McKeown - Global Migration
McKeown - Global Migration
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
World History Association and University of Hawai'i Press are collaborating with JSTOR to
digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of World History
* I am indebted to suggestions and assistance from Jerry Bentley, Jeffrey Burds, Adam
Kosto, Greg Mann, Patrick Manning, David Northrup, Pablo Piccato, Qiu Liben, Sam Rob
erts, Elizabeth Sinn, Anand Yang, Bin Yang, an anonymous reviewer for the Journal of World
History, and audiences at the World History Center of Northeastern University, June 2002,
the history department at the University of Canterbury in Christchurch, New Zealand, July
2002, and the World History Association Conference in Seoul, Korea, August 2002. All
remaining errors and poor conceptualizations are solely the result of my own obstinacy in
the face of good advice.
155
ing from the Russian steppes to Siberia and Manchuria, and a region
centered on Southeast Asia but extending across the rims of the Indian
Ocean and the South Pacific. The majority of migrants to each desti
nation also came from similar origins, although the column of "auxil
iary origins" shows migrant flows from other places.
These classifications are intended to suggest the larger trends and
broad comparability of long distance migration around the globe.
Nonetheless, the table is highly selective. It does not account for much
migration through Africa, western Asia, or within each of the sending
and receiving regions. Much of this was short-distance or overland
migration for which statistics are not always readily available (although
some flows, such as those from Europe to North Africa, are well docu
mented), and will be discussed in the next section.
The transatlantic migrations to the Americas are the best known
of these migrations. Over 65 percent of these migrants went to the
United States, with the bulk of the remainder divided between
Canada, Argentina (which had the largest proportion of foreign-born
residents), Brazil, and, to a lesser extent, Cuba. Over half of the emi
gration before the 1870s was from the British Isles, with much of the
remainder from northwestern Europe. As migration increased along
with new transportation technologies in the 1880s, regions of intensive
emigration spread south and east as far as Portugal, Russia, and Syria.
Up to 2.5 million migrants from South and East Asia also traveled to
the Americas, mostly to the frontiers of western North America or the
plantations of the Caribbean, Peru, and Brazil. Half of this migration
took place before 1885, after which the decline of indentured labor
recruitment and the rise of anti-Asian immigration laws began to take
effect.
Migration to Southeast Asia and lands around the Indian Ocean
and South Pacific consisted of over 29 million Indians and over 19 mil
lion Chinese. Most migration from India was to colonies throughout
the British empire. Less than 10 percent of this migration was inden
tured, although much of it was undertaken with assistance from colo
nial authorities, or under some form of debt obligation under kangani
labor recruitment systems.1 Over 2 million Indians also migrated as
merchants or other travelers not intending to work as laborers.2 Migra
may have been included under immigration categories such as "other than laborers." See
also Markovits, The Global World of Indian Merchants, 1750-1947 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cam
bridge University Press, 2000), p. 17; and Kernial Singh Sandhu, Indians in Malaya: Some
Aspects of Their Immigration and Settlement (1786-195-/) (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge Uni
versity Press, 1969), pp. 373-380.
3 Robert H. G. Lee, The Manchurian Frontier in CWing History (Cambridge, Mass.: Har
vard University Press, 1970); Donald Treadgold, The Great Siberian Migration: Government
and Peasant in Resettlement from Emancipation to the First World War (Princeton, N.J.: Prince
ton University Press, 1957).
Receiving
Americas 59 325 1.72
North Asia 22 104 1.57
Southeast Asia 42 177 1.45
Sending
Europe 265 515 0.67
South Asia 230 445 0.66
China 420 520 0.21
Africa 81 205 0.93
World 1200 2500 0.74
Sources: Colin McEvedy and Richard Jones, Atlas of World Population History (L
Penguin, 1978).
send hardly any at all. Nonetheless, average emigration rates from dif
ferent sending regions are broadly comparable. At first glance 19 mil
lion overseas emigrants from China or 29 million from India seems
like a drop in the bucket compared to the several millions from much
smaller countries like Italy, Norway, Ireland, and England. But if we
look at regions of comparable size, the rates are very similar. Some of
the peak emigration rates ever recorded were an annual average of 22
emigrants per 1,000 population in Ireland during the famine of 1845 to
1855, or 18 per 1,000 from Iceland in the 1880s.4 Some South Pacific
and Caribbean islands probably experienced similar rates. More typi
cal rates in periods of high overseas emigration are 10.8 per 1,000 from
Italy, 8.3 per 1,000 from Norway, and 7 per 1,000 from Ireland in the
first decade of the twentieth century.5 In comparison, the average
annual overseas emigration rate from Guangdong province in south
China, which had an area slightly larger and a population slightly
smaller than Italy, was at least 9.6 per 1,000 in the peak years of the
1920s. Hebei and Shandong provinces (sources of migration to
Manchuria) had a rate of 10 per 1,000 during that same decade.6
Other Flows
7 Dirk Hoerder, Cultures in Contact: World Migrations in the Second Millennium (Dur
ham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 2002), pp. 217, 355-356; Daniel Johnson and Rex
Campbell, Black Migration in America: A Social Demography (Durham, N.C.: Duke Univer
sity Press, 1981 ); Jean Meyer, "Les migrations mexicaines vers les Etats-Unis au Xx?me si?
cle," in Les Migrations Internationales: De la fin du XVll??me si?cle ? nos jours, ?d. CIDMSS
(Paris: Editions du CNS, 1980), pp. 681-696; Bruno Ramirez, Crossing the 49th Parallel:
Migration from Canada to the United States, 1900-1930 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press, 2001).
