Votes, Parties, and Seats
Votes, Parties, and Seats
AND SEATS
A Quantitative Analysis
of Indian Parliamentary
Elections, 1962–2014
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Vani Kant Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Vani Kant Borooah
School of Economics
Ulster University
Newtownabbey, County Antrim, United Kingdom
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
In memory of my father, Dev Kant Borooah (1914–1996): scholar, poet,
politician.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
PREFACE
My life changed irrevocably at the age of two when my father was elected
as the Member for Nowgong to India’s Lower House of Parliament (the
Lok Sabha) in the Indian General Election of 1951, and we moved from,
what was then, the sleepy backwater of the state of Assam to the hurly-
burly of metropolitan life in India’s capital, New Delhi. In those years
of living in New Delhi, discussion of electoral politics and parliamentary
affairs was very much the staple of conversation within the home, and I
grew up with an easy familiarity with terms like ‘whipping members into
lobbies’, ‘lame-duck sessions’, ‘waving order papers’, and—indignity of
indignities—‘naming by the Speaker’. Parliament and elections were, so
to speak, ‘in my blood’. Years later, after I moved to England and became
an academic economist, when politics ceased to be part of life’s quotidian
rhythm, my interest in parliamentary elections did not wane. This book is
the product of that undimmed interest.
The foundations of this book lie in a set of data which records the
details of the election result for each candidate, for all the constituencies,
in every Lok Sabha General Election from 1962 to 2014. The edifice built
upon this foundation, and discussed in this book, is the result of inter-
rogating these data. The central purpose of this interrogation was to give
shape to the notion of ‘electoral efficiency’ by which is meant the capacity
of a party to convert votes into parliamentary seats. Parliamentary elec-
tions in India—and also elections to its state assemblies—are conducted
under the First-Past-The-Post (FPTP) system: a single representative for
each of 543 constituencies is elected—on the basis of obtaining the largest
vii
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
viii PREFACE
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
PREFACE ix
Vani K. Borooah
Belfast
January 2016
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
CONTENTS
1 Introduction 1
8 Conclusions 151
Index 155
xi
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
LIST OF FIGURES
xiii
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
xiv LIST OF FIGURES
Fig. 4.6 IOR for the INC and the BJP compared 92
Fig. 4.7 IBF values for the INC and the BJP compared 93
Fig. 7.1 INC vote shares and vote share inequality: 1989–2014 140
Fig. 7.2 BJP vote shares and vote share inequality: 1989–2014 140
Fig. 7.3 Between income inequality as a proportion of total
inequality, decomposition by major states 143
Fig. 7.4 INC and BJP under- and over-performance with respect
to seats when each received an equal number of votes*
(*Negative and positive values represent, respectively,
under-and over-performance) 148
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
LIST OF TABLES
xv
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
xvi LIST OF TABLES
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
LIST OF TABLES xvii
Table 5.8 Vote shares of incumbents and challengers: BJP and INC in
non-Hindi-speaking states 110
Table 5.9 Differences in vote shares between BJP and INC incumbents
and challengers, Hindi-speaking states 111
Table 5.10 Differences in vote shares between BJP and INC incumbents
and challengers, non-Hindi-speaking states 112
Table 6.1 BJP and INC election results for eight Lok Sabha elections: 1989–
2014 117
Table 6.2 Constituencies contested by the INC and the BJP in Lok
Sabha elections: 1989–2014 118
Table 6.3 Vote and seat ratios and values of the amplification coefficient
in Lok Sabha elections: 1989–2014 121
Table 6.4 Vote and seat ratios and values of the amplification coefficient
in Lok Sabha elections for Hindi-speaking statesa: 1989–2014 124
Table 6.5 Vote and seat ratios and values of the amplification coefficient
in Lok Sabha elections for non-Hindi-speaking statesa:
1989–2014 125
Table 7.1 The contributions of the major states to the total Lok Sabha
votea 132
Table 7.2 Values of the Herfindahl, entropy, and dissimilarity indices
for the vote contribution of major statesa 134
Table 7.3 Inequality in the distribution of constituency vote shares 139
Table 7.4 BJP and INC seats for eight Lok Sabha elections, 1989–2014,
under an equally distributed scenario 144
Table 7.5 BJP and INC seats for eight Lok Sabha elections, 1989–2014,
under an equal voters’ scenario 147
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
CHAPTER 1
Introduction
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
2 V.K. BOROOAH
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INTRODUCTION 3
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
4 V.K. BOROOAH
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INTRODUCTION 5
it, thereby, redeemed itself after the indignity of winning just two seats
in its electoral debut in the previous Lok Sabha elections of 1984.
2. The 1989 election and the 1998 Lok Sabha elections bookended a
period of parliamentary instability during which in a span of 10 years,
India voted in five Lok Sabha elections: 1989, 1991, 1996, 1998, and
1999.4
3. In the decade after the 1989 Lok Sabha elections, India experienced—
what Jaffrelot (2003) termed—a ‘silent revolution’ as lower-status
groups increasingly captured political office and used political power to
alter the balance of power between the upper and the lower castes.
