BuscherandFletcher 2014 AccumulationbyConservation
BuscherandFletcher 2014 AccumulationbyConservation
net/publication/269390508
Accumulation by Conservation
CITATIONS READS
180 561
2 authors, including:
Robert Fletcher
Wageningen University & Research
112 PUBLICATIONS 4,044 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
The politics of space and place @ Wageningen University and Research View project
All content following this page was uploaded by Robert Fletcher on 11 December 2014.
Accumulation by Conservation
a b
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
a
Institute of Social Studies, Erasmus University, Kortenaerkade
12, 2518 AX, The Hague, The Netherlands. Email:
b
Department of Environment and Development, University for
Peace, P.O. Box 138-6100, Ciudad Colón, Costa Rica. Email:
Published online: 23 Jul 2014.
To cite this article: Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher (2014): Accumulation by Conservation, New
Political Economy, DOI: 10.1080/13563467.2014.923824
Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the
“Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis,
our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to
the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions
and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors,
and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content
should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources
of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims,
proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or
howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising
out of the use of the Content.
This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any
substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,
systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms &
Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-
and-conditions
New Political Economy, 2014
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13563467.2014.923824
Accumulation by Conservation
BRAM BÜSCHER & ROBERT FLETCHER
Following the financial crisis and its aftermath, it is clear that the inherent contra-
dictions of capitalist accumulation have become even more intense and plunged
the global economy into unprecedented turmoil and urgency. Governments,
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
business leaders and other elite agents are frantically searching for a new, more
stable mode of accumulation. Arguably the most promising is what we call
‘Accumulation by Conservation’ (AbC): a mode of accumulation that takes the
negative environmental contradictions of contemporary capitalism as its departure
for a newfound ‘sustainable’ model of accumulation for the future. Under slogans
such as payments for environmental services, the Green Economy, and The Econ-
omics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity, public, private and non-governmental
sectors seek ways to turn the non-material use of nature into capital that can sim-
ultaneously ‘save’ the environment and establish long-term modes of capital
accumulation. In the paper, we conceptualise and interrogate the grand claim of
AbC and argue that it should be seen as a denial of the negative environmental
impacts of ‘business as usual’ capitalism. We evaluate AbC’s attempt to
compel nature to pay for itself and conclude by speculating whether this
dynamic signals the impending end of the current global cycle of accumulation
altogether.
Bram Büscher, Institute of Social Studies, Erasmus University, Kortenaerkade 12, 2518 AX, The
Hague, The Netherlands. Email: buscher@iss.nl
Robert Fletcher, Department of Environment and Development, University for Peace, P.O. Box
138-6100, Ciudad Colón, Costa Rica. Email: rfletcher@upeace.org
Introduction
Both mainstream and critical analyses of our contemporary capitalist system agree
that one of its major problems is the way it systematically deteriorates environ-
mental conditions and, therefore, that if capitalism is to find another period or
cycle of stable accumulation it needs to find a way to effectively address these.
On the side of global capital, we can see this occurring in an unprecedented
manner at present. Green is hot. Companies, governments and non-governmental
organisations (NGOs) all over the world are eager to do and be seen as ‘green’.
Recognition of the need for more environmentally sustainable forms of capitalist
accumulation has become incredibly high over the last decade, with Al Gore and
David Blood’s ‘manifesto for sustainable capitalism’ one of the more recent in a
long series of similar calls.1
Yet this recognition entails a great contradiction, namely that capitalism is now
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
seen as the grand saviour of its own negative ecological contradictions (Büscher
2012), that is, the disjuncture between an economic system predicated on contin-
ual growth and the reality of finite natural resources (O’Connor 1988, 1994). This
is expressed in numerous ways. Increasing concerns about anthropogenic climate
change are channelled into carbon markets that claim to mitigate greenhouse gas
emissions through offsets (Paterson 2010, Lohmann 2011). Ecotourism markets
promise to redress the social and environmental problems caused by mass travel
(Fletcher and Neves 2012). Species and wetlands banking are promoted to
offset the ecosystem destruction wrought by industrial development (Robertson
2004, 2012, Sullivan 2013). The emerging Reducing Emissions from Deforesta-
tion and Forest Degradation (REDD+) initiative promises to reverse deforestation
by linking forest conservation to carbon markets (Angelsen 2009). Derivatives of
all of the above (and more) extend markets still further (Cooper 2010). And the list
goes on.
This trend – the increasing convergence of neoliberal capitalism and environ-
mental conservation – has become subject to a growing critique over the last
decade under the rubrics ‘neoliberal conservation’ or ‘NatureTM Inc.’ Yet
while this discussion has developed a number of useful lines of analysis, thus
far it has not adequately accounted for the logic of the need for capitalism to
become so focused on capitalising conservation, that is, on incorporating conser-
vation as an integral component of capital accumulation on a global scale (see
Büscher 2014). To address this lacuna, in this paper we bring in broader discus-
sions about the evolution of capitalism as a world-system that has gone through
various cycles and phases of accumulation.2 From this perspective, we contend
that the increasingly acknowledged reality of a certain finiteness to natural
resources means that environmental conservation must become more central to
a renewed stable phase of capitalist accumulation – hence, conservation’s impor-
tance to the capitalist system as a whole. In this sense, the increasing intersection
of capitalism and conservation documented by social science critics might be
understood as a transition to a new ‘phase’ of capitalist accumulation based on
a conservation model – one that takes into account the need for environmental
sustainability. Borrowing from Doane (2012), we employ the term ‘Accumulation
by Conservation’ (AbC) to designate this approach. Doane’s conceptualisation of
2
Accumulation by Conservation
the term differs from ours, however, and indeed adds an interesting aspect to our
discussion. Doane understands AbC mainly as the ‘enclosure of value’ (rather than
the more direct ‘enclosure of space’) (2012: 166), which happens ‘when environ-
mental organisations from the global North appropriate land that is already well
preserved’ (2012: 20). Hence, she describes AbC as a particular mode of conser-
vation governmentality (see Fletcher 2010), while we refer to broader systemic
dynamics in global capitalism as a system of accumulation and the role of environ-
mental conservation within this.