8 Orlando Patterson, "Migration in Caribbean Societies: Socioeconomic and Symbolic
Resource," in Human Migration: Patterns and Policies, pp. 106-145.
9 Jeffrey Burds, Peasant Dreams and Market Politics: Labor Migration and the Russian Vil
lage, 1861-1905 (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1998); David Moon, "Peasant
Migration, the Abolition of Serfdom, and the Internal Passport System in the Russian
Empire, c. 1800-1914," in Coerced and Free Migration: Global Perspectives, ed. David Eltis
(Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2002), pp. 324-360.
10 Kingsley Davis, The Population of India and Pakistan (New York: Russell and Russell,
1951 ), pp. 107-123; Arjan de Haan, "Migration on the Border of Free and Unfree Labour:
Workers in Calcutta's Jute Industry, 1900-1990," in Migration, Migration History, History:
Old Paradigms and New Perspectives, ed. Jan and Leo Lucassen (Bern: Peter Lang, 1999), pp.
197-222; Hoerder, Cultures in Contact, pp. 380-383.
11 Ge Jianxiong, Cao Shuji, and Wu Songdi, Jianming Zhongguo yimin [Concise history
of Chinese migration] (Fuzhou: Fujian Renmin Chubanshe, 1993), pp. 460-492.
12 Lydia Potts, The World Labour Market: A History of Migration (London: Zed Books,
1990), p. 71.
13 Imre Ferenczi and Walter Willcox, eds., International Migrations, vol. 1, Statistics
(New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1929), p. 1028.
14 Dennis Cordell, Joel Gregory, and Victor Pich?, Hoe and Wage: A Social History of
a Circular Migration System in West Africa (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1996); Philip Curtin,
Why People Move: Migration in African History (Baylor, Texas: Markham Press Fund, Baylor
University Press), pp. 33-39; Patrick Harries, Work, Culture, and Identity: Migrant Laborers
in Mozambique and South Africa, c. 1860-1910 (Portsmouth, N.H.: Heinemann, 1994);
Fran?ois Manchuelle, Willing Migrants: Soninke Labor Diasporas, 1848-1960 (Athens: Ohio
University Press, 1997); Pat Manning, Slavery and African Life: Occidental, Orientai, and
African Slave Trades (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 171-178.
15 Akram Fouad Khater, Inventing Home: Emigration, Gender, and the Middle Class in
Lebanon, 1870-1920 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2001).
16 Nearly 700,000 pilgrims were from the Dutch Indies. Centraal Kantoor voor de Sta
tistiek in Nederlandsch Indie, Statistisch Jaaroverzicht van Nederlandsch Indie 1938 (Bata
via), p. 140.
17 Calvin Goldscheider, "Israel," in Handbook on International Migration, ed. William
Serow, Charles Nam, David Sly, and Robert Weller (New York: Greenwood Press, 1990),
p. 132-135; G?lten Kazgan, "Migratory Movements in the Ottoman Empire and the Turk
ish Republic from the End of the 18th Century to the Present Day," in Les Migrations Inter
nationales, pp. 212-213; Justin McCarthy, Death and Exile: The Ethnic Cleansing of Ottoman
Muslims 1821-1922 (Princeton, N.J.: Darwin Press, 1995).
18 Aaron Segal, An Atlas of International Migration (London: Hans Zeil, 1993), p. 56.
China trade using some of the capital they earned to establish textile
mills in India. Of particular interest are the Sindworkies from the town
of Hyderabad in what is now Pakistan. After the 1860s, they spread
from Japan to the Panama Canal and Tierra del Fuego, establishing
upscale tourist shops that sold "curios" from around the world and
becoming prominent carriers of Japanese trade in the Dutch Indies.
Other merchant diasporas such as the Hadhramis (from Yemen), Hausa,
and Lebanese Christians joined the Chinese and Indians at this inter
face between expanding industrial enterprises and dispersed individual
producers and consumers around the world.19
Historical Trends
19 Linda Boxberger, On the Edge of Empire: Hadhramawt, Emigration, and the Indian
Ocean, 1880S-1930S (Albany: State University of New York Press, 2002); Philip Curtin,
Cross-Cultural Trade inWorld History (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1984);
Christine Dobbin, Asian Entrepreneurial Minorities: Conjoint Communities in the Making of
the World-Economy 1570-1940 (Richmond: Curzon, 1996); Markovits, The Global World of
Indian Merchants; Adam McKeown, "From Opium Farmer to Astronaut: A Global History
of Diasporic Chinese Business," Diaspora 9 (2000): 317-360.
