Transitions To Competitive Government
Transitions To Competitive Government
to
Competitive Government
SUNY series, Human Communication Processes
Donald P. Cushman and Ted J. Smith III, Editors
Transitions to
Competitive
Government
Speed, Consensus, and Performance
Ronald B. Cullen
and
Donald P. Cushman
Cullen, Ronald B.
Transitions to competitive government : speed, consensus, and performance /
Ronald B. Cullen and Donald P. Cushman.
p. cm. — (SUNY series, human communication processes)
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 0-7914-4657-3 (hc : alk. paper) — ISBN 0-7914-4658-1 (pb : alk. paper)
1. Competition, International. 2. International economic relations.
3. Government productivity. I. Cushman, Donald P. II. Title. III. SUNY
series in human communication processes
HF1414.C85 2000
354.72367—dc21 99-054267
10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
This book is dedicated to Marie,
my wife and partner
in the consultancy business and life.
Her commitment to research and the
development of knowledge is for me an inspiration.
RBC
Contents
List of Exhibits ix
Acknowledgments xiii
1 Government in Crises 1
Part
I A Vision to Guide Government Reform 31
2 Lessons from Business 37
3 The Management of Transitions to National Competitiveness 55
4 Implementation Strategies for Competitive Government 79
5 Responding to External Pressures: Value-Chain Coalignment
and the Delivery of Government Services 105
6 Leadership Strategies for Transforming Governmental
Competitiveness 133
Part II A Management Platform for Government Change 169
7 The Challenge of Transition 175
8 Planning and Evaluation Strategies for Competitive
Government 199
9 Reinventing and Reengineering Government Management
Systems and Values 229
10 Resource Management Strategies for Competitive Government 251
11 Governance Systems and Management Reform 271
Part III Benchmarking the Transition to Competitive Government 281
12 Managing Transitions to National Competitiveness 285
References 319
Index 329
vii
List of Exhibits
ix
x LIST OF EXHIBITS
This book emerged from a collaboration with Don Cushman that started on
a visit to Phillip Island, and developed in Melbourne, Hartford, Albany, Catania,
and London. When we started, we did not share the feeling that “reinvention”
was the complete new paradigm, that the solution to the crisis in government
management was at hand. As we finished, the consensus was that the most
extensive government management reform in the U.S. for decades had only
solved part of the crisis. We believe that it is important to view reform as an
ongoing transition from where government management currently is to where
it might be in the future. It is now important to expand the reform framework
and learn from and build on what has been achieved. The ideas in this book
can contribute to that process.
I would like to thank those politicians, colleagues, and clients who as-
sisted me to learn about the business of government and those who helped
with comments on parts of this manuscript. Thanks also to Skye who helped
more than she knew and who will hopefully grow up in a world where books
like this no longer need to be written.
Ron Cullen
August, 2000
xiii
Transitions
to
Competitive Government
Chapter 1
Government in Crises
1
2 GOVERNMENT IN CRISES
but still fail to deliver increases in national competitiveness. The likelihood that
implementation will fail increases as the rate of change increases. The solution
for government is to address performance directly. Surrogates for performance
often reflect old solutions and old ways of viewing the world. The strategies
which government must now employ to address these core roles and public
expectations of government performance are light years removed from ap-
proaches which seemed to work well enough even a decade ago.
In Exhibit 1.1. Changing Roles of Government, we define the core roles
of government as adding to “competitiveness,” adding “social value,” and
maintaining “governability.” Key implementation strategies for government
are summarized as part of Exhibit 1.1.
Our intention in starting with such generalized roles is to place the crises
and the solutions in context, and to provide a framework for both evaluation
Implementation strategies
Viable Access to
development strategy multinational companies
Effective macro-financial Access to overseas markets
management Competitive workskills and
Optimize national assets and technology
resources
Competitive taxes and charges
Effective domestic markets
Competitive infrastructure
Government roles
NATIONAL
COMPETITIVENESS
Increase net
production Recognize diverse
needs and priorities,
Effective income negotiate interest
distribution SOCIAL GOVERNABILITY group boundaries
Balance impacts on VALUE
current and future
generations Manage the comfort
Effective access zone impacts of
to work government programs
Competitive social
infrastructure Manage cycle dynamics to
Effective equity protection bridge gaps between expectations
and safety net services and delivery
6 GOVERNMENT IN CRISES
and the study of differences. This general statement of roles does not assume
that differences are not important. Results and strategies that are considered
successful in one nation will not necessarily meet the needs of another. Com-
mencing our examination of government management at this generalized level
allows us to explore the impact of globalization and external change on
governments and government management systems. Although the three roles
are different, there are major interconnections between these roles which
need to be examined to understand the causes of the current crisis. For ex-
ample, action to respond to changes required by the competitiveness role
impact on both the social value role and the governability role. Unless a
nation can fund and deliver its basic value system and unless government
can govern, there is little prospect of achieving and maintaining world
competitiveness.
Competitiveness
Social Value
Governments need to be seen to improve the short- and long-term well-being
of citizens. Governments have key roles in regulating the framework within
which resources are distributed within a country. Most governments use this
process to address the needs of disadvantaged groups.
Historically, businesses delivered employment while governments addressed
income redistribution, provided safety nets, and selected services. Competitive-
ness was assumed to occur almost independently of the structures used to
deliver social value. Today the links are all too apparent in many countries. For
example, employment underpins the social structure of most nations. Additions
to social value need to maximize both competitiveness and employment. A
number of countries, seeking to manage these factors independently, have dis-
covered they can no longer fund old value systems and old solutions.
The pressures of global competitiveness have made employment less cer-
tain and retraining a fact of life for most workers. Governments need to address
access to employment more actively than in the past. The pressures to shorten
cycle time and respond strategically to industrial opportunities have threatened
many of the old systems which provided some security in the sense that they
were predictable and were seen to address historical needs. Governments in
developed countries have found that the pressures of competition have threat-
ened their capacity to fund old value systems. Governments today need to
manage the social impacts of change and to address emerging social needs.
These demands increase as governments commit to competitiveness objectives.
Global pressures are altering both the overall wealth and the distribution
of that wealth in most countries. In developed countries, the increasing mo-
bility of the labor force requires new responses from governments, labor
unions, and business. Developing countries face even greater transition pres-
sures as wealth and labor costs grow and as community expectations about
the benefits of increased competitiveness develop.
The pressures on governments to respond to changing patterns of win-
ners and losers in the economic system cannot be managed to restore the past
or to insulate groups from the pressures of change. There is an urgent need
for governments to redesign safety nets, and to think through the options to
protect those disadvantaged by change. The challenge differs between coun-
tries but almost no government can expect to move into the new millennium
without redesigning strategies for adding social as well as economic value.
Governability
Governments must manage change while at the same time maintaining the
scope to govern. In suggesting that maintaining the scope to govern is a core
8 GOVERNMENT IN CRISES
Fundamental trends are altering the way in which business must operate to
succeed and the way in which wealth is created and distributed between and
within nations. These same trends are altering the role of government and the
way in which government and business must operate to compete.
Government in Crises 9
We now examine the impact of five external trends on the way in which
governments are managed and on the relationship between the business and
government. Globalization, competition for scarce resources, and technology
development and transfer are fundamentally altering the value-chain of many
industries. Technology is revolutionizing approaches to integration and con-
trol in both the business and government sectors. The need for governments
to respond to increasing diversity within and between nations and the need to
manage these issues under the glare of mass information, which highlights
differences and inequities in the process of government, are generating new
constraints on governments and on government management platforms.
Globalization
The traditional model for external relationships was to manage them to con-
tribute to the domestic economy of a nation by buffering the domestic economy
from undesirable external pressures. However, the capacity of nations to buffer
their values and development from external influences has all but passed. This
has created new external threats and opportunities. Governments can no longer
respond effectively to recession or deliver economic growth and employment
in isolation. Nations need to access global resources, technologies, and
markets. The price for this access is the need to meet external needs and
expectations.
Nations are forming new external regional alliances which are seen to
assist individual nations to access global markets.
Competition
Nations must compete externally for a share of global resources and for
access to markets and technologies. The traditional model for competition
conveniently separated the role of government and business: government was
required to regulate markets; business and industry groups were required to
operate independently to create added value. This approach has proved un-
able to cope with external changes; in the new global economy, government
and industry need to work together to optimize the share of global resources
accessed by a nation or region.
Global resources are increasingly allocated by business networks such as
multinationals, by international trade and investment, and by agencies such as
the World Bank which seek to facilitate development. Nations that fail to
respond effectively are accessing a decreasing share of these global resources.
As global market forces compare the systems and regulatory regimes of
nations, governments are being forced to address new external imperatives
10 GOVERNMENT IN CRISES
which impact on taxation, trade, and financial regulation. The role of govern-
ment can no longer be studied separately from the rest of the economy. The
way in which business and government interact is no longer fixed; it has
become a key variable in new approaches to government. The boundaries
between the two sectors are changing as integration between the private and
public sectors becomes more critical. Government must work with the busi-
ness sector to gain a share of global resources and to develop the internal
resources required to exploit global markets and technologies.
Technology
To compete, nations must access and apply developing technologies cost
effectively. The development of technology has made technology access and
technology transfer, the application of new technology and advanced techno-
logical information and processes, key issues for the economic competitive-
ness of nations.
Old technology tends to be reflected in established production values and
practices; new technology requires adaptation of those values and practices to
facilitate technology transfer. The traditional model for technology transfer
was to develop a technology base hierarchically, starting with low technolo-
gies and leading to higher technologies and then upgrading and developing
the base incrementally. These strategies are no longer effective. Pursued in
the current global environment, they are a prescription for disaster and eco-
nomic exploitation.
To develop as part of the global economy, countries need: to recognize
that many technology changes are necessarily discontinuous; to access tech-
nologies strategically at all levels; to apply and exploit technologies to pro-
duce competitive advantage; and finally, to position themselves to exploit
emerging technologies.
These strategies in turn require nations: to develop international alli-
ances; to reform labor markets; to review approaches to education and train-
ing; to accept and manage technological redundancy as a cost of remaining
competitive; and to develop public and private sector partnerships to access
key technologies. Generic skills are no longer enough; governments must
ensure that there is a strategic fit between the demand- and supply-sides of
the education and training system.
Diversity
In addition to globalization and competition for resources and markets, govern-
ments must manage major increases in the level of diversity between nations,
regions, and interest groups. This requires new approaches by governments.
Government in Crises 11
Information
have outflanked these old strategies in many countries. Information about the
performance of governments is more readily available, as is information about
the performance of other nations.
Performance or the lack of it can no longer be hidden, and public expec-
tations are now more demanding. The grand plans and platitudes that char-
acterized much national planning are no longer persuasive, either to key
interest groups within a country, or to external groups who increasingly re-
quire evidence of performance as a prerequisite for investment and trade.
crises have challenged two ideas central to Ohmae’s analysis: the assumption
that business and unfettered market forces can increasingly meet national as
well as business needs and address the core insecurities of people; and the
assumption that the performance of governments is in some senses a second
order issue, for it is not a critical prerequisite for national performance.
A number of analysts have argued that governments remain critical to
national competitiveness. These authors argue for a shift in the roles of gov-
ernment rather than for its gradual abolition. This argument is advanced in a
major analysis of national competitiveness by Michael Porter (1990). If Porter
is correct, government needs to develop a new role which works with busi-
ness to deliver improvements in national competitiveness. Porter argues that
this role needs to be a catalyst for change rather than a protector of existing
business interests. Eisuke Sakakibara (1993) argues a similar case for national
differences from a Japanese perspective. The Porter analysis is also supported
by several more general studies which focus on the impact of the global
markets. Yergin and Stanislaw (1998), in a cross-country analysis of the
changing role of government and the marketplace, have argued that while
central planning and direct service delivery by governments has declined,
other government roles such as creating and maintaining markets, addressing
social “safety net” issues, maintaining trust in government, and ensuring re-
sponses reflect national differences and values have become more important.
George Soros (1998) in a useful study of global financial markets argues that
the failure of governments to regulate these markets and to manage the im-
pacts on nations is a major impediment to the operation of global markets.
In our opinion, the case for external causes is compelling. Assuming that
changing external pressures are the underlying causes of the government crises
does not mean that reform can ignore internal factors and the interaction of
external factors with governability. A number of authors have addressed the
impact of these wider changes on governability. Drucker (1993) explores these
restraints on governments in a penetrating analysis of national structures and
political processes. John Kenneth Galbraith (1992) in an insightful, if depress-
ing, examination of the politics of contentment, explores much the same prob-
lem. If these authors are correct, it follows that the solutions to the current crisis
must also find new ways to manage diversity and, where these cannot be found,
redefine the role of government to fit these new realities.
The cause of governability problems can also be related to the failure of
governments to address changes in their traditional role and to the institution-
alized and centralized strategies used to manage consensus. In part, the re-
forms proposed by Osborne and Gaebler (1993) recognize the negative impacts
of these traditional approaches. This analysis suggests that old frameworks
for government management, which seek to eliminate diversity, have exacer-
bated the problem.
14 GOVERNMENT IN CRISES
What are the implications of this discussion of causation for our analysis
of government transitions? We believe that the current crisis has been caused
by the inability of traditional government roles and management to respond
to new pressures for global competitiveness and by the failure of governments
to manage effectively the pressures generated by entrenched interest groups
which resist change and slow a nation’s capacity to respond.
It follows that our analysis of the crisis in government management
needs to start by examining external pressures and the strategic fit between
these pressures and the role and management systems used by government.
We need to move beyond the impediments to change discussed by Drucker
and Galbraith and, in the process, develop management tools to manage the
impacts of change. Although government reform needs to address these ex-
ternal changes directly, most government reform remains inwardly focused.
Reform programs, which seek to put the government house in order without
recognizing that the house is burning down, or is at least in the midst of a
major externally induced crisis, seem bound to fail.
We have explored the changing role of governments and the external pres-
sures that governments must address. We have suggested that a key cause of
the crisis in government management is that government responses to exter-
nal pressures have been inadequate. We now examine the measurement of
national competitiveness and government competitiveness and address the
reality that some government are responding more effectively than others.
Exhibit 1.2. National Competitiveness—The Role of Government in Se-
lected Countries compares evaluations for selected countries on the basis of
national competitiveness and the contribution of governments to national
competitiveness. A number of differences between countries can be identified
from these data. Most countries that rank low on the contribution of govern-
ment policies to competition also rank low on overall national competitive-
ness, for example, Indonesia, India, Korea, Columbia, Turkey, Czech Republic,
Government in Crises 15
80
Taiwan ◆ Canada ◆
Finland
Spain ◆ Iceland ◆
China USA ◆
◆
◆
◆
Thailand ◆U.K.
60 ◆ Netherlands
◆ Philippines Norway
◆ Denmark
◆ Japan
Portugal Austria ◆
Brazil ◆
◆ Hungary
◆
Mexico ◆
40 ◆Israel
South Africa Argentina ◆ ◆Germany
◆
◆
◆Indonesia India
◆ Korea ◆ Greece
20 ◆ Colombia
◆ Sweden
Turkey France ◆
◆
◆ Czech Rep.
◆ Poland Belgium ◆
◆ Russia ◆ Italy
0 ▼ ◆ Slovenia
0 20 40 60 80 100
National competitiveness index—100 most competitive
Low national / government
competitiveness
Source: The World Competitiveness Yearbook (1999). Country ranks converted into a competi-
tiveness index with 100 being the most competitive country.
Note: The Yearbook ranks countries on overall country competitiveness and on a number of
factors including “government.” This points on the chart are the government factor and country
(national) competitiveness indices for each country.
Poland, Russia, and Slovenia. Most countries that rank high on national com-
petitiveness also rank high on the contribution of government policies, for
example, United States, Singapore, Finland, Luxembourg, Switzerland, Hong
Kong, Canada, Ireland, and Australia.
A number of countries rank high on government competitiveness but
obtain a lower ranking for national competitiveness, for example, Iceland,
Taiwan, New Zealand, Spain, Chile, Malaysia, and China.
Three conclusions can be drawn from this material. First, countries vary
widely in competitiveness and this is a measure of their success in exploiting
the external changes discussed earlier. Second, there is a relationship between
16 GOVERNMENT IN CRISES
Internationalization
Infrastructure
Management
Government
Finance
People
United States 1 0.0 1 1 15 1 1 1 1 6
Singapore 2 0.0 18 2 1 9 13 4 12 4
Finland 3 4.0 4 11 10 8 2 3 6 1
Luxembourg 4 1.1 3 3 7 2 15 12 20 10
Netherlands 5 0.9 7 6 18 3 7 2 8 12
Switzerland 6 0.0 8 26 4 4 10 15 3 9
Hong Kong 7 –0.8 36 5 2 7 19 5 22 14
Denmark 8 –0.5 10 12 22 5 9 11 9 2
Germany 9 –1.0 11 7 31 6 6 18 4 20
Canada 10 0.8 12 24 12 11 8 8 13 7
Ireland 11 3.3 2 8 5 16 23 7 11 21
Australia 12 1.4 16 28 8 10 4 16 16 11
Norway 13 –0.6 9 25 20 19 3 19 17 5
Sweden 14 –0.7 27 15 39 13 5 6 6 17
United Kingdom 15 0.7 26 4 19 12 17 20 14 24
Japan 16 –3.8 29 21 23 25 20 26 2 13
Source: Rankings from The World Competitiveness Yearbook 1999, IMD: Geneva 1999.
Note: Factor rankings in bold are potential strengths. Factor rankings in italics are potential
weaknesses. Average variation is the average reduction in rank (increase in competitiveness)
1995–1999.
Cullen showed that OECD education data and The World Competitive-
ness Yearbook competitiveness data can be combined to benchmark the per-
formance of Australia’s nations educational and training system. Exhibit 1.4.
Benchmarking Workskills and National Competitiveness repeats this analysis
using 1998 and 1999 data. The upper chart uses workskill rankings derived
from the proportion of the workforce who have completed secondary school,
obtained a major trade qualification, or obtained higher level qualifications.
The lower graph repeats the analysis using the proportion of the workforce
with degree or higher level qualifications. These results show a strong corre-
lation between country rankings based on qualification profiles and country
competitiveness. The relationship is strongest for the secondary school and
higher education profile which includes all those who complete school, a
trade qualification, or a degree program.
Three points should be noted in examining this analysis. First, most
examinations of national education and training systems examine inputs and
access. Some extend this to an examination of current flows through educa-
tion and training systems. Only a few studies examine the links with competi-
tiveness. Second, although the proportion of the workforce in different countries
with defined levels of minimum educational qualifications is an imperfect
measure of workskills, a number of studies suggest that these measures pro-
vide a useful comparative measure. Third, the analysis suggests that these
workskill measures impact on competitiveness by differentiating countries
rather than through absolute inputs to production functions. Cullen extends
this by suggesting that differentiation is likely to be hierarchical with coun-
tries first being differentiated on the bases of secondary school profiles and
then on the basis of higher level qualifications. Finally, to be useful, bench-
marks need to shorten the cycle time between education and training deci-
sions and outcomes in terms of competitiveness. One way to do this is to
project future qualification stocks on the basis of existing education policies.
OECD projections provide a sound staring point for such benchmarking.
Our purpose in raising this analysis is not to explore the complex issues
which underpin this analysis but to illustrate the use of available international
data to benchmark government contributions to national performance. Al-
though education and training programs are only one link that determine
competitiveness, a simple examination of country differences and the impact
of existing policies on future qualification can provide key options for a
country to add value to workskills.
The objective is not to manage a shift in qualifications in isolation but to
manage a country’s profile against projected shifts for competitors. The pri-
orities for each country are different. They depend on the existing skill base,
education and training outputs, and on a study of the likely competitiveness
impact of the education and training policies of competitors.
• The challenge for the United States is not that other countries will pass
historically high U.S. secondary school qualification profiles, but that
they will catch up and neutralize a source of competitive advantage.
20 GOVERNMENT IN CRISES
The challenge for the United States is not only to ensure that as other
countries match U.S. profiles, the United States maintains an advan-
tage by improving the quality and relevance of qualification, but also
that higher level profiles remain ahead of others and that retraining is
responsive and competitive.
projects. The time delay between the approval of a change and the delivery
of results (implementation cycle time) is not managed directly and in times
of cut backs in resources tends to increase rather than decrease.
There are three reasons why lengthening implementation cycle times
reduce the chances of successful implementation. First, increased cycle time
improves the scope for interest groups opposed to change, to emerge, and to
act. Governments, faced with major resistance to change, tend to move to
restore the capacity to govern by modifying the change. In the end, the
objective often becomes survival and the original objective of the change is
forgotten or seriously compromised. Second, increased cycle time increases
the chances that management attention and resources will be diverted to
address some new crisis before results have been delivered and communi-
cated effectively. Third, increasing cycle time increases the chances that the
external environment will change reducing or eliminating the core value of-
fered by the original solution.
The failure to deliver has led to almost continuous management and per-
sonnel changes in government. These changes, combined with ongoing budget
cut backs, have eroded the capacity of public administration to respond. Many
governments today need to rebuild management systems and to recognize that
a competitive nation requires a competitive government management system.
They must do this without access to the new growth opportunities which fueled
the post consolidation development of the business sector.
We now examine three set of solutions to the government crisis.
Cut back management addresses the need to balance the supply and
demand for resources. Many governments have responded by reducing the
size and impact of government. Although the process of rationalization was
needed in many countries, the process in government has often been driven
by budget imperatives combined with the need to remove the “dead hand of
government” from business in order to let business operate.
Cut back management is seldom successful in a vacuum. The process in
business was driven by the need to deliver profits and to create a new base
from which further development could emerge. The element which is missing
from many of these government management experiments is the new mission
which must be protected and nurtured as part of the process. In government,
cut back is often driven by budget shortfalls and an ideological position that
the solution to the government management crisis is to obscure the financial
deficit problem in a flurry of short-term actions rather than to fix the under-
lying management deficit which caused the problem in the first place.
Devolution addresses the need to provide managers with the scope to
govern. Reform of management structures usually involves deregulation of
traditional input controls over personnel and line item budgets and the use of
business solutions to structures, systems, and management skills. However,
Government in Crises 23
the customer not the bureaucracy, earning rather than spending, prevention
rather than cure, from hierarchy to participation and teamwork, and leverag-
ing change through the market.
These ideas have led to solutions which are a major improvement on
previous attempts to improve the performance of government. As practitio-
ners explore problems with a new found freedom to solve them, more ex-
amples will emerge. The new-style reforms provide a new focus for the grass
roots delivery of many functions and services. These reforms work because
they introduce new approaches to the delivery, shorten the traditional value-
chain, deregulate government activities, and seek to develop new approaches
to resource management, evaluation, and accountability.
However, these approaches are as yet dangerously incomplete? In seek-
ing to build on current changes and address some of the weaknesses which
seem to be emerging, our analysis suggests that a number of gaps remain to
be recognized and explored.
Competitiveness
First, new approaches to managing the links between grass roots reform and
adding value to national competitiveness have not yet developed. Many of the
reforms are clearly applicable to the delivery of grass roots services to cus-
tomers. These new approaches need to balance short- and long-term interests
and meet short-term needs within a framework of priorities which builds
future wealth and manages national transitions to protect national interests.
Long-Term Value
Second, the links between one-off changes and long-term added value need
to be further considered. The criteria for managing both performance and
public expectations of performance remain vague in many of the cases ex-
plored. The assumption seems to be that performance once restored will be
driven by a new focus on customers and services. This seldom occurs. An
effective basis for the ongoing evaluation of change and for addressing the
inevitable failures needs to be identified and implemented.
Allocative Tension
Third, strategies for managing allocative tension where agencies are not self-
funding cannot be solved by the new micro-reform agenda. These problems
are compounded by budget cut backs. While some important ideas are ad-
vanced, this is an area which can subsume governments and cause major
uncertainties.
Government in Crises 25
Implementation
Fourth, although the management of implementation is often as important as
the solutions, current prescriptions tend to assume that deregulation and a
customer focus will provide the focus to correct this problem. The need to
manage the impact of change on various interest groups is only partly ad-
dressed by current reform processes. There are two problems with this as-
sumption. The need to devolve the responsibility for managing external
implementation impacts is assumed to be addressed by devolution. Where the
customers are the major interest group, this is likely to occur. However, where
there are different impacts on different interest groups, new tools are required
to focus management on the delivery of specific impacts. In addition, the
need to use devolution to reduce cycle time or the time it takes government
to recognize a need and address it is not explored.
address the reality that traditional systems of government have broken down.
There is no simple incremental solution for most government management
systems; they must implement a new management base which meets the
needs of all national stakeholders. If they do not, national competitiveness
will suffer and the well-being of citizens, if not actually eroded, will suffer
compared with nations who elect to be competitive.
