CH 12 The Black-Scholes Formula
CH 12 The Black-Scholes Formula
1 / 45
The Black-Scholes Formula
2 / 45
12.1 INTRODUCTION TO THE BLACK-SCHOLES
FORMULA
• Call Options
• Put Options
• When Is the Black-Scholes Formula Valid?
3 / 45
Binomial Option Pricng
• When computing a binomial option price, we can vary the
number of binomial steps, holding fixed the time to expiration.
• Changing the number of steps changes the option price.
• Once the number of steps becomes great enough we appear to
approach a limiting value for the price.
5 / 45
Call Options
where
ln(S/K ) + (r − δ + 12 σ 2 )T
d1 = √
σ T
√
d2 = d1 − σ T
• The function N(x) in the Black-Scholes formula is the cumulative
standard normal distribution function (mean 0 and variance 1)
6 / 45
Call Options
where
∆ = e−δT N(d1 )
B = −Ke−rT N(d2 )
• It can be shown that when the number of steps go to infinity, the
solution of ∆ and B of the binomial pricing formula converge to
the solution of the Black-Scholes formula
7 / 45
Call Options
Example. (12.1) Let S = $41, K = $40, σ = 0.3, r = 8%, T = 0.25 (3
months), and δ = 0. What is the call option price?
ln(S/K ) + (r − δ + 12 σ 2 )T
d1 = √
σ T
2
ln( 41 0.3
40 ) + (0.08 − 0 + 2 ) × 0.25
= √
0.3 × 0.25
√ √
d2 = d1 − σ T = d1 − 0.3 × 0.25
8 / 45
Put Options
• Using the Black-Scholes equation for the call, we can also write
the put formula as
9 / 45
Put Options
• Method 2 (parity):
P = C − PV (F − K )
= 3.399 + 40e−0.08×0.25 − 41 = 1.607
10 / 45
When Is the Black-Scholes Formula Valid?
11 / 45
12.2 APPLYING THE FORMULA TO OTHER ASSETS
• Options on Currencies
12 / 45
Options on Currencies
where
ln(x/K ) + (r − rf + 21 σ 2 )T
d1 = √
σ T
√
d2 = d1 − σ T
• The price of a European put follows from put-call parity:
P(x, K , σ, r , T , rf ) = C(x, K , σ, r , T , rf ) + Ke−rT − xe−rf T
13 / 45
Options on Currencies
0.12
ln( 1.25
1.2 ) + (0.01 − 0.03 + 2 )
d1 =
0.1
d2 = d1 − 0.1
14 / 45
12.3 OPTION GREEKS
15 / 45
Definition of the Greeks
16 / 45
Delta
• Delta (∆) measures the option price change when the stock
price increases by $1.
∂C(S,K ,σ,r ,T ,δ)
- ∆= ∂S
17 / 45
Delta
18 / 45
Delta
• How does delta change with moneyness?
- An in-the-money option will be more sensitive to the stock price
than an out-of-the-money option.
0(OTM) ≤ ∆ ≤ 1(ITM)
Example.
- If a call is deep in-the-money (i.e., the stock price is $60), it is
likely to be exercised and hence the option should behave much
like a leveraged position in a full share. Delta approaches 1 in this
case and the share-equivalent of the option is 1.
- If a call is out-of-the-money, it is unlikely to be exercised and the
option behaves like a position with very few shares. In this case
delta is approximately 0 and the share-equivalent is 0.
- An at-the-money option may or may not be exercised and, hence,
behaves like a position with between 0 and 1 share.
19 / 45
delta is always increasing, so gamma is also always increasing
Gamma
• Gamma (Γ) measures the change in delta when the stock price
increases by $1.
∂ 2 C(S,K ,σ,r ,T ,δ)
- Γ= ∂S 2
• Gamma is always positive for a call or put.
20 / 45
Vega
21 / 45
Theta
• Theta (θ) measures the change in the option price when there is
a decrease in the time to maturity of 1 day.
- “theta” and “time” share the same first letter
,T −t,δ)
- θ = ∂C(S,K ,σ,r
∂t
22 / 45
Theta
• Options generally—but not always—become less valuable as
time to expiration decreases.
- Some special cases (Ch 9).
call
put
23 / 45
Rho
• Rho (ρ) measures the change in the option price when there is
an increase in the interest rate of 1 percentage point.
- interest rate “r” and “rho” share the same first letter
- ρ = ∂C(S,K∂r,σ,r ,T ,δ)
• Rho is positive for a call. I’m paying strike in call
- Exercising a call entails paying the fixed strike price to receive the
stock
- A higher interest rate reduces the present value of the strike.
• Rho is negative for a put. I’m getting strike in put
- z put entitles the owner to receive cash
- A higher interest rate reduces the present value of the cash.