20 Leslie Page Moch, "Dividing Time: An Analytical Framework for Migration His
tory Periodization," in Migration, Migration History, History, pp. 41-56, and "The European
Perspective: Changing Conditions and Multiple Migrations, 1750-1914," in European
Migrants: Global and Local Perspectives, ed. Dirk Hoerder and Leslie Page Moch (Boston:
Northeastern University Press, 1996), pp. 115-140.
1846-1851-1856- 1861- 1866-1871- 1876- 1881-1886- 1891-1896- 1901-1906- 1911-1916- 1920-1926- 1931-1936
50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 1900 05 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
1800 -,
1600 -
24 Anthony Reid, "South-East Asian Population History and the Colonial Impact," in
Asian Population History, ed. Ts'ui-jung Liu (Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press, 2001),
pp. 45-62.
tively tight organization within the British empire and the relatively
high level of assisted migration to European-owned plantations. Much
more perplexing is the characterization of Chinese migration as inden
tured and the consistently low estimations of Chinese migration in
Western language scholarship ranging from 2 to 8 million.31 Even the
incomplete Chinese numbers in the most widely used source of migra
tion statistics, Ferenczi and Willcox's International Migrations, account
for nearly 8 million Chinese.32 Most citations, however, tend to draw
from other secondary works, eventually leading to studies by Chen Ta,
Arnold Meagher, and Chen Zexuan, all of whom were counting only
contract labor migration.33 The projection of these numbers as a com
plete accounting of Chinese migration is laden with assumptions about
the nature of Asian migration.34
Dirk Hoerder's recent attempt at a comprehensive global history of
migration, Cultures in Contact, also explains Asian migration primarily
in terms of European intervention. His chapter on Asian migration in
the industrial age is titled "Asian Contract Labor System (1830s to
Periodization
The late 1920s was one of the high points of global mass migrations.
But studies that privilege the transatlantic migrations generally take
1914 to be the end of the age of mass migration. This date makes some
sense from the perspective of the North Atlantic, where migration pat
terns were severely disrupted by World War I and its aftermath. The
war produced rigid passport controls and massive refugee streams that
were unfamiliar to western Europe (although not to Russia, south
eastern Europe, and Asia Minor). Germany severely restricted immi
gration after the war, the United States erected quotas in 1921 and
1924, and Italy restricted emigration in 1927. It appeared to be a new
era of migration control, rigid borders, and nationalistic prejudices.38
But it is far from clear that movement was severely diminished
within the larger transatlantic system beyond those three (admittedly
important) nodes of Germany, Italy, and the United States. Over 2
million workers traveled to France in the 1920s, and migration to
Australia, New Zealand, and American destinations other than the
United States (and the United States before 1924) resumed levels
equivalent to the first decade of twentieth century. Emigration from
eastern Europe and Portugal?areas at the expanding periphery of the
transatlantic system?even increased during the 1920s.39 Immigration
to the United States from other parts of the Americas also increased
to over 150,000 a year, the highest rates ever.40 It is also unclear that
immigration policy was categorically more restrictive. Immigration
policy actually grew less restrictive in Canada over the 1920s, while
remaining fairly constant in Argentina and Australia.41
What seems to be at stake in insisting that 1914 was the end of mass
migration is not just the number of migrants, but the belief that a new
era of nationalism, rigid borders, and government regulation had
taken root. The postwar years are depicted as a break from the regime
38 Kulischer, Europe on the Move; Moch, Moving Europeans, pp. 155-170; Saskia Sas
sen, Guests and Aliens (New York: New Press, 1999), pp. 85-90.
39 Kulischer, Europe on the Move, p. 152. Kulischer also notes that Siberian migration
reversed in the immediate post-revolution years, as local polices were erected against the
interests of Russian settlers, but migration resumed familiar eastward patterns by the mid
19208, facilitated by central directives overriding local policies (pp. 74-84).
40 Mauice Davie, World Immigration: With Special Reference to the United States (New
York: McMillan, 1936), p. 208.
41 Ashley Timmer and Jeffrey Williamson, "Immigration Policy Prior to the 1930s:
Labor Markets, Policy Interactions, and Globalization Backlash," Population and Develop
ment Review 24 (1998): 743.
of free migration in place before the 1920s. But rather than posing a
dichotomy of before and after 1914, it would be better to understand
regimes of regulation as part of a cumulative process that had been
taking place since at least the 1870s. The concurrent growth of migra
tion since the mid-nineteenth century was part and parcel of the
expansion of borders and regulation, including numerous projects to
encourage, restrict, select, protect, distribute, and monitor migration.
Extending the era of mass migration into the 1920s acknowledges
both the global scale and the long-term relationship of migration and
politics since the early nineteenth century.42 This also helps provide
insight into how different migration systems became segmented across
the globe.