There are two implications of our analysis for the reform of government
management. First, governments need to refocus reform from internal to
external factors. Second, governments need to ensure that internal reforms
deliver reduced cycle time (speed), maintain the scope to govern and address
impacts on diverse interest groups (consensus), and deliver expected results
(performance).
The idea of consensus and enthusiasm for government changes is both coun-
terproductive and unnecessary. In reality, government seeks to maintain a
comfort zone within which interest groups and the public allow government
to govern. This approach requires government to find new ways of both
planning strategic priorities and managing the impacts of projects throughout
the project cycle.
Performance: Many changes have not delivered grass roots impacts.
Many government management systems manage processes or functions and
assume that long-term added value is delivered. Few processes manage short-
term impacts unless a crisis emerges which must be addressed. We argue first
that the focus of reform must be to enable managers to manage performance
directly, and second, that the time horizon of these evaluations must be short-
ened rather than extended.
dismantle old systems and replace these with new strategies and management
tools which can manage the future.
Governments are in the midst of a more fundamental change than many
realize. They are navigating a turning point which is every bit as challenging
as that confronted by business. In many respects, they are navigating with a
combination of traditional tools which are clearly broken and with tools
borrowed from business which only address part of the government manage-
ment problem.
In this chapter, we have described the new form of government manage-
ment which is developing as competitive government. Many government
management systems have no option but to “jump the curve.” If they hold
back they will lurch from crisis to crisis. Worse, their nation’s share of global
resources will be cut as governments and nations better able to exploit new
global realities outperform them. Nor do governments really have the luxury
of changing at their own pace. Whether they understand it or not, they are
competing with other nations and governments. And some of these competi-
tors are already off and running.
Our discussion of the transition to competitive government is divided
into three parts. Part 1 discusses changing ideas about government and devel-
ops a vision to guide government reform.
Part 2 examines the challenge of translating these ideas into action. Al-
most all the core systems of government are being reinvented. The process
must be coordinated and the new solution must be comprehensive. To suc-
ceed, the implications of these changes must be understood by government
managers and by the communities they impact.
Part 3 examines the need to translate these visions and strategies into a
specific government transition to competitive government. Governments have
learned to manage individual change projects. The challenge for many is to
mange sequential interrelationships between these projects to maximize added
value and implement a transition. This transition must respond to the external
and internal pressures facing the government of a specific nation, it must
chart a realistic course between the current and future performance of a
government, and it must be benchmarked to enable government to navigate
through turbulent seas.
Part I
33
34 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
ness, the context is different. In particular, government leaders, far more than
their business counterparts, must seek solutions which also maintain the scope
to govern by managing the impact of change on diverse interest groups.
Chapter 6 explains the leadership strategies, tools, and evaluation procedures
employed by two successful but different real time transitions to national
competitiveness. We explore Singapore’s transition from a centrally planned
to a strategically managed government. Next, we explore the U.S. government’s
attempt to make a transition from a decentralized control to a strategically
managed government.
Chapter 2
37
38 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
deliver improved performance. Assuming the proposal seems viable, the pri-
mary focus shifts to examining the policy implications of agreeing. What
would be the impact on existing policies? How many other groups and busi-
nesses would claim similar treatments? How could flow on applications be
refused without appearing to discriminate in favor of the current project?
How might the proposal be funded? Can it be funded from hidden sources or
slack in existing approved programs? If the proposal must compete with other
proposals for a share of new funding, how can this be managed? How will
government handle the threat this poses to other existing projects and other new
projects? Who might sponsor the proposal in government? Who would be
likely to oppose the proposal in government? In addition, the government
manager must address the possibility of failure and the reality that this will be
treated far more seriously by the media and the public than success. Finally, the
government manager must examine the overall impact on comfort zones.
For the government manager, the value of the project is not the dominant
consideration. Even when the project has high value, these other consider-
ations raise difficult issues which take time to resolve. The business manager
seldom has time. There are markets to service, competitors to address. The
business manager sees government inaction and concludes that government
does not understand business, that government processes are inefficient and
almost certainly wasteful. The government manager, assuming that he or she
has not been desensitized, senses this frustration but sees the problem in
terms of the business manager not understanding or caring about the prob-
lems government must address.
To the government manager, the business manager seems impatient and
only interested in achieving a gain for his or her shareholders at the possible
expense of others. Although success for the government manager involves
spending the allocated funds, the real focus of evaluation is usually whether
program decisions are seen to have created trouble for government or at-
tracted public criticism.
A number of strategies can be used to remove or clear these blockages.
First, improve communications directly; ensure that business managers, seek-
ing access to government funding, understand the risks government takes
whenever it discriminates in favor of one option over another; and make
working with business to create a world competitive industrial base a key
success criterion for government managers. Second, improve understanding
by locating within business people who understand government and by locat-
ing within government people who understand business. Third, distance gov-
ernments from the allocation process by developing autonomous entities
charged with the mission of adding value to industrial competitiveness. Fourth,
provide less time for negative reactions to develop and seek to match the
decision cycles of business and government, by shortening government cycle
time for the approval and delivery of such assistance.
Lessons from Business 41
A COMPARISON OF BUSINESS
AND GOVERNMENT DEVELOPMENT
Regardless of how many times and how loudly those who have
not tried it assert the contrary, running a government bureau-
cracy is not the same as running a business.
—Downs and Larkey, The Search for Government Efficiency
Over the last half-century, both private and public sector organizations have
moved through a cycle of changes. Exhibit 2.2. A Comparison of Business
and Government Development Cycles suggests that both business and gov-
ernment have moved through a cycle which started with bureaucratic man-
agement, and was followed by market driven expansion, which inevitably led
to periods of rationalization followed by a period of consolidation and growth
which focused not only on core markets and strengths but also on global
trends and the actions of competitors. The similarities support those who seek
to apply business solutions to government. However, government and busi-
ness faced different challenges.
The bureaucratic starting point is not surprising. Initially, the bureau-
cratic solution was the only management option which allowed business and
government to harness the benefits of specialization (Morgan 1986). For gov-
ernment, the rule-driven predictability and contained power used by the bu-
reaucratic model to coordinate activities, offered additional value (Imparato
and Harari 1994).
Both sectors experienced a growth phase which led to over extension. In
the case of business organizations, growth dispersed core strengths and weak-
ened their capacity to respond to more demanding market conditions when
these occurred. In the case of government, access to revenue growth, which
grew almost independent of government activity, allowed governments to
purchase popularity by responding to one need after another. In the end, the
mix of activities undertaken by many governments proved to be both
unfundable and unmanageable.
Rationalization was an inevitable consequence for both sectors. The pro-
cess came a decade earlier for business because of the direct links between
markets and funding. The government funding crisis was delayed as govern-
ments deferred the need to bring budgets into balance. As a consequence,
when the correction finally came for government, it was somewhat deeper. In
addition, many governments addressed the symptoms, the need to balance
budgets, rather than the causes, the need to rationalize function and rethink
the role and priorities of government in a global economy.
The business rationalization cycle was keyed into regrouping around core
strengths and exploiting new growth opportunities. Business after business
divested unwanted business and set about exploiting new opportunities.
42 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Governments tended to see the crisis and the need to rationalize as a long-
term diminution of their role and relevance. Governments experience difficulty
abandoning areas unless there are obvious alternative sources of service. Gov-
ernments experience difficulty managing the allocative tensions unleashed when
a system designed to allocate growth attempts to allocate reductions.
Lessons from Business 43
By failing to identify the new changes and develop new roles, many
governments missed important opportunities to use cut backs to build for the
future. The assumption that services could only be delivered in traditional
ways led some governments to miss important opportunities to reinvent de-
livery structures. Managing reductions without a coherent view of the future
has sapped the morale of many government managers and has led the public
and business to undervalue the future role which government must play if
nations are to succeed.
Management Responses
Management by Objectives
The movement to management by objectives (MBO) conceptualized by Peter
Drucker in the 1950s (Drucker 1954) enabled business to halt the process of
over specialization and focus outwards to respond to a changing external envi-
ronment. There are two quite different reasons why MBO systems broke down
in business. First, many MBO systems became institutionalized. Managers
abdicated their strategic leadership role to hierarchical systems which distilled
and segmented objectives. Rationalization forced many businesses to slash these
hierarchical management systems, devolve accountability to business units, and
evaluate the performance of these units strategically by setting demanding
44 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
High-Response Management
External pressures on both business and government are forcing organizations
to shorten cycle time. Shorter cycle times require an increased focus on the
Lessons from Business 45
A VISION
Goals • Focused, opportunity driven, • Complex, problem driven, internally linked, subject to ongoing
externally linked, hierarchical adjustments as government responds to interest group pressures
Governability • Shareholder control exercised • Consensus and diversity driven, governments operate within a comfort
through directors and key managers zone and adjust implementation priorities to achieve this
TO
Planning and • Plans are a general mandate for • Plans focus on long-term government objectives
criteria that are more complex than those addressed by business. The success
criteria for government organizations are more complex. Measurement is often
difficult. Objectives tend to span each of the three missions of government:
competitiveness, social value, and governance.
49
which defer evaluation.
50 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
systems have not. Traditional government system managed inputs and some-
times the input conversion process. The presumption was that the perfor-
mance of the whole was a measure of the performance of all the parts.
Ideas about effective government are shifting. Traditional government
sought to manage through rules and funding allocations within which ser-
vices are not only regulated and provided, but also society’s problems are
somehow resolved by more government spending. Competitive government
seeks to be a catalyst for change, to work with other parts of a society to
improve national competitiveness, to address emerging social challenges, and
to maintain the scope to govern.
To deliver this change, business / government roles need to shift from gov-
ernment as a provider of support services and subsidies to government as a
partner in the change process. The new challenge is how the leveraging of busi-
ness and government resources and skills improve national competitiveness.
The resource management challenge has shifted from raising revenue to
ensuring that growth is allocated to areas of priority in order to reduce expen-
diture, to match global competitors, to reduce traditional expenditure levels
and change priorities, and to address new social values and priorities. Allo-
cating reductions rather than growth is a challenge for government systems
which seldom cost transactions or results. The solution is to shift to results-
based budgets and to identify the real cost of government transactions. This
transition is perhaps the most demanding aspect facing governments seeking
to remain competitive.
Government management is shifting from fixed cycle times supported by
segmented functions and queues which often extend in times of cut back to
flexible cycle times supported by task-based value-chains which can be man-
aged by agencies. The key to many of these changes is to decentralize re-
source management, to encourage agencies to raise revenue as well as spend
it, and to use project mandates to negotiate the scope required to deliver key
change results.
Finally, the communication task in government needs to shift from claim-
ing the credit for successes and obscuring the responsibility for failures to
assisting government to deliver results and manage impacts in order to deliver
a public perception that changes have added value.
Performance Management
We have discussed the changes in business management which have assisted
business to respond to external change. Much of the rationalization of the
1980s can be seen as providing business organizations with a new focus not
only on markets, and on changing value-chains, but also to focus on the
delivery of product to market.
Lessons from Business 51
Objectives
Cycle Impacts
Second, the time span of evaluation is reduced by managing short-term cycle
impacts. Performance-based planning systems translate objectives into specific
short-run impacts which can be monitored and evaluated. The idea of fore-
casting and monitoring short-term impacts is relatively rare in government.
Reform usually manages either the big picture or inputs.
Evaluation
Third, evaluation starts with impacts and then moves to examine the conse-
quences for strategies and long-term objectives.
52 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Support Objectives:
What are the key support activities which the unit must address in order to meet the
core objectives?
What specific contribution is required? What is the likely impact on key objectives of
failing to deliver the support activity?
What impacts are expected over one, two, or three years?
In the case of national government, the support objectives relate to the functions
managed by government: business services and infrastructure; community services
and infrastructure; market access and regulation; taxes and tariffs; checks and bal-
ances; workskills and access to employment; government business leverage; and re-
source balance.
Impacts include government functions seen to be competitive relative to selected
benchmark countries and seen to be supporting rather than retarding key transitions.
General Management:
What are the general management functions required to support effective change?
What is the strategic fit between these priorities and the structures systems and staffing
available to the unit?
What is the agenda for change?
What specific contributions are required to the delivery of core objectives?
What improvements are expected over the next one, two, or three years?
How will these impact the delivery of core objectives?
In the case of national government, the general management functions are defined
as: strategic leadership; cycle-focused management and communications; performance
management; comfort zone management; and results driven resource management.
Impacts include the removal of management systems which are unable to manage
change, the successful introduction of specific management reforms, and the coordi-
nation of the timing of these reforms with the requirements of a particular national
transition.
Lessons from Business 53
Ronald C. Moe (2000) argues that the emphasis on autonomy and results can
conflict with the role of the legislature and the rule of law. It seems to us that,
while Moe is right to identify the weakness in control and the impact on the
traditional role of the legislature in the U.S. reforms, he is wrong to assume
that the needs of the legislature necessarily conflict with the emphasis on
impacts and results. The rhetoric about results often obscures a reduced
emphasis on strategic results and a reduced accountability to both the legis-
lature and the executive. The problem flows from attempting to use business
management modes without working through ideas about performance.
The conflict between the freedom to manage and deliver results and the
rule of law depends on how results are defined, who defines them, and whether
the interface between the legislature and the executive are treated as a battle-
field or as part of the reform process. In the end, both the legislature and
executive government managers are interested in defining and achieving results.
Both are part of the process of managing impacts on various interest groups.
Later chapters of this book will examine new solutions for the reform of
government management in detail. The objective of this chapter is to review
some of the ideas about business and government management which under-
pin our analysis. Several important lessons for public sector reform can be
drawn from this analysis.
First, while governments can learn from business, they cannot be man-
aged as a business. Business managers are perhaps a decade ahead of govern-
ment in addressing the need to rationalize and respond to new global realities.
However, there are important differences between the way in which business
organizations and governments manage. These differences become more
important when roles are changing and government is seeking to adopt ap-
proaches and systems for the management of change which have been devel-
oped by business.
Second, governments can learn from business how to move the focus
of management from internal to external realities. Traditionally, government
management reform addressed the internal symptoms of breakdowns by
fine tuning processes, structures, and roles. Management reform needs to
start with an analysis of external change and the changing role of govern-
ment instead of assuming that this is either static or that it can emerge from
54 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
55
56 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
HIGH RESPONSE
Strategic Management
ss
Re or t- l lon
ern by ene
Sh ntro lity
ge
ate s
co xibi
lim mpe al fo
an
fle
gic
ch
Co tern
al
Ex
str r m
SS
ate
NE
gic
VE
MA ency s
s
su ited titiv cus
NA
b-u by en
Sy a pt
ici ive de
ET
lim pe t fo
ma exc
us
GE
by
De
MP
foc
i
Co b-un
ME
vo
CO
nit
m
lve
NT
Su
e
d
co
tra
ntr
ns
Regulated transition
ol, tha it au
itio
ss
De lf-co l fra rs su
Se ntro elive omy
slo ited titiv us
w r by ene
vo ntr me b-
lim mpeal foc
o d on
e
lut ol wo
un
ns
ion
po
Co tern
es
t
In
Development transition
Deregulated transition rk
tems have been painfully slow to respond to even simple new needs. Re-
sponses, when they do occur, tend to be bound by past assumptions and
precedents.
We argue that there are powerful systemic reasons why governments
have been slow to respond. Much government reform remains focused on
second order issues such as efficiency, budget balancing, and accountability.
Many government reforms are designed independently. This segmentation
often acts to restrain rather than support competitiveness.
Also, the implications of national competitiveness transitions for govern-
ment differ depending on the starting point. Moving from high-production to
high-response requires planning and regulation to shift from an internal focus
to an external focus. Moving from high-autonomy to high-response requires
an increase in strategic planning to focus national resources on external is-
sues. Both transitions impact on the comfort zones which enable governments
to govern as do attempts to postpone change which also threaten national
wealth and a nation’s capacity to resource its development and value system.
Four transitions are shown in Exhibit 3.1.
A development transition, which seeks to build competitive production
capacity and uses this as a base for managing a transition to competitiveness
through high-response, is to the left and upward on Exhibit 3.1. Although
each has chosen a very different government response, Japan and Singapore
are examples of countries embarked on this type of transition.
A deregulated transition, based on the development of competitiveness
through high-response by deregulating and introducing market forces to vari-
ous centrally planned economies, is to the right and upward on Exhibit 3.1.
The changes in Eastern Europe are examples of this transition. Within the
former eastern bloc countries, governments have chosen different responses
and some countries have been far more successful than others.
A regulated transition, which is based on the belief that external mar-
kets are best exploited by competitive businesses operating in a relatively
regulated internal environment, is a vertical transition on Exhibit 3.1. Regu-
lation strategies address internal market access, value system, equity issues,
and are developed to accommodate differences and competition. The Euro-
pean community reforms are an example of this type of transition. Within this
community the role of companies, nations, and governments are shifting.
A devolved transition, which is based on devolution and the empower-
ment of subunits, is an upward transition from the high-autonomy position on
Exhibit 3.1. The United States has followed this transition successfully in
recent years. Preconditions for the success of this strategy include: strong and
effective subunits; a degree of shared interest between those units and the
national interest; and systems of values and regulation that ensure a degree
of transparency and embrace competition as a non-negotiable value.
60 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Competitiveness
The competitiveness variable refers to the key strategies used by a nation to
deliver competitiveness. These range from the low-cost, high-efficiency pro-
duction strategies for competitiveness, which characterizes the high-production
mode to the reliance on subunit performance, which characterizes the high-
autonomy mode to the external focus and high-response strategies, which
characterizes the high-response mode.
The transition from production priorities toward subunit autonomy is a
well-documented transition for business seeking to respond to complexity.
Increasingly highly centralized government systems are also breaking down.
The challenge for government management is first to ensure that enterprises
are provided with a competitive environment and second that those busi-
nesses contribute national value as well as business value.
The transition from high-autonomy to high-response solutions requires a
capacity for strategic interaction between business and government. This
capacity is weakened by some transitions to high-autonomy management.
From a management viewpoint, the difficulty with high-autonomy solutions
is often to be found in the processes prescribed to deliver autonomy. Where
these processes are driven by the view that the key to autonomy is uniform
government responses supported by market processes, the capacity of govern-
ment to address change and to manage the challenges presented by diversity
can be seriously eroded.
Government
Government must develop three strategies to support transitions: a competi-
tiveness strategy, a social value strategy, and a governability strategy. Any one
The Management of Transitions to National Competitiveness 61
Management
Management refers to the way in which a nation coordinates the performance
of a subunit to deliver national objectives. Management strategies range from
the low-power management by self-control strategies of the high-autonomy
mode to the management by exception techniques, which characterizes the
high-production mode to the strategic management by results approach re-
quired to support the high-response model.
62 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
High-Response
High-response government monitors respond to external changes. The objec-
tive is to position a nation in order to exploit external opportunities and
optimize national benefits. The high-response mode focuses on generating
wealth by exploiting external opportunities. In order to respond strategically
and to shorten cycle times, nations must trade-off some production efficiency
and some autonomy.
The government focus is on flexible business government relations that
support external competitiveness and on strategies to maintain comfort zones
by addressing change impacts and ensuring that social as well as economic
value is added as competitiveness increases.
The challenge for government is first to reform old systems and reduce
cycle times to remove restraints on business performance and then to move
beyond this stage to add value to that performance. The flexibility required to
provide strong leadership on selected issues, while providing business with the
scope to address many other issues, reduces certainty about government roles
and impacts. The challenge for government reform is to develop management
systems which can add value while also maintaining support for change.
The high-response management focus is external and strategic. Manage-
ment systems need to provide short-run control without reducing the need for
longer-term flexibility. Management needs to understand short-run cycle
impacts on diverse groups and manage them effectively.
High-Production
The high-production mode seeks competitiveness through low cost produc-
tion and access to markets. This involves trade-offs with both autonomy and
response. Autonomy needs to be limited by the needs of production processes.
Responses to external changes need to be limited to protect core production
technologies and performance.
The Management of Transitions to National Competitiveness 63
High-Autonomy
The high-autonomy mode optimizes the autonomy of subunits and relies on
these units to adapt, respond, and deliver wealth. To fully exploit this mode,
nations must trade-off both efficiency and response.
The high-autonomy model works spectacularly well, and the trade-offs
are limited, when there is an effective fit between the priorities of subunits
and of the nation. However, attempts to alter the priorities of subunits tend to
be seen as eroding autonomy and are often resisted. The challenge is to gain
the benefits of high-autonomy within a framework of priorities which can
coordinate effective responses.
The government focus is on providing infrastructure and services and
providing a regulatory framework, which defines and protects autonomy.
Equality of treatment between citizens and companies is usually a value
which underpins the operation of high-autonomy systems. The national man-
agement focus is on deregulation and devolution and assumes that subunits
will deliver. Within major business units the management focus is often high-
response and strategic. However, business units need to work within a frame-
work which protects overall high-autonomy values.
Development Transition
Transition to High-Response
The second part of the development transition, the transition from high-
production to high-response, is critical to maintaining the benefits of produc-
tion and to continuing the process of wealth creation. The Competitiveness
Model suggests that the high-response part of this transition requires a rever-
sal, or more properly a major shift in the role of government. The Model also
suggests that high-response will involve some trade-off of production efficiency
for response. The production to high-response transition needs to focus on
external opportunities and on the flexibility to exploit them. Change strategies
to support this transition need to address four issues.
First, the change process is driven by the benefits of competitiveness and
wealth creation. There are four major threats. Significant interest groups may
opt for autonomy rather than competitiveness. Government, finding the short-
term centralized role required to develop and coordinate initial production
strengths attractive, may fail to recognize that this role must change to sup-
port the transition to the high response mode. Business may conclude that
production equates with competitiveness and that the management styles
required to improve production can also deliver competitiveness. Finally, the
process of devolution could erode the strategic focus required to ensure that
a nation with limited resources can achieve world competitiveness in selected
industries. Any of these threats can decrease competitiveness quite rapidly
and erode the capacity of the nation to deliver the public benefits which are
required to underpin ongoing development.
Second, governments often coordinate priorities in the high-production
mode. The move to high-response usually devolves to business units much of
the responsibility for scanning the environment and responding to new needs.
However, devolution will only produce long-term gains if the public interest
as well as private interests are met.
Third, governments need to ensure that the impacts of change and wealth
creation on social value are managed effectively. Old systems of income
distribution and safety nets are unlikely to prove adequate.
Fourth, governance depends upon the capacity of a government to mange
comfort zones. We will discuss later the complexity of these zones but clearly
government must address both internal and external comfort zones. Tensions
between internal and external comfort zones must be managed for the devel-
opment transition to succeed.
model that buffered external forces and focused internal development, built
large efficient companies with clear competitive advantages, and then used
those companies to access world markets.
Japanese Transition
Japan has used a development model to achieve many of the characteristics
of the high-production mode and then has developed high-response through
networks of multinational companies. The Japanese development model has
been discussed by many authors and from many viewpoints—see, for ex-
ample, Robert Christopher (1983), Aron Viner (1988), Jim Powell (1989), and
Eisuke Sakakibasa (1993).
The Japanese transition to high-response, while progressing, is encoun-
tering difficulties. The overall competitiveness index after outperforming most
nations for a decade is now in decline.
The ranking for the government factor graphed in Exhibit 1.3 is rela-
tively low and is also declining. Government in Japan has been slow to
recognize and respond to threats to competitiveness and to address emerging
social needs. This low ranking for government in part reflects the smaller role
of government and perhaps depreciates the importance of the business gov-
ernment interface in the Japanese system.
The Japanese transition includes some interesting and very effective
government/business roles. In particular, major companies provide some of
the services and comfort zone management provided by governments in other
models. The large multinational companies and clusters, which must deliver
high-response in the Japanese model, have encountered difficulties maintain-
ing their momentum. While this has allowed the scope of Japanese govern-
ments to remain more focused, these structures are now coming under some
pressure. Whether they can adapt to meet the needs of the high-response
mode seems a critical issue for the Japanese transition. Pressures to open
previously closed parts of the Japanese economy are likely to continue and
place further pressures on comfort zones. Peter Drucker (1999) suggests that
the Japanese system faces major problems in making the transition to self
management because of the dominant role assumed by companies in provid-
ing lifetime employment which he describes as organzied immobility. Drucker
argues that, in a world driven by knowledge values, companies will increas-
ingly be unable to deliver this traditional role.
Singaporean Transition
Singapore’s transition presents a simpler and interesting variation on this model.
We discuss the Singapore transition in more detail in chapter 6. Our analysis
68 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
The conflicts between external and internal comfort zones in Japan are
less obvious, because the external comfort zones tend to be internalized via
the Japanese multinational corporations. However, the tensions between these
companies driven by world markets and the requirements of the Japanese
domestic economy are growing. Restoring Japan’s competitiveness will re-
quire many reforms but most importantly it will require a new role for gov-
ernment that has yet to emerge.
