with the competition issues raised in the com
stated as follows in its final order in the matter: "Sectoral regulators hav
technical expertise to determine access , maintain standard , ensure safety
tariff. They set rule of game i.e. entry conditions, technical details, tariff, sa
and have direct control on prices, quantity and quality. Thus sectoral regul
the dynamics of specific sectors, whereas the CCI has a holistic approach a
functioning of the markets through increasing efficiency through competitio
roles are complementary and to each other and share the objective of obta
benefit for the consumers."19
20 Neeraj Malhotra v. Deustche Post Bank Home Finance Ltd. & Ors., [201
[Competition Commission of India].
21 Id.
40
In the case of Achintya Mukherjee v. Loop Telecom Pvt. Limited & Ors.,23 the CCI
took a more proactive view in suggesting an amendment to the licence agreements
between the DoT and service providers to permit operators to enter into roaming
agreements with more than one operator.
As evident from the orders cited above, the CCI has made clear its intention
so far to remain within the bounds of overseeing the promotion of competition
in India, and not extend its jurisdiction to opine on technical matters under the
domain of sectoral regulators. However, the line between a competition issue and
a technical sectoral matter may not be clear in all cases.
PefinitiQn of "enterprise"
The CCI has generally taken a broad view of the term "enterprise" as defined
in the Competition Act. It has held that public sector commercial undertakings,
statutory bodies performing commercial activities and governmental departments
procuring materials fall within the term "enterprise".24
41
In the case of Jindal Steel & Power Ltd. v. Steel Authority of India Ltd
rejected the contention that Indian Railways was not an enterprise
Competition Act since it performs sovereign functions.26 Instead,
Indian Railways is engaged in the activity of "transport", which is
the definition of "service" in Section 2(u) of the Competition Act and
qualifies as an "enterprise". Further, in the same case, the CCI rejecte
that public policy could be used as a basis to support differential tre
public sector corporation such as Steel Authority of India Ltd.27
B. Horizontal Agreements
Department, Office of the Director, Andhra Pradesh Open School, Andhra Pradesh &
Ors., MANU/CO/0096/2011 [Competition Commission of India]; Jindal Steel & Power
Ltd. v Steel Authority of India Ltd [2012] 107 CLA 278 [Competition Commission of
India].
25 Jindal Steel & Power Ltd. v Steel Authority of India Ltd [2012] 107 CLA 278 [Competition
Commission of India] [Hereinafter, "Jindal Steel Case"].
26 Jindal Steel Case, supra note 24, at 1 42
27 Jindal Steel Case, supra note 24, at Ï 41.
28 Builders Association of India v. Cement Manufacturers' Association & Ors., 2012
CompLR 629 (CCI) [Competition Commission of India] [Hereinafter, "Cement case"].
42
The CCI imposed a fine of an aggregate amount of about Rs. 6300 crores
(approximately US$1 .2 billion at an exchange rate of US$1= Rs. 50) upon the cement
manufacturers in question, which amounted to 50% of their profits for the duration
of the cartel after 2009, when the Competition Act came into effect.
Second, the CCI applied its finding on the broad scope of the term
"agreement" to the circumstantial evidence of "price parallelism" in the cement
market. It held that: "[circumstantial evidence concerning the market and the conduct of
market participants may also establish an anticompetitive agreement and suggest concerted
action. Parallel behaviour in price or sales is indicative of a coordinated behaviour among
participants in a market"31 Specifically, the CCI held that where parallel behaviour
"cannot be explained but for some sort of anticompetitive agreement and action in concerť'32
this would indicate collusion. In the present case, the CCI based its adverse finding
on the records of activities of the CMA and perceived correlation between meetings
of its members and price increases, coupled with the overall low capacity utilisation
by the cement companies.
Third, the CCI has considered the peculiar circumstances of the information
sharing by the parties being carried out on the orders of the Department Of
Industrial Policy and Promotion, the Government of India (the "DIPF'), which
required the collation of certain data by the CMA. The CCI rejected arguments
that since the CMA was mandated to collate such information by the DIPP, and
observed that "[t]he fact that it is being done under the instruction of DIPP does not
absolve CMA or the cement companies engaged in this exercise from running afoul of the
43
provisions of the Act" .33 However, the CCI has not specifically explained
for rejection of such arguments.
Further, the CCI did not adequately explain the quality and rel
the data exchanged using the platform of the CMA. In addition, th
address the argument of the cement companies that the data collect
by the CMA was historical price data, and therefore, its significance
In this regard, the order briefly refers to the fact that the informat
the CMA contained " details of production and dispatch",34 and that t
the meetings of the CMA reveal that the cement companies were " d
price of cemenť'35 to support its finding that the information shar
members was sensitive.
On the whole, the CCI's order in the Cement case, while providing room for
criticism, was significant in its signalling of the CCI's positive intent to deal with
major cartels and its willingness to impose large fines for infringing behaviour.
Trade Associations
The CCI has imposed fines and behavioural directions upon various tra
associations for violations of the Competition Act.36 In the course of its orders,
CCI has found that trade associations could provide a cost-effective and conv
manner of coordinating commercial decisions among competitors.
