Zhejiang Experience
Zhejiang Experience
Bibliographic data and classifications of all the ERIM reports are also available on the ERIM website:
www.erim.eur.nl
ERASMUS RESEARCH INSTITUTE OF MANAGEMENT
REPORT SERIES
RESEARCH IN MANAGEMENT
I. Introduction
The development of entrepreneurship and a private business sector in China pose various
Economics aims to find evidence that long-term investment and long-term commitment
in and around firms can not be expected without deeply entrenched and state guaranteed
private property rights. On the other hand, empirical studies within the China field
concentrate on the political processes, in particular the interaction between the central
state and local governments, at the danger of neglecting market forces, economic
interests, and economic problems at stake1. The empirical study on which the following is
Firstly, it is assumed that in the course of the economic reforms firms became crucial
between firms as the interaction amongst all firms and their political environment that
Secondly, the official Chinese typology of enterprises will not be used. Instead the
economic concept will be employed which defines ownership and autonomy according to
administration are used only after they could be verified through interviews with
enterprises.
Finally, the empirical study, based mainly on interviews in Zhejiang province in 2000/01,
does not claim validity for its findings beyond the provincial borders. Provincial
politicians, if not lower level (county, village) leaders enjoy considerable discretion in
different forms of implementation. Yet, such differences can also reflect different local
cultures and development trajectories within China. It is for this reason that the research
agenda of which the following is a part aims at a comparative analysis of four or five
provinces3.
competition, and what ultimately turned the province into a success story?” The paper
will proceed as follows. After the description of the political process that accompanied
the development of the private business sector (Section II), some empirical findings will
be presented in the form of “cases” that illustrate the emergence of different forms of
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 3
firms, more specifically, why the family firm disappeared, how collective enterprises (via
management buy-outs) were privatised or corporatised; and how (official) stake holders
Some tentative interpretations of the problems of family firms within the network-
capitalism of China will be offered (Section IV). In the final part (Section V), the
significance of networks will be elaborated. The conclusion will put forward some
general thoughts on the use and importance of the empirical findings presented in this
study.
Zhejiang Province has played a leading role in the privatisation of enterprises since the
early 1980s when the ‘Wenzhou Model’ was first propagated5. Seen in hindsight, the
‘Wenzhou Model’ was an early form of privatisation that was based on capital
managed enterprises. Many respondents during the interviews mentioned that they went
through a ‘Wenzhou phase’ in the 1980s. They associated this with under-capitalisation
and the involvement of underqualified family members in the running of their enterprises.
The first phase of professionalisation for these enterprises began in the late eighties with
the promulgation of the standard regulations for shareholding (gufenzhi guifan tiaoli).
The standard regulations were the first step in enabling enterprises to define property
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 4
rights and separate collective and private enterprise shares. The impact of these
regulations was initially restricted by the economic recession of the years from 1989 to
1991, which reduced business for many small enterprises or forced them to close down.
The standard regulations were a national policy, which according to the interviews, was
participate in this transformation, rather than being enforced across the province as a
compulsory measure. Shares defined by the standard regulations did not constitute legal
titles for the owners. The ratio between private and collective shares allowable under
these regulations was flexible and could lead to de facto privatisation, dependent on the
local authorities. One of the respondents reported that in 1989 he was able to secure an 89
per cent share in a collective enterprise that he had built up in the preceding years.
Nevertheless, this enterprise retained its status as a collective until 1998, when it became
incorporated as a limited liability company and the owner legalised his personal share
while increasing it to 96.6 per cent. Other respondents in comparable situations reported
that they had to wait for years before their local authorities allowed them to formalise
their private shares, irrespective of the fact that their shares in their enterprises were
During the next phase from 1992, enterprises were offered the chance to convert to a
limited liability structure in anticipation of the Company Law which was still under
consideration by the National People’s Congress in Beijing and only came into force in
1994. This anticipation of the Company Law was in effect a further clarification of
ownership structures aimed at separating collective and private shares. According to the
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 5
interviews the registration of shares under this policy did not have a legal basis, but was
implemented by local authorities in preparation for the Company Law. Compliance with
these new policies depended on local authorities, which could determine the number of
enterprises participating as well as the maximum ratio of private shares. Private shares
When the Company Law was promulgated in 1994, provincial and local authorities
collective or state-owned and private shares under the new law happened faster than for
example in Shanghai or Beijing. Respondents reported that local authorities, for example,
without, however, enforcing any strict limits on the volume of private or public shares.
Until the end of the 1990s, enterprises were left to decide how to divide shares between
different forms of owners. While improving property rights, incorporation under the
Company Law did not necessarily lead to privatisation in the sense of guaranteeing a
majority for private shareholders. The enforcement of the incorporation under the
Company Law differed locally. Respondents in one of the localities visited stated that
while their local government supported incorporation, private shares in their locality were
generally not allowed to exceed 35 per cent. Yet, it is noteworthy that with the
implementation of the Company Law, the firm as a legal person became the owner of the
firm’s assets6.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 6
A further move towards privatisation and confirmation of private property rights was
(shenhua gaizhi) for the years 2000 and 2001. This reform aimed at reducing all public
enterprise shares to less than 50 per cent, effectively giving private entrepreneurs a
majority share in local enterprises. At the time of the interviews, the related reforms had
not been concluded. In one locality, they involved a number of smaller enterprises
already operating as quasi private enterprises, although their managers’ shares were still
kept at a maximum of 35 per cent by the local government. All these enterprises had
drawn up transition plans, which generally prescribed a probation period of one year for
the top managers who upon successful completion would gain a majority share in their
enterprise.