By mobilising this concept, the paper aims to interrogate whether or not this
qualitative change in the relationship between capitalism and conservation
indeed signals a transition to a new ‘phase’ of (relatively) stable capital accumu-
lation. But we take the argument further to interrogate how this ‘phase’ has (or
can) come about, and what it entails in terms of ‘structural adjustment’ in the
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
capitalist economy. After further introducing the conservation sector and its
newfound position within global capitalism, the third section outlines several
key contributions from world-systems and related literatures to understand
what defines phases and qualitative changes in global capital accumulation
and how environmental constraints are discussed in terms of these. In the
sections ‘Natural capital in the green economy’ and ‘Conservation as a mode
of accumulation’, we incorporate the literature on neoliberal conservation and
situate the logic of increasing capitalisation of conservation within the
broader historical development of the capitalist world-system – and particularly
the specific phase we currently find ourselves in (neoliberal capitalism after the
financial crisis). In the process, we endeavour to synthesise the two discussions
by offering a periodisation of major regimes and changes in the dominant forms
of global conservation concomitant with structural transformations within the
capitalist world economy as a whole. Finally, we evaluate the attempt at the
heart of AbC to compel nature to pay for itself within the framework of this
phase and conclude by asking whether this attempt might signal the looming
end of (this current cycle of) accumulation altogether.
has actively engaged with corporations for more than 20 years for
the purpose of improving environmental practices and conserving
nature. We challenge and collaborate with companies to improve
3
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
4
Accumulation by Conservation
accumulation’, hints at this in his discussion of the tensions related to the market-
based climate change regime, but does not focus on conservation.
This focus is crucial, we believe, for it allows us to go beyond the ‘quintessen-
tial’ environmental issue of climate change and look at the overarching political
economy of what Fairhead et al. (2012b: 237) have called ‘green grabbing’:
‘the appropriation of land and resources for environmental ends’. Corson and
MacDonald (2012: 264) explain how green grabbing signifies ‘emergent conser-
vation enclosures’ that
entail not only physical land grabs but also the privatization of
rights to nature, the creation of new commodities and markets
from nature, the green sanction for otherwise declining forms of
capital accumulation and the disabling of institutions that could
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
Both articles – as do the others in the special issues of which they are part (Fair-
head et al. 2012a, Corson et al. 2013) – show how conservation is increasingly
central to accumulation processes in contemporary capitalism.7 Yet they do not
give an account of how conservation is becoming an integral component of
capital accumulation on a global scale either.
The most important source for understanding the broader evolution of ‘capital-
ism on a world scale’ and the role of different ‘modes of accumulation’ within this
is the world-systems literature (Wallerstein, 1974, Braudel, 1992, Arrighi, 2009),
which will primarily inform our discussions here, combined with important
related contributions from geography (Harvey 1989, 2005, 2010, Smith 2008)
and the critical social sciences more generally (Mandel 1978, Lash and Urry
1987, Jameson 1991, Nealon 2008). Our aim is not to provide comprehensive
reviews of these complex literatures, nor to fully do them justice. Our more
modest aim is to use several of their core contributions, particularly those concern-
ing phases and transitions in regimes of accumulation and core – periphery
relationships within the world-system, to inform the ongoing discussions on the
links between capitalism and conservation to develop a broader analysis of the
importance of conservation to capitalism on a world scale.
Conservation has scarcely been on the radar of these literatures, although environ-
mental issues more generally certainly have been (see Smith 1994, Hopkins and
Wallerstein 1996, Goldfrank et al. 1999, Wallerstein 2004: 82, Hornborg et al.
2007). Over time the importance of ‘natural resource management’ as an essential
element of the accumulation process has been acknowledged, and more recent inter-
ventions have built on this to develop further insights (Li 2008: 140, Arrighi 2009:
383, Moore 2010). One of the most important of these for our paper is the relation
between capitalism’s poor ecological record and the world-system currently experi-
encing a ‘signal crisis’ portending the potential transition from one accumulation
cycle to another (see especially Arrighi 2009, Moore 2010, 2011). We draw on
this work to frame the central insight from the literature addressing the relationship
between capitalism and conservation reviewed above: that the capitalist system has
become increasingly preoccupied with environmental sustainability.
5
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
the still unverified capacity of the agencies of the East Asian econ-
omic expansion to ‘open up a new path of development for them-
selves and for the world that departs radically from the one that is
now at a dead-end’. This would require a fundamental departure
from the socially and ecologically unsustainable path of Western
development in which the costs for the reproduction of humans
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
Li (2008: 140) examines this argument in relation to China and asserts that
Li (2008: 140) argues that this is ‘completely wishful thinking’ and that China will
not be able to incorporate the negative environmental contradictions of capitalism
into a new mode of capitalist accumulation (see also Gulick 2011). He stresses,
however, that capitalism is in a phase where environmental conservation
becomes crucially important, signalling a qualitative change in capitalism on a
world scale.
