Trade
Trade
p2 p2
=
ωH ωF
Also, given that both countries use the same utility function and consumers have identical
preferences, the relative prices will be such that:
pn β n
=
ωj βj
ωH
Now, let's calculate :
ωF
ω H p2 w H p 2 β 2
= × = ×
ω F wF p 2 w F β H
b) Since good 2 is produced in both countries, we can express the consumption of good 2 in
both countries as:
LH
C 2 ,H =
l2 , H
LF
C 2 ,F =
l 2 ,F
Given the relative prices and wages, we can determine the consumption of goods 1 and 3 using the
budget constraint:
wj
C n , j= × β n × C 2, j
pn
c) Market clearing conditions imply that the total amount of each good produced equals the
total amount consumed:
L H =l 1, H +l 2 , H +l 3 ,H
LF =l 1 , F +l 2 , F +l 3 , F
Using the relative prices and wages, and the consumption equations derived in part b, we can
express l n , j for each n ∈{1 ,2 , 3 } and j ∈{ H , F }.
d) (i) When z 1 , F increases, the labor productivity in producing good 1 in the foreign country
increases. As a result, the relative cost of good 1 is reduced in relation to other items. As a
result, both countries' consumption of good 1 rises, which could raise both nations' utility
levels.
(ii) When z 2 , F increases, it directly affects the production of good 2 in the foreign country.
This could affect the relative prices and wages, potentially altering consumption patterns
and thus utility in both countries.
(iii) When z 3 , F increases, similar effects as in scenario 1 might occur, affecting the
consumption pattern and utility in both countries.
(iv) When the vector (z 1 , F , z 2 , F , z 3 , F ) is scaled up by a factor γ >1, it uniformly increases
the labor productivities in the foreign country for all goods. This will likely lead to a
decrease in relative prices of goods produced in the foreign country, potentially altering
consumption patterns and utility in both countries.