"Free" migration was itself a product of government regulation in
many instances. The abolishment of the slave trade required intensive
government intervention against the activities of private traders and
recruiters. The regulation of the Chinese coolie trade in the 1860s and
18 70s entailed the collaboration of Chinese and European officials to
circumscribe the activities of private recruiters and establish regula
tory institutions that assured that each migrant had entered into his
contract "freely" and "voluntarily."43 The expansion of Indian migra
tion throughout the British Empire was a direct result of this type of
intervention. All migration moves through social and political land
scapes. The idea of a free migration must always be contextualized in
its political context in which certain other processes and interests
must also be constrained.
Colonial and national policies toward migrants and natives have
42 Jane Caplan and John Torpey, eds., Documenting Individual Identity: The Development
of State Practices in the Modern World (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2001);
Cindy Hahamovitch, "Creating Perfect Immigrants: Guestworkers of the World in Histor
ical Perspective," Labor History 44 (2003): 70-94; John Torpey, The Invention of the Passport:
Surveillance, Citizenship and the State (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 2000);
Aristide Zolberg, "The Great Wall Against China: Responses to the First Immigration Cri
sis, 1885-1925," in Migration, Migration History, History, pp. 291-315, and "International
Migration Policies in a Changing World System," in Human Migration: Patterns and Policies,
ed. William McNeill and Ruth Adams (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1978), pp.
241-286. For summaries of migration laws, see International Labour Office, Emigration and
Immigration (Geneva: 1922), and Ashley Trimmer and Jeffrey Williamson, "Racism, Xeno
phobia or Markets: The Political Economy of Immigration Policy Prior to the Thirties,"
NBER Working Paper 5867, 1996, pp. xix-xxxi.
43 Robert Irick, Ch'ing Policy Toward the Coolie Trade 1847-1878 (Taipei: Chinese
Materials Center, 1982); Anthony Reid, "Early Chinese Migration into North Sumatra,"
in Studies in the Social History of China and South-east Asia: Essays in Memory of Victor Pur
cell, ed. Jerome Ch'en and Nicholas Tarling (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press,
1970), pp. 289-320.
also had a significant effect on the size and nature of migrant flows.
Chinese migration to colonial Southeast Asia and Siam in the middle
of the nineteenth century was inseparable from the enormous revenue
farms auctioned out to Chinese entrepreneurs, which were nexi for
labor recruitment and settlement of the interior. Later policies that
framed natives as rural dwellers with rights to the land and in need of
protection from exploitative "alien" Chinese or Indians were crucial
in the development of extensive "middleman" networks by Chinese
and Indians. In turn, these networks channeled further migration and
expanded well beyond direct European influence to create a world
densely enmeshed in an expanding global economy.44 These policies
were much different than those in the Americas that treated many
(but not all) immigrants as potential citizens, and developed policies
of selection, recruitment, and protection to facilitate the realization of
this ideal.
Nationalism and the policing of territorial boundaries were also
part of the same historical processes that produced migration. Many
immigration restrictions and border controls were erected in reaction
to immigration, building on the fear of cultural contamination, declin
ing living standards, or political subversion. Leo Lucassen has argued
that the rise of mass political participation and the welfare state was
most responsible for the perceived need to restrict the entry of migrants
who may compete for political resources.45 But migration also has a
positive relation to nationalism and the control of territorial bound
aries. The opening and encouragement of migration into Siberia and
Manchuria were both partially impelled by the perceptions of the
Russian and Chinese governments that these borderlands must be
claimed and fortified. Japan and Italy both encouraged overseas migra
tion as a way to expand national interests. The Italian emigrant pass
port requirements of 1901 were intended to facilitate high-quality
44 John Butcher and Howard Dick, The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business Elites
and the Emergence of the Modern State in Southeast Asia (New York: St. Martin's, 1993); Gary
Hamilton and Tony Waters, "Ethnicity and Capitalist Development: The Changing Role
of the Chinese in Thailand," in Essential Outsiders: Chinese and Jews in the Modern Trans
formation of Southeast Asia and Central Europe, ed. Daniel Chirot and Anthony Reid (Seat
tle: University of Washington Press, 1997), 258-284; McKeown, "From Opium Farmer to
Astronaut"; Carl Trocki, Opium and Empire: Chinese Society in Colonial Singapore, 1800
1910 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990).
45 Leo Lucassen, "The Great War and the Origins of Migration Control in Western
Europe and the United States (1880-1920)," in Regulation of Migration: International Expe
riences, ed., Anita Buocker, Kees Groenendijk, Tetty Havinga, and Paul Minderhoud (Ams
terdam: 1998), pp. 45-72.
migration that was not refused entry at foreign ports, as well as to main
tain tabs on young males who were required to perform military ser
vice.46 Emigrant communities have also been important sites for learn
ing and propagating ideals of nationalism and for the reification of a
homeland that must be nurtured, fortified, and protected.47
Perhaps one of the earliest and most significant examples of migra
tion control has been the cutting off of Asian migration to the Amer
icas and Australia in the last two decades of the nineteenth century.