In the same tradition, but introducing more nuance regarding the political
ecology of world-systems, Jason Moore’s ‘concern is with neoliberalism as a
phase of world capitalist history, and therefore a specific moment in the modern
world-system’s patterns of evolution and recurrence’ (2010: 390). Describing capit-
alism as not merely a ‘“world-economy” but as world-ecology, joining together the
accumulation of capital and the production of nature in dialectical unity’ (2010:
396, emphasis in original), Moore argues that ‘we can best discern the nature of
the present global crisis – including speculations on eco-catastrophe that have
gained traction on the left . . . by clarifying how we understand nature–society
relations in the history of capitalism’ (2010: 395, emphasis in original). He asks:
6
Accumulation by Conservation
His answer is the latter, again signifying the idea that we have reached, as he
phrases it, ‘the end of a road’ in the sense that contemporary capitalism is in
the midst of a qualitative sea change (see also Moore 2011). Many other world-
system thinkers came to similar conclusions earlier (see especially various chap-
ters in Goldfrank et al. 1999).
Despite their attention to the environmental limits of accumulation, however,
these analyses do not focus on conservation and what the ‘environment’ means
in a potential phase beyond extraction and energy cycles (cf. Li 2008). Or
phrased differently, by stating that we have come to the ‘end of the road’,
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
world-system analysts have lost sight of the abundant empirical dynamics that
show that the possibility of a relatively new phase of ‘AbC’ is something that is
taken quite seriously in elite capitalist circles. In the word of Jeffrey Horowitz,
founder of Avoided Deforestation Partners – ‘an international network dedicated
to advancing U.S. and international climate and energy policies along with
business solutions that include robust incentives to protect tropical forests’ – a
‘corporate conservation revolution’ is taking place:
To get a taste of who these ‘visionary corporate leaders’ are, one can visit the web-
sites of the three largest BINGOs: CI, TNC and WWF. Together, the corporate
partners of these organisations provide a who’s who of the most environmentally
destructive companies in the world, now all committed to international environ-
mental conservation.9 Two leaders of these companies, Rob Walton of Wal-
Mart, the retail corporation, and Wes Bush of Northrop Grumman, a security
and military defence technology company, proudly proclaim on the CI website
that ‘there is a direct connection between international conservation and
America’s economic and national security interests’.10 Hence, these – and
other – corporate elites are taking conservation seriously; so seriously, indeed,
that MacDonald (2010a: 531), Igoe et al. (2010: 490) and Holmes (2010: 626)
refer to conservation as part and parcel of the ‘transnational capitalist class’
central to Sklair’s (2001) ‘sustainable development historic bloc’.
7
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
in Barcelona this debate had been marginalised, the one motion to end the partner-
ship defeated, and the WBCSD’s presence showcased in numerous sessions (Mac-
Donald 2010b). By the 2012 WCC in Jeju Island there was no public resistance at
all: the WBCSD occupied the most visible pavilion in the conference entrance
hall; its President participated in the World Leaders Forum and the organisation’s
many events were openly endorsed by the IUCN Secretariat (Fletcher, in press). In
this growing IUCN – WBCSD alliance, then, the most influential conservationists
and the most powerful corporations in the world have become, essentially, one and
the same. In its ‘Vision 2050’ report, the WBCSD presents a paradigmatic AbC
perspective, viewing environmental constraints as both a profound challenge to
and opportunity for capitalist enterprise, stating that in the bold new future envi-
sioned in the report:
Of course, this is not to say that AbC will overcome the ecological contradictions
of contemporary capitalism. Yet, this should not deter us from asking what this
envisaged or hoped for phase of accumulation might look like. It is by addressing
this question that we have a more solid base on which to explore what the world-
systems analysts allude to, namely that capitalism will likely be unable to success-
fully incorporate its negative environmental contradictions.
8
Accumulation by Conservation
The causes of these crises vary, but at a fundamental level they all
share a common feature: the gross misallocation of capital. During
the last two decades, much capital was poured into property, fossil
fuels and structured financial assets with embedded derivatives.
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
Specifically, this perspective argues that what is necessary is better (which the
report basically defines as ‘more’) investment which could be channelled away
from areas that have essentially distorted the idealised neoliberal logic of the mar-
ketplace – ‘property, fossil fuels and [derivatives]’ – towards the real need of the
world, i.e. solving global environmental problems. In other words, in the bold new
‘green economy’, capital will be ‘allocated’ properly, meaning that it conserves
the resources underlying the capitalist mode of production, rather than destroying
them. In terms of world-system analysis, the point becomes to correct the ‘under-
production’ of basic inputs and raw materials through the production of natural
capital (Moore 2010: 393).
In the process of making the transition to a natural capital phase of AbC,
however, some important assumptions are made, and to clarify these we refer to
the old ‘capitalist transition’ debates that raged from the 1950s to 1970s, which
sought to explain the transition from feudalism to capitalism. Following Meiksins
Wood (2002), we should ask whether there is a ‘commercialisation model or
assumption’ in the idea of the transition to natural capital and AbC. Meiksins
Wood posits that the origin of capitalism is habitually explained as ‘there really
being no origin’ at all: ‘capitalism seems always to be there, somewhere; and it
only needs to be released from its chains’ (2002: 4). She argues that
9
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
As Meiksins Wood explains, this was, in classical political economy, the meaning
of ‘primitive accumulation’ – ‘“primitive” only in the sense that it represents the
accumulation of the mass of wealth required before “commercial society” can
reach maturity’ (2002: 30–1). This, she asserts, was changed by Marx, who con-
ceptualised capital as a social relation instead of simply ‘wealth’ or ‘profit’; hence,
‘his emphasis on the transformation of social property relations as the real “primi-
tive accumulation”’ (2002: 31, emphasis in original).