The active implementation of the Company Law was only one aspect of the support
extended to private enterprises by local state institutions which guided their transition to
concerned new regulations for the sale of public land introduced in 1999. Public land had
been under the control of local governments or village communities which had used the
sale of land, or more precisely, the sale of long-term usage rights, as a way of
accumulating capital for setting up local enterprises. Collective enterprises with no access
to bank finance often relied on this method exclusively. During the nineties, this became
maximise their cash revenues from land sales at the cost of expanding private enterprises
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 7
in need of new industrial sites. In 1999, a general restriction was introduced when all land
sales by communities had to be conducted through public bidding under the supervision
General legal protection of private enterprises was also improved through protecting
them from corrupt officials. Again, local regulations were issued that threatened officials
repeatedly found enjoying banquets or other invitations by the same enterprises. The
official hold on a firm’s cash flow was better monitored; to redirect cash for financing
In short, while private property rights became officially acknowledged when firms
became legal persons, local authorities honoured property rights even before private
shares became legally binding entitlements. Likewise, local authorities could implement
land and real estate markets by which land, formerly controlled by the state or
The Zhejiang example shows that local administrations can guide and support the
establishment and protection of property rights for private entrepreneurs without the
active corporate involvement of local officials that has given rise to the notion of local
themselves and the way they take up the economic opportunities created in this transition
process.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 8
One unexpected observation in this context was the exclusion of family members from
Zhejiang in particular and China in general would rather have indicated the opposite
enterprises was a common occurrence for many respondents. However, with the
exception of smaller enterprises, such as restaurants, this does not suffice to define these
enterprises as family enterprises. Firstly, in the case of all larger enterprises, capital
contributions by family members were generally not made in the form of long-term
equity capital, but rather on a short-term basis of two to three years and at interest rates of
twice or three times the level of the going bank rate. As a source of enterprise finance,
family members thus offered little advantage over business partners or friends. Another
avenue for family members to become shareholders was through the requirement of the
Company Law of a minimum number of two shareholders. Respondents agreed that these
positions would generally be filled with trustworthy members of the core families who,
however, irrespective of their family status, would only receive minimum shares to
ensure that they remained at arm’s length from enterprise management. In the view of
respondents, the involvement of family members always implied the risk that they might
demand a say in the management of the enterprise on the basis of their capital
The Garden of Manifold Pleasures is one of those new Limited Liability Corporations
whose directors and shareholders feel slightly overwhelmed by their new titles and
authority. In 1984, when Mr. Zhou Weiming and his wife were assigned a building and
some surrounding space by the local street committee in Hangzhou Upper District
(Shangchengqu), they had so little money that it did not even occur to them that they
were dealing with something that might be called capital. The family’s cooking skills
attracted customers and as their restaurant slowly grew, they were able to make some
savings and invest in new equipment. The neighbourhood committee was not much
interested in their commercial dealings as long as the Zhous created employment only for
family members. This changed as Mr. Zhou slowly increased his staff from the original
eight family members to 52 people recruited from the neighbourhood. The committee
now provided more space and received payments from the restaurant. At the end of this
process, Mr. Zhou acted as the owner, claiming net profit, while the neighbourhood
When local policies required that the street committee enterprises be converted into
Limited Liability Companies, Mr. Zhou solved the problem by asking his two sisters to
become silent shareholders. Together they received a share of 30 per cent, while Mr.
Zhou and his wife took a share of 60 per cent, thus fulfilling the requirement that
corporations needed at least two shareholders. Mr. Zhou could have increased his
majority to 70 per cent, but he felt it wise to include the street committee with a ten per
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 10
cent share. He made this offer to the Street Committee in view of its original contribution
in form of land and the building and “in order to keep the good relations going”. Profit is
distributed according to shares, while all major decisions are made by him (and his wife).