Nearly 50,000 Chinese migrated to the California gold rush from 1851
to 1855. Total migration to California and Australia amounted to
135,000 in the 1850s, perhaps amounting to a quarter of all Chinese
emigration. All these migrants were funded and arranged by Chinese
capital (albeit transported on European ships) and depended on Chi
nese mining skills. Chinese were flowing into the same paths as Euro
pean migrants until international intervention in the coolie trade in
the 1870s and anti-Asian immigration laws in the Americas and Aus
tralia after the 1880s severely reduced migration to these destinations.
Chinese migrants to the Americas declined from 20-35 percent of all
Chinese migrants in the 1850s through the early 1870s to 2-5 percent
per year after 1890. Half of all Asian migration to the Americas had
already taken place by the mid-i88os and was cut off just when Asian
migration in general began to boom. The resulting segmentation of
migration systems has since framed understandings of Asian migrations
as categorically different and less significant than transatlantic migra
tions. But this segmentation was precisely an example of the kinds of
government intervention that continued to accumulate through the
1920s and 1930s.
Some of the larger implications of taking 1914 as a break can be
seen in work by Jeffrey Williamson and his collaborators, especially The
Age of Mass Migrations with Timothy Hatton and Globalization and
History with Kevin O'Rourke. They argue that migration was a critical
aspect of globalization in the North Atlantic, contributing to a con
vergence of wages, living standards, and industrial production across
nations. This argument is linked to a periodization in which the late
nineteenth century until 1914 was a period of globalization, the period
from 1914 to 1950 was one of deglobalization, and the period after
48 In a World Bank publication, Williamson goes so far as to call the period before
1914 a "belle ?poque," the period from 1914 to 1950 the "dark middle years," and the sub
sequent era a "renaissance." See Jeffrey Williamson, "Globalization and Inequality, Past
and Present," The World Bank Research Observer 12 (1997): 118.
49 Kevin O'Rourke and Jeffrey Williamson, Globalization and History: The Evolution of
a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1996), p. 286.
50 Paul Bairoch, Economics and World History (New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1993).
51 Timothy Hatton and Jeffrey Williamson, The Age of Mass Migration: Causes and
Economic Impact (New York: Oxford University Press, 1998), p. 249.
Migrant Networks
Much recent work on the sociology and history of migration has placed
migrants in the context of extensive networks that cross nations and
53 Historical and theoretical work on migration networks around the world include
Te?filo Altamirano, Presencia Andina en Lima Metropolitana (Lima: Pontificia Universidad
Cat?lica del Per?, Fondo Editorial, 1984); John Bodnar, The Transplanted: A History of Immi
grants in Urban America (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1985); Monica Boyd,
"Family and Personal Networks in International Migration: Recent Developments and New
Agendas," International Migration Review 23 (1989): 638-670; Madeline Hsu, Dreaming of
Gold, Dreaming of Home: Transnationalism and Migration between the United States and South
China, 1882-1943 (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2000); James H. Jackson
and Leslie Page Moch, "Migration and the Social History of Modem Europe"; Ivan Light,
Parminder Bachu, and Stavros Karageoris, "Migration Networks and Immigrant Entrepre
neurship," in Immigration and Entrepreneurship, ed. Ivan Light and Parminder Bachu (New
Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers, 1993), pp. 25-49; Jan and Leo Lucassen, eds.,
Migration, Migration History, History; Fran?ois Manchuelle, Willing Migrants: Soninke Labor
Diaspora; Adam McKeown, Chinese Migrant Networks and Cultural Change: Peru, Chicago
and Hawaii, 1900-1936 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2001); Alejandro Portes and
J?zsef B?r?cz, "Contemporary Immigration: Theoretical Perspectives on Its Determinants
and Modes of Incorporation," International Migration Review 23 (1989): 606-630; Oded
Stark, The Migration of Labor (Cambridge, U.K.: Basil Blackwell, 1992); and Charles Tilly,
"Migration in Modern European History," in Human Migration, pp. 48-72, and "Trans
planted Networks," in Immigration Reconsidered, pp. 79-95. For a general review of migra
tion theories, see Douglas Massey, Joaqu?n Arango, Grame Hugo, Ali Kouaouci, Adela
Pellegrino, and J. Edward Taylor, "Theories of International Migration: A Review and
Appraisal," Population and Development Review 19 (1993): 431-466.
munities are the social space within which many migrant decisions and
activities take place. They produce a social geography that is not con
gruent with physical geography. A migrant may have more knowledge
of distant Penang, Omsk, or Chicago than the nearby market town,
because that is where all his uncles and cousins are.54
Such networks both create and constrain opportunities. Migration
would generally be too expensive and risky without the information,
assistance, and opportunities provided by friends, relatives, and other
resources available through these networks. It would also be a point
less endeavor without the links to home and family maintained within
these networks, through which money, support, and the other fruits of
migration could be channeled. But the very strength of these channels
also restricts opportunities. It is very difficult for an established net
work to access new job opportunities and new destinations, even if only
rudimentary new skills are necessary and the economic benefits are
high. Many migrant elite even had an interest in controlling and lim
iting information and opportunities, so as to further profit from their
position at the nexus of opportunities.