Singapore, the Asian country which focused most on managing the con-
gruence of internal and external comfort zones has performed well through-
out this crises. Singapore already meets many of the external criteria now
being applied to its neighbors. Singapore has also developed a style of gov-
ernment which integrates national objectives with the objectives of multina-
tional companies effectively.
Finally, the analysis suggests that adopting the forms of government
management that work in developed economies is no solution for many of
these developing countries. The challenges facing these governments are dif-
ferent; government must manage a production to high-response transition;
and, to succeed, government must access ongoing growth rather than simply
protect a high-historical wealth base.
Deregulated Transition
Regulated Transition
EC Transitions
The Western European experience provides interesting examples of attempts to
pursue this type of transition. The Western European transition is both diverse
in the sense that different nations within the EC are embarked on different
transitions, and incomplete in the sense that major changes are still underway.
Many articles provide a contemporary view of these changes, see, for example,
The Economist (1993) and (1994). Ole Borre and Elnore Scarebrough (1995)
explore the implications of these transitions for government.
The Western European experience is characterized by a tradition of cen-
tral government and planning, and by attempts to maintain the more tradi-
The Management of Transitions to National Competitiveness 73
tional role for government. While the role of national governments is chang-
ing, many of the traditional government roles are simply shifting to the Eu-
ropean Community (EC) level. The development strategy has been to buffer
national economies from external, particularly non-EC forces and to develop
consensus through central planning while reducing national barriers. Like the
development transition discussed earlier, the transition sought is to the left
and upwards on the model, at least at the overall EC level.
There are parallels and differences with the development-based transi-
tions discussed earlier. The aim of development is similar; however, the focus
for subunit development is different. In the European model, the focus is at
least in part national rather than industry-based. The issues of consensus
management and comfort zone management, which must be addressed to
manage such a transition, are clearly more difficult than for the various Asian
development models.
The model can also be applied to particular nations within the EC. Ex-
pansion of markets and competition generated by opening up internal borders
offers major opportunities. Consensus at the national level tends to involve
government unions and business. The United Kingdom under Mrs. Thatcher
arguably severed many of these constraints and moved to a high-autonomy
model. Germany and France retained a centralized model. While the German
model appears to focus on a negotiated public sector—private sector inter-
face, the French model retains more of the characteristics of the traditional
government planning and regulatory model. In addition, the breakdown of
barriers to the Eastern European countries represents both a major opportu-
nity and a major threat to the transitional consensus process.
There are interesting issues raised by the United Kingdom transition. The
United Kingdom has a more international focus, and has sought to become
competitive at the cost of employment and various social services. It has
reduced the tripartite consensus model and has sought to enable companies
to access Europe and the global markets.
Devolved Transition
an increased role for both government and management both within and
across subunits.
This transition differs from the deregulated transition discussed earlier in
two important respects. Power already resides in devolved subunits. Also, the
devolved transition assumes that the system has already optimized production
processes around these devolved subunits. Change strategies to effect such a
transition need to address four quite different issues.
First, the process needs to be driven either by perceptions of crisis or
expectations of rewards. For example, the idea that unless there is change the
wealth base will erode is often used to build a sense of impending doom and
to establish support for the short-term sacrifices required to implement change.
The major threat is that significant interest groups will reject the reductions
in autonomy required, paralyze the change process, and erode the long-term
wealth and competitiveness of the nation. If this is allowed to occur, the
erosion of wealth can be expected to threaten governability.
Second, the role of government in the high-autonomy mode is to ensure
that citizens are treated equitably. Within this framework, the roles of govern-
ment and business are separate; business sets the development agenda while
government provides services and support for various parts of the economy.
The transition requires a shift in the role of government to a shared role with
business to deliver strategic impacts. This requires government to differenti-
ate between equals without creating so much uncertainty that progress cannot
occur. Differentiation can be either hidden or managed to contain its impact.
Where it is open, the task of government is to redraw the boundaries, to
ensure that one-off decisions do not destroy values and expectations across
the system.
Third, government needs to ensue that other impacts of change and wealth
creation on social value are managed effectively. Usually government must
manage this in the face of change which is seen to be eroding traditional
benefits and creating new reactivities and gaps in wealth distribution.
The Management of Transitions to National Competitiveness 75
and services, or the latter will not be coordinated with industry policies and
the need to access the global economy. However, recent improvements in
competitiveness suggest that the transition is occurring. The U.S. government
has experienced major comfort zone restraints. It is not surprising that the
reform of government has become a major priority to support the current
transition. The restoration of U.S. competitiveness is discussed in detail in
chapter 6.
79
80 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Exhibit 4.1. The Time Span and Focus of Evaluation in Business and
Government
FOCUS OF CONTROL
BUSINESS
GOVERNMENT
High
GOVERNMENT
BUSINESS
High
FOCUS OF CONTROL
Annual resource budgets Longer-term financial targets
82 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
are vague and usually nonexistent in the short term. Any focus on results is
long term. Popularity often replaces added value as the prime focus. Electoral
success is often seen to be a surrogate for the evaluation of results.
Shifts in the focus of government evaluation from the traditional inward
focus to an outward focus which addresses external impacts and from long
term to short term, are central to solving the implementation problems of
government. Implementation requires management strategies / tools which pro-
vide a focus on short-term impacts; it needs to provide government managers
with new flexibility to manage cycle time and cycle impacts. These reforms
are discussed in later chapters.
Our discussion of solutions addresses three different solutions, each of
which is supported by important management concepts and tools.
The first strategy, to manage impacts directly, examines the two types
of impacts discussed in chapter 1: competitiveness impacts and comfort zone
impacts. A key tool is the Impact Management Model (IIM), which explores
the interaction between impacts on both added value (competitiveness) and
comfort zones at the same time.
The second strategy, to manage cycle time directly, extends the idea of
impact management by applying it dynamically to the various cycle stages
which government projects traverse between the identification of a need for
change, the delivery of results, and the communication of those results to key
interest groups. We present a theory of the management of cycle dynamics in
government which explains many failures and explores related management
tools. We discuss three aspects of cycle time management in the government
sector: the need for more flexible project timing; the need to actively manage
project length; and the need to actively manage and sequence cycle impacts
to reduce the risk of implantation failure.
The third strategy, to develop cycle-focused communications changes
the way in which governments communicate change. We examine the impli-
cation of the theory of cycle dynamics on the way in which governments
communicate their plans and activities. Cycle-focused communications has
the capacity not only to alter the way in which government managers see their
external environment, but also to alter the way in which governments use
communications.
and the need for long-term flexibility. The implementation of change requires
new approaches to planning and to the management of grass roots impacts.
Chapter 8 presents an approach to planning which identifies impacts and links
them to longer-term results.
The successful implementation of change requires new approaches to the
management of grass roots impacts on both national competitiveness and on
the comfort zones which provide government with the scope to implement
change. Government administrative systems must manage both these types of
impacts at the same time. Solutions, which focus on one type of impact, for
example, electoral popularity, and ignore others are almost always counter-
productive.
The tools for ensuring that projects lead to operational outputs and real
added value constitute performance management. The tools for ensuring that
comfort zones are maintained and resistance to changes minimized constitute
comfort zone management. The keys to these new approaches to management
are more flexible approaches to planning, more effective management of
impacts and the management of cycle times to increase the speed of many
government responses.
Exhibit 4.2. The Implementation Impact Model summarizes an implemen-
tation model which can be used to map implementation performance. The
performance impact and comfort zone impact measures are shown on the ver-
tical and horizontal axis of Exhibit 4.2. The comfort zone within which gov-
ernments will be allowed to govern covers the indifference and support columns
in the center and right of Exhibit 4.2. The performance zone within which
governments can add value is defined by the high performance row at the top
of the grid.
Four zones identified in Exhibit 4.2, illustrate the combinations of per-
formance and comfort zone impacts: competitive government, performance at
any cost, popularity at any cost, and disaster. The model suggests that gov-
ernment administrators must manage both project performance and comfort
zones at the same time. The objective of a government management system
is assumed to be not only to manage impacts, but also to maintain projects
in both the positive performance zone and in the comfort zone (competitive
government zone).
The model focuses on the interaction between competitiveness impacts
and comfort zone impacts. This interaction is important during implementa-
tion and during the consolidation cycle when end perceptions of a government’s
performance are developed.
The model can be used to map the performance of different governments
and to identify the likely direction of consolidation. The idea that public
perceptions of performance consolidate after results have been delivered is
important. The model suggests that there is a lagged relationship between
84 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
COMFORT ZONE
High performance
COMPETITIVE GOVERMNENT
PERFORMANCE
Government manages both project performance
PERFORMANCE and comfort zone impacts at the same time to
AT ANY COST deliver high added value. while remaining
+
ZONE
within the comfort zone
Government seeks
PERFORMANCE IMPACT
to implement change
but fails to manage
Low performance
comfort zone
impacts. In the short
term, effectiveness
may be threatened by
0
Unsustainable
position
+ 0 –
Opposition Indifference Support
COMFORT ZONE IMPACT
added value and the comfort zone which will operate to consolidate govern-
ments towards the diagonal axis. While other factors such as poor communi-
cations or the overselling of expected benefits can disturb this simple rule, the
idea remains powerful and can be used to test government communication
strategies for consolidation.
both governments. Both were led by strong leaders, or, at least, by leaders not
well known for changing their minds. Both presided over increased national
competitiveness. Both left a legacy of underprivileged to be addressed by
their successors.
But there are also differences. The Thatcher administration clearly added
value to British competitiveness by deregulating the labor market, by using
privatization rather than tax increases to fund the business of government, and
by leveraging off Britain’s position within the European Community. While
the Thatcher years added value, they also failed to keep government in the
comfort zone. In part, this was a reaction to the growing gap between the rich
and poor. In part, this was a reaction to a perception that solutions were too
doctrinaire; they did not address the needs of interest groups beyond those
closely supporting one political party. In the end, the political rhetoric had
little relationship to the causes of increased competitiveness. Worse, the gov-
ernment came to believe its own rhetoric. If the poll tax had not forced a
change of direction, some other equally marginal idea would have. The end
point of the Thatcher administration can be positioned in sector one of Ex-
hibit 3.3. Interestingly, her successor inherited the popular recognition that
the government had performed and had to do little more than address comfort
zone issues more flexibly to win another term.
The Reagan administration presided over a gradual restoration of U.S.
competitiveness. This appears to have been driven by business more that
government although government certainly contributed. Government exposed
the economy to market pressures and reduced the role of the State but the
shift was less dramatic than in the United Kingdom where safety nets were
institutionalized. However, President Reagan understood how to maintain
comfort zones. He retired popular having added less value to national com-
petitiveness than Thatcher. The conclusion of the Reagan administration can
be mapped in sector four of Exhibit 3.3. Interestingly, President Bush, Reagan’s
successor, continued similar strategies but he lacked the skills to manage the
complex comfort zones which underpin government in the United States as
skillfully as his predecessor.
The changes which are underway are testing the internal consensus for change
in many countries and in many political systems. A key element of this model
of government is the need to develop and maintain the scope to govern. Both
Peter Drucker and John Kenneth Galbraith identify the problem. Drucker sees
the problem as the failure of political parties to deliver their traditional role
which was to transmute the pressures of minorities. Galbraith sees the prob-
lem in terms of the extension of privilege to the majority of the population
and to the desire of such groups to maintain their comfort zones. Whatever
the cause, there can be little doubt that much of the recent government reform
has either ignored governability or presumed that less government and more
efficient government will somehow restore trust in governments and the right
to govern.
88 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
principles for guiding action” in order for the parties to achieve “mutual
advantage.” The factors which generate advantage for one interest group are
usually different from the factors which create advantage for another. The
solution is not common commitment and a uniform focus, it is to understand
differences and develop processes which can negotiate impacts.
The techniques for managing comfort zones, including respect for differ-
ences, a focus on solutions offering specific value rather than common value,
and the management of project impacts on key interest groups, are central to
successful public sector management. Particularly where governance has
degenerated into a series of conflict-based negotiations, many interest groups
will seek to use change impacts from one project to negotiate unrelated benefits.
The task of governance structures and government managers is often to fence
off one set of impacts from other essentially unrelated negotiations.
Our examination of the task of managing comfort zone impacts reveals
the importance of managing both impacts and the sequence of impacts cre-
ated as government develops an idea and translates it into action. The impacts
at one stage of the government cycle are related to the impacts in previous
stages. This leads to the idea of cycle time management which offers pow-
erful management and communication strategies for maximizing performance
while minimizing negative comfort zone impacts.
Our analysis does not suggest that government managers are hostage to
the comfort zone but it does suggest that they must manage it more effec-
tively. Governments can both manage the boundaries of the comfort zone
directly and manage cycle impacts to improve the chances of successful
implementation. Government strategies for managing comfort zone impacts
vary for different stages of the government cycles.
Many government managers see their salvation in terms of new systems and
a new stability. They accept that the world is undergoing change but argue
that high response is not their responsibility. Yet this solution is illusory.
Buffers break down in times of rapid change. Even where government seeks
to reduce its role in order to maintain a buffer, the critical requirements of
government can seldom be ignored. Dhanabalan correctly points out that the
90 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Managing cycle timing and length addresses the tension between the
identification of some need for change and the time taken to deliver results
and to communicate the benefits of that change to key interest groups. Over-
all cycle time can be segmented into four sub-cycles which describe the
basic value-chain which governments must manage, for example, consen-
sus, legislative (and budget), implementation (delivery), and consolidation.
The strategic management of overall project timing and cycle length
requires managers to realign government value-chains, to reduce cycle time,
to enable projects to exploit external events, and to deliver benefits before
initial support erodes.
Business has learned that the timing of projects is critical to their suc-
cess. Speed to market is important because competitors threaten profitability.
In government, the market is ignored; competition is between interest groups
and with other projects. While speed and timing are also critical to success,
many government processes assume that projects should start when the nec-
essary legislative and budget approvals have been scheduled and obtained;
projects should proceed at a rate determined each year by budget allocations
which ignore cycle time and focus on competition for scarce resources. These
assumptions are counterproductive in a high-response world and maximize
the risks of failure
Competitive government must find ways to manage the timing of projects
more strategically, to exploit windows of opportunity as they arise, and to
reduce cycle time in order to deliver results before opposition to change
erodes support for implementation.
There are three strategies which can be used by government managers to
manage the tension between the interests of various groups and the positive
and negative impacts associated with the implementation of change.
Governments and business need to work together to scan the environment and
make effective judgments about the opportunity for effective change. Newly
elected governments can accomplish a great deal. There are examples of
governments doing this. There are examples of government building a man-
date for change and failing to act on attaining power until it is too late. While
the idea that timing is as critical to public sector change as to private sector
92 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Not all project cycles can be shortened. The third strategy is to manage
change in stages which build a momentum for change. Where delays are
outside of the managers control, it is important to engineer the break points
to ensure they consolidate to the right on the Impact Model. Building a
momentum for change is important. Maintaining and exploiting that momen-
tum once it is established is also important.
There are two proven techniques for stopping government initiatives. The
first technique is to convince government to act at the wrong time or on the
wrong premise; this weakens the consensus cycle and sets the scene for
failure as government seeks to implement a proposal without the underlying
initial support needed to convince interest groups to accept implementation
impacts. The second technique is to emphasize the impact of costs and to
delay the impact of benefits. As the program impacts negatively on different
interests, its opponents gain allies, and opposition is mobilized to stop the
project, or alternatively, to force concessions which reduce the initial value to
the point where the project adds little or no value.
Exhibit 4.3. Cycle Impact Model provides a management tool which can
be used to manage cycle impacts. The Cycle Impact Model (CIM) is an
extension of the Implementation Impact discussed earlier. The CIM can be
used to address impacts and solutions for each cycle stage. The CIM is a
management tool that reflects four realities of cycle impact management.
First, impacts need to be managed throughout the project cycle to maintain
each project both in the positive performance zone and in the comfort zone.
Second, project support will be stronger in some stages of the cycle than
others. Third, there is a need to ensure that major adjustments forced by
comfort zone issues also preserve added value. Fourth, project design and
implementation needs to be managed to establish the preconditions for a
long-term consolidation to the right on the model.
The numbers in Exhibit 4.3 divide the overall government cycle into four
cycles: a consensus cycle (0–1); a legislative cycle (1–2); an implementation
cycle (2–4); and a consolidation cycle (4–5). We now discuss strategies for
each of these cycles.
COMFORT ZONE
PERFORMANCE
2
ZONE
Implementation
+
cycle (2–4)
4 1
5
PERFORMANCE IMPACT
+ 0 –
Opposition Indifference Support
COMFORT ZONE IMPACT
interest groups seem likely to stop specific projects, trade-offs and negotia-
tions are required. The objective is to gain authorization with minimum trade-
offs and constraints. Gaining legislative approval is seldom the end of
negotiations with groups opposed to change.
cycle (2–3) represents initial planning and action to deliver proposed project
value. Perceptions of value increase as the detail is understood but opposition
also increases as negative impacts, both real and imagined, are also commu-
nicated to key groups. The movement is upward and to the left on the model.
Where the endpoint is outside the comfort zone governments take action to
restore the comfort zone. This usually involves compromises that reduce the
initial planned value. This part of the implementation cycle is shown as
(3–4) in Exhibit 4.3.
Managers need to manage the dynamics of project impacts either by
bringing forward positive impacts or shortening cycle time in order to sell end
benefits as imminent. Another challenge is to manage negative impacts. Not
everyone benefits from every project, and some individuals and interest groups
may be disadvantaged. Planning must address these realities, and organize
timing and communication strategies to neutralize resistance.
The added value of a project can diminish considerably during the deliv-
ery stage, as constituencies lobby to offset perceived disadvantages. Leader-
ship requires the negotiation of such impacts. The challenge is to position
implementation within a comfort zone which enables implementation to pro-
ceed without sacrificing results to the point where reform fails to add value.
public attention from the idea that the government has failed, and, if possible,
to present the outcome as a success.
CYCLE-FOCUSED COMMUNICATIONS
The traditional notion that the project should be scheduled for maximum
efficiency and the communication strategy should sell the project and address
criticisms underestimates the need to integrate planning and communication
strategies and to manage comfort zones. The communication function in
government needs to be reengineered to support government cycles with
proactive cycle-focused communication strategies which balance expectations
against delivery, manage the dynamics of negative impacts, and consolidate
project benefits when they are available.
The traditional approach to government segments the task of adding
value from the task of selling that value to various publics. Traditional objec-
tives for communications in government have focused on: the development of
a positive image using grand plans; an emphasis on consensus; and the avoid-
ance of both the idea of and responsibility for failure. The use of polling as
a diagnostic tool and as a means of supporting traditional communication
strategies has become so widespread that, on occasions, the polls seem to
have become more newsworthy than the policies or the politicians they seek
to evaluate. Often the polls address short-term consensus issues which do not
relate directly to the sort of comfort zone impacts suggested above. Often
they do not address directly the issue of competitiveness and added value.
A new communication strategy is required to support high-response
management. In the case of project dynamics, communications strategies need
to evaluate the impacts on interest groups, support the process with cycle
driven communication strategies. New communications strategies not only
need to address the idea of evaluation, but they also need to present depar-
tures from plan as situations to be corrected rather than signs of project
failure. Communication needs to use benchmarks to dimension discontinuous
change; it needs to lift overall comfort about the direction of change.
of government. The net result was a standoff between the president and the
legislature. The reforms were abandoned.
A number of points can be drawn from this experience. First, if the
proposal had been managed differently, opponents would have been under
more pressure to deliver. Second, the impact on interest groups and comfort
zones was not managed particularly well. As the detail was examined, the
ranks of opponents to the proposals grew. Third, the standoff can be seen as
a temporary consolidation.
It is interesting to consider whether the cycle at this point is seen as
having added value, whether the proposals remain in the comfort zone and
could be rejuvenated, and who the public credits and blames for the standoff.
Our guess would be that the president gained points for identifying the prob-
lem but his solution was seen as flawed. Whether a different approach to the
management of cycle impacts could have made more progress must remain
an open question. The delay in moving and the lack of attention to comfort
zone impacts established the preconditions for failure, at least this time around.
But those who blocked the solution, although they succeeded were forced to
appear negative. The alternative solutions such as they were articulated, also
seemed to be flawed.
In 1993, John Hewson lost an election in Australia that has been described as
unlosable. He did it by presenting a manifesto for changes which was largely
sensible, but which spelt out in detail many of the implications. Worse, the
manifesto was produced well before the election. Hewson broke most of the
imperatives that cycle theory suggests. He paid the electoral price. The govern-
ment of the day attacked the negatives until they swamped the positives which
as far as the electorate were concerned were in the future and obscure.
In 1996, John Howard led the same party to government successfully. He
confined himself to neutralizing government promises, to offering a broad agenda
for improvement. He released these details very late in the election campaign.
This ensured that a public who disliked the incumbent government and prob-
ably had come to regret keeping Hewson from office three years earlier, made
John Howard, Prime Minister of Australia with a near record majority.
Summary
short-run control over change; and the threshold levels which define the comfort
zone.
Finally, where there can be no effective control of the entire cycle, the
theory can still be used to inform communications strategies. Where the cycle
is broken, the cycle impact model emphasizes the need to control the breakpoint
and set up pressures which reinforce the required change.
with the scope to manage cycle impacts, but also because they increase rather
than reduce cycle time. Although many of these solutions draw on key ele-
ments required for competitive government, they often ignore the need to
manage implementation impacts.
Sixth, our analysis suggests that the failure to manage cycle impacts and
to use cycle-based communications has caused many unnecessary implemen-
tation breakdowns. Many implementation problems are not caused by politi-
cal opponents or by vested interests opposed to change but by the way in
which managers mismanage cycle dynamics. The idea that a communication
strategy should manage perceptions of discounted net project value across
different interest groups changes the management landscape for many gov-
ernment agencies. Cycle-based management, when pursued skillfully, can
stimulate government management systems to manage performance instead
of avoiding it and to negotiate the scope to manage performance directly
rather than to blame nonperformance on restraints imposed by others.
Chapter 5
Chapters 1–4 advanced four propositions about the crisis in government and
its solutions.
105
106 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
GOVERNMENT
Interest
National groups
companies
between the public awareness of a problem and the cycle time required to
build a consensus that the problem is a high priority need requiring an im-
mediate governmental response (consensus cycle time). The second tension is
between a public consensus on government’s need to respond to a high pri-
ority problem and the cycle time it takes government to formulate an appro-
priate program, move it through the legislature, and achieve a budget allocation
(legislative cycle time). The third tension is between the legislative mandate
to solve a problem and the scope for management to actually deliver results
(implementation cycle time). The gap between mandates and scope for action
includes resource gaps, workskill gaps, and comfort zone gaps. The fourth
tension is between public expectations of projects and public perceptions of
results achieved (consolidation cycle time). The coalignment of a government’s
actions within these four cycle times is the essence of effective management
of governmental processes.
Environmental scanning in the public sector has four roles.
VALUE-CHAIN THEORY
[A]n organization’s ability to continuously improve its effectiveness in
managing organizational interdependence will be the critical element
in successfully responding to environmental forces in the 1990s.
—Rockert and Short, ITT in the 1990s
112 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
time by starting more and finishing fewer projects. We now discuss each of
these issues.
Implementation
Implementation
Budget review
Consolidation
and budget
A VISION
Consensus
Scheduling
Legislative
INPUTS OUTPUTS
TO
GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
• Benefits to
Competitive
• Legislation: • Development/ Evaluation • Development/ users
needs
development/ authorization and revision authorization • Effective
Social value
debate/vote • Resource of budget • Resource transition
needs
• Budget: acquisition priorities: acquisition • Ongoing
Interest group priority/ • Project delivery proposal/ • Project delivery support for
pressures debate/vote debate/vote change
GOVERNMENT PROCESSES
Consensus cycle Performance
Annual Budget
Legislative/budget cycle Cycle review/audit
systems. In considering the need for reform, features of the traditional gov-
ernment value-chain need to be considered.
Access to Resources
A budget mandate is a necessary but not sufficient condition for access to
resources. After obtaining a legislative/ budget mandate for action, agency
managers must negotiate access to the personnel and other resources required
to implement their mandate. The central agencies of government often seek
to control the policy personnel and financial systems which are required to
support implementation. Although policy impacts and the scheduling of pro-
posals into the budget and legislative cycles are dealt with as part of the initial
legislative budget mandate, negative impacts are often addressed through policy
driven interventions by central agencies.
Traditional government systems also control employment, classification
levels, structures, and roles making the task of assembling a group to imple-
ment a proposal difficult and time consuming. These difficulties expand where
the project requires new types of resources or growth in agency resources
Government controls over other management processes, for example, pur-
chasing or system development, also act to further delay cycle time.
