Choice Under Risk and Uncertainty
Choice Under Risk and Uncertainty
• Perloff, Chapters 17
Recall: Consumer Choice and Demand Under Certainty
• Choosing the optimal bundle/combination of two goods
• Each combination is expected to give the same level of
satisfaction/utility.
• Indifference curve analysis
• Shows combinations of two goods that give the consumer the same
level of satisfaction/utility.
• ICs further out give higher levels of satisfaction.
• Shape of IC
• Downward sloping (for normal goods) implies a diminishing marginal
rate of substitution (MRS) due to diminishing marginal utility.
2
Indifference curve analysis
3
Finding the optimum consumption
4
Recall: Consumer choice and demand under certainty
5
Uncertainty and risk
• Uncertainty affects consumption decisions.
• Consumers consider the outcomes of their choices under a
number of possible circumstances (states of nature) – rejection
or acceptance.
• Risk is sometimes used to quantify these uncertainties.
• What is meant by risk?
• Hazard or chance of loss
• i.e.; a situation in which the likelihood of each possible
outcome is known or can be estimated, and no single
possible outcome is certain to occur
• How do people decide what to do in uncertainty?
6
Uncertainty and risk
7
Assessing risk - Probability
• Probability indicates how likely an event is to occur
• Ranges between 0 and 1
• The sum of the probabilities of all possible outcomes is equal to 1
• We use the frequency with which an outcome occurred to estimate
the probability
• For instance, if it rained 20 times on an August bank holiday in the last 40
years, then the frequency that is rained, 𝜃 theta, is given by;
!
• 𝜃="
#$
• 𝜃= %$
= 0.5
Probability
9
Probability Distribution
• A probability distribution relates the probability of
occurrence to each possible outcome.
• Mutually exclusive—when only one of the outcomes can
occur at a given time.
• Exhaustive—when no other outcomes than those listed
are possible.
• Where outcomes are mutually exclusive and
exhaustive, exactly one of these outcomes will occur
with certainty, and the probabilities must add up to
100%.
Probability Distribution
Expected value
12
Expected value - example
• Gregg, a promoter, schedules an outdoor concert for tomorrow.
• How much money he’ll make depends on the weather.
• If it doesn’t rain, his profit or value from the concert is V =
$15.
• If it rains, he’ll have to cancel the concert and he’ll lose V =
−$5, which he must pay the band.
• He knows that the weather department forecasts a 50% chance
of rain.
• Expected Value?
𝐸𝑉 = Pr(𝑛𝑜 𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑛)×𝑉𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒(𝑛𝑜 𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑛) + Pr(𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑛)×𝑉𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒(𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑛)
1 1
= ×$15 + ×(−$5) = $5
2 2
13
Variance and standard deviation
14
Variance and standard deviation
15
Example: Deal or no deal
16
Deal or no deal – example 1
• The banker offers the contestant £6500 to abandon the game. What
should the contestant do?
• What is the expected value?
17
Deal or no deal
• What is the expected value?
• Each outcome is equally likely. Hence, the probability of any
outcome =1/5
• 𝐸𝑉 = 0.2 £5 + 0.2 £500 + 0.2 £1000 + 0.2 £10000 +
0.2 £50000 = £12301
• The banker’s offer (£6500) is below the expected value
• The difference (£12301- £6500 = £5801) is the risk premium
• The amount the consumer will pay to avoid the risk
• If the individual chooses the banker’s offer they are willing to
pay the risk premium to avoid the risk of the gamble.
18
Deal or no deal - example 2
£50 £250000
£100
19
Deal or no deal - example 2
£50 £250000
£100
20
Deal or no deal – which gamble is riskier?
• The greater the SD relative to the EV, the greater the risk.
• The banker’s offer relative to the EV:
• In the first example, this is £6500/£12301 = 53%
• In the second example: £12500/£50231 = 25% of the EV
• Standard deviation in the first example = £19208
• Risk is, therefore, £19208/£12301 = 1.56
• Standard deviation in the second example = £99825
• Risk = £99825/£ 50231 = 1.99
• The second game is riskier than the first
21
Attitudes towards risk
22
Expected utility
• We assume that the individual knows the value of each possible
outcome and the probability that it will occur.
• A rational person maximises expected utility.
• Expected utility (EU) is the probability-weighted average of the utility
from each possible outcome.
• 𝐸𝑈 = Pr 𝑋 ×𝑈 𝑋 + Pr 𝑌 ×𝑈 𝑌
• Where the utility function U depends on payoffs; U(X) is the utility
from X; U(Y) is the utility from Y
• EU captures the trade-off between risk and value, whereas the
expected value considers only value.
23
Expected utility
24
Expected utility
25
Example: Risk aversion
• Irma, who is risk averse, makes a choice under uncertainty. She has
an initial wealth of $40 and has two options:
• Nothing, and keep the $40 (her utility is U(40)=120) with
certainty.
• Buy a share
• Her wealth will be:
• $70 if the start-up is a success – utility of 70, U(70) = 140
• $10 otherwise – utility of 10, U(10) = 70
• Irma’s subjective probability is 50% that the firm will be a success.
• Her expected utility from buying a share is:
• 0.5U(10) + 0.5U(70) = 0.5*70 + 0.5*140 = 105
26
Risk aversion
27
Risk premium
28
Risk neutrality and risk preference
constant increasing
marginal utility marginal utility of
of wealth, wealth
29
Risk avoidance through risk sharing and
spreading
30
Investing Under Uncertainty
Attitudes toward risk affect people’s willingness to invest.