44
trade associations, for instance where these lead to collective boycott of a single
enterprise.39
C. Vertical Agreements
In the case of Cine Prekshakula Viniyoga Darula Sangh v. Hindustan Coca Cola
Beverages Pvt. Ltd. & Ors,40 the CCI considered whether an exclusive supply
agreement between a cinema operator and Hindustan Coca Cola Beverages Pvt.
Ltd ("HCC") and the practice of specifying a higher maximum retail price for
soft drinks in the cinema constituted an anti-competitive agreement, or abuse of a
dominant position, or both. The CCI disagreed with the DG's finding on the relevant
market as the closed market inside the premises of the multiplexes owned by the
cinema operator. Such an interpretation, in the CCI's view, would lead to every
exclusive supply agreement entered into by any retail outlet, restaurant or store
being anti-competitive. However, while disagreeing with the narrow delineation
of the relevant market by the DG, the CCI did not fully explain its interpretation
of the relevant market in this case. Merely on the basis that the relevant market is
broader than the DG's definition, the CCI found that neither the cinema operator
nor HCC were dominant in the relevant markets. Further, the CCI concluded that
the exclusive supply agreement in question did not clause an appreciable adverse
effect on competition in India on the basis that the term of the agreement was for
a short period of four months, the agreement was terminable by either party by
giving 30 days notice, and therefore the agreement cannot be said to have resulted
in denial of market access to the competitors.
In the case of Jindal Steel & Power Ltd. v Steel Authority of India Ltd,41 Jindal Steel
alleged that the agreement between Indian Railways ("IR") and Steel Authority
of India Ltd ("SAIL") for exclusive supply of rails by SAIL to IR contravened the
Competition Act since it resulted in foreclosure of the market for such rails to new
39 Vijay Gupta v. M/s Paper Merchants Association, Delhi & Ors., MANU/CO/0010/2011
[Competition Commission of India].
40 Cine Prekshakula Viniyoga Darula Sangh v. Hindustan Coca Cola Beverages Pvt. Ltd.
&Ors., MANU/CO/0084/2011 [Competition Commission of India] [Hereinafter, "Coca
Cola case"].
41 Jindal Steel case, supra note 24.
45
entrants. The relevant market in this case was found to be the market fo
long rail steel, compliant with the relevant technical specifications throug
IR was found to be a monopsonist buyer of long rail steel, and SAIL
be the monopolist seller of such steel at the time the agreement was
until Jindal Steel developed capacity to produce such long rail steel.4
46
Tię-jn jirrąngęmęnte
In the case of In Re: IELTS Australia Pty Ltd., IDP Education Pty Ltd., IDP
Education India Pvt. Ltd. and Planet EDU Pvt. Ltd.47 The complainant was engaged
in the provision of counselling services for students desiring to study in Australia,
and alleged that IELTS which conducted the relevant tests for students to study
in Australia, was providing such counselling services free, thereby affecting
competition in the market for provision of counselling services. The CCI made the
following observations in relation to tie-in arrangements under Section 3(4) of the
Competition Act: "In a ' tie-in ' arrangement, as a condition of purchase, a purchaser is
also made to buy some other good. The basic philosophy behind a ' tie-in arrangement' being
treated as violative of competition law is that it harms the consumer as he is forced to buy
a good (the tied one) which he may not necessarily want at the time of purchase of a good
that he actually wants (tying good). So, the consumer may be better off if the products are
sold separately. Another effect of ' tie-in ' is that low quality product may achieve a higher
market share than otherwise it would have on account of rider ship."48 On the facts of the
case, the CCI held that there was no anti-competitive conduct since there was a
benefit arising to consumers and evidence to show an anti-competitive effect had
not been led.49
In certain of its orders, however, the CCI has indicated that for vertical
agreements to have an appreciable adverse effect on competition, both parties to
47 In Re: IELTS Australia Pty Ltd., IDP Education Pty Ltd., IDP Education India Pvt. Ltd.
and Planet EDU Pvt. Ltd., 2011 CompLR 49 (CCI) [Competition Commission of India].
48 Id.
47
the agreement must have some market power. In the case of Autom
Association, Hathras, UP v. Global Automobiles & Ors . and Pooja Expo
Limited,50 the CCI observed as follows: " Normally the competition in the
of production-supply chain may possibly be adversely effected when both
agreement possess some market power in their respective spheres of market T
the reason that in EU vertical agreements are not given much of a thoug
parties possess at least 30 percent market share in respective markets ."51 On
CCI concluded that since the two enterprises involved had "insignificant
the market in which they are operating and are fringe players (...) none of
of causing any AAEC in any of the markets
IV. Conclusion
Within this new framework of law, the CCI has made a significant cont
towards development of awareness of competition law in India, not leas
imposition of substantial fines on parties infringing the Competition Act. It
identified and attempted to address complex issues arising under the C
Act, such as those related to information sharing in the Cement Case.
48
49