Studies of aggregate nation-to-nation movements can be quite suc
cessful at explaining the ebbs and flows of particular streams, but they
provide few tools to understand the mechanisms of migration. For
example, one village may have a population so devoted to emigration
that even the fields are left barren or leased to outsiders, while another
village a few kilometers down the road with almost identical condi
tions may produce no migrants at all. Aggregate models and economic
approaches are also hard pressed to explain why migrants may choose
to travel to one location when wages and opportunities are clearly
superior elsewhere. Why would some Italians choose to work in Mon
treal when the local French Canadians were looking for better-paying
work in New England?55 In other words, individuals making decisions
(the "free" migrants) are the basic unit of most economic and aggre
gate models, yet those studies have little understanding of the social
conditions under which those decisions are made (although scholars
56 For critiques of national perspectives, see Hasia Diner, "History and the Study of
Immigration: Narratives of the Particular," in Migration Theory: Talking Across Disciplines,
ed. Caroline Brettell and James Hollifield (New York: Routledge, 2000), pp. 27-42; Donna
Gabaccia, "Is Everywhere Nowhere? Nomads, Nations, and the Immigrant Paradigm of
United States History," Journal of American History 86 (1999): 1115-1134; and Nancy
Green, "The Comparative Method and Poststructural Structuralism: New Perspectives for
Migration Studies," in Migration, Migration History, History, pp. 57-72.
57 Donna Gabaccia, "Women of the Mass Migrations: From Minority to Majority,
1820-1930," in European Migrants, pp. 90-111. See also J. D. Gould, "European Inter
Continental Emigration: The Road Home: Return Migration from the U.S.A.," European
Journal of Economic History 9 (1980): 41-112; Ewa Morawska, "Return Migrations: Theo
retical and Research Agenda," in A Century of European Migrations, pp. 277-292; and Portes
and B?r?cz, "Contemporary Immigration."
return migration from the United States both rose over the course of
the twentieth century as migration moved away from frontier settle
ment to wage labor in cities and factories. While recognizing the broad
applicability of this generalization, she also points out that female
migration for all ethnic groups follows the same cycles?linked to busi
ness cycles?as male migration. Higher proportions of women also
migrated to industrial New England than to the rural West. That is to
say, the usual linkage between female migration, family settlement on
frontiers, female and return migration may not be accurate. Many
female migrants were also wage laborers, just like the men. More spe
cific explanations must be sought.
Gabaccia suggests that the difference in migration demographics
over the course of the nineteenth century can be understood also by
looking at family structure. Migrants from northern Europe who dom
inated migration to the United States in the mid-nineteenth century
were from areas where nuclear families predominated. Husbands and
wives were dependent on each other for economic sustenance, and
many women had experience in market activities. Southern and east
ern Europeans, who dominated in later migrations, tended to have
ideal families that were larger multigenerational units. Women could
remain at home as part of a larger economic unit and were also more
likely to be involved in subsistence than market activities.
The history of female migration from Ireland offers an even more
particular situation, based on historical circumstances. Irish migration
was unique in that it maintained nearly equal proportions of male and
female migration and very low return rates throughout the nineteenth
and early twentieth centuries. The potato famine encouraged the
migration of unusually high numbers of women in the mid-nineteenth
century, who got a lock on household service jobs in the United States.
This established a pattern of high rates of female migration and per
manent settlement in North America that would continue for nearly
a century (and was mirrored in short distance migration of women to
European cities to work in shops and as household servants).
These specific histories can explain some of the shifts in female
migration and return rates, but even northern Europeans tended to
produce increasing numbers of male sojourners over the late nine
teenth and early twentieth centuries. No single explanation can
account for everything, but multiple explanations highlight the ways
in which a single network was shaped by multiple forces, including his
torical contingencies, patterns set by previous migrants, structural eco
nomic relations between different parts of the world, and local cultural
forms like family structure.
No single explanation can account for everything, but multiple
58 Qiu Liben, Cong shijie kan huaren [Looking at Chinese from a world perspective]
(Hong Kong: Nandao, 2000). He acknowledges that many of his colleagues estimate 20
million overseas Chinese migrants, but prefers an estimate of 10 million (pp. 19, 30).
great numbers because they did not have the power to influence gov
ernment regulations and social opportunities in their favor. Chinese,
however, were able to mobilize long-standing commercial and labor
recruiting networks to develop a niche as middlemen and business
men. No broad patterns of migration and settlement should be taken
for granted. They are all the product of particular social and economic
histories.
Contemporary Migration
59 The literature on this topic is vast. Let me suggest only two of the more sustained
arguments, Stephen Castles and Mark Miller, The Age of Migration: International Population
Movements in the Modern World (New York: Guilford Press, 1993), and Alejandro Portes,
Luis E. Guarnizo, and Patricia Landolt, "The Study of Transnational ism: Pitfalls and Prom
ise of an Emerging Research Field," Ethnic and Racial Studies 22 (1999): 218-237.
60 Susan E Martin, ed., World Migration Report 2000 (Geneva: United Nations and
World Organization for Migration, 2000); Hania Zlotnik, "International Migration 1965
96: An Overview," Population and Development Review 24 (1998): 429-468.