Evaluation
Evaluation is segmented on the basis of processes and resources rather than
impacts and results. Segmenting evaluation and relating it to budget reviews
shifts the emphasis away from using resources to deliver outputs towards
using resources to protect territory and maintain the scope to manage. At the
end of the process there seems no point in reviewing final outcomes or results.
116 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Cycle Time
Cycle time is an outcome of these processes rather than an active manage-
ment variable. Cycle time is system rather than management constrained.
Management of cycle time is shared between central agencies, the legislature,
and project managers. The concentration of central processes on an annual
cycle is a government device which aggregates decisions to manage allocative
tensions and to standardize processes in order to simplify interactions be-
tween the legislature and executive government. However, this solution has a
number of terminal disabilities for high-response government, for example,
cycle time is extended unnecessarily, managers are prevented from managing
cycle time directly, and the focus of evaluation shifts away from performance
and results toward the retention and acquisition of resources.
Over Segmentation
Over segmenting value-chain functions to optimize efficiency often extends
cycle time. Exhibit 5.4. Value-Chain Segmentation and Cycle Time focuses
on the standardization and queues used to coordinate traditional government
value-chain functions. The first diagram illustrates the use of queues to co-
ordinate the value-chain. The second diagram in Exhibit 5.4 illustrates the
relationships between value-chain segmentation and costs. The third diagram
shows the relationship between value-chain segmentation and cycle time.
In examining Exhibit 5.4, note that each new segment introduced into a
value-chain also requires an additional queue. Both total costs and cycle time
are impacted by these queuing solutions. First, total costs are a function of
the reductions caused by specialization and economies of scale offset by the
increasing costs of coordination and control. Second, production delays (cycle
time) are extremely sensitive to the segmentation because of the impact of
queuing time.
Responding to External Pressures 117
Production
segment x
Production
segment 1
Input Output
Queue x
Queue 1
Repeat
production
segments 1–x
SEGMENTATION
Direct
production
costs Total production plus
coordination costs
Cost of Cost of
minimizing coordination
cycle time
Low
VALUE-CHAIN REGMENTATION
Total production plus
production delay Coordination
delay
Production
Delay caused delay
by minimizing
costs
Low
118 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Coordination by Queues
The focus on queues and on segments rather than on outputs encourages
governments to extend cycle time by starting more and finishing fewer projects.
While such strategies address short-term pressures on the comfort zone, they
also create longer-term pressures as lack of result impacts leads groups to
discount government commitments
Existing Value-Chain
Focus the existing value-chain and reduce cycle times by modifying elements
of the chain and coordinating the interrelationships between them. Govern-
ment can focus on making the existing value-chain more effective by accel-
erating performance and evaluating impacts. Simply focusing on timing can
be effective because most government management systems see timing as an
output of the system. However, many government value-chains are limited by
general central processes which are not directly linked to a specific project.
For example, in Exhibit 5.3, the legislative and budget cycles and the budget
Responding to External Pressures 119
Deregulation
Reduce cycle time by deregulating specific functions in the value-chain and
focusing these functions on project needs rather than on system needs. For
example, the delays created by corporate government policy personnel and
finance systems can be reduced by deregulation of the management pro-
cesses. This strategy frees government managers to manage implementation
but does little to address the dead hand of the legislative and budgeting
systems of government. In addition, deregulation provides managers with the
scope to both manage and mismanage resources. There are too many cases
of empires built and garnished with resource flexibility provided by deregu-
lation to ignore these risks. If these empires also delivered added value to the
public, the excesses might be seen as a small price to pay for performance.
But often the public is worse off because there are fewer funds available for
services, and because they see themselves as paying for the new excesses of
autonomous managers.
Simplification
Identify elements that are not critical to delivery and either eliminate these
functions or manage them in parallel with critical functions rather than in
sequence. Examples of reengineering solutions include: the use of agency and
program mandates to define organizational and resource boundaries within
which executive government can act; the use of project teams which cut
across agency and budget boundaries; corporatize areas of government which
can operate as businesses or quasi businesses to allow these entities scope to
raise their own revenue and deal with their own customers; and move some
functions out of the government value-chain altogether, for example, by priva-
tizing or setting up independent tribunals or authorities to manage particular
functions. Moving activities to the private sector can remove them from the
political framework and from the political consensus process.
Devolution
Arrange government structures both within and between agencies to enable
managers to directly manage value-chain interdependencies. Structures should
seek to provide the scope for autonomous management of specific value-
120 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
chains or at least seek to define agency boundaries that include the more
difficult interdependencies. Where agency structures must segment interde-
pendencies, overlapping project structures can be used to provide a manage-
ment focus. Where management must be segmented across the value-chain,
boundary coordination units at key interfaces can be used to manage strategic
interdependencies.
Reengineering Value-Chains
A task force normally involves government officials, topic experts, and com-
munity leaders in a process of constructing a public consensus and formulat-
ing legislative programs aimed at solving high priority problems. This group
can be from twenty-five to several hundred, depending on the size of the
problem to be solved and the interest groups needed to forge a public
consensus.
Responding to External Pressures 123
Environmental Scanning
During the winter of 1993, the Republican Party in the United States was
confronted by several facts as they prepared for the upcoming legislative
elections. The Democratic Party controlled the Presidency and both Houses
of the legislature by what appeared to be a comfortable margin. House Mi-
nority Leader, Newt Gingrich reflected on the political environment as he saw
it at the time—
The first indication that the environment was changing was the appear-
ance of a large number of eager and attractive Republican candidates for the
fall legislative election. They were young, educated, and had grown up ques-
tioning the legacy of the 1960s. They were critical of liberalism on economic
and social grounds. Excellent candidates were emerging to challenge Demo-
cratic Party dominance of both houses of the Congress and of the state gov-
ernorships and legislature. At that time the Democrats controlled thirty
governorships and thirty-one legislatures with Republicans controlling eigh-
teen governorships and only seven legislatures. For decades, scores of Demo-
cratic held positions had gone unopposed but now that was changing.
In January of 1994, Newt Gingrich held a weekend retreat of House
Republicans; they settled on a campaign strategy for the fall election, now
known as the “Contract With America.” What happened at that meeting is that
public opinion polls had revealed several issues on which over 60 percent of
all Americans felt the U.S. government should act. Newt Gingrich describes
the result—
Revolutions have to be built one step at a time. The first step was to
commit the party to the idea that we should run on idealistic bold
reforms and be prepared to keep our word. By June we had agreed to
hold a Capitol steps event in September involving ten major program
statements. The ten points basically selected themselves as deeply felt
desires of the American people. We knew from long experience that
people were desperate for a law requiring Congress to obey the same
laws as everyone else. We knew that there was overwhelming support
Responding to External Pressures 125
for the balanced budget amendment, the line-item veto, and term lim-
its. As the party of small businesses and family farms, we knew that
litigation reform and regulatory reform were strongly supported. As
conservatives and advocates of a prowork and profamily America we
knew that welfare reform, a child tax credit, increased savings oppor-
tunities, and capital gains tax cuts to increase economic growth would
strengthen America. Finally, as conservatives, we felt the liberals had
weakened our national defense and our laws against criminals and
child pornographers. We believed that these should be strengthened. It
can literally be said that the Contract with America grew out of our
conversations with the American people and out of our basic conser-
vative values (Gingrich 1995).
which to challenge the Democratic president, not by mere rhetoric alone, but
by legislative action on high-priority public issues. Environmental scanning
requires that a government find solutions to high-priority problems by imple-
menting the following: monitoring public attitudes and expectations, bench-
marking other governmental units, learning from their performance, and by
its own creativity.
Value-Chain Management
We have explored how Newt Gingrich and the House Republicans built a
high-priority consensus during the 1994 congressional election process. This
was an important step in the public consensus processes. Let us now examine
how House Speaker Gingrich managed the legislative consensus development
processes in the House. This involved the use of value-chain theory at the
functional unit level. It involved legislative proposal hearings, legislative de-
bates and votes, budget debates and votes, and implementing agency assign-
ment for the legislation.
Since the Republican Party in the House had promised the American
people they would vote on the ten proposals which made up the Contract with
America within the first one hundred days of taking office, careful planning
and a great deal of work would be required to keep this promise. Jim Nussle
was picked by the House Republicans to head a transition team from Demo-
cratic to Republican leadership in the House of Representatives. He was
backed by a strong and aggressive team. The opening agenda of Speaker
Elect of the House Newt Gingrich, was to audit the House management
system, cut committee staff, and shrink the size of the House administrative
units in order to make them more responsive. In retrospect, four changes in
administrative procedures proved to be very important. First, several young
committee chairmen were picked, disregarding the seniority system. Bob
Livingston, Tom Bliley, and Henry Hyde became chairmen of Appropriations,
Commerce, and Judiciary, even though they did not have seniority. In each
case, Speaker Gingrich thought it would bring a higher “level of aggressive-
ness and risk taking needed to the position” (Gingrich 1995). Second, the
committee structure of the House was streamlined with several former com-
mittees being eliminated and/ or combined. This speeded up the legislative
hearing process, Gingrich reported (Gingrich 1995).
David Dreier of California led the task force on this issue. He concluded
that several committees were no longer necessary, while others needed to be
reorganized or renamed. The Merchant Marine and Fisheries Committee, the
District of Columbia Committee, and the Post Office and Civil Service Com-
mittee all disappeared. The Energy and Commerce Committee, which John
Dingell had turned into an empire, lost railroads and part of its energy juris-
diction. Other committees were renamed and refocused. The Armed Services
Responding to External Pressures 127
Continuous Improvement
In the prior section of the discussion on value-chain theory, we explored how
the U.S. House of Representatives implemented the Contract with America in
just ninety-one days. It is significant that all of these efforts were strongly
Responding to External Pressures 129
Summary
A number of points can be drawn from this case study. First, legislative proce-
dures and the role of political parties are as much in need of reform as manage-
ment processes. Political parties cross interest groups and can manage priorities
to provide a base for action. In recent times members of parties in many countries
have lost that discipline. Legislative processes are in need of review in most
legislatures. However, an effective legislature requires politicians committed to
action and processes which enable them to deliver decisions.
Second, these reforms can be informed by a focus on cycle time. As with
other government processes, the target focused attention and commitment.
The need to deliver the target identified systems and procedures that were
critical to the result.
Third, environmental impacts must be managed in real time. The impact
on public preferences of the actions taken by Republicans was to change
some of those preferences. As preferences changed, the process became
130 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
vulnerable to comfort zone issues with the scope to challenge the agenda.
Broad consensus about problems and solutions represents a brief opportunity
for change. But the devil is often in the detail. The need to spell out proposals
in detail enables opponents to generate opposition and uncertainty.
Fourth, the process was further complicated in this example because the
translation into public impacts required action by executive government which
was in many respects hostile to the initiatives or at least intent upon ensuing
that political costs and benefits were realigned as part of the process. This
emphasizes the importance of controlling the break point in the cycle. In the
case, of the Contract with America, the president was forced to react and
accept many of the core ideas. But in the process he assumed control of the
break point. In the end the reformers appeared to be the obstructionists. But
had there been no contract, there would have been no change.
option but to hire managers able to effect these transitions, remove the re-
straints that stop government systems from either succeeding or failing, and
facing up to the risks and opportunities offered by change.
Four issues for reform can be identified from our analysis of value-chain
coalignment. First, reforms of value-chains need to also reduce cycle time
and provide managers with the scope to manage cycle time and to manage
comfort zone impacts. Almost all attempts at reforming government manage-
ment attempt to deregulate, to free up processes and roles, and to focus on
key tasks and functions. Some reforms clearly provide a strong focus for the
management of cycle time and for external accountability. For example, the
case studies presented in reinventing government powerfully reconfigure both
value-chains and the environmental focus of specific agencies. It is not difficult
to see why these changes work. But other situations are more complex and
some reforms simply miss the need to provide a new focus for the manage-
ment of cycle time. In such situations, reform is not only likely to fail, it
could well prove to be counterproductive. The solution is to extend the reform
agenda by finding alternative value-chain configurations to match new needs.
Second, reforms need to focus government managers on the management
of two key environmental boundaries. Government needs to directly manage
its boundary and it must indirectly manage the national boundary. Devolving
part of this management responsibility to operating agencies is important and
requires new ways of managing relationships between steerers and rowers.
The simple demarcation which suggests that comfort zone impacts can be
managed hierarchically is a recipe for ongoing crisis management and the
unelectability of incumbent governments.
Third, the application of value-chain theory needs to recognize the fixed
nature of traditional processes and the major comfort zone impacts which are
unleashed when these processes are bypassed. Just as successful business
organizations have learned to interact with their external environment to shape
opportunities, governments must learn to interact with the groups which cre-
ate the comfort zone and reposition the comfort zone itself by altering expec-
tations and increasing acceptance of the need for change.
Fourth, government reforms must move from one-off interventions to
reforms which generate continuous improvement. Most government reforms
lurch from crisis to crisis. Reform needs to establish the basis for continuous
improvement. Change strategies for government must meet three criteria:
they must be implementable; they must address current problems; and they
must produce a base for addressing future problems and exploiting future
opportunities. The most obvious weakness in many reforms is the lack of
ongoing evaluation and benchmarking. Once the crisis is past and the public
believe it is no longer an urgent issue, there are many vested interests in the
government system that opt for moving on to the next issue. Four actions are
132 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
133
134 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Richard Beckhard and Reuben T. Harris (1989) argue that the key to manag-
ing change lies in managing transitions not end points. Mapping progress,
including the progress of competitors for world resources, is part of the
management of change.
Traditional government management systems are not well suited to
managing change. Such systems respond to external pressures for change
incrementally, cycle time is slow, responses are often segmented, and the
future is assumed to be no more than a linear extension of the past. Few
organizations or governments can survive with linear solutions today. The
future is turbulent, uncertain, and different.
Leadership Strategies 135
new realities, and developing a new focus on task performance which enables
government staff and external interest groups to understand and join the transition.
A weakness with many government change processes is that they fail to build
a base for ongoing change by allowing the new management platform to
erode. Effective transitions need to build ongoing changes on the base man-
Leadership Strategies 137
Exhibit 6.4 indicates that the United States owes its top ranking to top
ranking in “domestic economy,” “internationalization,” “finance,” “infrastruc-
ture,” and “science and technology.” In recent years the U.S. has consolidated
this position by improved its rankings for “management” and “people” and
it’s ranking for “government” has declined.
Leadership Strategies 139
Singapore owes its top ranking to a high ranking for “government,” “in-
ternationalization,” “management” and “people.” In recent years, the ranking
for “infrastructure” has improved markedly. As discussed in chapter 3,
Singapore has maintained competitiveness following the 1998 financial crises
in Asia; however, the 1999 rankings show a deterioration in several key
rankings. The report also lists weaknesses in the competitive stance of each
nation. The United States has been particularly aggressive in the production
of new technologies such as computers and telecommunications which are
increasing worker productivity. However, this has led to massive downsizing
and middle-management layoffs, combined with a rapidly growing salary
differential between the best and least educated citizens. Singapore’s chief
problems arise from a limited population base, its relatively small investments
in R & D expenditures and its large overseas investment (The World Competi-
tiveness Report [Yearbook], 1995).
The World Competitiveness Yearbook offers us a unique insight into
two of the world’s most competitive economies. The U.S. economy and the
Leadership Strategies 141
Singapore is a city-state with an area of 244 square miles located at the tip
of the Malaysian peninsula. It has a diverse population of 2.8 million people,
77 percent Chinese, 15 percent Malay, and 7 percent Indian. Singapore gained
independence from Malaysia in 1965 and has already accomplished a great
deal in just thirty years. First, its average income has risen from $3,072 U.S.
dollars in 1960 to over $22,000 U.S. dollars in 1994. This represents a trans-
formation from a city of small restaurant and shop owners into a major
international manufacturing and service hub. Second, the overall quality of its
telecommunications, seaport, and airport are considered the best in the world.
Third, Singapore’s people have the highest savings rate in the world (45
percent), its labor force is rated the most productive, and it has the world’s
highest proportion of technologists. Finally, Singapore’s business environ-
ment is considered the most supportive and risk free business environment in
the world (Sisodia 1993).
In large part, these accomplishments are the result of governmental lead-
ership, a partnership with multinational firms, and Singapore’s success in
transforming its high-production central planning economy to a high-response
strategic management economy.
142 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Source: EDB (L. Low, T. Heng, S. Wong, T. Yam, and H. Hughes, Challenge and Response
[Singapore: Times Academic Press, 1993]).
Year of
Inception Program Level
1986 IC Design Engineer Postgraduate
1987 Automation Engineer
1989 SMT Engineer
1988 Automation Designer Post Diploma
1987 Tool and Die Designer
1989 Consumer Electronic Product Designer
1989 FA-Tronics Technology
1989 SMT Technician Post ITC
1987 Precision Engineering (Tool and Die Making) Advanced
1990 Precision Engineering (Machine Technology) Craftsmen
1991 Precision Engineering (Tool and Die Making) NTC-1
Source: EDB (L. Low, T. Heng, S. Wong, T. Yam, and H. Hughes, Challenge and Response
(Singapore: Times Academic Press, 1993), p. 264).
When a nation’s GDP rises from $3,000 U.S. dollars per person in 1960 to
over $22,000 in 1994, a massive transformation must take place in that nation’s
educational system in order to accomplish that task. Government planning is
based on one simple premise in the manpower development area. That premise
is the recognition that technical manpower is one of the crucial inputs of a
modern economy. Therefore planning seeks to avoid shortages or surpluses of
technical manpower in pursuit of economic growth. Thus, planners must (a)
identify future requirements for skilled manpower, and (b) design an educa-
tional system to produce the manpower required. In 1989, the then minister
of education outlined the proposed changes to the educational system to meet
1995–1996 workforce needs.
Exhibit 6.6 summarizes key education and training initiatives. The future
emphasis in the educational system is going to be on technology and less on
general broad-based learning. This will help children maximize their potential
and talents. The priority in the next few years should not be on expanding
university education, but on providing technical, commercial, and vocational
education. The goal is to have about 20 percent of the students studying
academic subjects and pursuing university degrees and 70 percent studying
technical, commercial, and vocational courses. The only expansion in univer-
sity enrollment would be in teaching, engineering, business studies, and para-
medical services.
In addition, the three polytechnics will increase their student intake and
their curriculum and a fourth polytechnical college will be established. Through
the EDB, the government has collaborated with such countries as Japan,
France, and Germany to establish specialized technical institutes. These in-
clude the Japanese Institute of Software Technology (JSIST), the German
Singapore Institute in Precious Tools, and the French-Singapore Institute in
Petrochemical Technology.
In addition, the Vocational and Industrial Training Board (VITB) has
planned to open twelve Institutes of Technical Education to provide training
in engineering. These institutes will take ten thousand school leavers or about
25 percent of those who do not go on into higher academic training.
In addition, the diffusion of new technologies in companies requires
training and retraining to develop the analytic and problem solving skills of
workers. This training will be funded by the skills development fund and the
National Productivity Board in industry-based training centers to advance
industry specific skills. Tables 1 and 2, Exhibit 6.5 presents a list of such
projects.
Finally, in 1964 the Economic Development Board established the Singapore
Institute of Management (SIMS) which offers one Ph.D., eight master degrees,
148 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
e.g., Seiko
Japanese
Japax
Companies Sankyo
Matsushita
Mitufoyo
CIM
FMS
MR DNC
IC SM
De T
P
C/
sig
CN
EDB
Institutions
/C tion
A1
La Visi
AM
la
se on
CA imu
r
D
S
▼
▼ Robotics
Automation
American European
Companies Companies
Source: EDB (Heng T. Low, S. Wong, T. Yam, and H. Hughes, Challenge and Response (Singapore:
Times Academic Press, 1993), p. 263.
ten bachelor degrees, and eighteen certificate programs in business and com-
puter sciences for those seeking continuing education. In 1993, SIMS had
4,313 students enrolled in degree programs and 7,269 enrolled in workshops
and seminars (The Singapore Institute of Management 1993).
In spite of this rather vast array of training offered by the government
and, in conjunction with the private sector, training institutes and training
Leadership Strategies 149
The Asian financial crises and downturn tested the effectiveness of Singapore’s
transition. Although growth was interrupted, 1999 saw a return to strong
growth in Singapore’s economy. Singapore had already developed many of
the internal reforms that other countries in the region still needed to address.
In 1998, the government responded to the crises by cutting costs and taxes on
business. Recovery in Singapore appears to have been driven by both internal
and external factors. Prime Minister Gow Chock Tong attributed the recovery
to the 1998 cost cuts, a recovery in the global electronics sector, an upturn
in the Japanese economy, and to the continued strength of the U.S. economy
(The Wall Street Journal 2000).
• The People’s Action Party has had the uninterrupted support of the
Singapore people for over thirty years. This has provided the government
with the long-term political support necessary to plan, make mistakes,
learn from these mistakes, and adjust.
150 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
• The government has been careful to allow the pressures of the global
economy to test governmental policy in a competitive marketplace and
to force the refinement of those policies.
• Singapore government’s success in transforming its economy from a
central planning to a strategic management, from a high-production to
a high-response system, has led the governments of China and Vietnam
to invite Singapore’s government to develop and lead two of its free
trade zones in a similar transformation.
• Singapore has served as a demonstration project for the pioneer func-
tioning of Economic Development Boards by many countries and for
the development of a variety of public/private sector educational and
training interfaces.
• Singapore has acted as a catalyst for the development of the entire
southeast Asian region. Malaysia, Indonesia, and Thailand are all
benefiting from Singapore’s success.
• The chief limitation to the proper functioning of Singapore’s govern-
ment in the global economy is a rapid change in cycle time of the
global economy. When government correctly anticipates cycle changes,
development works well. When it does not and has to react to unan-
ticipated cycle changes, the human and economic costs can be high.
• Finally, the chief threat to Singapore’s government strategy is a loss of
political support by the Singapore people. Singapore’s proactive long-
term planning and long-term responses to changes in the global market-
place would be undermined should this trust in government be eroded.
twenty of GE’s former top executives have become successful CEOs of such
global firms as GTE, Allied Signal, Goodyear Tire, Owens-Corning, Ryland
Group, General Dynamics, Wang Laboratories, Sundstrand, Rubbermaid,
M/A Communications, USF&G, Zorn Industries, Clean Harbor, and Systems
Computer Technology, suggesting that GE’s global adaptations are principled,
systematic, and representative of the best U.S. firms, rather than a function of
one firm’s unique capabilities (Cohn 1992). Let us briefly explore GE’s three
transformations in the last thirteen years in response to changes in the global
marketplace and draw some conclusions regarding the pressures this places
on the U.S. government’s operations.
GE—Transformation 1
To the Most Competitive and Valuable Firm in the World
In 1981, Jack Welch became CEO of the General Electric Corporation and
anticipated GE’s first need for a transformational change. Welch recalls his
thoughts:
GE—Transformation 2
To a Boundarylessness Firm through Speed,
Simplicity, and Self-Confidence
In April of 1988, this first massive reengineering effort was all but complete
and Welch began to anticipate the need for a second transformation in GE.
Welch reflects (Welch 1988):
[T]oday the world is even tougher and more crowded. Korea and
Taiwan have become world-class competitors, as hungry and aggres-
sive as Japan was in 1981. Europe is on fire with a new entrepre-
neurial spirit and leadership that is among the world’s best. Many of
its most aggressive companies, like Electrolux and ASEA of Swe-
den, Philips of Holland, and Siemens and Bayer of Germany, are
after our markets through acquisitions and joint ventures—just as we
are going after theirs. . . . At the same time, the Japanese are more
sophisticated and aggressive than ever—building servicing plants
outside Japan, including dozens just over the Mexican border.
By 1988, GE’s challenges were internal and even larger than in 1981.
Welch reflects:
going to win in the 1990s. If you can’t produce a top quality product
at the world’s lowest price and get it to market in less time than your
competitors, you’re going to be out of the game. In such an environ-
ment, 5 percent annual increase in productivity and quality will not
be enough; more will be needed. (Welch 1988)
to work, but also this principle will significantly enhance worker skills so
that they can find another job if the company no longer needs them—a
place where employees are ready to go but eager to stay. In order to actu-
alize this goal (a) develop employee awareness that the only road to job
security is increasing market shares; (b) develop employees who are more
action-oriented, more risk-oriented, and more people-oriented; (c) develop
employees who relentlessly pursue individual and group goals; (d) develop
employee skills and performance through timely and quality education pro-
grams; (e) hold employees responsible for meeting productivity and financial
targets; and (f) reward high-performance and deal effectively with low
performance.