Each of these aspects is discussed, in turn, below.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
6 V.K. BOROOAH
support—on the charge that the government was ‘spying’ on the INC’s
leader, Rajiv Gandhi—paving the way for the dissolution of the 9th Lok
Sabha and the start of the General Election campaign of 1991.
After the 1991 elections, the INC, with 244 seats, formed the govern-
ment (with Narasimha Rao as Prime Minister after the INC’s dynastic
heir, Rajiv Gandhi, was assassinated in May 1991) with the BJP, on 120
seats, as the main opposition. This government lasted its parliamentary
term, and the 1996 General Election followed five years later.
The INC made a poor fist of it in the 1996 elections: even though it
won a larger share of the vote than the BJP (28.8 percent compared to
20.3 percent), it ended up winning fewer seats (140 compared to the
BJP’s 161). With the BJP, as the largest single party, unable to form a gov-
ernment—Atal Bihari Vajpayee lasted just 13 days as Prime Minister—and
the INC, as the next largest party, refusing even to try, the outcome was a
minority government. This was formed as a coalition of several smaller par-
ties and labelled the ‘United Front’ with Deve Gowda as Prime Minister.
The United Front excluded both the BJP and the INC but was sup-
ported by the latter. In April 1997, the INC withdrew its support to
the United Front, which was increasingly beset by internal wrangling
between its constituent parties, but agreed to support another United
Front coalition (which included Lalu Prasad Yadav’s Rashtriya Janata Dal
and Mulayam Singh Yadav’s Samajwadi Party as constituents) with Inder
Gujral as Prime Minister. Eleven months later, after Gujral had refused to
accede to the INC’s demand to drop three ministers from the Dravida
Munnetra Kazhagam (DMK) party from his government, the INC with-
drew its support, and this government also collapsed: the 11th Lok Sabha
was dissolved, and in February 1998, a fresh set of parliamentary elections
were held to elect the 12th Lok Sabha.6
The 1998 elections continued the low fortunes of the INC: it obtained
the same share of the national vote as the BJP (26 percent) but ended up
with fewer seats (141 compared to the BJP’s 182). The outcome of the
election was a coalition government, headed by the BJP with Atal Bihari
Vajpayee as Prime Minister. By the end of the year, this coalition also
collapsed as one of its partners—the All India Anna Dravida Munnetra
Kazhagam (AIADMK) with 18 seats—withdrew its support. This led to
the General Election of September 1999 to elect the 13th Lok Sabha.7
Since the Lok Sabha elections of 1999, India has enjoyed stable govern-
ment with each government completing its five-year term. The 1999 elec-
tion resulted in a coalition government, labelled the National Democratic
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INTRODUCTION 7
Alliance (NDA), with the BJP’s Atal Bihari Vajpayee as Prime Minister.
The Lok Sabha elections of 2004 and 2009 resulted in an INC-led
coalition of centre-left parties, labelled the United Progressive Alliance
(UPA): respectively, UPA-I and UPA-II. After the Lok Sabha elections of
2014, Narendra Modi became Prime Minister as head of a BJP majority
government.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
8 V.K. BOROOAH
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INTRODUCTION 9
April 2011, the niqab was banned in public places. All these laws were
based on the principle of secularism (laïcité).
In India, on the other hand, the wearing of religious symbols is not
only permitted, but also anyone who objected to, or took action to pre-
vent, such practices, by ‘hurting the (relevant) community’s religious sen-
timents’, would be viewed as non-secular or, to use a term popular in
India, ‘communal’. In France, the right of the magazine Charlie Hebdo
to publish anti-Islamic cartoons is regarded as a triumph of secularism; in
India, the ban on Salman Rushdie’s Satanic Verses, because it would, or
might, offend Muslim sentiments, is also a victory for secularism. On the
French view of secularism, the sacred is trumped by the profane; from the
Indian perspective, the sacred invariably trumps the profane.
There can be little doubt that some actions taken in France, on the prin-
ciple of laïcité, are insensitive to cultural differences and may even appear
provocative. The decision of some schools not to offer their Muslim and
Jewish pupils any dietary alternative when pork is the main item on the
schools’ menu is a good example of cultural insensitivity.12 It is safe to say
that on an Indian view of secularism, a similar situation would not arise.
In India, however, problems arise when what practitioners of a religion
find hurtful is taken to unreasonable, indeed unacceptable, extremes. The
reluctance to employ persons from the lower castes to cook school meals,
in order not to offend upper-caste sensibilities that food touched by lower
caste hands is rendered unclean, is an example of such pathology. On the
French principle of laïcité upper caste children would have to eat food
cooked by lower caste persons or else go hungry. The Indian attitude is
to tiptoe around the problem and, with much handwringing, attempt to
square the circle by expressing sympathy for both points of view.
A consequence of secularism in India is that each religion has an incen-
tive to preserve its identity in undiluted form—immune to any proposals
for reform—because such proposals, by ‘hurting its sentiments’, would fall
foul of the secular principle. The upshot is that the same heightened sense
of identity that reservation policies provide the backward caste groups is
provided by secularism to religious groups.