One of our main questions, then, is whether the shift to AbC is also seen by its
advocates as a ‘natural’ extension of the logic of capital accumulation ever further
into nature, and whether, consequently, it is assumed that nature harbours ‘innate’
capabilities, assets or qualities that have always already made it fit for capital
accumulation. The pervasive term ‘natural capital’ seems to suggest so, but we
need to be careful here. Many conservationists, especially, do not see nature as an
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
explain how capitalism proceeds only through exacting extensive social (and
environmental) costs. AbC, by contrast, is seen as potentially a new ‘phase of
capitalism’ as a whole, imbued with a productive form of power that shapes
new joint environmental and accumulation possibilities.
As noted earlier, while conservationists characteristically portray themselves as
locked in a fierce battle to defend natural spaces against the forces of industrial
destruction, Brockington et al. (2008) contend that conservation and capitalism
have always been conjoined, with conservation merely one way to try to
harness ‘natural capital’ for economic gain. As Büscher et al. (2012) point out,
however, conservation stands somewhat distinct from other efforts to commodify
natural capital, for while the latter usually involves resources’ extraction and
transformation into mobile commodities, the former seeks to lock resources in
place and thus commodify them in situ through ostensibly non-consumptive use.
Yet these analyses – and indeed the growing neoliberal conservation literature
more broadly – have so far not attempted to describe the larger historical process
by which this commodification has unfolded and the ways it has transformed over
time. Phrased differently, an overall assessment situating conservation within
capitalism-as-a-whole has not yet been offered (cf. Büscher 2014). Inspired by
the aforementioned literatures, we attempt to do so here by providing a periodisa-
tion of capitalism and concomitant periods and transformations of the dominant
global conservation strategy.13 Table 1 outlines this periodisation and forms the
basis of what follows in this section.
As the table indicates, our analysis divides the history of conservation into three
periods, roughly corresponding to commonly accepted periodisations of trans-
formation among regimes of capitalist accumulation offered by researchers
including Lash and Urry (1987), Arrighi (2009), Harvey (1989) and Mandel
(1978). We combine all of these into the typology presented here. In this
reading, the current global expansion of conservation begins in the latter nine-
teenth century with the creation of the original National Parks in the USA: Yel-
lowstone in 1864 and Yosemite in 1972.14 These parks were paradigmatic
examples of ‘fortress conservation’, protected areas maintained through state-
centred command-and-control measures (the so-called fences-and-fines strategy)
and funded primarily via direct appropriations by states and/or private donors
(Brockington 2002, Igoe 2004). In its emphasis on top-down control of rigidly
11
12
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
1860s– Colonial/Fordist/ Vertical integration; statism Liberalism/ Fortress Protected areas; state funding and
1960s organised capitalism and violence Keynesianism conservation wildlife tourism
1970– Post-Fordism/ Flexible accumulation and Roll-back Flexible CBC; ICDPs; biosphere reserves;
2000 disorganised decentralisation neoliberalism conservation ecotourism and bioprospecting
capitalism
1990s Roll-out TFCAs and PES
neoliberalism
2000– Financialisation/casino Spectacular accumulation, Fictitious Carbon markets; species/wetlands
present capitalism networks and crisis conservation banking; financial derivatives and
REDD
Sources: Mandel (1978), Lash and Urry (1987), Harvey (1989), Arrighi (2009), Nealon (2008) and Büscher (2014).
Accumulation by Conservation
In the last decade or so, within the context of this roll-out neoliberal pro-
gramme, the dominant regime of accumulation seems to be shifting yet again,
away from production of commodities and towards increasing emphasis on finan-
cialisation and speculation – what Harvey (1989) calls ‘casino capitalism’ (see
also Nealon 2008, Arrighi 2009). Arrighi (2009: 6) understands this shift as part
of a historical pattern, describing it as an ‘alternation of epochs of material expan-
sion (MC phases of capital accumulation) with phases of financial rebirth and
expansion (CM’ phases). Together, the two epochs or phases constitute a full sys-
temic cycle of accumulation (MCM’)’. Moore (2010) goes further to assert that
financialisation entails an attempt to dispense with the conversion of money
into commodities altogether and pursue a direct M–M′ transaction (see also
Büscher 2014). According to both Arrighi (2009) and Harvey (1989), this strategy
is pursued when expanded commodity production no longer possesses the
capacity to absorb accumulated capital at a scale sufficient to maintain current
rates of profit and the emphasis thus shifts from spatial to temporal fixes,
seeking to reduce the turnover time of invested capital in order to both displace
overproduction into the future and to increase returns in the present.
In conservation, this shift is signalled by growing interest in a variety of innova-
tive financial instruments including carbon markets, species and wetlands banking,
environmental derivatives and suchlike (see Sullivan 2013). The first concrete step
in this stage can be identified with the development of the global carbon market from
the late 1990s onwards as a result of the United Nations Framework Convention on
Climate Change (UNFCCC)’s Kyoto Protocol (Bumpus and Liverman 2008,
Lohmann 2011, Böhm et al. 2012). The shift was facilitated by the newfound con-
ceptualisation of nature as an ‘environmental services provider’ (Sullivan 2009),
promoting the idea that people removed from a particular resource still benefit
from it and should, therefore, finance its conservation remotely. As Büscher
(2014) describes, such instruments represent the increasing abstraction of conserva-
tion efforts from attachment to any particular place, allowing value to be generated
remotely and circulate freely around the globe. Indeed, recent years have witnessed
the rise of environmental stock exchanges (e.g. the European Union Emissions
Trading Scheme, and the Chicago and London Carbon Exchanges) and ‘environ-
mental services marketplaces’ (e.g. www.speciesbanking.com) to facilitate this
process (Sullivan 2013). In this modality, different conservation investments are
14
Accumulation by Conservation
In other words, financial resources from the ‘core’ are invested in conserving
natural resources in the ‘periphery’ based on the economic logic of maximum
profit-seeking, maintaining lucrative development opportunities domestically by
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
2012).