Three new mechanisms were put forward to create a tension capable of
meeting these new goals (1) reengineering GE’s corporate culture, (2) cre-
ation of a world-class continuous improvement program, and (3) creation of
a rapid responsive communication system.
By late 1988, Welch began to notice that most of his top management
team and business leaders had bought into GE’s need for a transformation,
but middle and line managers were still prone to fight or ignore the need to
change. The mechanism put in place to alter these behaviors was a new
continuous improvement program called “Workout.” Workout was designed
to ensure that employees, suppliers, and customers could speak candidly to
managers without fear of retribution. Thus, placing pressure on middle and
line managers from above and below to change—as Welch had hoped—the
process quickly exposed GE managers who did not “walk the talk.”
Workout was a world-class continuous improvement program aimed at
reengineering GE’s organizational processes by increasing the firm’s pro-
ductivity and quality while decreasing its response time. The program in-
cluded (1) a self-managed team program called a “New England Town
Meeting,” (2) a cross-functional team program called “process mapping,”
(3) a benchmarking “best practices” program, and (4) an aggressive outside
linking program. The practical objective of workout was to
demonstrated also the need for a new type of manager, a process manager
who could coalign an organization’s total assets. It allowed employees to spot
bottlenecks, time binds, inventory shortages, and overflows.
Since implementing such a cross-functional teamwork program, GE ap-
pliances has cut its sixteen-week manufacturing cycle in half, while increas-
ing productivity 6 percent and decreasing inventory costs 20 percent. The
program has cost less than $3 million to implement and has already returned
profits 100 times (Stewart 1993).
Next, GE put in place a rapid response communication system. This
system was designed to dramatically speed up information flow to and from
the market. Monday through Thursday, issues were generated by sales force
employees regarding growth opportunities, competitor moves, quality prob-
lems, process delivery issues, and sent to Friday’s business town meeting.
This meeting included business leaders and about sixty to seventy unit lead-
ers. They explored and acted on each issue raised. On Friday afternoon,
televeision broadcasted this meeting’s results directly to regions and plants
where they were discussed in a teleconference; a game plan was set for
dealing with these issues.
This rapid turn around time in decision-making energizes change, over-
comes resistance to change, while involving all management layers in the
action plan. Where it used to take fourteen weeks to get an order, make the
product, and then sell it, in some businesses GE has cut that time in half and
in others by a factor four, saving billions of dollars in costs each year (Chief
Executive Magazine 1992).
GE—Transformation 3
A Multipolar Multicultural Firm:
The Push to Become a Major Player in the Pacific Rim Markets
In 1992, Jack Welch began to reflect on the need for a third transformation
in GE. He believed that the slow 3 percent projected growth rate for Euro-
pean, United States, and Japanese core markets over the next several years
would limit GE’s growth. He believed that if GE was to remain a global
leader, it must take steps to position itself in the major emerging markets of
the Pacific Rim, China, India, Mexico, and Southeast Asia. Welch also be-
lieved that to remain a global leader, GE had to shift its center of gravity from
the U.S. / Europe relationship to the U.S. /Pacific Rim markets. This was to be
accomplished through a two-pronged strategy with specific performance tar-
gets for each (Smart et al. 1993).
These markets are presently growing and will continue to grow at 8 to
12 percent per year for the next ten to twenty years. In addition, GE’s growth
158 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
in revenue from these areas has gone from $10 billion to $20 billion in the
last three years.
billion from Japan), is larger ($7 trillion vs. $4 trillion in Japan and $2 trillion
in Germany), and creates more jobs (7.5 million between 1990–1995) than
any other market in the world (Aley 1995).
Because of corporate adaptation to change in the highly competitive U.S.
market, firms like GE, Motorola, and Intel become world-class competitors in
their home market and carry that competitive stance with them when they
enter other regions of the global economy. In the second quarter of 1995, U.S.
productivity rose 4.8 percent (Duff 1995). The nature of open competition in
the U.S. market provides the American people and American firms with strong
and clear expectations about what government’s role should and must be in
fostering competitiveness. Attention is now directed to what those expecta-
tions are and how the U.S. government has moved from an autonomous to a
strategic management system in an attempt to meet those expectations.
a given industry. Several years ago AT&T was divested for this reason and more
recently attempted acquisitions in the telecommunication and software indus-
tries have been halted. Every combination of firms which might limit compe-
tition is delayed until the Justice Department completes such an investigation.
Limit the Access of Other Nations to the U.S. Market Because They Limit
U.S. Access to Their Markets
Recent negotiations between the U.S. government and the governments of
Japan, Korea, Germany, and China have threatened to limit the access of
these nation’s firms to the U.S. market by imposing quotas, taxes, and/or
preventing product entry to the market because access to their markets were
restricted by government. Most recently, the Japanese loosened import rules
on auto parts in exchange for the United States dropping a proposed tax on
Japanese luxury cars. Similar negotiations are now underway with Korea. The
U.S. government is involved in over two hundred negotiations of this type.
nation involved fails to trade fairly (i.e., live up to copyright laws, etc.).
Recent negotiations with China and Vietnam have turned on this issue.
The major problem of advanced countries and their governments is the cost
of their value system. It is normal to want to maintain or raise one’s standard
of living, to want higher wages, a more comprehensive health care program,
better retirement, and more jobs. It is understandable to want to work less, to
pay fewer taxes, and to protect the environment. But all of these values
contain a price tag. They have to be paid for by government and their people.
The more competitive a nation or firm the more wealth is created to pay for
the value system. The more sophisticated the value system, the more competi-
tive a country or firm has to be. Between 1980–1992, the net public debt in
the United States and Western Europe doubled. This indebtedness demon-
strates the large margin of error between what those nations want and what
they can afford. In both regions their competitiveness cannot support their
wants. They must begin to reduce their costs. In Europe the size of the public
sector is three times what it is in Japan. In the United States the cost of
entitlements will soon tie up over 70 percent of the government’s budget. In
Asia similar problems are beginning to emerge. What can we learn from the
two most competitive nations in the world about how to solve these prob-
lems? We suggest six common lessons and two important diverse lessons.
We have provided a rather extended analysis of two of the world’s most
competitive economies. We have observed the transformation of a central
planning high-production economy toward a strategic management high-re-
sponse economy. We have observed a high-autonomy economy evolve to-
wards a strategic management high-response economy. We have also learned
several important lessons from our analysis regarding the global competitive-
ness of nations.
First, both Singapore and the United States realize that (a) access to a large
core market, (b) a strong scientific and technical workforce, and (c) a private
sector which can attract capital in order to provide the infrastructure neces-
sary to increase growth and rapid technological development are the essential
factors involved in long-term competitive advantage.
Singapore has developed a government strategic management system
which maximizes its major resources, people, and its location in southeast
Asia, the most rapidly expanding market in the world. Singapore’s attempt to
help Malaysia, Indonesia, Thailand, Vietnam, and China develop seeks to
provide this city-state with a central role in the world’s potentially largest
core market.
The United States has developed a private sector strategic management
system which maximizes its main resources, its manufacturing, agricultural,
Leadership Strategies 163
and service firms, and their location in the largest and most profitable market
in the world. U.S. firms are rapidly expanding into Asia in an attempt to
exploit the potentially largest and currently most rapidly expanding market in
the world.
Both nations are currently attracting large capital investments and both
are investing heavily in telecommunication infrastructure. Singapore’s educa-
tion and manpower policies are substantially stronger than those in the United
States, but the base they have to draw from at this point in time is more
limited.
Second, both Singapore and the United States have made important ad-
vances in generating more and better paying jobs. However, in both cases, a
shortage of skilled labor has developed—in Singapore because of its limited
population base and in the United States because of structural weaknesses in
its educational systems. In both nations, productivity is growing and so will
the demand for a more skilled workforce. In both nations, the government is
supporting a brain drain from abroad to fill the gap. However, as other nations
improve their standards of living and pay for skilled work, this solution may
not work. Jobs may migrate along with skilled workers. For example, in the
United States between 1980 and 1992, manufacturing output doubled, but
manufacturing jobs decreased by 10 percent. At the same time, manufacturing
output and jobs in Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and Malaysia increased by 25
percent (Smadja 1994).
Third, competitiveness has added value to both economies. In Singapore,
it is raising the nation’s standard of living while in the United States, in-
creased competitiveness is required to maintain the current standard of living.
Wages and disposable income in both Singapore and the United States have
changed dramatically. In Singapore, GDP has risen from $3,000 U.S. in 1960
to $22,000 in 1995, while disposable income has risen 500 percent. Between
1973 and 1992, blue-collar workers in the United States have lost 15 percent
of their purchasing power, while real income peaked in 1976 at $24,000 per
person. Today, sixteen years later, real income is $23,000 and purchasing
power remaining has decreased 15 percent. In the United States, 7.5 million
jobs have been created that could push those figures upward, but a shortage
of skilled labor and no effective national labor policy designed to meet those
unfilled needs is pushing real wages down (Narisetti 1995).
Fourth, both the government in Singapore and the private sector firms in
the United States have located a successful strategic development model.
Development proceeds in strategic phases. Each phase has involved the
adaptations of a dramatically higher value added product output. The move-
ment between stages is transformational while the mastery of each phase is
incremental. The goal in each phase is to dominate through excellence. The
observable characteristics of domination are (Vollman 1994): a dramatic growth
164 A VISION TO GUIDE GOVERNMENT REFORM
Key Differences
The diverse lessons we can learn from our two case studies may be even more
significant.
First, the contribution of government targets was different in each tran-
sition. In Singapore, the government selection of targets for operationalizing
its vision of an export-based economy employs specific educational and eco-
nomic goals and targets (e.g., attracting x amount of foreign investment through
incentives to power industries, educate x number of computer scientists, etc.).
These goals lack the normal political ideology or values which serve as a drag
on government action. In the United States on the other hand, the values the
American people hold in regard to individualism, or universal health care,
and so forth are unmanageable as operational principles which not only create
significant problems for government and debate over their implementation
but also divide the nation and makes government immobile.
Second, the challenge of maintaining the scope to govern was different
for each transition. In Singapore, the need for strong and extended support of
government by the people could undermine governmental action if it did not
exist. If Singapore had two strong parties with separate vision within which
each could get the power but not hold it, then the current strategic manage-
ment system would be undermined. In the United States shifting political
power has had a limited effect on the economy because most institutions
which can effect the economy have been placed beyond political influence
(i.e., the Federal Reserve Board). So governments come and go, but the
economy goes on.
171
172 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
they must fix the weaknesses in traditional systems while also retaining pre-
vious strengths. In part 2, we address the internal reforms required to produce
such a platform for transition. The first challenge is to create a platform
which can solve current problems by aligning new management strategies
structures and systems with the new external realities. The second challenge
is to convert on-off changes into an effective platform for transition to address
future problems and exploit future opportunities. We consider detailed change
strategies and management tools which can be used to replace the traditional
static management platform used by governments with a platform for transi-
tion.
Chapter 7 addresses the challenge of transition. We suggest that devolu-
tion and differentiation are central to future government performance. Man-
aging the transition from a tightly controlled uniform system to a devolved
and differentiated system presents three challenges for government reform.
First, there is the challenge of coordinating devolution with new forms of
output focused accountability. Second, there is the problem of managing a
network of differentiated activities and cultures. Third, there is the challenge
of maintaining some capacity to address the public interest.
Chapter 8 addresses planning and evaluation strategies for competitive
government. Devolution and differentiation require new approaches to the
management of performance. In chapter 8, we present a strategy for shifting
government planning and evaluation away from inputs and processes towards
results and measurable impacts on the external environment. High-response
solutions to government management require strategic thinking by govern-
ment. This needs to be supported by new approaches to planning and evalu-
ation. We examine recent criticisms of strategic planning and argue that strategic
planning and evaluation in government is essentially an implementation tool;
it must be developed to avoid planning inertia. We present a performance
improvement planning and evaluation process and discuss its application to
three quite different performance problems: the reform of a national taxation
agency, the reform of services for the schooling of disabled children, and
measuring the performance of senior managers.
Chapter 9 presents strategies and tools for reinventing and reengineering
government management systems and values. The task of facilitating change
requires both the removal of the blockages created by traditional input con-
trolled systems and the replacement of these traditional systems by new forms
of coalignment which focus on the management of government performance
and on holding agencies and managers accountable for results. We suggest that
the role of structures needs to shift from coordinating work or distributing
power to providing a focus for autonomy and accountability. We explore three
change management strategies / tools. We discuss the use of a network of per-
formance contracts as a tool for focusing change. We discuss the use of project
A Management Platform for Government Change 173
175
176 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
SHARED PERFORMANCE
RESPONSIBILITY ORIENTED
Accountability—for strategic performance
▼
Medium
FAILURE ZONE
▼
REGULATED UNFETTERED
CONSUMPTION ENTERPRISE
Low
Note: Failure zone—high risk of under performance or administrative breakdown due to lack of
strategic fit between internal controls and external accountability for performance.
The point about this failure zone is not that it defines areas in which
agencies are likely to fail but that moving a government agency or bureau
from regulated consumption to performance management requires a transition
through this failure zone.
Most government changes in recent years have moved agencies horizon-
tally to the right on the Performance Management Grid. There is no doubt
that deregulation is required to enable managers to add value to government
programs. However, the lack of effective measures of accountability has led
to perceptions of failure. All too often the solutions have been new structures,
new managers, and new pressures for reregulation rather than solutions which
develop a new focus for performance that coaligns units more effectively.
For example, the short-term focus of many changes is to reduce costs in
order to plug budget gaps In many cases, short-term accountability is defined
in terms surviving the challenge of reduced expenditures. But in the longer-
term accountability for performance requires a negotiation of performance
parameters either with customers or government or both. Viable long-term
change also requires an audit of existing structures systems and staffing not
only to focus management accountability for delivery, but also to avoid the
shared accountability option discussed above. Viable long-term change also
requires managers to establish the basis for continuous improvement which
includes an ongoing evaluation of performance and an ongoing drive to im-
prove performance.
• Review internal and external rules against the need to manage cycle
time. Where simple rules allow rapid responses, consider retaining
these as an option for managers who can work within them.
The business world has discovered that devolution and differences are im-
portant to managing in a high-response environment. Alvin Toffler advanced
these ideas in the 1970s as part of a classic study which argued in favor of
segmenting the Bell system. The benefits of devolution and moving agencies
186 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
closer to markets will not emerge unless governments too finds ways to
encourage diversity rather than conformity. The other side of the devolution
coin is that the central framework must be capable of repositioning the sys-
tem and realigning the missions of government.
The optimal strategy structure and values required for a government
agency to perform is a function of the performance required. For example, the
optimal arrangements for operating schools will always differ from the opti-
mal solution for managing prisons.
In a volatile environment, agencies must obtain the flexibility to address
needs and manage delivery. In part, this process involves devolution to place
management discretion closer to delivery action. The process must also in-
volve experiments to find out what works and what does not and to develop
confidence amongst internal and external groups that new solutions can add
value. These two processes, devolution, and the need to experiment, require
differences between delivery agencies/ units. While these differences are the
key to reform, they create new coordination problems for bureaucracies used
to coordination by standards and rules. The rules and processes must be
dismantled to allow differences to emerge.
On the other hand, many agencies are funded by taxpayers who do not
receive direct benefits. The opportunity costs of expanding one agency at the
expense of another must be managed. Where there is competition there must
be some way to encourage agencies that add value. All this requires central
agencies of government able to manage diversity rather than conformity. The
successful management of diversity requires a shift in the internal values of
government from a belief that performance flows from internal rules and
conformity to a belief that coordination can focus on performance.
• Promote short-term benefits/ impacts and build the idea that these are
part of longer-term benefits.
• Neutralize uncertainties created by change, where this is possible.
• Neutralize responses to any failures and wastage that occur as part of
high-response operations, by accepting these as part of change, and by
introducing processes to review and learn from difficulties.
Source: Summarized from Public Service Board (1984) and R. B. Cullen, “The Victorian Senior
Executive Service,” Australian Journal of Public Administration 45, no. 1 (March 1986): 60–68,
73, and chap. 8.
The Challenge of Transition 191
Second, the flexible management structures that had been established were
able to support the new government with very few problems. Third, in ad-
dressing these problems the government moved to reduce cycle time and to
reduce expectations of government. This also acted to manage comfort zone
tensions, at least in its initial term.
In 1996, the Kennett government was generally seen to have been suc-
cessful and was reelected for a second term. Just as the government’s first
term was seen as a successful response to an external crises, the government’s
second term was seen as failing to build on this success. As the financial
crises receded, Kennett was increasingly seen as arrogant and insensitive to
comfort zone issues. In an interesting parallel with Margaret Thatcher, he
came to believe that adding value was simply a matter of continuing to pursue
his own particular values and solutions.
The government was increasingly criticized over perceived favoritism in
its dealings with business, and showed a weak appreciation of the conflicts
which can occur between private and public interests. The government moved
to stifle criticism and to dismantle those with the scope to independently
review its operations. In particular, Kennett moved to reduce the powers of
the state auditor, one of the few remaining statutory bodies able to examine
and report on the activities of executive government in Victoria.
Although business continued to thrive in Victoria, in important areas
such as health and education, the Kennett government was seen as failing to
add value. Government outputs were not evaluated, discussion of these issues
was resisted by the government, and the resources allocated to areas of gov-
ernment such as health and education were not benchmarked against other
states. Education funded well over the Australian average in 1992, was cut to
below the Australian average by 1998. Outputs from education and health
were seen to fall.
Over this period, regional Australia was hard hit by external factors.
While no easy solutions existed for governments around Australia, the Kennett
government abandoned key elements of comfort zone management by failing
to manage the impact of various policies on regional Victoria and by appear-
ing disinterested in the needs of those outside the state capital.
In 1999, Kennett failed to win a third term of government, losing a close
election.
Deregulation/Reregulation Tension
The tensions between pressures for deregulation and the need to also reregulate
need to be managed skillfully if the benefits of transitions are to be delivered.
Most transitions must deregulate in order to reduce cycle time and costs and
to provide government managers with the scope to manage. This often in-
creases uncertainty and negatively impacts the comfort zone. While govern-
ment activities and services often require new forms of strategic regulation,
the purpose of regulation should be to produce defined results. Regulations
The Challenge of Transition 197
The case study illustrates the need to manage change as a transition using
cycle time management and cycle impact management techniques. Initially
the Cain governments were keen to criticize program performance and com-
mit to improvement. In the first term some improvements were delivered and
the public saw the reforms as progressive. Later, as debt increased and disas-
ters emerged, the public grew to discount promised benefits and criticize
delays in delivering promised results. In the end, the government was re-
moved by electors and a new government, the Kennett government was elected
to fix the problems created by financial mismanagement.
Chapter 8
199
200 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
The Reagan Administration’s view (OMB 1990) of the need for planning and
the need to reform budget processes makes an interesting comparison with the
Clinton Administration’s (Gore 1993) focus. While there are similarities there
are also differences. The Reagan model sees program budgeting as central to
the process; the Clinton reforms focus on the evaluation of performance by
devolved agencies. The end solution requires both these perspectives: planning
needs to be devolved to natural business and project groups; also the perfor-
mance of these groups needs to be evaluated centrally to correct mistakes and
ensure that the public interest can be addressed at each level of the process.
In chapter 2, we argued that business and government approach strategic
management differently. Exhibit 8.1. Reasons Why Government Plan lists a
range of applications of planning in government agencies. Only the first
group of reasons, which address performance management or added value,
has direct parallels with business planning. Even there as we have discussed,
goals are more complex and require more negotiation. The other groups of
reasons identified in Exhibit 8.1, comfort zone management and political
management add important dimensions to planning in government. In busi-
ness plans are often a guide to action. In government, the objective of plans
is seldom action. Instead, government planning processes are often used to
develop consensus, to allocate resources and provide a framework for com-
pliance, and ultimately to define rules to protect individual autonomy.
Business strategic management models scan the environment for opportu-
nities, examine what an organization would like to exploit, examine the re-
source and strategic base, and assesses what is feasible; then business selects
a viable strategy. Once selected, that strategy is used to develop purpose driven
budgets and structures. Government starts with agencies, structures, or interest
groups, allocates scarce resources to these groups, and then decides how best
to spend these resources. Agencies that have resources seek to lock up base
funding and minimize the prospects of reallocations. Agencies that need re-
sources seek to present their needs as more important than they really are.
We have oversimplified these differences to ague that reforming govern-
ment planning must change the strategic management role in government
agencies from securing and spending resources to one of adding value by
delivering results. Government value systems tend to presume that resources
(inputs) rather than the need to respond strategically to external opportunities
and threats (outputs) or the need to deliver planned results (implementation)
is the constraint to action.
Planning and Evaluation Strategies for Competitive Government 201
What are the limitations of strategic planning in the business sector and how
might these impact on the use of strategic planning in the government sector?
As businesses become more complex, plans become more complex. In benign
environments, planning can remain introspective, seeking to coordinate all
aspects of a business. The ideal of an integrated plan supported by an inte-
grated information and control system is too mechanistic to survive in the
uncertain world of business. It must be replaced by three important ideas.
First, planning should be driven by external rather than internal realities;
planning should scan the environment for opportunities and threats; it should
assist organizations to neutralize threats and exploit opportunities. Second,
planning and control should focus on a few core ideas that matter for a given
competitive transition rather than everything which occurs in an organization.
Third, the key to managing responses to a dynamic environment is to intro-
duce modularity and simplify interfaces rather than to attempt to retain high
levels of internal integration.
However, strategic planning for business has often failed to deliver high-
response solutions. Henry Mintsberg (1994) in an important review of stra-
tegic planning warns against adopting processes such as strategic planning as
a substitute for strategic thinking and management. He draws a distinction
between analysis which underpins planning and implementation processes
and synthesis which underpins the development of strategy. Mintsberg’s point
is that, although these processes are useful tools for implementing strategic
responses, they do not produce strategic thinking or priorities. Many break-
downs can be traced to ineffective strategic thinking caused by an overreli-
ance on planning processes which all too readily produce their own inertia.
Ralph D. Stacey (1990) in a powerful analysis of the impact of volatility
on planning suggests that the focus of control changes. For a closed environ-
ment where outcomes are predictable, he suggests that control by analysis
and the management of variance is appropriate. As the environment becomes
less certain but can be contained, control breaks down but grand plans can
still be used to focus control. In turbulent environments, requiring high-response
times, the end goals change. Control needs to focus on specific impacts rather
204 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
If Stacey is correct, and we think he probably is, his analysis has four
major implications for the way in which governments must change the way
in which they plan and evaluate.
First, the traditional approach which segmented short-term budget control
from grand plans must be bridged. Government organizations need planning
but they do not need an out-of-date road map to a future which will never exist.
Second, the focus of planning must move close to the impacts it seeks
to create. Trial and error cannot be centralized and institutionalized. Outputs
and results cannot be planned as part of some remote program aggregation.
The focus of planning and control must differ to fit the external and internal
requirements confronting an agency or program.
Third, planning frameworks must cease attempting to remove uncertainty
and focus that uncertainty on the links between short-run impacts and longer-
term missions. Planning frameworks need to focus the judgment of managers
on these linkages rather than away from them. Planning must allow scanning
of the environment which alters long-term missions.
Fourth, the opportunism which Stacey identifies as part of dynamic plan-
ning in business also seems critical for government, but the focus may be
different. Many government products and services are more stable than busi-
ness services, but the problem of implementing change is more difficult. As
we have discussed earlier, much of the opportunism in government involves
timing: starting projects when there is support; delivering them rapidly; using
the results of one change experiment to build the scope for the next.
they call for a clarification of agency functions and roles to remove overlaps.
Quite apart from the danger of paying consultants to convert their solutions
into client problems, the planning processes which they introduced seldom do
more than reflect the existing culture of the government organizations. Many
attempts to reform government machinery at this general level increase rather
than decrease bureaucratic conflict over territory and resources.
While strategic planning can be adapted to address many of these govern-
ment needs, attempts to transplant the business planning model to government
without adaptation have often failed to deliver value. There are a number of
simple translations of strategic planning to the government sector. First, plan-
ning can be used to draw together an overview of the way in which the parts
of government must interrelate and contribute to key missions and objectives.
Such plans focus on grand visions, on macroroles, on functions, and on re-
sources. Second, planning can be associated with budgets to assist government
to resolve key allocative tensions and to explain the general purpose to which
government expenditure are directed. Third, planning can also be used to con-
sult interest groups and explore the impacts of various options. Such plans
should never attempt to plan action. They are exploratory, they need to outline
problems, stimulate reactions and explore a range of options.
The limitations of strategic planning in high-response situations identified
by Stacey and Mintsberg’s criticisms are both highly relevant to government.
Henry Mintsberg’s call for strategic leadership is more difficult to address
because government systems have typically discouraged strategic thinking.