Sources: International Labour Office, World Statistics of Aliens: A Comparative Study of Census
Returns, 1910-1920-1930 (Geneva: 1936), p. 56; World Organization of Migration, World
Migration Report 2003; Zlotnik, "International Migration," p. 431. Segal, Atlas of World
Population, counts 90 million migrants in 1910, which amounts to 5.5 percent of the world's
population, but gives no source for this number.
people who may have already resided abroad for decades but only now
applied for permanent residence (as is the case in United States
statistics). My numbers also count people who would not normally be
defined as "international migrants," such as those who traveled to
Manchuria, Siberia, Burma (within the colonial jurisdiction of India),
or Kazhakistan (which would now be counted as international migra
tion). But they do not count many migrants within Europe, the Amer
icas, Asia, and Africa who did cross international borders. Moreover,
increased immigration restrictions around the world means that many
contemporary long-distance migrants are uncounted because they are
illegal.
Despite these difficulties, it seems not unreasonable to assert that
the mobility of people intending to stay for a relatively long period of
time (more than a year) reached levels in proportion to world popula
tion in the 1990s that are comparable to the early twentieth century.
But, even if accurate, this still may not be a meaningful comparison.
For example, 454 million annual tourist arrivals were counted in 1990,
reminding us that temporary global mobility has surely reached unpre
cedented proportions.61 In fact, the shifts in categories used to measure
migration may be of more significance than the actual numbers them
selves. We cannot understand migration without simultaneously
understanding the social processes by which they have been produced,
recorded, and processed as "refugees," "guest laborers," or "illegal
aliens." The new categories (like the high tourist numbers) remind us
that the structures of global mobility are constantly changing in the
context of both political and economic processes. Volume alone is
meaningless if we do not understand the broad patterns and distinc
tions that shape migration, and have been used to understand, calcu
late and control migration. Those very borders that define interna
tional migration, and the populations inside them which are now seen
to be challenged by that migration are themselves the products of pre
vious migration and regulation, much of which has been quickly for
gotten.
Most of the statistics used in the tables and figures, except for overseas
migration from South China, are from published sources, which are
mostly based on port and immigration statistics. The availability of sta
tistics does not mean the numbers are necessarily reliable. ]. D. Gould,
"European Inter-Continental Emigration 1815-1914: Patterns and
Causes," European Journal of Economic History 8 (1979): 598-605, and
several articles in Imre Ferenczi and Walter Willcox, eds., International
Migrations, v. 2, Interpretations (New York: National Bureau of Eco
nomic Research, 1931), discuss the sometimes serious discrepancies
between departure and arrival statistics in the transatlantic migra
tions. I have encountered similar problems with Chinese and South
east Asian sources. The difficulties of accounting for return and repeat
migration further complicate the significance and reliability of any
quantitative estimate.
For the transatlantic numbers, Ferenczi and Willcox, eds., Interna
tional Migrations, v. 1, Statistics (New York: National Bureau of Eco
nomic Research, 1929), p. 172, is used for the years up to 1880, and
B. R. Mitchell, International Historical Statistics: Europe 1750-1993, 4th
ed. (New York: Macmillan Reference, 1998), pp. 129-140, is used for
subsequent years. Over 200,000 migrants from Turkey, Lebanon, and
Syria are not included in Figures 1 and 2, but discussion of this emi
gration can be found in Robin Cohen, Global Diasporas: An Introduc
tion (Seattle: University of Washington Press, 1997), p. 95, and Akram
Fouad Khater, Inventing Home: Emigration, Gender and the Middle Class
inLebanon, 1870-1920 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2001).
Numbers for migration from Russia into Siberia and central Asia
before 1914 are from Donald Treadgold, The Great Siberian Migration:
Government and Peasant in Resettlement from Emancipation to the First
World War (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1957), pp.
33~35- Numbers for the period from 1914 to 1927 are more specula
tive. Estimates can be found in Eugene Kulischer, Europe on the Move:
War and Population Changes, 1917-47 (New York: Columbia Univer
sity Press), p. 83; V. V Obolensky-Ossinsky, "Emigration from and
Immigration into Russia," in Ferenczi and Willcox, International Migra
tions, v. 1, p. 576; and Treadgold, pp. 236-238. Kulischer (p. 112)
offers an estimate of 4.7 to 5 million migrants for the period from 1927
to 1939. This estimate has circulated widely, but archival research may
lead to a revision.
Nearly 25 million Chinese to Manchuria after 1891 are counted in
Thomas Gottschang and Diana Lary, Swallows and Settlers: The Great
Migration from North China to Manchuria (Ann Arbor: University of
Michigan, Center for Chinese Studies, 2000), p. 171, but much over
land migration may have passed uncounted. Gottschang and Lary (p.
64) also suggest that up to half a million Chinese moved into Siberia
before 1917. Numbers for migration to Manchuria before 1891 are
For emigration from South China ports other than Hong Kong and
Macao before 1876, I made estimates based on G.William Skinner,
Chinese Society in Thailand: An Analytical History (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell
University Press, 1957), pp. 58-59, and on anecdotal reports found in
Meagher, pp. 143-145, and Lee Poh Ping, Chinese Society in Nineteenth
Century Singapore (Singapore: Oxford University Press, 1978), p. 86,
that suggest immigration rates of 10,000 a year to Singapore in the
1840s and 1850s and 20,000 a year in the early 1870s.