Mr. Zhou is concerned about local competitors. They have an impact on his business and
he has to keep an eye on them. Competition forces him to constantly upgrade his
restaurant. He insists on relying on his personal savings for investment. The only instance
when he used bank finance for an investment was when he bought a new Karaoke
equipment. However, the relatively small sum was more than covered by the fixed-term
deposit he kept in the same bank. Mr. Zhou does not think that he could go bankrupt, as
long as the restaurant remains small and does not incur any debt. In the worst case he can
“return to unemployment”. Any expansion would mean to use “outsiders”, i.e. people not
The important point to note here is that it was the Company Law that provided the
Respondents agreed that shareholder positions would generally be filled with trustworthy
members of the core families who, irrespective of their family status, would only receive
minimum shares and no management rights. The formal aspects alone, of family
shareholders, or even a low-level employee, do not fulfil the definite requirements for
classification as family enterprise9. Some respondents explained that they had taken
preventive measures to ensure that family members remained excluded from management
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 11
functions after their retirement. Their justification was that family members were
generally not qualified for management tasks. The collective memory of the many failed
family enterprises that had to be taken over by functioning enterprises during the
recession of 1989 to 1991 in order to maintain employment might have served as a lesson
This indicates a special resource constraint family firms may face. Their ability to expand
beyond the local community is less due to a lack of finances and connections (social
actually preceded the legalisation through the Company Law. Like other forms of
privatisation, they often evolved from an informal contractual basis and subsequently
utilised the Company Law for conversion to private ownership, as the example of Pump
The general manager laid the foundations for Pump Factory Ltd. Soon after 1976 when at
the age of 18 he started work as an apprentice at a small repair workshop for water pumps
in his native village. In 1983 he headed the small collective enterprise, which by that time
had nine workers producing spare parts for pumps. Their annual turn-over was several
thousand Yuan. The small collective entered a boom period when local farming reverted
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 12
to households, and farmers began investing in small individual water pumps to replace
the large village-owned pumps. Demand for these locally produced pumps was so strong
that the workshop kept increasing production even during the recession years after 1989.
Eventually, the village administration decided to liquidate its ownership rights of the
In 1994, in preparation of incorporation under the Company Law, the asset value of the
enterprise was estimated at 20 million Yuan and shares over this amount were offered to
the workforce. The general manager originally intended to acquire a 51 per cent majority,
but for political reasons had to settle for a 49 per cent share. He was required to make an
initial cash payment of 2 million Yuan to the village and allowed to pay the remainder in
instalments from his expected future profit share. His deputy paid in 500,000 Yuan and
further six managers together 800,000 Yuan for smaller individual shares. The remaining
shares were given to the workers and employees of the enterprise. In theory, these shares
were transferable. Yet, as other interviews indicate, they were linked to the jobs and
could even serve as a means to keep demands for pay rises at bay. The local government
invested the proceeds from this buy-out in a new administration and market centre for
Since 2000 political restrictions on maximum individual share have been lifted. The next
planned step in the development of the enterprise is to list the company on the share
The points to note here are that one entrepreneurial manager together with seven
colleagues pooled savings to buy a majority share from a village whose leadership was
obviously more than willing to give up control over their “collective” assets. The trust in
the managerial skill of the buyers and the general prospect of the firm were enough to
allow the manager to claim forty-nine per cent of ownership shares for a sum equivalent
to ten per cent of the registered capital. Even if his and his colleagues’ down payment can
deal offered to him can also be seen as a rent that scarce managerial talent can demand
Once more, privatisation and the acknowledgement of property rights can be shown to be
the outcome of local politics rather than of national legislation. This form of privatisation
depends on social capital and networking between firms and local authorities.
Social capital can instigate entrepreneurial activity that precedes the establishment of
enterprises at a stage when property rights cannot even take effect. This social capital is
generated within networks. The following case illustrates the flexible functioning of
social capital in a network that led to the formation of a private company. In the end, this
network venture included none of the original stakeholders, who had planned and set up
the enterprise.
In the case of the Street Lighting Factory Ltd., the object of privatisation was not a
tangible asset, but rather a business opportunity conceived by the original state-owned
enterprise and the local Bureau of Industry and Commerce. They could have expanded
their own existing structures for this purpose, but instead chose to privatise. For this
among their own ranks who would be able to organise the supply of high-tech
components to China’s most advanced producer of street lighting. For the respondent this
offered a chance to start his own company. Arguably, he faced considerable risk, because
on offer was not a binding supplier’s contract, but simply the reasonable chance to enter a
lucrative market, provided that he could meet challenges of new technologies, quality
control and reliability. There was the chance that by using his old connections with the
state-owned enterprise, he might develop business links with their joint venture partner, a
The respondent decided to face the challenge. As a physics graduate of Shanghai’s Fudan
University in the 1960s, he had had a model career as a technical cadre in his home city’s
industrial administration in Zhejiang. Rising through the technical ranks, he had become
factory director of a local specialised glass factory from 1982 to 1985. From there he had
moved to the local industrial and commercial administration to take charge of general
years. In the seventies, this enterprise had bought semi-finished products from the
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 15
respondent’s factory. In 1993, the state-owned enterprise required for its joint venture a
supplier of mercury vapour street lighting components and contacted local industrial
administrations and the respondent’s former factory in search for an entrepreneur who
would be able to set up a new enterprise to look after this business opportunity. In the
end, the choice fell on the respondent after his local industrial administration and former
The respondent required investment funding of 500,000 Yuan of which 400,000 Yuan
were for equipment and 100,000 Yuan for running costs. He and his deputy, his former
chief engineer from his time as a factory director, contributed 60,000 Yuan each for their
individual shares of together thirteen per cent of the registered capital. Five smaller
investors who were interested in employment with the company acquired another
fourteen per cent. The bulk of sixty per cent came from a local private entrepreneur who
had set up his own electrical goods company in 1988 and who interestingly enough
claimed no position in the management. This ownership structure set up in 1993 has
remained unchanged. With the exception of one, the small investors have left the
company, but retained their shares. In 2000, the company registered as a Limited
Today, the majority investor holds the position of Chairman of the Board of Directors.