This dynamic is undergoing still further intensification at present with the rise,
briefly noted above, of discourses concerning the so-called Green Economy in
relation to the recent Rio+20 conference (see Brockington 2012) and the TEEB
initiative promoted there (where the private sector unveiled its ‘Natural Capital
Declaration’), the IUCN’s WCC later that year (Fletcher, in press), and related
fora (MacDonald and Corson 2012). Indeed, the discourse of ‘fictitious conserva-
tion’ is increasingly pervasive, suggesting the apotheosis of ‘natural capital’ from
marginal externality to central preoccupation of the capitalist system. What all of
this means in terms of the overarching cycles of accumulation of which it is part
and parcel will occupy us next.
Jameson adds that ‘such economic necessities then find recognition in the varied
kinds of institutional support available for the newer art, from foundations and
grants, to museums and other forms of patronage’. Conservation is one of these
forms of aesthetic production, namely of the ‘natural’ landscape, aiming to
make the wider environment, and its ‘ecosystematic embedding’, conducive to
the ‘frantic economic urgency’ of contemporary capitalism.
This works in several ways. First, conservation provides spaces for rest and
recovery from this urgency (i.e. to mediate the Polanyian destruction of society
and accommodate the countermovement, ecotourism being the quintessential
17
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
expression of this dynamic; Fletcher and Neves 2012). To give but one example,
according to the late Anton Rupert, one of South Africa’s wealthiest capitalists in
his days, and a staunch supporter of conservation in Africa:
Embedded deep in the psyche of man is the oldest symbol of all, the
Garden of Eden. This is a place of peace and reflection free from
divisive barriers and physical constraints. Affluent Western man
needs for the health of his soul to take time off from the frenetic
treadmill of his existence to return to the Garden for refreshment
and contemplation, and the growth of tourism to wilderness areas
endorses this. (PPF 2000: 2)
Africa also plays into exactly this feeling, providing elites with a space ‘to
escape the rat race and get away into nature for a while’.16
Second, it facilitates the infusion of a deeper capitalistic logic within nature, the
capitalisation of nature ‘all the way down’ (Smith 2007). This, interestingly, links
in with the commercialisation model described above, in that nature is progress-
ively imbued with capitalist qualities it apparently always possessed. Third, con-
servation helps to overcome the metabolic rift by ostensibly offering an
experience of ‘nature –culture unity’ to counter the sense of alienation produced
by capitalist social and labour relations (Fletcher and Neves 2012).
All of this leads to strange contradictions. For example, capitalists are incred-
ibly eager to stimulate ‘out of the box thinking’, which is what they claim is
needed to tackle the ‘green challenge’. As hedge fund manager Stanley Fink
states of the effort to commodify carbon forest stocks:
Yet the ‘box’ they talk about is actually a money container that needs continuous
enlarging to capture the accumulation of capital that is and remains the number
one priority. Moderate critics often emphasise the paradox of mainstream
approaches to sustainable development, the futility of championing an economic
model of growth in a world of finite resources, yet the foundation of this growth
model in the basic structure of capitalist accumulation is rarely highlighted
(Büscher et al. 2012). As with any form of accumulation, such contradictions
can be overcome for a time through spatial and/or temporal displacement
(Harvey 1989), but eventually this capacity for expansion will be exhausted and
the contradictions rendered unavoidable. Hence, while in the recent past main-
stream environmentalists pursued continued expansion of the global conservation
‘estate’ grounded in unerring faith that concerns for conservation and
18
Accumulation by Conservation
markets fail to develop – as they have until now – the system turns to financia-
lisation instead to try to capture the promised potential that conservation has
proven unable to deliver to this point. Signs of the potential signal crisis this
dynamic points to include: growing assertion of inherent conservation/develop-
ment trade-offs as well as calls for conservation estate consolidation and
PADDD, noted above; reduction of funding for conservation due to the economic
crisis conditioned by loss of frontiers for displacement of accumulation crisis and
increased production costs due to resource depletion; impending ecological col-
lapse due to loss of unpolluted space in which to externalise production costs;
an increased rich– poor gap despite attempts to alleviate crisis; recent stagnation
of global and regional carbon markets (Bond 2011, Coelho 2012) and so forth.
Observing all of this, Moore concludes in no uncertain terms that ‘neoliberalism
has reached the limits of developmental possibilities, the financial crises and
inflationary crescendo of 2008 marking the “signal” crisis of the neoliberal order-
ing of relations between humans and the rest of nature’ (2010: 391).
Conclusion
The preceding analysis has important implications for both research concerning
AbC and for understanding the process itself. As noted above, ecological Marxists
like O’Connor (1988, 1994) and Bellamy Foster (2000) have demonstrated that
attempts to incorporate sustainable resource use and conservation have been
central to planning and thinking about capital accumulation since the nineteenth
century, as exemplified by the German forest industry (Scott 1998), the US con-
servation movement, colonial protected area creation and so on. But these ecologi-
cal Marxists, while pointing out capitalism’s so-called second contradiction
between the imperative for continual growth and finite resources, do not really
describe the logic by which environmental conservation functions as an attempt
to resolve both this second contradiction and the first one (the growth imperative
conditioned by the need to displace accumulated capital created by overproduc-
tion crisis) on which the second is predicated (Brockington et al. 2008). This is
something that neoliberal conservation scholars, the present authors included,
have been starting to do. Yet this analysis has been limited to date since it has
not yet sought to situate the process within a global world-system perspective,
20
Accumulation by Conservation
Acknowledgements
We sincerely thank the reviewers of the paper for the constructive comments and the participants of a seminar at
the Institute of Social Studies, where the ideas in this paper were first presented.