Stacey’s call for short-run control and long-term flexibility runs counter to
government values, which focus on grand plans and end points rather than
short-term results. The need for experimentation and short-run evaluation is
based on the need to learn by trial and error, to learn from both success and
failure. In government, failure is seen as dysfunctional rather than a learning
experience. The traditional government solution is to avoid short-term evalu-
ation at all costs.
For example, the Clinton-Gore reforms in the U.S. illustrate the chal-
lenge of introducing performance planning in government. These reforms
have added value to the competitiveness of government in the U.S.; a number
of agencies have improved customer service and reduced costs; old manage-
ment values have shifted.
However, the links between detailed improvements and the core perfor-
mances of government are not defined for many agencies. Where there is an
alignment between agency and national roles, the changes are likely to add
value. Where there is no alignment, the planning process is likely to reduce
value by obscuring the need for discontinuous change. Where the planning
process becomes an end in itself, Minzberg’s “strategic leadership” seems
likely to be one of the early casualties. Solutions such as external benchmarking
and evaluation, a closer examination of the impact of agency performance on
206 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
the success or failure of key missions. Ensure that evaluation addresses im-
pacts on both the comfort zone and added value axis of the Implementation
Impact Model. Fourth, institute a series of ongoing detailed audits which will
provide useful feedback but at the same time desensitize the public to detailed
evaluations. Implementation problems can seldom be identified in isolation
from solutions. The scope of government audits needs to be extended to
require audit groups to consult with managers and to offer realistic solutions
to major problems rather than a scorecard on performance.
Exhibit 8.2 details the three-column model used in the plan to translate gen-
eral objectives into implementation strategies and impacts. This system al-
lows the short-term control and long-term flexibility discussed by Stacey,
which essentially affects the left-hand column and part of the implementation
strategies with the identification of short-run impacts. Short-run impacts pro-
vide a basis for evaluating progress and for the management of implementa-
tion impacts.
Planning and Evaluation Strategies for Competitive Government 209
STRATEGIC RELATIONSHIPS
Strategic fit analysis examines the fit between management and support action strat-
egies and program delivery objectives, both short- and long-term. This involves a
review of structures, values, systems, resource management, and information systems
to optimize their contribution to government performance.
The system provides a basis for shortening evaluation cycles and for a
flexible ongoing evaluation of performance. Plans that do not explore impacts
are difficult to evaluate. Plans that do not specify links with the core objec-
tives of government tend to develop their own focus and agenda or worse
enable participants to project different agenda onto the reforms.
The three-column implementation impact model facilitates the processes
of planning and evaluation. Planning, using this framework, is a left to right
process with a major focus on implementation and external fit issues, evalu-
ation is a right to left process with a major focus on short-run impacts, an
evaluation of the implications for strategies, and the achievement of longer-
term objectives. The links between impacts and strategies and objectives are
flexible. The system is designed to focus judgments about these linkages
rather than replace the need for such judgment.
We will now illustrate the application of the PIPES framework to three
quite different government management situations.
In the early 1980s, the Australian tax system was in crisis. Tax statutes had
become noncompetitive. Many legal and some illegal practices had grown to
the point where the national taxation base was threatened. The agency re-
sponsible for collecting tax, the Australian Taxation Office (ATO) was fo-
cused on the processing requirements of a rapidly failing system. More
importantly, public exposure of various problems had led to a lack of confidence
in the equity of the tax system and in the capacity of the tax collection agency
to perform.
Planning and Evaluation Strategies for Competitive Government 211
External Fit between Reform Policies and the External Change Priorities
The program delivery objectives reflected the major organizational units within
the agency. Each of these units had a change agenda. The plan can be used
to focus on the coordination of these changes and to identify strategic issues
that must be managed to deliver planned external responses. The key objec-
tives were: to collect tax revenue; to reform tax legislation in order to block
loopholes and simplify administration; to manage the impact of change on the
community; to improve the system for resolving disputes; to improve the
effectiveness of revenue collection including debt collection, the issue of tax
assessments, and the development of systems to support the revenue collec-
tion programs; to increase taxpayer compliance and revenue collections by
developing new approaches to audit.
Clearly the program delivery strategies are interrelated. The increased
compliance objective is dependent on all of the earlier objectives. Traditional
government planning and project systems tend to segment these changes and
treat interrelationships as secondary issues. Unless these systems become
strategic and manage external relationships actively, the risk is that individual
changes will be completed without achieving the overall impacts required.
The plan links objectives to strategies to impacts moving from left to right in
Exhibit 8.3. Most change strategies commence with a general view of objec-
tives, a focus on strategies, and little focus on the immediate (within one year
impacts). The planning framework links these elements and enables the links
between individual change strategies and overall objectives to be examined;
it enables cycle impact management to be developed.
The impacts in the right-hand column of the plan provide a basis for
examining implementation impacts and cycle time issues. Many of the change
programs extended beyond one year. Traditional planning processes did not
focus on immediate impacts. The translation into immediate impacts enables
various impact management tools to be used and enable various short-run
coordination issues to be explored. Internally, the focus on short-run impacts
identified key interdependencies. The review addressed the need to communi-
cate cycle impacts to a wider audience, notably the government audit group and
legislators interested to evaluate the change process. Exhibit 8.4. Projected
Change Impacts presented a summary of the changes projected for the ATO in
one, three, and five years.
Externally, the audit problem reflected a failure to manage cycle expec-
tations. Essentially because the timing of impacts was not part of the com-
munication agenda, the basis for evaluation was weakened and unrealistic
expectations about change developed. The case illustrates the importance of
managing cycle time and cycle impacts. Cycle-based management and com-
munications are important. Selling end solutions to a public whose evaluation
cycle is growing ever shorter, is a prescription for failure. The ATO could
easily have published Exhibit 8.4 at the commencement of the change pro-
cess. Had this occurred, much of the unease about the change process might
have diminished. In addition, the public would have been placed in a position
to evaluate progress against the ATOs own assessment of likely impacts.
Our next example of strategic planning in action examines the use of the
PIPES framework to review overall strategies for reform and to identify and
remove a number of implementation blockages. The case examines the man-
agement of reforms to expand the schooling options available for children
with disabilities in the public school system in one state of Australia (Victoria).
We start by discussing the underlying problem which reformers set out
to solve. School students with disabilities were traditionally streamed into
special schools resourced to meet their special needs. The streaming and the
special schools tended to focus on particular medical disabilities.
In recent years, there has been a trend for countries to review options
for the education of disabled children and to resource options which enable
some such students to be educated in a regular school, assisted by specialist
support services. This option is described as the “‘integration” or “regular
schooling” option. The state of Victoria led Australian developments in this
field.
Reforms in the Victorian school system aimed to make access to regular
school an option for all children with disabilities. Initial resistance was high.
By any standards the change was highly successful. The change strategy is
summarized below.
• To declare that all parents had a choice; if they chose a regular school,
the school must enroll the handicapped child.
• To establish a series of committees to allocate funding and support
services to each child on the basis of availability and need.
• To lobby for additional resources as additional students transferred to
or were identified in the regular school system.
• To argue against any form of classification of students and to promote
regular school options as offering high-value to all students.
218 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
The regular schooling option grew and the budget to support it grew.
Advocates saw this as proving that regular schooling could meet all needs.
The impact of the success of this program on special schools was largely
ignored. These schools continued to grow but the students enrolled were
now those with greater levels of disability. Special schools sought to repo-
sition their programs in order to meet the needs of different groups of
students; this was resisted by those who saw the success of integration as
making special schooling irrelevant. Advocates of the regular school option
sought to sell this as the only progressive option for all students. Special
schools instead of being seen as part of the solution for disabled students
were seen as resisting change and consuming resources better allocated to
regular school options.
The success of the strategy created new problems which were not recog-
nized by those working within the frameworks which had been established to
manage the initial change. The first problem was related to resourcing and
delays. The lack of assessment and evaluation made it very difficult not only
to manage numbers, but also to ensure that the available resources were
targeted to those needing assistance. The committee structure dealt with needs
on a case-by-case basis. While this is a highly effective approach for a small
pilot change program, it is a senseless approach for an established program
facing ongoing pressures to expand. The value-chain meant that students
were often enrolled and the additional resources were provided later. This
placed students and schools in an impossible position. It placed the commit-
tees in an unnecessarily powerful position. The procedures for allocating
resources through committees proved cumbersome and, more importantly,
caused delays. Students were enrolled without resources and the consultative
processes were then seen to add value by acquiring these resources.
Second, freedom of choice became freedom to select the regular school-
ing option. This combined with the lack of assessment and evaluation led to
a failure to recognize the need to also develop special school options. Advo-
cates of the regular schooling options grew to feel that once the option worked
for some students it should work for all. The strategy to phase out special
schools seemed to be to contain and then reduce the funding for special
schools, to reduce their capacity to add value by fencing off collaboration
between special schools and regular schools, and to oppose the distribution
of information about special school options to parents.
Third, advocates of the “integration” option failed to see or understand
the need for ongoing performance improvement. For example, even when the
audit report quite correctly identified major problems with the program, these
could not be communicated effectively to those involved. The value of a
number of constructive suggestions for change was in danger of being lost.
Planning and Evaluation Strategies for Competitive Government 219
External Criticisms
In 1992, the state auditor tabled a devastating report of the program. The
audit report suggested there was no control of the effectiveness of the pro-
gram. Far from transferring students from special schools, the program had
increased the total numbers of students identified as disabled, and initiatives
to provide specialist support had failed to deliver. The government response
was to criticize the audit report and suggest that the auditor did not under-
stand the issues involved. It was a classic case of government attempting to
shoot the messenger.
The government commissioned an independent review of the programs.
This review (Cullen and Brown 1992) used the performance management
framework to evaluate program performance and to assist participants to
refocus on the educational needs of students. The review supported many
of the audit criticisms and laid out a plan for improvement. Exhibit 8.5.
Draft Performance Improvement Plan: Integration and Special Education in
Victorian Schools presents a summary of the plan presented in the report of
the review.
This planning framework had different objectives to the PIPES plan pre-
pared to strengthen strategic focus for the ATO discussed earlier. In this
case, the plan was used to assist participants in these systems to understand
the need to see both regular and special school options as part of an overall
solution for children with disabilities. Although the program delivery state-
ments seem obvious, they broke new ground for many of these involved
who had come to support particular solutions on a somewhat doctrinaire
basis.
The policy of student choice had become a one way choice—to attend
a regular school. There was no evaluation of educational outcomes because
this was seen to type particular students. There was considerable resistance
to producing advice to parents that laid out the various regular and special
school options. The first strategy in the plan attacked this blockage head on.
The review included a draft information sheet that combined details of all
available programs.
The idea that schooling in special schools was more costly than resourcing
programs for similar students in regular schools was disproved by unit costs
included in the Cullen/Brown report. The resource management issue was not
to save resources by transferring students between special and regular schools
but to allocate resources against student’s needs quickly and more effectively.
220 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
• A salary structure for the SES bands used overlapping pay ranges. This
provided the scope for performance pay; it provided flexibility to re-
cruit externally without disturbing established relativities, and it broke
the direct link between pay and status which underpinned the tradi-
tional system.
Three values were identified as required to drive the new SES system.
First, improved program delivery and service to the public comes from im-
proving management in public sector agencies. Second, evaluating the results
of change and improvement initiatives is critical to ensuring that real im-
provements in value are delivered to the public. Third, effective service to the
public requires a senior management system which actively seeks to maxi-
mize the contribution of each senior manager.
(continued)
Planning and Evaluation Strategies for Competitive Government 225
Exhibit 8.6. General SES Key Result Areas and Competencies (Cont.)
Key Result Area Competencies
GENERAL • The capacity to contribute to overall agency
MANAGEMENT— perspectives on corporate issues outside the
Corporate direct responsibility of the manager
Management • The capacity to ensure that individual decisions
Be an effective manager are consistent with the corporate policies and
of the senior management priorities of the agency
team within an agency • The capacity to assist colleagues to achieve
particular manager results for which they have primary
responsibility
• The capacity to work with colleagues to achieve
results where these require a joint contribution
GENERAL • The capacity to manage staff effectively and to
MANAGEMENT— achieve agreed results
Personnel • The capacity to consult with staff to develop a
Management work environment which meets staff needs and
The management of human in which the staff is used effectively
resources of the organization • The capacity to understand and use the personnel
to enable it to deliver system to recruit, promote, and organize staff
approved projects or effectively
programs effectively • The capacity to ensure that the personnel system
operates on the basis of merit and that
government EEO policies and programs are
implemented effectively
• The capacity to develop the management potential
of staff to provide for the future needs of an
agency and the public employment
GENERAL • The capacity to understand and use the budget
MANAGEMENT— system of government to ensure that resource
Resource needs are considered and proper priorities
Management addressed
The management of all • The capacity to adapt targets and programs to
human, financial, and match the resources allocated to deliver them,
physical resources available to monitor and manage resources, to deliver
to the manager to deliver agreed programs and projects within agreed
priority program results budgets
efficiently and effectively • The capacity to identify, diagnose, and address
resource issues that affect program delivery
• The capacity to identify areas of low priority
in the areas under the managers direct control,
to identify resources for reallocation, and to
introduce improvements to ensure that
available resources are used effectively
226 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
229
230 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
These systems were driven by four ideas about management: the idea
that development could be incremental; fairness, rather than performance,
should be the focus of government management; success requires rules to
ensure predictable treatment; and, finally, the inefficiencies associated with
failure can be avoided by rules designed to identify and require compliance
with “best practice management processes” which were seen to be indepen-
dent of the task required. None of these ideas can survive the transition to
high-response management. A misplaced belief that the past can be revisited,
that these ideas will somehow reemerge triumphant, has caused many other-
wise useful changes to collapse.
There are two prerequisites for the implementation of specific transitions.
First, before ideas like cycle time management, performance planning, and
evaluation can be translated into action, management structures and systems
need to be altered to connect government managers to these new management
Government Management Systems and Values 231
tools and to remove system blockages to response. Second, new systems need
to protect against the twin forces of reversion and inertia that often emerge
to erode the benefit of particular reforms.
The management and system strategies and tools available to support a
particular transition to competitive government are outlined in Exhibit 9.1.
Performance Management Strategies / Tools for Government Transitions. Value-
chains need to be shortened by reengineering the core technologies used by
many government systems. Conventional structures and regulatory regimes
must change to high-response solutions. Personnel and resource management
systems must change to focus not only on new needs and on results, but also
to shift core organizational values. Finally, new structures and systems need
a new focus on change management and on building a management platform
for ongoing improvement.
It is the purpose of this chapter to discuss each of these changes, to
identify common difficulties, and to outline effective solutions and change
management tools.
Corporate Government
Mega Agencies
Major Program Clusters
The idea that structure must follow strategy is well-established. It follows that
as the environment forces ongoing changes in the strategies of government
and business agencies, structural changes and resource changes must follow.
Traditional government structures and resource management systems com-
mence with structures (or “fiefdoms”) move to resource allocations, and then
address the detailed delivery of results. In many respects, the challenge of
Government Management Systems and Values 233
There are real limits to the efficiency and effectiveness that any
government can achieve. These limits arise from the nature of the
problems that governments are obliged to address, from the
constraints that governments must honor in attempting to solve
the problems, from the large scale of many government organiza-
tions, and from the intentionally adversarial character of govern-
ment processes.
—Downs and Larkey, The Search for Government Efficiency
Indeed one could say that firms become lethargic and bureau-
cratic when the practices, systems, and controls in place take on
a life of their own, divorced from the business problems they were
designed to address.
—Fombrun, Turning Points
The role of personnel management is to attract, retain, and motivate the staff
required to deliver key results, to match the skills of staff to the tasks to be
performed, and to do this cost effectively by minimizing the long-term costs
to government of personnel resources. The need to alter personnel systems
and organizational values has been discussed. In this section, we examine
specific solutions and threats.
The need to reform resource management is central to shortening cycle
time and developing more flexible structures. The solution is to move to
results-based budgeting focused on operating units. Because of its impor-
tance, we discuss this particular reform in chapter 10.
VALUE SHIFT
Away from management values that see performance in terms of not failing
toward values that focus in the need to actually succeed: Management values
that see performance as inevitable have ignored the need to define performance
and to manage the delivery of services to the public.
Away from a focus on failure toward a focus on meeting changing needs:
Management values, which see change as a response to failure rather than a
response to new external priorities, maximize the trauma of change.
Away from unfettered freedom toward how managers use flexibility, whether
they deliver agreed results: “Devolution at any cost” solutions have encouraged
the dismantling of traditional controls without developing increased accountability
for results.
Toward accepting that structures and systems are management variables to be
used to deliver performance rather than a fixed framework within which
performance is defined: “Business management” solutions have sought to
transplant business solutions into the government sector without developing the
focus on performance required to guide these approaches.
Away from prescribed roles toward discretionary roles that use skills and
optimize value for the organization: Bureaucratic job design, which separate
work roles from the skills and capacities of persons in positions, have
underemphasized the importance of the discretionary component of work roles.
Away from consensus and legislative cycles as dominant determinates of
success toward values that see impact management and implementation and
critical: Management values, which see legislative and budget approvals as a
mandate to implement without managing comfort zone impacts, often find the
mandate evaporates as interest groups block or alter changes.
Away from values that see cycle times as fixed toward values that see cycle
time as a key management variable: Management values, which see cycle time
as a given and presume that implementation follows from regulated consumption,
miss the opportunity to manage cycle times and impacts.
Away from remedial communications toward a focus on using communications
to manage cycle timing and to manage the gap between public expectations of
change and the benefits actually delivered: Management values, which see
success in terms of completing programs, and communicate this to interest groups,
often find the gap between their concept of success and the communities expecta-
tions of them is large.
change crisis is seen to have passed. Second, the threat that in seeking to
consolidate new arrangements systems will introduce new inertia against
ongoing change.
242 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
Three key management tools can be used to build ongoing change and
improvement skills into government systems. The first is the use of a network
of performance contracts. Contracts ensure that broad changes can be trans-
lated into structures rapidly. The second is the use of project teams to manage
critical changes. Project teams can shorten cycle time and because they are
short-lived they can avoid some of the institutional inertia that is created
when organizational units develop and own particular changes. In chapter 5,
we discussed continuous improvement processes and the needs to maintain
the effectiveness of government structures.
Agency Structures
Committee
PROJECT TEAM
▼ ▼
▼
Monitoring Process
sector. There are major skills and abilities to learn differences between these
two groups.
Second, successful organizations had a full array of continuous improve-
ment tools available to managers and employees (i.e., self-managed, cross-
functional, benchmarking, and outside linking teams) and provided specific
training in the most successful versions of each type of program while unsuc-
cessful organizations did not.
Third, successful governmental organizations modified continuous improve-
ment tools to fit the unique hierarchical management systems they employed,
while motivating performance through competitive peer pressure and institu-
tionalizing inhouse learning from the organization’s most successful units. Thus,
let us explore: first, one model of a successful continuous program, and second,
outline several examples of its effective implementation.
reports excluding their own. Peer review is undertaken for three reasons. It
allows each team to learn from all the other teams. Peer review is always the
most informed and most critical evaluation which can be provided, because
all workers are knowledgeable and involved in the same task. The rank order-
ing of team performance creates a competition and learning environment for
all teams which provides high motivation in the next attempt to continuously
improve.
Sixth, the peer reviews on each team are then made public and can but
do not need to be included in each individual’s annual performance appraisal.
Such an inclusion creates three important performance outcomes. It provides
a measure of an individual’s team effort. It provides an across individuals
evaluation of performance not directly tied to one’s supervisor. It provides
increased pressure to improve performance in the next try based on peer
perceptions.
Seventh, one begins this process all over again with either the same or
new set of priorities and targets. Normally, such cycles in government are
three to six months in time. Such continuous improvement programs have
several unique features which enhance governmental performance. Note that
on future attempts to improve, most teams will attempt to far exceed the
targets set in order to gain peer approval. This process creates a culture in
which change, top-down and or bottom up, is readily accepted because it is
initiated so frequently from the bottom up. While removing the manager’s
individual responsibility for evaluating success or failure, it makes manage-
ment an integral part of the team process. It allows each team to set its
measures of performance with management approval thus allowing for con-
sensual measures of performance. Finally, multiple teams at work in each
agency or unit have an additive and sometimes even a multiplicative effect on
organizational motivation, learning, and performance, subsequently lifting pro-
ductivity, quality, and response time.
Successful improvement programs have been used in (1) the Malaysian Min-
istry of Education to reengineer its technical education system by benchmarking
the Singapore, German, and American technical educational systems (MTDI
1996); (2) the Egyptian Ministry of Agriculture to privatize agricultural pro-
grams in the upper Nile, by employing cross-functional teams to develop
marketing, sales, and distribution functions for their organizations (MTDI
1996); (3) in Poland by the Ministry of Commerce to create medium and
248 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
For a country, the value system is like the overhead costs in a company.
They have to be paid in priority at the beginning of each budget year. Com-
petitiveness should provide the necessary wealth creation to pay for the value
Government Management Systems and Values 249
system a country has chosen. The more sophisticated the system, the more
competitive the country has to be.
The dilemma is that, if a country loses its competitiveness, then it cannot
afford to pay for its value system anymore. In a first stage, governments step
in to soften the reality. This is what they did in the 1980s through massive
public spending. Eventually, however, their level of indebtedness becomes
such that they are confronted with the delicate alternative of either reducing
the cost and the scope of the value system, or significantly increasing com-
petitiveness. To be competitive, a government must shift to an output
performance-oriented management system, effectively employ project man-
agement and continuous improvement programs, and be evaluated against the
best governments and most effective programs in the world, or lose its com-
petitiveness and modify its value systems to fit within its diminishing re-
sources for implementing that value system.
might the change process be protected from these dangers? The answer is to
evaluate the reforms in the same way the reformers argue that agency man-
agement should be evaluated, in other words, focus on noticeable changes in
results. While it is necessary to also monitor surrogates like system changes,
for example, strategic plans, and financial deregulation, the end evaluation is
not whether these are implemented or whether the government power base
has shifted, the test is whether all this has generated noticeable improvements
in national competitiveness and in service to the public.
Osborne and Gaebler present a powerful model for moving beyond sys-
temic reform. They focus on best practice examples, on pilot changes, and on
experiments leading to improved performance. The strength of Osborne and
Gaebler’s work is that it benchmarks examples of best practice. The reform
proposals developed by the National Performance Review are extensive, but
are they enough to overcome the problems identified? The danger implicit in
the implementation of these ideas in the U.S. government are: cycle time will
stretch rather than shrink; the system will impose its own uniformity; the
central political controls will not be altered to enable units to deliver value;
and collectively the system will be unable to alter internal funding priorities
fast enough to respond to new opportunities rather than deficits.
The need to strengthen the implementation strategy in the U.S. is becom-
ing apparent. Mission overlaps and fragmentation are widespread (Mihm 2000).
Middle level jobs have proliferated and job design remains bureaucratic (Light
2000). The continuous improvement process seems to be addressing second
and third order problems. J. Christopher Mihm, arguing the need for ongoing
reform, concludes that focusing delivery agencies on results does not come
quickly or easily. Donald F. Kettl (2000), reviewing progress, suggests that,
while much has been achieved, two key deficits remain: “government’s per-
formance deficit—the gap between government’s goals and its results—and
its confidence deficit—citizens’ trust in its ability to get its job done.”
We argue that performance-based structures, value-chains, and personnel
and resource management systems are required to implement particular tran-
sitions to competitive government reform. Change management needs to protect
the system from the twin threats of reversion and inertia by ensuring that one-
off changes are irreversible and, by building into each, change processes that
commit the system to ongoing evaluation and improvement.
Chapter 10
251
252 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
create new wealth and employment. The impact of these changes on comfort
zones must be managed skillfully. Each reduction disenfranchises some inter-
est group or other and provides a focus for those who wish to erode the scope
of government to govern.
Responding to this crisis requires government to reinvent and reengineer
the way in which they allocate and manage resources. Most government
budgets are input not output driven. Most government budgets focus on ac-
cessing resources and allocating resources between competing needs. Most
forward financial projections are little more than bids designed by agencies
to access new funds and protect existing funding. It is not therefore surprising
that attempts to reform government management must address the need to
manage resources differently.
This section discusses the changes to resource management required to
support a transition to high-response government. We discuss the need to
manage an emerging fit between the sources and applications of funds, and
we discuss the need for budgets which focus on results, on costs, and on
prices rather than on inputs such as staffing numbers and line items of expen-
diture. Finally, we present an action plan for a transition to results focused
budgets.