The Board discusses and decides all major issues, such as major investments,
technological innovations, daughter companies and large bank loans by voting according
to shares. While this gives crucial powers to the majority shareholder, the operational
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 16
side of the business is the sole responsibility of the respondent who is the general
manager. The distribution of profit is unusual. Sixty per cent are re-invested; out of the
remaining forty per cent the respondent as general manager receives half as his dividend.
This exceeds by far the sum he would be entitled to on the ground of his thirteen per cent
chare of registered capital. Again, this additional benefit needs to be seen as a premium
for product ideas, managerial skills in perceiving business opportunities, and his ability to
turn old contacts into business relations, as the following explanations given during the
During the start-up period the company actually did not receive any orders from the
Shanghai Joint Venture. On an informal, personal basis the management was able to
obtain technical information, which was relayed through a network of contacts of people
who in the past had worked for the Joint Venture and maintained links with its technical
staff. Initially, the new company only managed to sell to smaller domestic clients in
Southern China and to some Middle Eastern countries. By 1995, the quality of their
products had reached a level where the Shanghai-based Joint Venture finally accepted
them as a supplier. From then on, their production expanded rapidly. By 2000, sixty per
Relations with their Shanghai client have now become so close that the company is
investing in new technologies in order to keep pace with technological innovations by the
Shanghai client who provides technical know-how and information required for changes
in products and quality. The joint effort led to new products that are expected to open the
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 17
South Korean market and further export opportunities. In 2000, the company obtained its
first medium-term bank credit, to be paid back within three years, to finance the required
To note here is that this profitable private firm is based on a public-private network that
originated in the former state sector11. The network in this example has a very specific
function in providing input for which there was and still is not yet a market in China.
Such non-tradable resources are not limited to state controlled input, but include venture
capital, technical know-how, managerial talent and potential access to clients (or
reputation).
Furthermore, the case is remarkable for the interplay between the network and the
institution of property rights. While participants of the network used their social capital to
devise the new enterprise, they relied on institutional support, specifically the property
rights provided under the Company Law, to create a spin-off that had its own corporate
A third noteworthy feature is that a group of investors or a network can establish private
property rights by the way of incorporating companies.12 Regardless what the actual
and ownership claims are not disputed, they are able to establish private property rights.
The investiture of the general manager as second major shareholder and major dividend
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 18
recipient once more indicate the extent to which managerial talent and social capital is
The apparent absence of family enterprises on the one hand and the ubiquity of networks
and their obvious ability to take on functions that are generally assumed to be the
functional links and transitions between the two. Before turning to this topic, let us first
take a closer look at the entrepreneurial role of the family in a broader framework.
While the existing literature on the structure of the Chinese firm strongly emphasises the
role of the extended family in the establishment of new firms, as well as at the core of the
private sector in general, the striking empirical result of surveys in Shanxi, Zhejiang and
Jiangsu indicate that the notion of the extended family as the major basis for private
enterprise will not survive extended empirical scrutiny13. This unexpected outcome from
interviews in these provinces justifies a more detailed look at the data and the underlying
variables. The tables below result from surveys in these three provinces.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 19
Total 71 100,0
At first sight, the data set seems to be dominated by firms established and managed by
one individual: the Schumpeterian entrepreneur. The second largest group are firms
established by friends. There is reason to add the category of private investors this group,
as these were also friends or colleagues in most cases. Thus, responses to this general
One could argue that even if family ties were not evident in the establishment of the firm,
they still might serve as a surrogate capital market in that the institution of the extended
family allows to pool savings for one entrepreneurial family member to rely on. It was
therefore specifically asked if the family functions as a source for accumulating the initial
endowment of the firm. As Tab. 2 shows this was the case in only twenty seven per cent
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 20
of the cases. Again friends come in first, in particular in the 1980s and early 1990s when
Tab. 2: Was the family a source of funds for capital assets (i.e. land, plant and
machinery, etc.) when the firm was first set up? (v34)
yes 19 27,1
no 51 72,9
Total 70 100,0
While 47.8 per cent of respondents answered that family connections were not important
for the success of a firm (v 115), the importance of friends is reflected in the next
questions, which asked who the entrepreneur would turn to for support in case of
economic problems.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 21
Banks 36 52.9
Friends 11 16.2
Shareholders 2 2.9
No need 2 2.9
Nobody 2 2.9
Company in same sector 2 2.9
Mother company 2 2.9
Employees 2 2.9
Court 1 1.5
Family (Family members) 1 1.5
Total 68 100,0
Finally, when asked about the general importance of the family for business success, the
following answers shed a striking light on the demise of the (extended) family as an
economic actor. Only five out of forty four agreed (or slightly agreed) with the statement
“Family connections with a wide range of people are crucial to the success of the firm.”