Notes
1. See http://www.economist.com/blogs/schumpeter/2012/02/sustainable-capitalism and http://www.
generationim.com/media/pdf-wsj-manifesto-sustainable-capitalism-14-12-11.pdf (accessed 8 March 2013).
2. This is of course not to say that the differential ways in which broader capitalist processes manifest itself on
regional, national and local levels are not important; to the contrary. This, however, is not the main focus or
contribution of this paper.
3. We employ the term ‘environmental conservation’ broadly to refer to any type of deliberative activity aimed
at having a positive (i.e. non-destructive) impact on nature and natural resources (such as wildlife, ecosys-
tems, water bodies and so forth).
4. But see Brockington and Scholfield (2010) and Holmes (2010) for cautionary notes about the power and
dominance of these BINGOs.
21
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
5. http://www.conservation.org/sites/celb/pages/main.aspx (accessed 8 November 2011).
6. http://www.nature.org/aboutus/ourpartners/index.htm (accessed 8 November 2011).
7. We here define capitalism broadly as a political economic system geared towards stimulating the logic of
capital. This logic of capital, in turn and crucially, is a process (not a thing) of putting forth money or
resources in order to acquire more money or resources (Arrighi 2009: 8, Harvey 2010). This means that
‘accumulation’ is not accidental to capitalism; it is, according to Marx’s famous quote, ‘Moses and the pro-
phets!’ Exactly how accumulation must proceed and be organised, however, has transformed dynamically
over time and is subject to heated debates.
8. http://news.mongabay.com/2013/0226-swf2013-horowitz.html (accessed 20 March 2013).
9. TNC’s ‘corporate partners’ include Boeing, BP, Coca-Cola, Delta Airlines, Dow Chemicals, Caterpillar,
Dupont, Monsanto, Rio Tinto, Shell and Wal-Mart (http://www.nature.org/about-us/working-with-
companies/companies-we-work-with/index.htm). CI’s corporate partners include Agropalma, ArcelorMittal,
BHP Billiton, Cargill, Northrop Grumman, Chevron, Exxon Mobile, McDonald’s, Vale, Cerrejon Coal and –
interestingly – some of the same companies also on TNC’s list, including Coca-Cola, Shell, BP and Wal-
Mart. Finally, WWF’s partners include Alpro Soya, HSBC, IKEA, Johnson and Johnson, IBM, Sony, Pana-
sonic, Nike, Nokia and – again – Coca Cola. See http://wwf.panda.org/what_we_do/how_we_work/
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
The Kyoto Protocol recognized that emission reductions in the industrial world would prob-
ably be more expensive than reductions in the developing world and that if developed
countries were forced to meet their emission-reduction targets alone, they would face econ-
omic impacts because of the high marginal costs of reductions in domestic emissions.
The emerging REDD+ mechanism promises to intensify this strategy by creating a new global framework
for the transfer of emissions reductions to rural areas of less-developed societies where opportunity costs are
lower than inn industrialised regions.
16. See http://www.raptorsviewwildlifeestate.co.za/aboutus.aspx (accessed 12 February 2014).
17. See http://www.padddtracker.org/ (accessed 15 March 2013).
Notes on contributors
Bram Büscher is Associate Professor of Environment and Sustainable Development at the Institute of Social
Studies, Erasmus University and holds visiting positions at the Department of Geography, Environmental Man-
agement and Energy Studies, University of Johannesburg and Department of Sociology and Social Anthropology,
University of Stellenbosch in South Africa. He studies and teaches the political economy of conservation,
environment, development and energy, with most of his empirical work based in southern Africa. He is the
author of Transforming the Frontier. Peace Parks and the Politics of Neoliberal Conservation in Southern
Africa (Duke University Press, 2013) and, with Wolfram Dressler and Robert Fletcher, editor of NatureTM
Inc: New Frontiers of Environmental Conservation in the Neoliberal Age (University of Arizona Press, 2014).
22
Accumulation by Conservation
Robert Fletcher is Associate Professor in the Department of Environment and Development at the University for
Peace in Costa Rica. He is the author of Romancing the Wild: Cultural Dimensions of Ecotourism (Duke Univer-
sity Press, 2014) and co-editor of NatureTM Inc: Environmental Conservation in the Neoliberal Age (University of
Arizona Press, 2014).
References
Angelsen, A. (ed.) (2009), Realizing REDD+: National Strategy and Policy Options (Bogor: CIFOR).
Arrighi, G. (2009 [1994]), The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times (London:
Verso).
Arsel, M. and Büscher, B. (2012), ‘NatureTM Inc: Changes and Continuities in Neoliberal Conservation and
Environmental Markets’, Development and Change, 43 (1), pp. 53– 78.
Bellamy Foster, J. (2000), Marx’ Ecology. Materialism and Nature (New York: Monthly Review Press).
Bellamy Foster, J. and Clark, B. (2012), ‘The Planetary Emergency’, Monthly Review, 64 (7), pp. 1 –25.
Böhm, S., Misoczky, M.C. and Moog, S. (2012), ‘Greening Capitalism? A Marxist Critique of Carbon Markets’,
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
23
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
Corson, C. and MacDonald, K.I. (2012), ‘Enclosing the Global Commons: the Convention on Biological Diver-
sity and Green Grabbing’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 39 (2), pp. 263–83.