The role of budgets in government differs from the role of budgets in busi-
ness. The role of budgets in government is: (a) to access funds frorm various
sources; (b) to regulate access to those funds; (c) to manage the tensions
created by the need to allocate funds between competing needs; (d ) to ratify
the negotiations required to achieve political and public support for govern-
ment; and, (e) to provide a basis for compliance auditing, which essentially
seeks to ensure that funds are spent for the purposes allocated.
Many attempts to reform government resource management systems
address only part of the resource management problem. For example, initia-
tives like program budgeting, while they certainly reshape reporting and
allocative tensions, are unlikely to solve the problem of ongoing government
deficits; they seldom shift the emphasis of resource management towards the
sort of grass roots results the public expect from government.
Strategies which enable government resource systems to support the tran-
sition to high response government are outlined in Exhibit 10.1. Improving
the Performance of Government Resource Management. We will now exam-
ine each of these objectives, managing resource balance, and, shifting to
results-based budgeting, in more detail.
Exhibit 10.1. Improving the Performance of Government Resource Management
Key Objectives Action Strategy for Implementation Impacts or Verification Outcomes
Resource Balance • Extend the financial planning horizon to • Balance government budgets
Manage government activities coordinate growth in revenues and expenditure • Increase the lead time available to managers
to balance available and to ensure an emerging balance and to minimize to vary resources
required resources without short-term disruption caused by short-run cuts
253
254 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
comfort zone impacts. Budget reform must also address the new allocative
pressures which targeting and extending the budget planning horizon places
on budget systems. Unless these pressures are managed effectively, they will
impact directly on the comfort zone by making government more difficult.
Exhibit 10.1 outlines three strategies for managing resource balance:
extend the planning horizon, manage the revenue base; manage the ex-
penditure base; and restructure budgets to manage allocative tensions more
effectively.
The first requirement for resource balance is to extend the planning horizon
in order to manage and contain emerging gaps. The key to effective resource
management reform is to establish a basis for the long term viability of
government which does not depend on overspending.
Exhibit 10.2. Managing Government Resource Balance outlines the ele-
ments which must be managed to balance resources. The first point to make
about the process is that resources always balance after the event. If the
process is not planned, the usual balancing items will be borrowing or funds
provided by creditors. The resource balance must manage the sources and
application of funds to achieve an emerging resource balance.
When government fails to plan these elements and deficits blowout dur-
ing the year, they have only two options: they must arrange emergency sources
of funding usually through borrowing or delaying payments to creditors; and
they must freeze or reduce expenditure immediately. Expenditure freezes are
best implemented by intervening to control inputs; for example, by freezing
or cutting staffing and halting purchasing. While these devices are effective
crisis management tools which deliver a short-run control, the impacts on
programs, agencies, and results are indiscriminate.
Even where governments manage to develop short term fixes to budget
shortfalls, many governments find that they lurch from one such problem to
another.
RESULTS
A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM
FORECAST ACTIVITY MEASURES
▼
Capital Projects TAXES AND
RESOURCE
Change Projects CHARGES
INPUTS
Staffing Transactions—User Funded
Transactions—General Funds
Purchases
Other Programs
▼
Price/Unit Costs per Direct User Fees ▼
▼ Activity Measure
FOR
RESOURCE RESOURCE
GOVERNMENT CHANGE
APPLICATIONS SOURCES
▼ ▼
RESOURCE
▼
▼
▼
UTILIZATION
Required / Available Borrowings
STRATEGIES FOR ACHIEVING RESOURCE Resources
BALANCE
Increase supply Asset Sales
Increase user charges / increase general taxes
and charges / asset sales / reduce working
capital.
Changes in
Decrease expenditure Working
Reduce activity forecasts / alter activity mix /
Capital
reduce unit prices / increase savings targets /
increase efficiency.
Resource Management Strategies 257
without reducing core activity levels. Second, the way to implement cuts
without reducing impacts is to avoid input controls and to devolve to managers
the scope to manage value-chains and introduce discontinuous change. Third,
the actual operating changes required to deliver given reductions are less than
suggested by forward plans. Most planning bases are inflated by planning
systems used by managers to protect the real base from review and the impact
of cuts. The most effective solution is to change the budget planning meth-
odology to eliminate such overestimates. Where this cannot occur, it is im-
portant that operational managers work off more realistic measures.
government should seek to fund this at marginal cost. The benefits are not
simply that the base is more realistic, the major benefit is the impact on
comfort zones. Many reductions become invisible.
Fourth, the focus on additional funding for new initiatives is seldom
balanced by a realistic assessment of the reductions (or savings) available
because previous initiatives have been completed. Government expenditures
usually comprise a mix of core activities and services and one-off projects to
deliver particular changes and benefits. The core activities need to be linked
to core activity load and productivity assumptions over time. Project activities
need to be evaluated against project plans that are one off in nature. A major
weakness in the design of government budget frameworks is that they focus
on global budgets which mix up these two activities. The effect of many
planning systems is to lock project expenditure into the global base. Although
it may be necessary to complete a project to earn these funds, the real bonus
for an agency is that, after this is completed, the funds keep rolling in forever,
or until they need to be used to absorb some “arbitrary” cut.
Fifth, incremental approaches to resource allocation fail to manage re-
source reductions. Attempts to lock in a budget base which meets existing
commitments and focus the allocation on new initiatives, work effectively in
times of growth. However, the incremental policy approach runs into serious
trouble when it seeks to allocate decreases in resources. In cutback situations,
the base cannot be protected, the funding shortfall is overstated, and the impact
of cuts is maximized. In addition, incremental systems, especially when com-
bined with ineffective evaluation of outcomes against plan, tend to reward
inefficient managers who overspend by leaving at least some of the
overexpenditure in the base for the next year.
There are many options for reducing these weaknesses. One attractive
solution which can eliminate many of these weaknesses and refocus many
government management tasks is to move to results-based budgets. When
government learns to view budgets as a means of purchasing added value, in
terms of transactions or projects, and when managers define their task as
delivering these results within a defined resource envelope negotiated on the
basis of volumes and prices, the budget debate shifts from a focus on protect-
ing inputs to a focus on producing outputs and onto the price of those outputs.
Specific strategies for managing a transition from the traditional budget sys-
tem to a results-based budget system are discussed later.
many options which increase budget flexibility and increase the scope for
government managers to manage, they all impact on comfort zones. Reform
of budgets which do not refocus the allocative tensions which government
must manage almost always fail once the immediate crisis has passed.
The traditional budget system manages allocative tensions by fixing the
budget cycle and focusing allocation on new growth. There are two compelling
reasons why this simple solution must change. First, as discussed above, the
process of cutback management requires an extension of the planning cycle.
Second, the need to devolve management and to provide managers with the
flexibility to manage cycle time and cycle impacts means that commitments
cannot be queued continuously through a centralized annual budget cycle.
Government approaches to resource management must now address wider
tensions unleashed by cutbacks and rapid change. They do this by segmenting
the old tensions into at least three levels and by devolving the management
of implementation of overall decisions to managers with an understanding of
the options and the power to vary detailed priorities and manage impacts.
The first level of tension is the overall allocation to each result area.
Result areas are usually defined in terms of major programs or megaagencies.
The second level of tension is the allocation within that result area to an
agency, bureau, project, or special purpose program. In part, these tensions
focus on the relative worth of outputs and the weighting which should be
used to allocate between agencies and activities.
The third level of tension is cycle time tension. Participants compete to
start programs and to obtain the benefits. The temptation for many govern-
ments is to start too many projects and finish them too slowly. While this may
appear responsive, it actually slows down cycle time and creates uncertainties
about the delivery of benefits. Strategies to manage this are discussed below.
Although they are far from solving the issues of results-based budgets, the
current U.S. reforms call for an extensive dismantling of the traditional sys-
tems and a serious attempt to combine devolution with a focus on results to
drive a new approach to financial management.
The second key objective in Exhibit 10.1 is to manage resources to
deliver results. Shifting the focus of financial management from “gatherer,
custodian and dispenser of funds” to “ensuring that funds add value and
deliver priority results” is a major challenge for government systems. Results
focused resource management needs to shift the government role from input
allocations to the purchase of services. The idea of government budgets as a
vehicle for purchasing services fits well with questions about added value and
the cost of services.
There are many reasons why the shift to results focused budgets is so
demanding. First, government systems seldom address results or evaluate them
in the short term. Second, government systems seldom fully cost services trans-
actions or projects. Instead, they measure direct costs and sometimes simply
incremental costs (the additional costs which cannot be met from existing
allocation). Third, the source of funding is often remote from those who receive
the benefits. Fourth, the delivery of results is often decentralized and managed
separately from the centralized financial budgeting process.
While there has been much discussion of the need to move to results-
based budgets for government agencies, strategies to achieve this are more
difficult to find. In this section, we identify a number of key issues which
must be addressed and then present a strategy for reform.
263
value project plans to expenditure.
264 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
on current and emerging priorities rather than on past priorities. New admin-
istrations seem relatively able to do this. However, the older a government
grows the harder it finds this process of closing down its own failures or of
recognizing that priorities, which seemed sensible a few years ago, are no
longer relevant.
How can the transition to results-based budgets break the nexus between
budget cycles and project delivery cycles to allow managers to shorten cycle
times? Results-based budgets meet two key needs of high-response manage-
ment, First the system enables base priorities to be aligned with future and
emerging needs more rapidly. Second, the system provides a new flexibility
for operating managers to manage inputs and cycle time. These flexibilities
can be extended by exploring a number of business-government comparisons.
static world inhabited by very gifted planners. In the real world, fully commit-
ted budgets represent a straitjacket within which change managers must seek to
operate. This overcommitment is explained by the belief that funds that are not
committed will be lost in cutback situations and by the difficulty managers find
in allocating cutbacks. Agency and program managers usually maintain their
own hidden reserves of resources. They need to be assisted to budget minimum
levels of discretionary resources; they need to be evaluated in terms of the
effectiveness with which they used such resources.
The need to provide operational managers with increased scope to man-
age cycle time was discussed above. This flexibility can be increased by a
number of devices which require flexible bridging funding but which increase
accountability for results.
• The idea of charging for working capital and project capital can be
associated with increased flexibility to manage timing.
• The idea of results-based funding is often focused by paying part or all
of grants when services are delivered. Although agencies would re-
quire working capital funding to shift to such an arrangements, it can
be an effective strategy. For example, paying for part of education
places when students enroll and paying part of the funding when they
complete their schooling is a logical way to shift market forces in these
notoriously input driven areas of government.
• Finally, there is the issue of who owns savings. Osborne and Gaebler
are correct is suggesting that the traditional system persecutes per-
formers. We need to ensure that the new financial management sys-
tems, which are evolving, do not repeat this mistake. If a manager can
deliver agreed results at less than the agreed value budget, the system
should encourage this to occur. Whether this is achieved by increased
project allocations, by performance bonuses, or by allowing agencies
to report a surplus instead of underspending needs to be examined.
While reform of financial management alone will not solve the crisis in
government management, it is a prerequisite for effective change. While there
is support for providing additional management flexibility within budgets and
for a move to focus on results rather than inputs, the difficulty of effecting
such transactions are often underestimated.
268 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
Governance Systems
and Management Reform
271
272 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
LEGISLATURE / ASSEMBLY
Tribunals
POLITICAL EXECUTIVE
Ombudsmen
NONPOLITICAL EXECUTIVE
Interest groups
Customers
Electors
Governance Systems and Management Reform 273
added value and governability are delivered more effectively than for compa-
rable governments, then the governance system is effective. If they are not,
then the governance system needs to be reviewed. Usually, the solution involves
improving the performance of executive government. This often involves
adjustment to other parts of the governance system. There are four roles
which the governance system needs to perform effectively.
First, the governance system provides for an examination of and contri-
bution to the priorities of government by elected representatives. Second, the
governance system contains a series of checks and balances While it is im-
portant for there to be an effective review of the performance of executive
government, checks and balances are only part of the solution. Where checks
expose the system to risks of failure, they may need to be augmented. Where
they are paralyzing the system, they may need to be modified to focus on
outcomes rather than processes.
Third, the governance system determines the way in which selected in-
terest groups interact with government. In particular, the legislature provides
a focus for interest group pressures on government. The legal system is in-
creasingly used to develop the power of particular interest groups or to con-
strain the power of executive government. The difficulty for competitive
government is not that there is review but that it introduces delays and forces
management to remove and centralize discretion.
Fourth, the way in which the executive branch coordinates it’s political
and nonpolitical parts is critical to the provision of strategic leadership and
to the devolution of executive functions closer to the users of government
services. In recent years, there has been a shift to convert the role of the
nonpolitical part of the executive branch from providing independent advice
to government, to a role in which it becomes no more than an agent of the
government of the day.
In this chapter, we examine the impact of different systems on the capac-
ity of government to deliver core roles and to manage the transition to na-
tional competitiveness. We suggest that governance systems are yet another
variable which will change as nations not only become more competitive, but
as they require government management to become more competitive. We
present an overview of the variables which need to be managed and the issues
which government management must address. First, we consider a typology
of government systems in order to identify key performance measures and
key management issues which flow from different structures. Second, we
examine the three boundaries identified in Exhibit 11.1: (1) the relationship
between the executive and the legislature; (2) the boundary between political
and nonpolitical parts of the executive; and (3) the boundary between the
274 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
governance system and the various interest groups which define the comfort
zone, enabling government to govern. Finally, we discuss the implications of
this analysis for the transition to competitive government.
This form of executive provides for an elected president separated from the
legislature. The power of executive government is intentionally limited by the
legislature. The United States is an example of this form of executive. The
president serves for a fixed term and can appoint executives to manage gov-
ernment. This system is less dependent on party unity. The system requires
a balance between the legislative and executive roles. Failure to maintain such
a balance can lead to absolute executive power or alternatively to gridlock.
Other forms of executives include the unlimited presidential and military
executives.
Closely related to the role of the executive is the role of the legislature or
assembly. The roles of the legislature, the method of electing the legislature,
and the number of chambers differ between systems.
The role of legislatures includes legitimizing polices developed by the
executive, representing the views of electors, providing a vehicle for national
debate, and scrutinizing the role and performance of the executive.
Of the systems studied all have two chambers except Singapore. The
Japanese and Singapore systems are characterized by long dominance of
particular political parties. Parties able to achieve such dominance build strong
links with special interest groups, particularly those which are critical to
national competitiveness.
The United States, United Kingdom, and Australian systems are adversarial
systems with strong governing and opposition groups in the legislature. The
existence of a strong opposition in the legislature provides an opportunity for
Governance Systems and Management Reform 277
groups who feel disenchanted with government decisions to focus their dis-
content into the political process. The U.S. legislature has developed sepa-
rately from the executive. The capacity of the U.S. legislature to scrutinize the
executive and review performance and advance alternative solution is high.
The committee systems are a more effective means of examining agency
performance than the systems of ministerial accountability used in the parlia-
mentary systems.
The devolution of comfort zone management is constrained by the leg-
islature except where the system is consensual rather than adversarial. The
parliamentary executive system provides for real time scrutiny which tends to
centralize comfort zone management. On the other hand, the use of party
structures often limits scrutiny. The limited presidential system has developed
more effective scrutiny processes. The U.S. committee structures are mark-
edly more effective than those which characterize parliamentary models. On
the other hand, the constraints built into the U.S. system limit its capacity to
respond and increase the pressure to find alternative delivery mechanisms
where responses are critical and need to be rapid.
All political governance systems need to be developed to facilitate the
reengineering of cycle time by removing the legislature from action paths and
strengthening its capacity to map general priorities and scrutinize actual
performance.
The ways in which the political and nonpolitical arms of executive government
interact are critical to the performance of different models of government.
In the U.S. system, the effect of politicization of the executive arm of
government is to increase the burden on the many other checks and balances
created by the Congress and the judiciary. While the U.S. system has many
such mechanisms, the effect is to increase regulation and decrease the scope
for devolution.
In the parliamentary executive systems, the politicization of the executive
arm increases the risks of executive excesses. These systems typically have
fewer checks and balances than the U.S. system. The two main checks are the
Parliament itself which is able to question ministers and debate issues, and
the existence of an independent nonpolitical executive corp which can pro-
vide a counter to executive excesses. Increasingly governments have politi-
cized these systems.
Part of the current reform process is the dismantling of the nonpolitical
part of the executive on the grounds that it has acted to protect its own
entrenched interests. While that is probably accurate, like most reforms the
process can go too far. We have discussed the Victorian experience. This is
paralleled in many other parliamentary executive systems. As these systems
fail, there is a good chance that the controls which the U.S. system has
developed will be imported to contain the scope of parliamentary executives
to act. Alternatively the breakdown of the party system may itself increase the
power of the legislature to scrutinize the performance of the executive in
these systems. As the power of the legislature increase in these systems, they
will need to reinvent and reengineer their internal processes to become more
informed and more effective. There is a danger that this will prevent the
devolution which is required to meet community needs.
What are the implications of this analysis for the development of effective
governance systems?
280 A MANAGEMENT PLATFORM FOR GOVERNMENT CHANGE
283
284 BENCHMARKING THE TRANSITION TO COMPETITIVE GOVERNMENT
This book set out to analyze the crises in government, draw on the new
solutions that are emerging in country after country, and present a framework
285
286 BENCHMARKING THE TRANSITION TO COMPETITIVE GOVERNMENT
address the reality that traditional systems of government have broken down.
There is no simple incremental solution for most government management
systems; they must implement a new management base which meets the
needs of all national stakeholders. If they do not, national competitiveness
will suffer and the well-being of citizens, if not actually eroded, will suffer
compared with nations who elect to be competitive.
There are two implications of our analysis for the reform of government
management. First, governments need to refocus reform from internal to
external factors. Second, governments need to ensure that internal reforms
deliver reduced cycle time (speed), maintain the scope to govern and address
impacts on diverse interest groups (consensus), and deliver expected results
(performance).
While different nations must manage different transitions that require differ-
ent contributions from government, our analysis identifies three common
characteristics of competitive governments: speed, consensus, and performance.
It is interesting that the concepts of speed and strategic response which have
proved so powerful in the business sector also seem to be key to improving
the performance of the government sector. However, the reasons why these
concepts add value in each sector are different.
288 BENCHMARKING THE TRANSITION TO COMPETITIVE GOVERNMENT
The idea of consensus and enthusiasm for government changes is both coun-
terproductive and unnecessary. In reality, government seeks to maintain a
comfort zone within which interest groups and the public allow government
to govern. This approach requires government to find new ways of both
planning strategic priorities and managing the impacts of projects throughout
the project cycle.
Performance. Many changes have not delivered grass roots impacts.
Many government management systems manage processes or functions and
assume that long-term added value is delivered. Few processes manage short-
term impacts unless a crisis emerges which must be addressed. We argue first
that the focus of reform must be to enable managers to manage performance
directly, and second, that the time horizon of these evaluations must be short-
ened rather than extended.
Attempts to convert them to this end will tend to destroy the political consensus
required to support change in a complex system.
Fourth, although both sectors have identified the need to devolve power,
government devolution must address complex performance issues and also
the need to manage comfort zones and diversity. Conventional attempts to
centralize the management of comfort zones and decentralize the manage-
ment of service delivery presume that the fit between these systems can be
maintained. The result is often a complex shared accountability which fails
to add value and often creates new comfort zone tensions. In addition, the
public applies different criteria of fairness to government agencies than they
do to business agencies.
Fifth, the techniques for managing comfort zones, including respect for
differences and a focus on solutions, offering specific rather than common
values, are key to successful public sector management. Although these tech-
niques are not part of most business solutions, they can often be added.
Where business solutions cannot be adapted to manage complexity and com-
fort zones, transplantation runs a high risk of rejection.
Sixth, before the government sector can benefit from new approaches to
management, it must change values which have served it well enough in the
past but which are now dysfunctional. Examples include the following: the idea
that short-term control can focus on inputs; the assumption that narrow special-
ist functions, effectively performed, will enable government to manage, change,
and address the changing role required of it; and the belief that success criteria
can be driven by survival, by not making mistakes, and by massaging comfort
zone issues without adding real value to the government equation.
Seventh, government management reform must also adapt and build upon
particular national and regional political systems. Many of these systems
separate the powers of the legislature, the executive, and the judiciary. The
operation of these frameworks has changed over time and can be expected to
continue to adapt. These structures provide important checks and balances;
they provide important links which focus relationships between interest groups
and executive government. It is important to manage the impact of reform on
these systems and to recognize that many of the business solutions ignore this
particular reality.
Our examination of external factors suggests that any analysis of the crisis in
government must start with an analysis of the impact of global change. While
examinations of government management often include a few paragraphs on
the changing state of the world, there are few frameworks which address
Managing Transitions to National Competitiveness 291
national differences, or are able to link these changes to the management role
of government. The National Competitiveness Model simplifies the issues
implicit in national competitiveness. It provides links with key management
variables and enables us to move beyond static, homogeneous, solutions not
only to examine differences between nations, but also to examine change as
a transition. A number of implications for the reform of government manage-
ment can be drawn from this analysis.
First, nations are pursuing different transitions to national competitiveness.
The nature of the transition depends upon the current competitiveness, on na-
tional aspirations, and on the national capacity to coordinate the different busi-
ness and government contributions required to support a particular transition.
Second, different transitions generate different opportunities and chal-
lenges for each nation and for government. Theories of government manage-
ment, which presume that the role of government is static or will emerge
from an internal consideration focused by appropriate management and policy
frameworks, are unlikely to notice, let alone respond to, these differences. It
follows that those who seek to copy the success of other nations, or worse,
export their own solutions to others, run a high risk of failure.
Third, while the model suggests that nations need to optimize production
autonomy and response, it also predicts that there must be trade-offs between
the three basic modes of management.
Fourth, transitions to competitive government must be underpinned by a
viable national competitiveness strategy which addresses not only where a
nation wishes to end up but where it is located on the model now and how
it intends to manage the transition.
Fifth, some transitions are implicitly more difficult to manage than oth-
ers. Nations which have choices should consider reviewing transition options
to ensure the choice for transition minimizes difficulties. For example, a
decision by a developing country to optimize autonomy before developing the
production strengths necessary to be competitive is likely to create a particu-
larly difficult transition dilemma. The combined need to reduce autonomy
without being in a position to deliver direct and immediate benefits creates
difficult comfort zone issues.
Sixth, this examination of the difficulty in managing transitions high-
lights the need for nations and government to benchmark and evaluate progress.
Such benchmarks are likely to be central to any attempt to evaluate the
performance of government.
implementation process to ensure that they actually are delivered. Our analy-
sis of these of implementation weaknesses raises a number of issues for the
management of transitions to competitive government.
First, traditional government management systems simply cannot address
cycle time management or the management of cycle impacts.
Second, cycle time analysis illustrates how business management solu-
tions can be extended to manage comfort zone impacts. It is not enough to
use traditional hierarchical segmentation which presumes that comfort zone
issues can be managed prior to implementation.
Third, solving the implementation problem in government requires man-
agement systems able to address three different priorities. Government systems
need to manage short-run impacts, balance impacts on added value and com-
fort zones in order to deliver added value while operating within the comfort
zone, and manage cycle inputs to maximize project support.
Fourth, the implementation impact model (IIM) and the cycle impact
model (CIM) discussed in chapter 4, provide tools that can be used to enable
government managers to focus on impacts and to manage cycle-based com-
munications. However, for impact management to succeed, other government
systems need to change. Planning and evaluation solutions need to identify
impacts and link these to wider objectives (chapter 8). Government managers
require new strategic leadership skills to manage the adjustments required to
maintain a project within the comfort zone throughout implementation (chap-
ter 6). The government value-chain must be reengineered to enable managers
to control cycle time and management cycles (chapters 5 and 9).
Fifth, many of the reform solutions adopted by governments create new
implementation problems not only because they do not provide managers
with the scope to manage cycle impacts but because they also increase rather
than reduce cycle time. Although many of these solutions draw on key ele-
ments required for competitive government, they often ignore the need to
manage implementation impacts.
Sixth, our analysis suggests that the failure to manage cycle impacts and
to use cycle-based communications has caused many unnecessary implemen-
tation breakdowns. Many implementation problems are not caused by politi-
cal opponents or by vested interests opposed to change but by the way in
which managers mismanage cycle dynamics. The idea that a communication
strategy should manage perceptions of discounted net project value across
different interest groups changes the management landscape for many gov-
ernment agencies. Cycle-based management, when pursued skillfully, can
stimulate government management systems not only to manage performance
instead of avoiding it, but also to negotiate the scope by managing perfor-
mance rather than blaming nonperformance on others.
Managing Transitions to National Competitiveness 293
The reason why responding to the current crisis is so difficult for many
governments and the reason why the changes to the government management
platform need to be so extensive are explained by an examination of the core
technologies which government management systems use to coordinate and
perform work.