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 22
Tab. 4: Family connections with a wide range of people are crucial to the success of
Total 36 100,0
These empirical findings cannot easily be dismissed and should be seen as a challenge for
further analysis. One obvious question in future studies would ask if the extended family
as an entrepreneurial core has withered away in the People’s Republic of China, and if so,
what caused this development. To claim that this is due to the global modernisation
process and point to the examples of other countries misses the point, as studies on
Overseas Chinese communities have convincingly proved that the Chinese form of loose
ties within the extended family can smoothly adapt to a working market environment14. A
socio-political argument might focus on the effects of the Cultural Revolution that left no
family untouched. If as a general experience a large number of families have been split
on political grounds, a drop in the general level of trust could be expected. Yet, the extent
to which such a drop in the level of trust within families leads to other, substitute forms
indicate, friendship seems to be a close enough surrogate for the extended family. When
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 23
asked to specify friendship links, the respondents named three groups: childhood friends,
friends from the military service and friends from college or university. All three groups
served as the focal point in forming networks. It is worth mentioning that Party
membership might have been appreciated, yet was not a decisive factor in network
formation.
on the resource-base of the family. Even if extended family ties had survived the political
and social changes during the first decades of the People’s Republic, the resource base of
families after thirty years of Communist rule (preceded by decades of civil war) was
certainly low when economic reforms started in the 1980s. The narrow resource base is
not limited to financial capital but includes all forms of human and social capital. Thus,
one of the strengths of the (old) extended family, namely that its access to a large pool of
differing talents, education and personal relations, was lost16. Instead, friendship links
considering that universities and the army have been two of the few broad institutions
outside the Party where people from all parts of the country and different backgrounds
could meet. One of the major problems facing successful firms is how to expand from
local origins into the national market. As the interviews indicate, this was an area where
the reliance on friends who had returned to their home provinces proved much superior to
relying on family members who most probably lived in the closer surrounding.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 24
The comparative advantage of networks built on friendship and common interest will
only work if the internal governance of the network shows similar or lower transaction
costs than the governance of families in regards to acceptance of norms of reciprocity and
could reverse the question and ask if the family should not be seen as a special form of
network built on trust among a predefined group of members, albeit not to the exclusion
of economic reasoning. This would deprive the family of its exclusivity and make it one
network amongst others among which the entrepreneur has to make a choice.
functioning markets and legal process will have been established in the process of further
marketisation. At the firm level the networks show up in the form of shareholding, cross-
shareholding or “holdings”. At the level of industries they manifest themselves (if they do
The establishment of private property rights in China has been an incremental process
persons) as owners of capital assets and from collective rights to the establishment of
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 25
firms that as legal persons own corporate assets. Rather than on national legislation, the
speed of this process depends on local politics, that is, the operation of local networks. It
seems too easy to point to one group, say, Communist Party cadres, the village or
township, the Industrial and Commercial Bureau, let alone the family, as natural partners
in the formation of networks. A more systematic analysis of the background of firms and
Networks are formed and maintained via entry and exit of individuals. They provide
(1) Both private property rights protection and contractual security are generally
collective goods provided by local state agencies in charge of the enforcement of liability
and contractual obligations. Weak state enforcement can be complemented by the internal
Uniquely for China, and in contrast to more generally known cases of patronage
systems21, local state agencies can be part of networks in which they cooperate with other
partners to establish private property rights. In this, they are undoubtedly helped by
national legislation on which they can rely to legally sanction their actions, but the
the first place. The required initiative and active participation by local government
To conclude from this that patronage networks would disappear once national law
enforcement agencies will function better seems premature, however. Most networks do
not limit their ‘range of services’ to protection but also offer access to non-tradeable
input.
The non-tradability of many resources is certainly one of the most severe constraints in
the development of firms and the private business sector. It explains, for example, why
product diversification, but instead expand via investment into unrelated lines of
production. A resource to which a firm happens to have access needs to be put to best
use, whether this use adds up to a business core or not, as costly intra-firm slack is to be
inefficiently used resources amongst its members. By doing so, the network can broker
access too much needed assets, enlarging the resource base of its member firms22.
In this case, too, we may conclude that better functioning markets, i.e. less state
controlled input, will drive out networks. As likely as this is, in particular, if further
marketisation is accompanied by better law enforcement, it does still not imply that
The reason is that non-transferability is not limited to state control. Other hard-to-transfer
inputs include (tacit) knowledge, business routines, and learning; in short activities which
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 27
respond by network formation, for which Silicon Valley is the best-known example.
(3) As the real option approach in capital markets has shown it is worthwhile for
firms to buy an option on assets, such as patents, before relative prices are generated in
markets which then decide on the execution of such an option23. Such “fishing for
opportunity” strategy is what networks do in the case of the private sector in China. Once
profitability of the use of an asset is perceived, but cannot yet be calculated, networks get
an option. By doing so, they create a pool of different options available to different
entrepreneurs or firms. Seen in this light, networks serve as learning platforms that allow
failure of individual firms, as each individual failure helps to improve the calculation of
future outcomes and stabilise expectations. Unlike private firms, networks are able to
exploit these possibilities, as the sunk costs involved in individual failure can be
All in all, these findings cannot come as a surprise to transaction costs economics. The
use of the market in China is still a costly way for allocating resources and investing in
new products or new sectors24. The results of the empirical study suggest that networks
are less costly devices when it comes to better exploiting non-transferable input and
VI. Conclusion
Once in a while it is worthwhile to ask ‘is the fact a fact’, even in a theory-driven field
like economics. This implies that instead of testing existing theories or searching for
data on which new ‘models’ can be built. For example, as for our purpose the State
Empirical research in China needs to generate “raw data” that allow employing the
and quantitative methods developed for analysing such data. Taking into account the time
constraint most empirical research faces, such a procedure implies that the idea of dealing
with large numbers and tools developed for this purpose has to be given up. In other
words, economics has to move away from macroeconomics and econometrics toward
other social sciences where such techniques are well established, like for example
The use of case studies poses another problem. If case studies are to offer more than
anecdotes, they need to be structured along conceptual terms, which allow subsequent
repetition of the research design. The research agenda of which the findings presented
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 29
here form a part distinguishes two periods and two techniques: There is first the pre-
sample period for which the relevant data were gathered through open interviews. For the
sample itself, data are generated with the help of a standardised questionnaire. While the
latter technique is well established in the social sciences, the former is rather new.
