Samplepractice Exam 2019 Questions and Answers
Samplepractice Exam 2019 Questions and Answers
Answer the questions on a separate sheet. Your work can be scanned and sent to me, or if
you prefer you can print it and bring to my office hours. This worksheet has 10 question,
for a total of 175 points.
Name:
Location Game 15
Signaling Game 25
Cournot Duopoly 20
Announcing Integers 10
Total: 175
YG Entertainment
D(elay) R(elease)
where D denotes delaying and R denotes releasing the album. ci denotes the cost of delaying for record
label i. This cost is label i’s private information. Assume that ci takes two possible values, 0.25 and 1.25.
The probability that ci = 1.25 is p and therefore the probability that ci = 0.25 is (1 − p). In addition, the
realization of ci is independent across record labels.
(a) 10 Marks How many “types” does each record label have? How many strategies does each record
label have? Substitute in the possible values for ci and represent this interaction as an incomplete
information game.
Solution:
Each record label has two “types” - given by their (independent) draws of ci . This means that each
country’s strategy defines an action for each “type”. Specifically the strategy set Si for each player
i is:
Si = {(D, D), (D, R), (R, D), (R, R)} for i = 1, 2.
So each label has 4 strategies.
(b) 5 Marks If p = 1/2, is there a Bayesian Nash equilibrium in which each label always chooses D,
regardless of its cost ci ?
Solution:
Since the game is completely symmetric we only need to check that the strategy profile (D, D) is
a best response to the other label choosing (D, D) for one label. The expected payoff from the
strategy profile (D, D) for label i when label −i is choosing (D, D) is:
Therefore, for the strategy profile (D, D) to form part of a BNE, it must be true that:
with p = 1/2.
(c) 10 Marks If p is arbitrary, is there a Bayesian Nash equilibrium in which each record label always
chooses D, regardless of its cost ci ?
Solution:
Since the game is completely symmetric we only need to check that the strategy profile (D, D) is
a best response to the other label choosing (D, D) for one country. The expected payoff from the
strategy profile (D, D) for country i when country −i is choosing (D, D) is:
Ei [(D, D)|(D, D)] = −0.25(1 − p)2 + −0.25p(1 − p) + −1.25(1 − p)p + −1.25p2 = −0.25 − p
Therefore, for the strategy profile (D, D) to form part of a BNE, it must be true that:
Ei [(D, R)|(D, D)] = −0.25(1 − p)2 + −0.25p(1 − p) + −2(1 − p)p + −2p2 = −0.25 − 1.75p
Ei [(R, D)|(D, D)] = −2(1 − p)2 + −2p(1 − p) + −1.25(1 − p)p + −1.25p2 = 0.25(3p − 8)
Ei [(R, R)|(D, D)] = −2(1 − p)2 + −2p(1 − p) + −2(1 − p)p + −2p2 = −2
Clearly each of the above inequalities are satisfied for all values of p, therefore if p is arbitrary there
is still a BNE in which each country always chooses D regardless of its cost ci , this is given by:
(a) 5 Marks Given p1 and p2 , compute the location of the consumer who is just indifferent between buying
from each of the two vendors - call this location x?
Solution:
The location of the indifferent consumer, denoted x, is given by the solution to:
or
2
k (1 − x) − kx2 = V2 − V1 + p1 − p2 (rearrange)
k − 2kx = V2 − V1 + p1 − p2 (simplify l.h.s)
2kx − k = V1 − V2 − p1 + p2 (multiplying by -1)
(b) 3 Marks Given your answer in (a), write the demand function and the profit maximization problem
of each firm.
Solution:
Define the demand function for each firm
1 V 1 − V 2 − p1 + p 2
D1 (p1 , p2 ; V1 , V2 ) = x = +
2 2k
and
1 V 2 − V 1 − p2 + p 1
D2 (p1 , p2 ; V1 , V2 ) = 1 − x = +
2 2k
Since production costs are zero, the profits for firm i is simply its revenue pi Di . Hence, in a
Bertrand-Nash price-setting equilibrium, firm 1 chooses p1 , given p2 , so as to maximize:
1 V 1 − V 2 − p 1 + p2
p1 D 1 = p 1 +
2 2k
(c) 6 Marks Solve the maximisation problem to derive the best-response function of each firm. Show the
two best-response functions in a graph that has p1 on the horizontal axis and p2 on the vertical axis
(when plotting the graph assume that V1 = V2 and k = 1).