The traditional government approach to coalignment was to standardize
processes and clarify roles and functions. Actions were processed longitudi-
nally through the value-chain. Coalignment was managed by queuing and
prioritizing each stage of the value-chain. This technology is incapable of
responding to the needs of a high-response environment. Uncertainty and
resource restrictions tend to lengthen rather than shorten cycle time. This
suggests that incremental reform is not an option for most government agen-
cies; it explains why reforms, which deregulate without a strong focus on
cycle time and cycle management, tend to fail.
The blockages created by traditional government management systems
and technologies seem terminal for many parts of government. There is no
choice but to “jump the curve,” abandon these traditional systems and rein-
vent government. Legislatures and corporate government groups now have no
option but to hire managers able to effect these transitions, remove the re-
straints that stop government systems from either succeeding or failing; they
must face up to the risks and opportunities offered by change.
Four issues for reform can be identified from our analysis of value-chain
coalignment. First, reforms of value-chains need to reduce cycle time, pro-
vide managers with the scope to manage cycle time, and manage comfort
zone impacts. Almost all attempts at reforming government management at-
tempt to deregulate, to free up processes and roles, and to focus these on tasks
and functions. Some reforms clearly provide a strong focus for the manage-
ment of cycle time and for external accountability. For example, the case
studies presented in reinventing government powerfully reconfigure both value-
chains and the environmental focus of specific agencies. It is not difficult to
see why these changes work. But other situations are more complex and some
reforms simply miss the need to provide a new focus for the management of
cycle time. In such situations, reform is not only likely to fail, it could well
prove to be counterproductive. The solution is to extend the reform agenda
by finding alternative value-chain configurations to match these new needs.
Second, reforms need to focus government managers on the management
of two key environmental boundaries. Government needs to directly manage
its boundary, and it must indirectly manage the national boundary. Devolving
294 BENCHMARKING THE TRANSITION TO COMPETITIVE GOVERNMENT
Devolution/Accountability Tension
Effective transition requires a complex and dynamic balance between deregu-
lation and the development of a new accountability for results. The case study
shows that old input controls of government can be dismantled and cycle time
Managing Transitions to National Competitiveness 297
Deregulation/Reregulation Tension
The tensions between pressures for deregulation and the need to also reregulate
need to be managed skillfully if the benefits of transitions are to be delivered.
Most transitions must deregulate in order to reduce cycle time and costs and
to provide government managers with the right to manage. This often in-
creases uncertainty and negatively impacts the comfort zone. While govern-
ment activities and services often require new forms of strategic regulation,
the purpose of regulation should be to produce defined results. Regulations
should not be allowed to become ends in themselves. Community groups and
legislatures who have often embrace overregulation as a way of influencing
“big” government, need to find new ways to influence government activities.
or the central government agencies, they had unfettered scope to address the
needs of factions and their own predilections about good government. The
management reforms in Victoria left major powers with agency chief execu-
tives. The expectation was that they would focus on performance and resist
pressures to politicize appointments. Many effective managers succumbed to
ministerial pressures. In the Victorian system, ministers have no particular
management expertise. When they ceased to listen to advice about good
management from career managers, many also ceased to practice it.
There are two threats to the introduction of dynamic planning and evalu-
ation system in government. The first threat is that the system will adapt to
the planning process and subsume it; that plans become bland, issues are
avoided, and the prospect of negative evaluation is avoided. The second threat
is that plans will become static as was the case with education failing to
recognize the need to build the change process through an ongoing improve-
ment process.
system which includes a legislature or assembly and the judiciary. The ways
in which these elements of the governance system interact have probably
created part of the current crisis. Certainly attempts to reform one part of the
governance system independently of the other parts create tensions and reac-
tions which are dysfunctional. While governance systems differ between
nations, there are some common challenges they must all address if nations
are to compete and address the many new issues which only governments can
address and which citizens expect government to address.
First, if governments are to devolve power, reduce expenditure, and re-
allocate priorities, they have little option but to reduce the cost of regulation
and review processes imposed upon agencies. This can only occur if there is
a negotiation with the legislature and perhaps the judicial arms to reinvent
relationships. This does not mean that the important role of the legislature in
oversighting the activities of executive government should diminish but, in
many cases, the strategies need to alter.
Second, governance systems must accommodate diversity or have it grow
around them. The danger of holding on to central controls too long is that the
public will come to see the governance system itself as the problem. Accom-
modating devolution means the legislature must agree to the environment for
operation review, overall priorities, and review performance.
Third, the scrutiny role of the legislature needs to be developed and
redefined. The solution for different nations will differ. As a start, the
oversighting role of the legislature might address improvements in service to
the public rather than the fabric of rules and criteria which currently focus
their considerations. Second, these reviews might address the cost of regula-
tion, review, and consider the opportunity cost they represent in times of
declining budgets. The U.S. Committee systems offer value for systems that
do not have powerful review functions. Effective government audit functions
are critical and need to be nurtured as part of the reform process.
Fourth, the politicization of executive government is probably a necessary
reality today. However, sources of independent advice needs to be fostered,
particularly in parliamentary executive systems where political managers are
often not managers at all. The answer is to develop rules about tenure, perfor-
mance, and changes of government that are part of the culture and are under-
stood. Also, there needs to be statutory appointments with a responsibility to
offer advice. Finally, review and advisory functions might be further distanced
from government by privatizing them and by internationalizing them.
Fifth, the intrusion of the judiciary in administrative processes needs to
be reviewed to evaluate its impact on administration. The judiciary, of course,
has an important role in ensuring that both the legislature and the executive
behaves constitutionally. However, the combination of the judicial system, the
rules, and case law, which drives many bureaucracies, is a prescription for
low value solutions. One answer is to create specialized tribunals able to
302 BENCHMARKING THE TRANSITION TO COMPETITIVE GOVERNMENT
assess these issues independently from the viewpoint of the public interest
rather than the legal fabric which has been developed to depersonalize
government.
SOCIAL VALUE
• Has the well-being of citizens increased? Has government assisted improvements?
• Have the training and industry development strategies been established to deliver
ongoing access to employment?
• Has government responded to the needs of citizens disadvantaged by change? Is the
system of safety net service for citizens who fail to achieve minimum access to
services through other systems adequate in terms of benchmark countries?
• Can consumers access basic services such as health transport power and water at
world competitive costs?
• Are systems of appeal and review adequate to protect citizens against discrimination?
Transition strategy. Are the social impacts of the national transition being addressed
effectively? How are the constraints between the cost of nation’s value system and the
funding available to support it being managed? Are funds being targeted to those most
in need? What are the immediate challenges which must be addressed over the next
year? Are these likely to be addressed?
Benchmarks. Social value maintained or improved compared with benchmark coun-
tries. Social value performance improved over the last year.
GOVERNABILITY
• Has government both added value and maintained the scope to govern? Is
governability less of a constraint to national performance than for competitors?
Transition strategy. What are the comfort zone impacts of the national transition?
Are these being addressed effectively? Who are the key interest groups with a capacity
to halt change? How are the needs of these groups being managed by government?
Benchmarks. Governability compared with benchmark countries.
GOVERNMENT MANAGEMENT
• Is there a strategic fit between the changing role of government and the
structures, systems, workskills, and values in government agencies? Has the gap
closed or opened in the last year?
Transition strategy. Are government structures systems and leadership seen as
better able to support the national transition than they are in the case of key
competitors? If these have a competitive edge, what is the likely lead time before
competitors respond? How can leadership be maintained?
Benchmark changes. Government performance compare with benchmark nations.
307
Exhibit 12.2. Planning the Transition to Competitive Government (Cont.)
Impacts or
Key Objectives Action Strategy for Implementation Verifiable Outcomes
Social Value • Increase wealth available for distribution within the economy Additional social value
Improve both the short- • Ensure that systems of income distribution, including taxes, benefits and provided to citizens
and long-term well- markets, support both improvements in competitiveness, and the delivery
being of citizens of equitable access to national resources Preconditions for future
• Manage the impact of spending and debt on current and future improvements in
generations social value established
• Ensure that the laborforce and workskill development system delivers
access to work and meets emerging community and business needs Social value comparable
• Provide social infrastructure which meets the diversity of national needs with selected benchmark
while also facilitating long-term improvements in national competitiveness countries
and wealth
• Ensure that consumers can access, at world competitive costs, basic
community services, including education, health, transport, power, water,
and security services
• Provide appeal and review processes to protect individual rights,
encourage equity, and discourage discrimination. Provide safety net
services
Governability • Recognize diverse needs and priorities. Negotiate boundaries which Governability seen as less
Develop and maintain address the needs of key influence groups of a constraint on key
the scope to govern • Manage comfort zone impacts to ensure that governability does not strategic changes and on the
become a major constraint on the transition to competitive government overall national transition to
• Manage cycle dynamics to integrate government communications to increased competitiveness
position government implementation within the comfort zone required than it is for key competitors
for effective government
Exhibit 12.2. Planning the Transition to Competitive Government (Cont.)
Impacts or
Key Objectives Action Strategy for Implementation Verifiable Outcomes
SUPPORT OBJECTIVES
Manage traditional • Ensure that for each support area the links with key program priorities Government functions
government functions are identified in order that priorities are not distorted by focusing support core national
and services to on support functions in isolation and that provision is competitive objectives
support key objectives relative to benchmark countries
• Avoid the tendency for functions to become ends in themselves Government functions
competitive relative to
selected international
benchmarks
Business services and • Ensure the provision of business services and infrastructure which supports key strategic priorities and is
infrastructure competitive with services provided by other countries
Community services • Provide cost effective (to users) infrastructure which addresses key needs and which is comparable to
and infrastructure benefits delivered by comparable countries. Ensure that benefits are seen to improve over time
Markets access and • Ensure that domestic markets serve the needs of both producers and consumers. Manage external
regulation competition to avoid unfair competition, facilitate the growth of domestic production, and avoid the
development of high-cost domestic production
Exhibit 12.2. Planning the Transition to Competitive Government (Cont.)
Key Objectives Action Strategy for Implementation
Taxes and tariffs • Deliver a taxation and tariff regime which is internationally competitive in its impact on business,
manages opportunities for external arbitraging of the domestic taxation system, redistributes income to
meet agreed social objectives and, funds competitive levels of government services and activities
Checks and balances • Develop systems of regulation review and sanctions that enable the various stakeholders in a nation to
feel they are treated equitably. Ensure that these systems do not create gridlocks and reduce national
competitiveness
Government business • Develop a government business interface which supports a world competitive industry base as well as
leverage the need for the internal regulation of business
• Avoid the anticompetitiveness impact of government subsidies by leveraging government and business
expenditure to maximize impacts on external competitiveness
Workskills and access • Ensure that education, training systems, and business combine to produce world competitive work
to employment skills for each industry and enterprise
• Ensure that industry priorities as well as access and education, and training priorities drive the
development of workskills
• Ensure that those who seek work are provided with access to the core skills required to enable them
to contribute to changing business needs
• Ensure that both highly talented individuals and those with limited potential fully develop their capacities
and workskills and are not blocked by access restrictions designed to regulate the development of
average skills and capacities
Resource balance Manage government activities to balance available and required resources by:
• extending the planning horizon to manage an emerging balance
• managing the revenue base
• managing the expenditure base to reflect real needs and priorities
• managing allocative tensions by changing the budget process to use devolved structures more effectively
Exhibit 12.2. Planning the Transition to Competitive Government (Cont.)
Impacts or
Key Objectives Action Strategy for Implementation Verifiable Outcomes
GENERAL MANAGEMENT
Develop performance • Manage the strategic fit between the changing role and priorities of Structures, systems, and
focused management government and government systems, structures, workskills, and values values that are blocking
systems, structures, change, identified and
values blockages removed
Strategic leadership • Define and communicate the key elements of a national transition to competitiveness
• Manage the impact of change on both competitiveness and governability
• Leadership which drives other performance and planning systems to ensure they implement agreed
priorities rather than coordinate the outputs from such systems
• Change government culture structures and systems to make national competitiveness a key mission or
government
Cycle focused • Reengineer government value-chains to enable government to manage cycle time
management and • Improvement implementation performance by managing cycle impacts to deliver added value and
communications maintain government within the comfort zone which enables government to manage change
• Change government communication strategies to focus these on implementation cycles and make
communications and management implementation strategies proactive rather than sequential
Results-based resource • Shift the traditional budget driven focus for government managers towards a system in which budgets
management are driven by agreements to deliver specific results which are linked to overall strategic planning
priorities of government
• Change traditional resource management systems to provide managers with the scope to manage overall
resources to produce agreed results and the scope to treat cycle time as a management variable
312
Exhibit 12.2. Planning the Transition to Competitive Government (Cont.)
Key Objectives Action Strategy for Implementation
BENCHMARKING
Performance • Introduce planning and evaluation systems which are strategic change-oriented and evaluative. Introduce
management new forms of accountability for both long- and short-term performance at all levels of government
• Coordinate the transition to performance management by balancing the need for deregulation with the
need for new forms of accountability
• Introduce performance-focused management structures which focus accountability and enable managers
THE
to manage cycle impacts and cycle time
• Introduce high-response technologies by reengineering value-chains to achieve task-based coalignment
TRANSITION
and which also provide a focus for continuous improvement
• Introduce performance-based personnel management with flexible workroles, a focus on individual
and team performance, and a performance-focused culture
• Develop systems solutions which inform decision-making, underpin flexible work scheduling, and
TO
support but do not predetermine performance evaluation
• Replace traditional system of internal regulation with performance-based systems, structures and
COMPETITIVE GOVERNMENT
workskills
Comfort zone • Manage government change to add value to different national stakeholders and ensure that the nation
management can manage the changes required to increase national competitiveness while also ensuring that the diverse
interest of stakeholders are recognized and least partially addressed so that the nation remains governable
• Replace the strategies of consensus and homogeneous values and priorities with a respect for diversity
and a negotiated solution which adds value to diverse groups
• Negotiate change impacts to manage the impact on diverse groups while also ensuring that national needs
and interests can be addressed effectively
• Recognize the uncertainties generated by change and develop alternative safeguards which meet the
needs of interest groups and legislatures for accountability and for the checks and balances required to
assure the rights of citizens
Managing Transitions to National Competitiveness 313
• The task of adding social value depends again on the production and
wealth base of the country. As discussed in chapter 6, Singapore adds
value by increasing the wealth of its citizens. The United States, start-
ing from a much higher base, needs to work to maintain value and
address the negative impacts of change.
While these core objectives are different, because they require different
actions, strategies, and generate different impacts, they are also interrelated.
Governments that pursue competitiveness without also pursuing clear strate-
gies to add social value soon discover that their capacity to govern is eroded.
Governments that pursue governability without also developing competitive-
ness will find their support base disappears. Governments that pursue social
value and leave competitiveness to others will find themselves bankrupt, or
replaced by others who are prepared to take the difficult decisions required
to cut back social value to levels which the country can afford.
The action strategies outlined in Exhibit 12.2 for core strategic objectives
flows from our earlier discussions. The impacts or outcomes which might be
used to evaluate progress are action-based and compare performance relative
to other counties.
Support Objectives
The support objectives are summarized in sheets 3–4 of Exhibit 12.2. We
have discussed a number of these support objectives in earlier chapters. The
point to draw out here is that these objectives need to be managed to support
the delivery of the core objectives discussed above. Many reforms address
these areas as objectives in their own right.
Resource limitations have eroded the capacity of many governments to
provide and even maintain infrastructure in recent years. While avoiding such
expenditure is a short-term solution to resource balance, it often creates major
long-term impacts by eroding competitiveness and social value. More im-
portantly, once these assets are run down, the recovery cycle is long and
expensive.
314 BENCHMARKING THE TRANSITION TO COMPETITIVE GOVERNMENT
General Management
Although management reform is critical to delivering competitive govern-
ment, successful reform needs to be prioritized and focused on the delivery
needs of projects which address key objectives.
We have identified five elements of general management reform which
we see as providing a useful framework for implementing and evaluating
change.
Managing Transitions to National Competitiveness 315
CONCLUSION
perfecting potplants towards whether the agency is meeting our needs more or
less effectively. And we should contemplate that in the end we all pay for the
special costs of counting potplants and writing reports about them. We need to
take up Peter Drucker’s challenge to identify successes as well as failures in
government and refocus our reward systems for governments and government
managers in order to recognize success where it occurs.
Finally, we need to discard the idea that we no longer need government.
We may need less government than in the past. We may need a different
government that we did in the past. But today, more than ever before, we
need effective government. Competitive government will not only add value
to nations that pursue it, but it will add value to managers who chose to work
in government. The new competitive global environment is already rewarding
nations with governments able to address new priorities and governments
who work with business to improve national competitiveness.
References
319
320 REFERENCES
Dunn, D. 1994. “Public Affairs, Administrative Faculty and the Winter Com-
mission Report.” Public Administration Review 54, no. 2 (March /April):
109–110.
The Economist. 1993. “The European Community: Back to the Drawing
Board.” (2 July): 20.
———. 1994. “Germany: Half-Hidden Agenda.” (21 May).
———. 1994. “Ready to Take on the World.” (15 January): 65–66.
———. 1995. “Back on Top?” 3–18 (16 September): 3–4.
Elling, T. 1994. “The Lion in Winter: An Academic Assessment of the First
Report of the National Commission on the State and Local Service.” Public
Administration Review 54, no. 2 (March /April): 107–109.
Fix, J. 1995. “Justice Department Fixated on Price Fixing.” USA Today B1 (8
September).
Fombrun, Charles J. 1992. Turning Points: Creating Strategic Change in
Corporations. New York: McGraw-Hill, 6, 10, 19–20, 211.
Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Pros-
perity. New York: Free Press.
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1992. The Culture of Contentment. London: Sinclair-
Stevenson, 6.
Garelli, Stephanie. 1994. “Is Competitiveness Unfair?” The World Competi-
tiveness Report 1994. Lausanne: IMD, 13.
Gingrich, N. 1995. To Renew America. New York: Harper Collins, 112, 121,
129, 247, 329.
Gore, Al. 1993. Creating a Government That Works Better and Costs Less:
The Report of the National Performance Review. New York: Plume, xxx–
xxxiii, 101–187, 107–114.
Gow Chock Tong. 2000. “Prime Minister, Republic of Singapore.” Reported
in the Wall Street Journal. “Singapore’s Economy Grew 5.6% in 1999,
Surpassing Expectations,” 2 January.
Henriques, D. 1995. “Making It Harder for Investors to Sue.” New York Times,
10 September, 3–4.
Hillkirk, J. 1989. “Firms Learn that Quick Development Means Big Profits.”
USA Today B10 (22 November).
References 323
Ohmae, Kenichi. 1994. The Borderless World: Power and Strategy in the
Interlinked Economy. London: HarperCollins, x–xi.
Osborne, David, and Ted Gaebler. 1993. Reinventing Government: How the
Entrepreneurial Spirit Is Transforming the Public Sector. Harmondsworth,
Middlesex, England: Penguin Books, xvi, 3, 111, 130, 161, 331. New York:
Plume.
Peters, Tom. 1993. Liberation Management: Necessary Disorganization for
the Nanosecond Nineties. London: Pan Books Ltd., p. 760.
Port, O., J. Cary, K. Kelly, and S. Forest. 1992. “Quality.” Business Week (30
November): 66–71.
Porter, Michael. 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York: The
Free Press, p. 681.
Powell, Jim. 1989. The Gnomes of Tokyo: The Positive Impact of Foreign
Investment in North America. New York: AMACON.
Report of the Public Service Board of Victoria. 1983. Melbourne: Govern-
ment Printer.
Report of the Public Service Board. 1984. Melbourne: Government Printer,
12–14.
Roberts, Nancy C. 1993. “Limitations of Strategic Action in Bureaus.” In
Public Management the State of the Art. Edited by Barry Bozeman. San
Francisco: Jossey Bass, pp. 153–172.
Rockert, J., and J. Short. “ITT in the 1990s: Managing Organizational Inter-
dependence.” Sloan Management Review 30 (Winter 1989): 7–17.
Rosato, D. 1995. “Business May Lose Treasured Tax Breaks.” USA Today B1
(15 September).
Roth, T. 1995. “U.S. Is Ranked Most Competitive Economy in World.” The
Wall Street Journal A2 (6 September).
Sakakibara, Eisuke. 1993. Beyond Capitalism: The Japanese Model of Mar-
ket Economics. Lantham, MD: University Press of America.
Singapore Institute of Management. 1993. Annual Report, pp. 1–8.
Sisodia, R. S. 1992. “Singapore Invests in the Nation-Corporation.” Harvard
Business Review (May/June): 40, 42.
Smadja, Claude. 1994. “Competition in the New York Order: The Tricky
Game of Setting the Rules.” World Competitiveness Report 1994, Lausanne:
IMD, 218.
326 REFERENCES
Smart, T., P. Engardio, and G. A. Smith. 1993. “GE’s Brave New World.”
Business Week (8 November): 64–70.
Soros, George. 1998. The Crisis of Global Capitalism. London: Little Brown
and Company.
Stacey, Ralph D. 1990. Dynamic Strategic Management for the 1990s: Bal-
ancing Opportunism and Business Planning. London: Kogan Page, 83.
Steedman, Hilary, Andy Green, Oliver Bertrand, Ansgar Richter, Marcus Rubin
and Klaus Weber. 1997. Assessment, Qualifications, and Standards: The
UK Compared to France, Germany, Singapore, and the U.S.: A Technical
Report. London: The Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
Stewart, T. 1993. “Reengineering: The Hot New Managing Tool.” Fortune (23
August): 41–48.
Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in Action: Social Science Bases of
Administrative Theory. New York: McGraw-Hill, 21.
Tichy, N. M., and P. Charon. 1989. “Speed, Simplicity, and Self-Confidence:
An Interview with Jack Welch.” Harvard Business Week (September /Octo-
ber): 112–120.
Toffler, Alvin. 1985. The Adaptive Corporation. New York: McGraw-Hill, 14.
Ventkatraman, N., and J. Prescot. 1990. “Environmental Strategy Co-Alignment:
An Empirical Test of Performance Implications.” Strategic Management Jour-
nal 11: 1–23.
Vessey, J. 1991. “The New Competitors: Think in Terms of Speed to Market.”
Academy of Management Executives 5: 22–23.
Viner, Aron. 1988. The Emerging Power of Japanese Money. Homewood, IL.:
Dow Jones-Irwin.
Vollman, Thomas. 1994. “Transforming the Manufacturing Enterprise: A Key
Issue for Competitiveness Today.” World Competitiveness Report 1994,
Lausanne: IMD, 222–226.
Welch, Jack. 1988. “Managing for the Nineties.” GE Speech Reprint 1988.
Workout (September 1991): 1–2, 4, 12, 20.
———. 1995. “Fall Will Bring Crucial Tests for Congress.” USA Today 6A
(14 August).
Wilson, James Q. 1989. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and
Why They Do It. New York: Basic Books, Inc., 131.
References 327
329
330 INDEX
Contract with America, 100–101, Downes, G., and P. Larkey, 20, 41,
123–130 79, 235, 237, 254, 274, 279
cost reductions, scope for, 258–259 Drucker, P., 8, 13, 43, 44, 67, 85,
Cullen, R.B., 18, 37, 45, 175–176, 87, 105, 277, 285
177, 178, 188, 190, 207, 229, dynamic strategic planning, 202–
231, 240, 248 207
Cullen, R. B., and N. F. Brown,
217, 219 Eastern European deregulated
Cullen, R. B., D. J. Cortese, and transition, 70–71
B. Gerorgiou, 210 education of children with disabili-
culture, shifts, 241 ties, 216–221
Cushman, Donald P., and S. S. environmental scanning theory, 108–
King, 45, 108, 244 111
Cushman, Donald P., and Phillip K. government boundary, 110
Tompkins, 88 limits to action, 111
cut back management solutions, 22 real time scanning, 110–111
cycle-based communication 96–99 tools, checklist, 111–112
cycle impact model, 92–96 European Community regulated
consensus cycle, 93 transition, 72–73
consolidation cycle, 95–96 executive governments and legisla-
implementation cycle, 94–95 tures, 274–275
legislative and budget cycle, 93– expenditure base, management of,
94 257–260
cycle time management external pressures, responding to,
cycle-focused communications, 105–108
96–98
cycle impact tension, 187–188
Fombrun, Charles, J., 44, 75, 133,
cycle impacts, 93–96
171, 235, 237
elements of, 89–91
forward expenditure projections,
project timing and cycle length,
259–260
91–92
Fukuyama, Francis, 62
speed, 26–27
time span of evaluation, 81
Galbraith, John Kenneth, 13, 87
Derbyshire, J. Denis and Ian Garelli, Stephannie, 161, 248
Derbyshire, 274 General Electric, transformation,
devolution solutions, 22–23 151–161
Dhanabalam, S., 89 Gingrich, N., 124–128
Index 331