The interviews followed a method developed in Stanford for the analysis of the
times and character of all demographic events experienced over the lifetime of the
organization (firms) in the set’26. The sequencing of events matters, as does the definition
In the empirical study introduced above, the events were entrepreneurship, i.e. the
activities that precede the registration of a firm or the beginning of production, ownership
and private property rights, diversification, and expansion beyond the local nexus27.
The findings of the study suggest revising both the conventional view of China, and the
economic actors, too, employ an economic calculus. The quick dismissal of the notion of
the family firm, which is seen as an inferior institution when compared to incorporated
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 30
firms linked by networks, offers one striking example. This is not to say, however, that
culture does not play a role. The ability to establish and maintain networks built on trust,
Moreover, the regional variations (or different ‘cultures’) within China might find their
networks and/or negotiated between firms and political authorities responsible for the
leadership rather than national legislation which determines the pace of implementation.
development, any empirical study faces the problem that on the one hand these variations
reflect different local business practises as remembered or negotiated, and on the other
hand the variations might reflect a different stages in the time path of the reforms.
Whatever the cause in each single case, it is necessary to construct a more specific theory
for transition economies that allows analysing the context in which the economic calculus
dominates choice, and in which economic actors find it more promising to revive and
Finally, the findings suggest that one should beware of falling into the availability trap.
To interpret or re-interpret China’s transition and economic development with the help of
easily available general literature or statistics can be misleading. The opening up of China
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 31
This literature further suggests that analysis based on conceptual terms, i.e. taking China
as a ‘case’, might offer additional and more fruitful insights than adopting the concept of
‘Chineseness’ for an analysis that confirms available information and merely adds
1
Oi and Walder (1999; Parris (1996 S. 1); Solinger (1993, S. 256); Yang (1989, S. 31); Henriot and Lu
(1996); Pearson (1994, p. 25); Wank (1995, p. 55).
2
The financial support by the Royal Dutch Academy of Science and the Trustfonds of the Erasmus
University is gratefully acknowledged, as is the support from the Australia Research Council through a
small grant by the University of New South Wales, Sydney.
3
Krug (2002a), Goodman (1999), Hendrischke (2002).
4
The following is based on Hendrischke (2001).
5
Nolan and Dong (1990), Liu (1992).
6
Company Law, paragraph 2, art. 4.
7
Shleifer and Vishny (1993).
8
Boisot and Child (1999), Fukuyama (1995), Redding (1996a, 1996b), Wong 1985.
9
See also Pistrui. (2001).
10
A point also noted in the family business of Overseas Chinese, see Carney (1998).
11
See also Lin and Zhu (2001), Nee (2000), Ding (2000).
12
Park and Luo (2001), Wank (1996), Tsang (1998).
13
The Shanxi sample of 1999 lists 27 interviews; the Zhejiang sample of 2000 comprises 26 and the
Jiangsu sample of 2001 27 interviews. The data set based on standardised interviews thus includes 80
respondents. Including the open interviews of the preceding years, more then 140 life histories of firms are
available.
14
Hamilton (1996), Kao (1991), Whitley (1995), Yeung (1994), Yoshira (1988).
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS_draft rev 12-09-01_hh.doc 32
15
Cheng and Rosett (1991), Menkhoff (1992).
16
Eastman (1988), Freedman (1970).
17
The best analysis so far is provided by Lever-Tracy. For Chinese firms in Australia, see Lever Tracy
(1996).
18
The best analysis so far is provided by Lever-Tracy. For Chinese firms in Australia, see Lever Tracy
(1996).
19
Luo and Chen (1996), Kao (1993), Tsan (1998), Xin and Pearce (1996), Hendrischke (2002).
20
Coleman (1990), Nooteboom (1996).
21
Gambetta (1993).
22
Krug and Polos 2001. An evolutionary model which will elaborate on the funcitoning of networks will be
presented at the INSEAD conference in Febr. 2002, see Krug and Hendrischke 2002. See also Luo and
Chen 1996.
23
Trigeorgis (1993).
24
Williamson (1994), Qian (2000), Davies, Leung, Luk and Wong (1995).
25
See Caroll and Hannan (2000), chap.5.
26
See Caroll and Hannan (2000), p. 101.
27
Other concepts not dealt with in the present study include trust, reciprocity, private exchange, transaction
costs and networks. See Krug and Belschak (2002 forthcoming).