Corson, C., MacDonald, K.I. and Neimark, B. (2013), Special Issue on ‘Grabbing Green’, Human Geography, 6
(1), pp. 1–164.
Cronon, W. (1996), ‘The Trouble with Wilderness’, in W. Cronon (ed.), Uncommon Ground (New York: W.W.
Norton), pp. 69–90.
Doane, M. (2012), Stealing Shining Rivers: Agrarian Conflict, Market Logic, and Conservation in a Mexican
Forest (Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press).
Dressler, W. and Roth, R. (2010), ‘The Good, the Bad, and the Contradictory: Neoliberal Conservation Govern-
ance in Rural Southeast Asia’, World Development, 39 (5), pp. 851–62.
Fairhead, J., Leach, M. and Scoones, I. (2012a), Special Issue on ‘Green Grabbing’, Journal of Peasant Studies,
39 (2), pp. 237–617.
Fairhead, J., Leach, M. and Scoones, I. (2012b), ‘Green Grabbing: A New Appropriation of Nature?’, Journal of
Peasant Studies, 39 (2), pp. 237– 61.
Fletcher, R. (2010), ‘Neoliberal Environmentality: Towards a Poststructuralist Political Ecology of the Conser-
vation Debate’, Conservation and Society, 8 (3), pp. 171– 81.
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
Fletcher, R. (2012), ‘Using the Master’s Tools? Neoliberal Conservation and the Evasion of Inequality’, Devel-
opment and Change, 43 (1), pp. 295–317.
Fletcher, R. (in press), ‘Orchestrating Consent: Post-politics and Intensification of NatureTM Inc. at the 2012
World Conservation Congress’, Conservation and Society.
Fletcher, R. and Breitling, J. (2012), ‘Market Mechanism or Subsidy in Disguise? Governing Payment for
Environmental Services in Costa Rica’, Geoforum, 43 (3), pp. 402– 11.
Fletcher, R. and Neves, K. (2012), ‘Contradictions in Tourism: The Promise and Pitfalls of Ecotourism as a Mani-
fold Capitalist Fix’, Environment and Society: Advances in Research, 3 (1), pp. 60– 77.
Fuller, R.A. et al., (2010), ‘Replacing Underperforming Protected Areas Achieves Better Conservation Out-
comes’, Nature, 466, pp. 365– 7.
Garland, E. (2008), ‘The Elephant in the Room: Confronting the Colonial Character of Wildlife Conservation in
Africa’, African Studies Review, 51 (3), pp. 51–74.
Goldfrank, W.L., Goodman, D. and Szasz, A. (1999), Ecology and the World-System (Westport, CT: Greenwood
Press).
Graeber, D. (2011), Debt: The First Five Thousand Years (Brooklyn, NY: Melville House).
Gulick, J. (2011), ‘The Long Twentieth Century and Barriers to China’s Hegemonic Accession’, Journal of
World-Systems Research, 17 (1), pp. 4– 38.
Harvey, D. (1989), The Condition of Postmodernity: An Inquiry into the Origins of Cultural Change (Oxford:
Basil Blackwell).
Harvey, D. (2005), A Brief History of Neoliberalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Harvey, D. (2010), The Enigma of Capital and the Crises of Capitalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Holmes, G. (2010), ‘The Rich, the Powerful and the Endangered: Conservation Elites, Networks and the Domin-
ican Republic’, Antipode, 42 (3), pp. 624–46.
Hopkins, T. and Wallerstein, I. (1996), The Age of Transition. Trajectory of the World-System, 1945– 2025
(London: Zed Books).
Hornborg, A., McNeill, J.R. and Martinez-Alier, J. (2007), Rethinking Environmental History: World-System
History and Global Environmental Change (Lanham: AltaMira Press).
Igoe, J. (2004), Conservation and Globalization: A Study of National Parks and Indigenous Communities from
East Africa to South Dakota (Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thompson).
Igoe, J., Neves, K. and Brockington, D. (2010), ‘A Spectacular Eco-tour around the Historic Bloc: Theorising the
Convergence of Biodiversity Conservation and Capitalist Expansion’, Antipode, 42 (3), pp. 486–512.
James, A.N., Gaston, K.J. and Balmford, A. (1999), A Global Review of Protected Area Budgets and Staff (Cam-
bridge: World Conservation Press).
Jameson, F. (1991), Postmodernism, or the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism (Durham: Duke University Press).
Kelly, A.B. (2011), ‘Conservation Practice as Primitive Accumulation’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 38 (4), pp.
683–701.
Lash, S. and Urry, J. (1987), The End of Organized Capital (Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press).
Li, M. (2008), The Rise of China and the Demise of the Capitalist World Economy (New York: Monthly Review
Press).
Lohmann, L. (2011), ‘The Endless Algebra of Climate Markets’, Capitalism Nature Socialism, 22 (4), pp. 93–116.
24
Accumulation by Conservation
MacDonald, K.I. (2010a), ‘The Devil is in the (Bio)Diversity: Private Sector “Engagement” and the Restructuring
of Biodiversity Conservation’, Antipode, 42 (3), pp. 513–50.
MacDonald, K.I. (2010b), ‘Business, Biodiversity and New “Fields” of Conservation: The World Conservation
Congress and the Renegotiation of Organisational Order’, Conservation and Society, 8 (4), pp. 256–75.
MacDonald, K.I. and Corson, C. (2012), ‘“TEEB Begins Now”: A Virtual Moment in the Production of Natural
Capital’, Development and Change, 43 (1), pp. 159–84.
Mandel, E. (1978), Late Capitalism (London: Verso).
McAfee, K. (2012), ‘The Contradictory Logic of Global Ecosystem Services Markets’, Development and
Change, 43 (1), pp. 105–31.