Solution:
The first order condition for this problem is
∂D1
D 1 + p1 = 0
∂p1
1 V 1 − V 2 − p1 + p 2 1
+ − p1 = 0
2 2k 2k
1 (V1 − V2 ) p2 p1
+ + − = 0
2 2k 2k k
Hence, solving for the best response p1 , yields
1
p1 (p2 ; V1 , V2 ) = [k + (V1 − V2 ) + p2 ]
2
By a similar calculation, we obtain that the best price-response by firm 2 is
1
p2 (p1 ; V1 , V2 ) = [k + (V2 − V1 ) + p1 ] .
2
Inspecting the best-response function p1 (p2 ; V1 , V2 ) , we see firm 1’s chosen price increases by £0.5
for every £1 increase in p2 . Hence in terms of a graph that has p1 and p2 on the horizontal and
vertical axis respectively, the slope of p1 (p2 ; V1 , V2 ) is 2. By the same argument, the slope of
p2 (p2 ; V1 , V2 ) is 1/2. The following graph illustrates the case where k = 1 and V1 = V2 .
p1 (p2 )
2
p2 (p1 )
p2
1
0
0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3
p1
(d) 1 Mark Solve for the Nash equilibrium set of prices given that V1 = V2 .
Solution:
With V1 = V2 the best response functions simplify to
k p2
p1 (p2 ; V1 , V2 ) = +
2 2
k p1
+
p2 (p1 ; V1 , V2 ) =
2 2
and it is easy to see that the unique price equilibrium is the symmetric outcome
p1 = p2 = k.
(a) 2 Marks Suppose that Alex knows he is playing against a “good” coach -
(i.e. P (coach=good) = 1), what price x would the “good” coach offer to Alex?
Solution:
Since the coach is “good”, Alex’s expected value of hiring the coach is given by:
3
Es = · 100 − x
4
If Alex doesn’t hire the coach he will lose the tournament and get a payoff of 0. Therefore Alex
will hire the coach as long as:
3
· 100 − x ≥ 0 ⇒ x ≤ 75
4
The “good” coach prefers to get hired as long as x ≥ 0. Since Alex is willing to pay up to 75 for a
“good” coach, the “good” coach will choose:
x = 75
(b) 5 Marks Suppose now that Alex believes a good or bad coach is equally likely (i.e. P (coach=good) =
1/2). In addition, the coach can only choose between two prices x1 and x2 where x1 > x2 and x1 ≤ 50.
Represent the game using an extensive form representation.
Solution:
[α] [β]
(0, 0) NH NH (0, 0)
1/2
Alex N Alex
Coach
(0, 0) NH t = bad NH (0, 0)
(c) 5 Marks Is there Perfect Bayesian (separating) equilibrium in which both types of coach are hired by
Alex? If yes, state the strategy profile and the associated beliefs. If no, explain why there is not.
Solution:
There are two cases to consider:
• (i) The “good” coach chooses x1 and the “bad” coach chooses x2 .
• (ii) The “good” coach chooses x2 and the “bad” coach chooses x1 .
[α] [β]
(0, 0) NH NH (0, 0)
1/2
Alex N Alex
Coach
(0, 0) NH t = bad NH (0, 0)
Clearly this is not a PBE because the “bad” coach has a profitable deviation - specifically the “bad”
coach would prefer to deviate and choose x1 since x1 > x2 .
[α] [β]
(0, 0) NH NH (0, 0)
1/2
Alex N Alex
Coach
(0, 0) NH t = bad NH (0, 0)
Clearly this is not a PBE because the “good” coach now has a profitable deviation - specifically
the “good” coach would prefer to deviate and choose x1 since x1 > x2 .
Therefore there is not a Perfect Bayesian (separating) equilibrium where both types of coach get
hired by Alex.
(d) 13 Marks Is there Perfect Bayesian (pooling) equilibrium in which both types of coach choose x1 and
are hired by Alex? If yes, state the strategy profile and the associated beliefs. If no, explain why there
is not.
Solution:
The extensive form for this strategy profile is:
(x1 , 75 − x1 ) Coach (x2 , 75 − x2 )
H H
t = good
x1 x2
[α] [β]
(0, 0) NH NH (0, 0)
1/2
Alex N Alex
Coach
(0, 0) NH t = bad NH (0, 0)
Clearly if both types of coach offer x1 and get hired, this is better than offering x2 irrespective of
Alex’s choice at that information set since x1 > x2 and x1 , x2 ≥ 0.