28
Einfuegen Ordner Uni
29
See references in the reference list for both topics.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS-lit final 12-06-01_hh.docBarbara Krug Page 1
17-12-01
Literature:
Boisot, M.H. and Child, J. (1999): Organisation as Adaptive Systems in Complex environments:
The Case of China, Organisation Science 10,3: 237-252.
Caroll, G.R. and Hannan, M.T. (2000): The Demography of Corporations and Industries,
Princeton.
Cheng, L. and Rosett, A. (1991): Contract with a Chinese Face: Socially Embedded Factors in
the Transformation from Hierarchy to Markets, 1978-1989, Journal of Chinese Law
5,2: 143-244.
Cheung, P.T.Y., Chung, J.H., and Lin Z. (eds) (1998). Provincial Strategies of Economic
Reform in Post-Mao China: Leadership, Politics/ and Implementation. New York and
London.
Chung, J.H. (ed).(1999). Cities in China: Recipies for economic development in the reform era.
London.
Coleman, J.S. (1986): Norms as Social Capital. In: Radnitzky. G. and Bernholz, P. (eds).
Economic Imperialism: The Economic Approach Applied Outside the field of
Economics. New York: Praeger, pp. 133-144.
Davies, H., Leung,T.K., Luk,S. and Wong.Y. (1995): The Benefits of Guanxi: The Value of
Relationships in Developing the Chinese Market, Industrial Marketing Management 24,
pp. 207-214.
Ding, X.L. (2000): The Illicit Asset Stripping of Chinese State Firms, The China Journal 43:1-
29.
Duckett, J. (1998). The Entrepreneurial State in China. London and New York.
Fukuyama, F. (1995): Trust. The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity, London.
Gambetta, D. (1993): The Sicilian Mafia: The Business of Protection, Cambridge, MA.
Goodman, D.S.G. (1999): King Coal and Secretary Hu: Shanxi’s Third Modernization, in: H.
Hendrischke and C. Feng (eds); The Political Economy of China’s Provinces:
Comparative and Competitive Advantage, London, pp. 211-248.
Hendrischke, H. and Feng, C. (eds) (1999). The Political Economy of China’s Provinces:
Comparative and Competitive Advantage, London.
Hendrischke, H., (2002): Eigentumsrechte und Privatisierung in Zhejiang, in: Festschrift Qiao
Wei, Trier (forthcoming).
Hendrischke, H., (2001): Can strong networks make up for weak institutions? Paper presented at
the International Convention of Asian Scholars, Berlin, August 9-12.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS-lit final 12-06-01_hh.docBarbara Krug Page 2
17-12-01
Henriot, Ch. and Lu, Shi (1996): La Réforme des Enterprises en Chine: Les enterprises
shanghaiennes entre État et marché, Paris.
Kao, J. (1993): The worldwide web of Chinese business, Harvard Business Review 71, 2,:24-36.
Krug. B. (2000), Comment to Qian Yingyi, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
156 (1):175-178.
Krug, B. (2002a) The Emergence of Firms with Shanxi Characteristics, Provincial China 8
(forthcoming).
Krug, B. (2002b), The Emergence and Development of the Private Business Sector in China:
The Case of Shanxi, Management International Review (forthcoming).
Krug, B. and Belschalk, F. (2002). Combining Commerce and culture: Establishing Business
Relations in China. (forthcoming).
Krug, B. and Hendrischke, H. (2002) China’s New Private Sector: An evolutionary model,
paper for New Models on Management and New Managers in Asia, INSEAD Euro-
Asia Centre, Fontainebleau, Febr. 8-9.
Krug, B. and Polos, L.(2000). ‘Entrepreneurs, enterprises, and evolution: the case of China.’
Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the International Society for New
Institutional Economics, Tuebingen, September.
Lever- Tracy, C. (1996): Diaspora Capitalism and the Homeland: Australian Chinese networks
into China, Diaspora 5,2, pp. 239-273.
Lin, Yi-min and Zhu, Tian (2001): Ownership Restructuring in Chinese State Industry: an
Analysis of Evidence on Initial Organizational Changes, The China Quarterly 166, pp.
305-341.
Menkhoff, Th. (1992): Xinyong or How to Trust Trust? Chinese non-contractual business
relations and social strcture. Internationales Asienforum 23: 262-288.
Nee, V. (2000): The role of the state in making a market economy, Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics 156,1: 66-88.
Liu, Yia-Ling (1992): Reform From Below: The Private Economy and Local Politics in the rural
Industrialization of Wenzhou. The China Quarterly 130:293-316.
Nolan, P. and Dong Furen (Hrsg.) (1990): Market Forces in China: Competition and Small
Business – The Wenzhou Debate, London.
Nooteboom, B. (1996): Trust, Opportunism and Governance: A Process and Control Model,
Organization Studies 17, 6: 985-1010.
Oi, J.C., and Walder, A.G. (eds) (1999): Property Rights and Economic Reform in China,
Stanford, CA.
Park, S.H. and Luo, Y.D. (2001): Guanxi and Organizational Dynamics: Organizational
Networking in Chinese Firms, Strategic Management Journal 22: 455-477.
Pearson, M.M. (1994): The Janus Face of Business Associations in China: Socialist
Corporatism in Foreign Enterprises, Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, 31: 25-46.