McShane, T.O. et al., (2011), ‘Hard Choices: Making Trade-Offs between Biodiversity Conservation and Human
Well-Being’, Biological Conservation, 144 (3), pp. 966– 72.
Meiksins Wood, E. (2002), The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso).
Moore, J.W. (2010), ‘The End of the Road? Agricultural Revolutions in the Capitalist World-Ecology, 1450–
2010’, Journal of Agrarian Change, 10 (3), pp. 389– 413.
Moore, J.W. (2011), ‘Ecology, Capital, and the Nature of our Times: Accumulation & Crisis in the Capitalist
World Ecology’, Journal of World-Systems Research, 17 (1), pp. 107–46.
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
Nash, R. (1973), Wilderness and the American Mind, 2nd ed. (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).
Nealon, J.T. (2008), Foucault beyond Foucault: Power and its Intensification since 1984 (Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press).
Neves, K. and Igoe, J. (2012), ‘Accumulation by Dispossession and Uneven Development: Comparing Recent
Trends in the Azores and Tanzania’, Journal of Economic and Social Geography, 103 (2), pp. 164–79.
O’Connor, J. (1988), ‘Capitalism, Nature, Socialism: A Theoretical Introduction’, Capitalism Nature Socialism, 1
(1), pp. 11–38.
O’Connor, J. (1994), ‘Is Sustainable Capitalism Possible?’, in P. Allen (ed.), Food for the Future: Conditions and
Contradictions of Sustainability (New York: Wiley-Interscience), pp. 125– 37.
Overbeek, H. and Van Apeldoorn, B. (2012), Neoliberalism in Crisis (Basingstoke: Palgrave).
Paterson, M. (2010), ‘Legitimation and Accumulation in Climate Change Governance’, New Political Economy,
15 (3), pp. 345– 68.
Peace Parks Foundation (PPF). (2000), Annual Review 1999 (Stellenbosch: Peace Parks Foundation).
Peck, J. and Tickell, A. (2002), ‘Neoliberalizing Space’, Antipode, 34 (3), pp. 380– 404.
Robertson, M. (2004), ‘The Neoliberalization of Ecosystem Services: Wetland Mitigation Banking and Problems
in Environmental Governance’, Geoforum, 35 (3), pp. 361– 73.
Robertson, M. (2012), ‘Measurement and Alienation: Making a World of Ecosystem Services’, Transactions of
the Institute of British Geographers, 37 (3), pp. 386– 401.
Robinson, J. (2012), ‘Common and Conflicting Interests in the Engagements between Conservation Organiz-
ations and Corporations’, Conservation Biology, 26 (6), pp. 967–77.
Roth, R. and Dressler, W. (eds) (2012), Special Issue on ‘The Global Rise and Local Implications of Market-
Oriented Conservation Governance’, Geoforum, 34 (3), pp. 363– 426.
Sandbrook, C. et al., (2010), ‘Value Plurality among Conservation Professionals’, Conservation Biology, 25 (2),
pp. 285 –94.
Sandbrook, C., Fisher, J. and Vira, B. (2013), ‘What Do Conservationists Think About Markets?’, Geoforum, 50,
pp. 232 –40. doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2013.09.009
Scott, J. (1998), Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed (New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press).
Sklair, L. (2001), The Transnational Capitalist Class (Oxford: Blackwell).
Smith, D.A. (1994), ‘Uneven Development and the Environment: Toward a World-System Perspective’, Hum-
boldt Journal of Social Relations, 20 (1), pp. 151 –75.
Smith, N. (2007), ‘Nature as Accumulation Strategy’, in L. Panitch and C. Leys (eds), Coming to Terms with
Nature. Socialist Register 2007 (London: The Merlin Press), pp. 16–36.
Smith, N. (2008), Uneven Development: Nature, Capital and the Production of Space (Athens: University of
Georgia Press).
Sodikoff, G. (2009), ‘The Low-Wage Conservationist: Biodiversity and Perversities of Value in Madagascar’,
American Anthropologist, 111 (4), pp. 443–55.
Sullivan, S. (2009), ‘Green Capitalism, and the Cultural Poverty of Constructing Nature as Service Provider’,
Radical Anthropology, 3, pp. 18–27.
25
Bram Büscher & Robert Fletcher
Sullivan, S. (2013), ‘Banking Nature? The Spectacular Financialisation of Environmental Conservation’, Anti-
pode, 45 (1), pp. 198– 217.
Sullivan, S. (2014), ‘(Re)Countenancing an Animate Nature’, in B. Büscher, W. Dressler and R. Fletcher (eds),
NatureTM Inc: New Frontiers of Environmental Conservation in the Neoliberal Age (Tucson, AZ: Univer-
sity of Arizona Press), pp. 222 –45.
United Nations Environment Program (UNEP). (2011), Towards a Green Economy. Pathways to Sustainable
Development and Poverty Reduction (Nairobi: UNEP).
Wallerstein, I. (1974), ‘The Rise and Future Demise of the Capitalist World System: Concepts for Comparative
Analysis’, Comparative Studies in Society and History, 16 (4), pp. 387– 417.
Wallerstein, I. (2004), World-Systems Analysis: An Introduction (Durham: Duke University Press).
WBCSD. (2010), Vision 2050: The New Agenda for Business (Geneva: WBCSD).
While, A., Jonas, A.E.G. and Gibbs, D. (2010), ‘From Sustainable Development to Carbon Control: Eco-State
Restructuring and the Politics of Urban and Regional Development’, Transactions of the Institute of
British Geographers, 35 (1), pp. 1– 19.
Downloaded by [Erasmus University] at 13:00 23 July 2014
26