We need to check that when both types of coach offer x1 , hiring the coach is a best response for
Alex. The expected payoff for Alex from hiring the coach is:
Ea [H|x1 ] = α(75 − x1 ) + (1 − α)(25 − x1 ) = 50α + 25 − x1
The expected payoff from not hiring the coach is:
Ea [N H|x1 ] = 0
50α + 25 − x1 ≥ 0
When both types of coach choose x1 Alex’s belief α is (using Bayes’ rule):
1/2
α= = 1/2
1/2 + 1/2
50α + 25 − x1 ≥ 0 = 50(1/2) + 25 − x1 ≥ 0 ⇒ x1 ≤ 50
Which is true by definition. Therefore when both types of coach offer x1 , it is a best response for
Alex to hire the coach.
The last thing we need to check is what happens at the Alex’s other information set. Alex can
either choose H or N H since it will not affect either type of coachs’ choice. However, whatever we
specify for Alex at this information set has to be consistent with his beliefs - β.
If Alex chooses H, the extensive form is:
(x1 , 7.5 − x1 ) Coach (x2 , 7.5 − x2 )
H H
t = good
x1 x2
[1/2] [β]
(0, 0) NH NH (0, 0)
1/2
Alex N Alex
Coach
(0, 0) NH t = bad NH (0, 0)
x2 −2.5
with α = 1/2 and β ≥ 5
If Alex chooses N H, the extensive form is:
[1/2] [β]
(0, 0) NH NH (0, 0)
1/2
Alex N Alex
Coach
(0, 0) NH t = bad NH (0, 0)
In summary, there are two sets of Perfect Bayesian (pooling) equilibria in which both types of coach
choose x1 and are hired by Alex. These are given by:
and
G1 G2
Player 2 Player 2
L C R L C R
T 2, 0 1, 1 4, 2 T 2, 0 1, 1 2, 0
Player 1 M 3, 4 1, 2 2, 3 Player 1 M 3, 4 1, 2 2, 3
B 1, 3 0, 2 3, 0 B 1, 3 0, 2 3, 0
Players move simultaneously. Player 2 knows which game nature has chosen, but player 1 does not. Please
answer the following questions.
(a) 5 Marks What is the strategy space for player 1? What about player 2?
Solution:
Remember that a strategy in a Bayesian game must specify an action for each type. Since player 1
does not know the game that will be played he can only specify one action. Player 2 however, can
specify an action for each realization of nature’s actions. Therefore the strategy sets are:
s1 = {T, M, B}
s2 = {(L, L), (L, C), (L, R), (C, L), (C, C), (C, R), (R, L), (R, C), (R, R)}
Solution:
Once we know the possible strategies for each player we can draw the normal form representation
and solve for the Bayesian Nash equilibrium. The normal form for this problem is:
Player 2
L, L L, C L, R C, L C, C C, R R, L R, C R, R
T 2, 0 1.5, 0.5 2, 0 1.5, 0.5 1, 1 1.5, 0.5 3, 1 2.5, 1.5 3, 1
Player 1 M 3, 4 2, 3 2.5, 3.5 2, 3 1, 2 1.5, 2.5 2.5, 3.5 1.5, 2.5 2, 3
B 1, 3 0.5, 2.5 2, 1.5 0.5, 2.5 0, 2 1.5, 1 2, 1.5 1.5, 1 3, 0
The way the payoffs in the above table are calculated is analogous to the method used in the
problem set. For example, when Player 1’s strategy is T , Player 2’s strategy is (L, L). Player 1’s
(a) 2 Marks Consider only pure strategies. What does it mean if a strategy, s′i , strictly dominates another
strategy, si , for player i?
Solution:
A strategy s′i strictly dominates another strategy si for player i if:
(b) 2 Marks Consider only pure strategies. Does player 1 have a strictly dominated strategy? What
about player 2?
Solution:
Neither player has a pure strategy that is strictly dominated by another pure strategy.
(c) 2 Marks Is there a pure strategy Nash equilibrium in the game above?
Solution:
No there is no NE in pure strategies.
(d) 4 Marks Is there a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium in which player 1 plays a mixed strategy of the
form: σ1 = (p, 1 − p) and player 2 plays a mixed strategy of the form: σ2 = (q, 0, 1 − q)? If there is,
find the values of p ∈ (0, 1) and q ∈ (0, 1) in the equilibrium. If there is not, explain why it is not an
equilibrium.
Solution:
For the above strategy profiles to be a mixed strategy NE the following must be true:
(e) 5 Marks Find all mixed strategies for player 2 that strictly dominate pure strategy M
Solution:
Define σ1 = (T − 1 − T ) and σ2 = (L, M, 1 − L − M ). If player 2 chooses pure strategy M her
expected payoff is:
E2 [M |σ1 ] = 5
Therefore we need to find all mixed strategies σ2 that give a greater expected payoff than 5.