Statistics on indentured labor migration from China until 1874
and emigration from Hong Kong from 1846 to 1855 are from Arnold
Meagher, "The Introduction of Chinese Laborers to Latin America:
The 'Coolie Trade,' 1847-1874" (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Cal
ifornia at Davis, 1975), pp. 105A, 108A. Hong Kong emigration data
from 1856 to 1939 were generously provided to me by Elizabeth Sinn,
from her Hong Kong Research Grants Council funded project, "The
Impact of Chinese Emigration on Hong Kong's Economic Develop
ment, 1842-1941." A summary of some of this data is in Elizabeth
Sinn, "Emigration from Hong Kong before 1941: General Trends," in
Ronald Skeldon, ed., Emigration from Hong Kong: Tendencies and Impacts
(Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1995), pp. n-34. Data for
other ports in South China are from the Returns of Trade and Trade
Reports of the Chinese Maritime Customs from 1876 to 1928, Lian Xin
hao, "Jindai haigang jianji yu Dongnanya huaqiao yimin" [Modern
port hygiene and Chinese migrants to Southeast Asia], Huaqiao Hua
ren Lishi Yanjiu (1997): 10th anniversary: 50-51, for Xiamen (Amoy)
from 1931 to 1940 and for Shantou (Swatow) from 1920 to 1934; and
Li Zhiya and Huang Yinying, eds., Huaqiao yu Qiaowu Shiliao Xuanji
Bian [Selected documents on overseas Chinese and overseas Chinese
affairs] (Guangzhou: Guangdong Renmin Chubanshe, 1991), pp. 39,
133-134, for Hainan from 1937 to 1938 and for Shantou from 1937 to
1939. I made estimates based on colonial immigration reports for the
remaining missing years in the 1930s.
I used emigration data from Hong Kong and Chinese customs
reports as the basis for preparing Figures 1 and 2 because they offer the
most complete statistical series. They are generally considered to be an
undercount because they often did not count emigrants who traveled
in Chinese junks and many Chinese tried to avoid medical exams
given by customs officers, and I have made additions based on colonial
statistics. The reports of the protector of Chinese in Singapore for 1881
to 1939 generally corroborate quite well with Chinese emigration sta
tistics, with the exception of migration from Hainan in the years up to
1902. Skinner's Chinese Society in Thailand, pp. 61 and 173, gives esti
mates based on Thai customs reports after 1882 that are up to 30 per
cent higher than emigration reports. Immigration statistics in the
Annual Report of the Philippine Commission and the Annual Report of the
Bureau of Customs in Manila from 1899 to 1939 are also up to 30 per
cent higher than emigration numbers.
Statistics for the Dutch Indies from 1900 to 1938 in Statistisch Jam
overzicht van Nederlandsch Indi? (Batavia) and Departement van Econ
omische Zaken, Volkstelling IQ30, v. 7, Chineezen en Andere Vreemde
Oosterlingen in Nederlandsch-Indi? (Batavia: 1935) are divided accord
ing to a variety of shifting and unexplained administrative categories.
I have found it impossible to make them correspond with each other
or with migration statistics from China and Singapore. I have thus
assumed that most migration to the Dutch Indies has been accounted
for by figures from China and Singapore. I have made the same assump
tion for seaborne migration to Burma.
Numbers for French Indochina are more perplexing. Immigration
statistics for Cochinchina (southern Vietnam) from 1879 to 1883 and
Hanoi from 1920 to 1924 are in Ferenczi and Willcox, International
Migrations, v. 1, pp. 154 and 920. Numbers for all of French Indochina
from 1923 to 1940 are in Annuaire Statistique de VIndochine (Hanoi). In
only one year (1926) do emigration statistics account for more than 30
percent of immigration statistics. Most migrants probably arrived by
junk, as suggested in Charles Robequain, The Economic Development of
French Indo-China, trans. Isabel Ward (London: Oxford University
Press, 1944): "The rich and well-to-do Chinese travel on big liners
like Europeans; but most of the immigrants are crammed together in
picturesque, ill-smelling groups on the decks of small boats." Assum
ing that many migrants to French Indochina were not counted as emi
grants by Chinese customs, I have constructed estimates of Chinese
migration to French Indochina based on available immigration statis
tics, population estimates, and anecdotal evidence that migration rates
decreased temporarily after the imposition of immigration restrictions
in 1906. See Wang Wen-Yuan, Les relations entre l'Indochine Fran?aise
et la Chine (Paris: Editions Pierre Bossuet, 1937), pp. 16-17.
The trends of Chinese migration recorded in Figures 1 and 2
account for 18.9 million Chinese emigrants to Southeast Asia and the
South Pacific. I think this estimate is conservative, especially before
1881 and after 1928, and the actual number could be as high as 22
million.