24 / 45
Psi
• Psi (Ψ) measures the change in the option price when there is
an increase in the continuous dividend yield of 1 percentage
point. you do not have stock, you only get stock but no dividend at maturity
∂C(S,K ,σ,r ,T ,δ)
- Ψ= ∂δ
• Psi is negative for a call.
- A call entitles the holder to receive the stock, but without receiving
the dividends paid on the stock prior to exercising the option.
- The present value of the stock to be received goes down when
the dividend yield goes up.
• Psi is positive for a put.
- A put entails an obligation to deliver the stock in the future in
exchange for cash.
- The present value of the stock to be delivered goes down when
the dividend yield goes up.
you hold stock and receieve dividend, so when dividend increases you fell good
25 / 45
Rho and Psi
26 / 45
Summary of Greeks
27 / 45
Greek Measures for Portfolios
• The same relation holds true for the other Greeks as well.
28 / 45
Greek Measures for Portfolios
29 / 45
Option Elasticity
30 / 45
Dollar Risk of the Option
• If the stock price changes by , the change in the option price is
Example. (12.7) Suppose that the stock price is S = $41, the strike
price is K = $40, volatility is σ = 0.30, the risk-free rate is r = 0.08, the
time to expiration is T = 1, and the dividend yield is δ = 0.
• The call price is $6.961.
• Delta is 0.6911.
• If we own options to buy 1000 shares of stock, the delta of the
position is 691.1 shares of stock
• If the stock price changes by $0.50, we expect an option price
change of approximately 1000 × ∆ × 0.50 = 345.55
31 / 45
Percentage Risk of the Option
• The option elasticity computes the percentage change in the
option price relative to the percentage change in the stock price.
• The percentage change in the stock price is simply /S.
• The percentage change in the option price is the dollar change
in the option price divided by the option price: ∆/C
• The option elasticity is the ratio of these two: Ω = S∆/C
• The elasticity tells us the percentage change in the option for a
1% change in the stock.
- It is effectively a measure of the leverage implicit in the option.
41 × 0.6911
= 4.071
6.961
32 / 45
Percentage Risk of the Option
• A call option is replicated by a levered investment in the stock.
• The implicit leverage in the option becomes greater as the option
is more out-of-the-money.
33 / 45
The Volatility of an Option
34 / 45
The Risk Premium and Beta of an Option
• The risk premium on the option equals the risk premium on the
stock times Ω. dS/C is the weight of stock in option
γ − r = (α − r ) × Ω
35 / 45
The Sharpe Ratio of an Option
• The Sharpe ratio for any asset is the ratio of the risk premium to
volatility
• The risk premium on the option equals the risk premium on the
stock times Ω.
Ω(α − r ) α−r
Sharpe ratio = =
Ωσ σ
• The Sharpe ratio for a call equals the Sharpe ratio for the
underlying stock.
- leverage per se does not change the Sharpe ratio
36 / 45
12.5 IMPLIED VOLATILITY
37 / 45
Implied Volatility
• How to measure future volatility?
- One approach is to compute historical volatility using the history
of returns (Ch 10). But expected future volatility can be different
from historical volatility.
• The option price should reveal the market’s expectations about
the future stock price distribution.
- An option market as the venue where volatility is traded and
revealed.
- Options are claims that investors use to hedge and speculate on
future values of the stock price.
• The option’s implied volatility is the volatility that, when put into a
pricing formula, yields the observed option price
• To compute a Black-Scholes implied volatility, assume that we
observe the stock price S, strike price K, interest rate r, dividend
yield δ, and time to expiration T. The implied call volatility is the σ̂
that solves
Option Price = C(S, K , σ̂, r , T , δ)
39 / 45
Computing Implied Volatility
40 / 45
Volatility Skew
41 / 45
Volatility Skew
42 / 45
VIX
• Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) has reported an
index of implied volatility called the “VIX” (its ticker symbol).
• The CBOE reported implied volatility for the S&P 100 index,
computed from near-the-money options.
• It is commonly referred to as the fear index or the fear gauge.
43 / 45
Using Implied Volatility
• Implied volatility is a standard descriptive measure with
important practical uses.
• If you need to price an option for which you cannot observe a
market price, you can use implied volatility to generate a price
consistent with the prices of traded options. Market-makers will
price options consistently with prices of similar options.
• Implied volatility is often used as a quick way to describe the
level of option prices on a given underlying asset: you could
quote option prices in terms of volatility, rather than as a dollar
price.
• Volatility skew provides a measure of the extent to which pricing
deviates from the assumptions underlying the Black-Scholes
model.
44 / 45
A Case Study: HSBC Option
45 / 45