The expected payoff from the mixed strategy σ2 is:
We require that this expected payoff is greater than 5 for all σ1 . This can be verified by setting
T = 0 and T = 1 and checking for dominance in both cases. In addition, it is clear that the mixed
strategy σ2 must assign M < 1 in order to strictly dominate. When T = 0 we have:
1−M 3(1 − M )
<L< and M <1
2 7
strictly dominate pure strategy M .
Player 3
L R
Player 2 Player 2
l r l r
Player 1 T 2, 2, 2 0, 0, 0 T 0, 0, 0 0, 0, 0
B 0, 0, 0 0, 0, 0 B 0, 0, 0 5, 5, 5
Solution:
Player 3
L R
Player 2 Player 2
l r l r
Player 1 T 2, 2, 2 0, 0, 0 T 0, 0, 0 0, 0, 0
B 0, 0, 0 0, 0, 0 B 0, 0, 0 5, 5, 5
Finding the best responses for each player it is clear that there are two Nash equilibria in pure
strategies, these are:
{T, l, L}, {B, l, L}
(b) 3 Marks Assume that Player 1 moves first, then Player 2, and then Player 3. Moreover, all players
observe the choices of their predecessors. Represent this scenario using an extensive form representation.
Solution:
The extensive form representation for this game is shown below:
P1
T B
P2 P2
l r l r
P3 P3 P3 P3
L R L R L R L R
2 0 0 0 0 0 0 5
2 0 0 0 0 0 0 5
2 0 0 0 0 0 0 5
(c) 10 Marks Using the extensive form representation in (b), find all sub-game perfect Nash equilibria.
Solution:
For an equilibrium to be sub-game perfect, requires that each player’s strategy specifies an action
at each information set that leads to a Nash equilibrium in every sub-game. To find such an equi-
librium, we first need to identify all sub-games.
As you can see, there are 7 sub-games in this game, we should start by solving for the Nash-
equilibrium in the sub-games at the bottom of the tree and then begin to work backwards up the
tree. The tree below highlights the best responses for each player in every sub-game (in red)).
P1
T B
P2 P2
l r l r
P3 P3 P3 P3
L R L R L R L R
2 0 0 0 0 0 0 5
2 0 0 0 0 0 0 5
2 0 0 0 0 0 0 5
However there are 4 Nash equilibria that are sub-game perfect, these are:
• (B), (l, r), (L, L, L, R)
• (B), (l, r), (L, L, R, R)
• (B), (l, r), (L, R, L, R)
• (B), (l, r), (L, R, R, R)
P1
R L A
P2
(0, 4)
L′ R′ L′ R′
Solution:
We can draw the normal form representation for this game (below):
Player 2
L′ R′
L −4, 0 2, 2
Player 1 R −2, −2 4, 2
A 0, 4 0, 4
(b) 10 Marks For each Nash equilibria you found in part (a), check if they are also perfect Bayesian
equilibria (PBE).
Solution:
Consider equilibrium {(A), (L′ )}. For Player 2 to play L′ is never optimal (for all possible beliefs p it
is optimal for Player 2 to play R′ . Then this Nash equilibrium is not a perfect Bayesian equilibrium.
Now consider equilibrium {(R), (R′ )}. For Player 2 to play R′ is optimal for all possible beliefs p.
Given that Player 1 plays R, the value of p has to equal 0 (p = 0). Given Player 2’s strategy it is
optimal for Player 1 to play R.
Then the strategy profile {(R), (R′ )} with p = 0 is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium.
P = 27 − 3Q
Both firms have zero marginal cost (MC=0) and face no fixed costs. Only three discrete quantities are
allowed: each firm i chooses:
qi ∈ {1, 2, 3}
(a) 2 Marks Write each firm’s profit function πi as a function of the two quantities, q1 and q2 .
Solution:
πi = (27 − 3qi − 3qj )qi where i, j ∈ {1, 2}, i 6= j
(b) 3 Marks Fill out the normal-form game table for the simultaneous move quantity setting game played
by the two firms.
Solution:
Firm 2
1 2 3
1 21, 21 18, 36 15, 45
Firm 1
2 36, 18 30, 30 24, 36
3 45, 15 36, 24 27, 27
(c) 5 Marks Use the normal-form game table to find the Cournot-Nash equilibria of the game. What are
the quantities produced, price, and profits in each of the equilibria?