Pistrui, D., Huang, W., Oksoy, D., Jing Zhao and Welsch, H. (2001), “Entrepreneurship in
China: Characteristics, Attributes, and Family Forces Shaping the Emerging Private
Factors,” Family Business Review XIV, 2: 141-158.
Qian, Yingyi. (2000): The Process of China's Market Transition (1978-98): The Evolutionary,
Historical, and Comparative Perspectives, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
Economics 156,1: 151-171.
Redding, S.G. (1996a): The Distinct Nature of Chinese Capitalism, The Pacific Review 9,3:
426-440.
Redding, S.G. (1996b): Weak Organizations and strong linkages: Managerial Ideology and
Chinese Family Business Networks, in: Hamilton, G. (ed) Asian Business Networks,
Berlin and New York, pp. 64-73.
Rozelle, S. and Li, G. (1998): Village leaders and land-right formation in China, American
Economic Review 82(2), pp. 433-438.
Rozelle, S., Park, A., Huang, J. and Xin, H.H. (2000): Bureaucrat to entrepreneur: The changing
role of the state in China’s Grain Economy, Economic Development and Cultural
Change 48(2):227-252.
Solinger,D.J. (1993): Urban Entrepreneurs and the State: The Merger of State and Society, in
Arthur Lewis Rosenbaum, A.L. (ed), State and Society in China: the consequences of
Reform, Boulder, Colorado, pp. 121-41.
Shleifer, A. and Vishny R.W. (1993): Corruption, NBER Working Paper 4372, Cambridge, MA.
Stinchcombe, A. L. (1965) Social Structure of Organization s, in: March, J.G. (ed) Handbook of
Organizations, Chicago, pp. 142-193.
Trigeorgis, L. (1993): Real Options and Interactions with Financial Flexibility. Financial
Management (automn): 202-224.
Tsang, W.K. (1998): Can guanxi be a source of sustained competitive advantage for doing
business in China?, Academy of Management Executive 12: 64-73.
Wank, D.L. (1995): Private Business, Bureaucracy, and Political Alliance in a Chinese City,
Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 33:55-71.
Wank, D.L. (1996): The Institutional Process of Market clientelism: Guanxi and Private
Business in a South China City, The China Quarterly 147 3: 820-838.
Whitley, R. (1995): Eastern Asian Enterprise Structure and Comparative Analysis of Forms of
Business Organisation, in: Gahuri, P.N./Prasad, S.B. (ed) International Management,
London, pp. 191-212.
Williamson, O.E. (1994): The Evolving Science of Organization, Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics 149,1: 36-63
Wong, S.L. (1985): The Chinese family firm: A model, British Journal of Sociology 36: 58-72.
Xin, K.R. and Pearce, J.L. (1996): Guanxi: Connections as Substitutes for Formal Institutional
Support, Academy of Management Journal 39:1641-1658.
C:\ERS files\81 krug\VfS-lit final 12-06-01_hh.docBarbara Krug Page 4
17-12-01
Yang, M.M. (1989): Between State and Society: the Construction of Corporateness in Chinese
Socialist Factories, Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, 22:31- 60.
Yeung W.C.H. (1994): Hong Kong Firms in the Asean region; transnational corporations and
foreign direct investment, Environment and Planning, 26: 1931-1956.
2001
Employee Perception on Commitment Oriented Work Systems: Effects onTrust and Perceived Job Security
Paul Boselie, Martijn Hesselink, Jaap Paauwe & Ton van der Wiele
ERS-2001-02-ORG
The Dutch Banking Chipcard Game: Understanding a Battle between Two Standards
Henk J. de Vries & George W.J. Hendrikse
ERS-2001-18-ORG
Empirical Evidence for the relation between customer satisfaction and business performance?
Ton van der Wiele, Paul Boselie & Martijn Hesselink
ERS-2001-32-ORG
Employee perceptions of HRM and TQM and the effects on satisfaction and intention to leave
Paul Boselie & Ton van der Wiele
ERS-2001-42-ORG
Macro Intentions, Micro Realities: A two-level strategic approach to the single European market
Alan Muller & Rob van Tulder
ERS-2001-70-ORG
The Causality of Supply Relationships: a Comparison between the US, Japan and Europe
Gjalt de Jong & Bart Nooteboom
ERS-2001-73-ORG
China Incorporated: Property Rights, Privatisation, and the Emergence of a Private Business Sector in China
Barbara Krug & Hans Hendrischke
ERS-2001-81-ORG
Entrepreneurship by Alliance
Barbara Krug & Judith Metha
ERS-2001-85-ORG
ii
2000
A Marketing Co-operative as a System of Attributes: A case study of VTN/The Greenery International BV,
Jos Bijman, George Hendrikse & Cees Veerman
ERS-2000-10-ORG
Is Polder-Type Governance Good for You? Laissez-Faire Intervention, Wage Restraint, And Dutch Steel
Hans Schenk
ERS-2000-28-ORG
The Strawberry Growth Underneath the Nettle: The Emergence of Entrepreneurs in China
Barbara Krug & Lászlo Pólós
ERS-2000-34-ORG
iii
Possible futures for the HR function in different market
Roger Williams, Jaap Paauwe & Anne Keegan
ERS-2000-54-ORG
iv