Solution:
The Nash equilibrium is:
q1∗ = q2∗ = 3
The price is:
P =9
The profits are:
π1∗ = π2∗ = 27
Now, assume that firms repeat the stage game above infinitely many times (T = ∞) and that both
firms discount their future profits by the same discount factor δ ∈ (0, 1). Given this infinite repetition,
the firms may be able to earn higher profits than in the one-shot game by engaging in collusion. Let δ ∗
be the minimum discount factor that sustains collusion. Please answer the following questions.
(d) 2 Marks How can the two firms increase their profits, π1 , π2 , (relative to the Cournot equilibrium
above) by colluding in the infinitely repeated game? Define explicitly the “grim” trigger strategies that
the firms are required to follow in order to achieve this. (Note: The firms are still able to use only the
three prices listed above).
Solution:
The grim trigger strategy for firm i is given by:
(
q coll = 2 if qi,s = q coll = 2 for all s<t
qi,t =
q N E = 3 otherwise
(e) 6 Marks Determine the range of values for δ such that the collusive outcome is played in every period
of the infinitely repeated game (using the grim trigger strategy from the previous question).
Solution:
The condition is:
Πcoll ≥ Πdev
which is true when:
π coll πN E
≥ π dev + δ
1−δ 1−δ
solving gives:
π dev − π coll
δ≥
π dev − π N E
Which gives:
36 − 30 6
δ≥ = = 0.66
36 − 27 9
(f) 2 Marks Would collusion in this model be possible if the game were repeated a large, but finite number
of times? If yes, what would the firms strategies be? If not, why not?
Solution:
There is a unique NE in the stage game q1∗ = q2∗ = 3 therefore finite repetition cannot induce any
outcome other than NE in every period - Nash folk theorem. Therefore collusion would not be
possible in this case.
(a) 1 Mark What is the set of pure strategies, Si , for each player i = 1, 2? What is the set of all pure
strategy profiles S?
Solution:
The set of pure strategies Si for each player is given by:
Si = [0, 100]
The set of all pure strategy profiles is the cartesian product of the two sets Si of pure strategies
si ∈ Si for i = 1, 2. In this case this is given by the following:
S = S1 × S2 = [0, 100]2
In this case the set of all pure strategy profiles is large so it is more appropriate to write it by
description (instead of enumeration).
(b) 9 Marks Find the solution(s) of this game by using the iterated elimination of strictly dominated
strategies.
Solution:
First notice that if player 1 announces s1 = 51, her payoff is given by:
First round: If player 1 announces s1 < 51 she’ll get s1 irrespective of what Player 2 announces.
Therefore, any strategy smaller than 51 is dominated by 51, Likewise for Player 2. We can then
eliminate all strategies between 0 and 50 for both players.
Second round: If player 1 announces 100 she can get at most 50. This is because Player 2
announces a number between 51-100. Therefore 100 is dominated by 51 in this reduced game.
Likewise for Player 2. We can then eliminate 100 for both players.
Third round: If player 1 announces 99 she can get at most 50. This is because Player 2 announces
a number between 51-99. Therefore 99 is dominated by 51 in this further reduced game. Likewise
for Player 2. We can then eliminate 99 for both players.
etc ....
Fourty-ninth round: If player 1 announces 53 she can get at most 50. This is because Player 2
announces a number between 51-53. Therefore 53 is dominated by 51 in this further reduced game.
Likewise for player 2. We can then eliminate 53 for both players.
Fiftieth round: If player 1 announces 52 she can get at most 50. This is because Player 2 an-
nounces a number between 51-52. Therefore 52 is dominated by 51 in this further reduced game.
Likewise for player 2. We can then eliminate 52 for both players.
Hence, only 51 survives the iterated elimination of strictly dominated strategies for both players.
As a result, the payoff for each player is 50. Formally, the strategy profile for the solution of this
game is given by: s = {51, 51}.
P1
T B
P2 P2
l r l r
P3 P1 P3 P3
L R L R L R L R
1 0 0 4 2 0 0 0
0 0 1 4 1 5 3 4
2 7 0 4 1 0 2 0
Solution:
Imperfect information.
(b) 2 Marks How many information sets does each player have?
Solution:
Player 1 → 2
Player 2 → 2
Player 3 → 2
Solution:
Player 1 → 4
Player 2 → 4
Player 3 → 4
Solution:
In total there are 5 subgames.
(e) 6 Marks What is the sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium (SPNE) in this game?
Solution:
Solve by backward induction starting from subgames at the end of the extensive form.
P1
T B
P2 P2
l r l r
P3 P1 P3 P3
L R L R L R L R
1 0 0 4 2 0 0 0
0 0 1 4 1 5 3 4
2 7 0 4 1 0 2 0