Arguably, Muslims in France and India have, in different ways, been
most affected by each country’s particular concept of secularism. In France,
Muslims, more than other religious groups, have been subject to the full
rigour of laïcité in terms of how they lead their public and personal lives.
In India, the policy towards Muslims has been one of non-interference,
most particularly with respect to Muslim personal law.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
10 V.K. BOROOAH
As regards the latter, a Muslim man in India can divorce his wife by
simply saying talaq (divorce) thrice and the All India Muslim Personal
Law Board declared in September 2015 that there was no scope of change
in the triple talaq system.13 Notwithstanding court judgements to the
contrary, Muslim husbands who divorce their wives are not required to
pay them alimony. This is due to the (INC inspired) Muslim Women
(Protection of Rights on Divorce) Act, 1986 which gave Muslim women
the right to maintenance for only three months after divorce after which
the onus of their maintenance was on their relatives.14 Yet, no attempt
is made to establish basic rights for Muslim women, in the form of pro-
tection from arbitrary divorce or maintenance payments in the event of
divorce, because it would be tantamount to attacking ‘Muslim identity’
and, therefore, fall foul of the secularism principle. This is notwithstanding
the fact that Article 44 of the Indian Constitution specifically requires the
state to secure for its citizens a uniform civil code throughout the territory
of India.
The failure to bring Muslims into mainstream life in India has, in fact,
failed Muslims. The Sachar Committee (2006), in its report to the gov-
ernment of India, quantified and highlighted the backwardness of Indian
Muslims. This report drew attention to a number of areas of disadvantage:
inter alia, the existence of Muslim ghettos stemming from their concern
with physical security; low levels of education engendered by the poor
quality of education provided by schools in Muslim areas; pessimism that
education would lead to employment, difficulty in getting credit from
banks; and the poor quality of public services in Muslim areas. In conse-
quence, as the Sachar Committee reported: one in four of 6- to 14-year
old Muslims had never attended school; less than 4 percent of India’s
graduates were Muslim, notwithstanding that Muslims comprised 13 per-
cent of India’s population; and only 13 percent of Muslims were engaged
in regular jobs, with Muslims holding less than 3 percent of jobs in India’s
bureaucracy.15
One of the reasons for protecting Muslim identity in India is because
it is acknowledged that Muslims—who, according to the 2011 Census,
comprise 14 percent of the population, with about 170 million adher-
ents—play a crucial role in determining electoral outcomes in India. On
one estimate, Muslim voters play a decisive role in determining the out-
comes in about 100 (of the total of 543) constituency elections.16 At the
same time, there are a large number of parties, national and regional, com-
peting for the Muslim vote: inter alia, the INC, the Rashtriya Janata
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INTRODUCTION 11
Dal, the Samajwadi Party, the Aam Aadmi Party, the All India Majlis-e-
Ittehadul Muslimeen, and the All India United Democratic Front, with the
latter two being explicitly Muslim parties. Paralleling the earlier discussion
on reservations, any political party in India that suggested measures that
might, even remotely, be construed as an attack on Muslim identity would
have to suffer the consequences of losing the Muslim vote.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
12 V.K. BOROOAH
NOTES
1. In response to the burden of social stigma and economic backwardness
borne by persons belonging to India’s ‘untouchable castes’, the
Constitution of India allows for special provisions for their members.
These are mainly in the form of reserved seats in the national Parliament,
state legislatures, municipality boards, and village councils (panchayats);
job reservations in the public sector; and reserved places in public higher
educational institutions. Articles 341 and 342 include a list of castes enti-
tled to such benefits, and all those groups included in this list—and subse-
quent modifications to this list—are referred to as the ‘Scheduled Castes’.
Similarly, Articles 341 and 342 also include a list of tribes entitled to similar
benefits, and all those groups included in this list—and subsequent modi-
fications to this list—are referred to as the ‘Scheduled Tribes’.
2. After Lal Bahadur Shastri’s untimely death, she was India’s third Prime
Minister. This count excludes Gulzarilal Nanda, who was interim Prime
Minister twice: first, from 27 May to 9 June 1964, after Nehru’s death and
Shastri’s appointment, and then, from 11 to 24 January 1966, after
Shastri’s death and Mrs Gandhi’s appointment.
3. See the previous note on Gulzarilal Nanda.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INTRODUCTION 13
4. If both the 9th and the 10th Lok Sabha had lasted their parliamentary
terms of five years, there would have been three fewer elections: in 1989,
1994, and 1999.
5. The 42nd Amendment (1976) to the Indian Constitution, passed under
Mrs Gandhi’s government, declared India to be a secular country.
6. The DMK was allegedly criticised by the Jain Commission’s inquiry into
Rajiv Gandhi’s assassination in 1991 though since the Jain Commission’s
report was never made public, the allegation could not be substantiated.
7. Its demands were that: a former naval chief, who had been sacked, should
be reinstated; the Defence Minister George Fernandes should be relieved
of his portfolio; and a Joint Parliamentary Committee probe should be
ordered (Frontline, 24 April—7 May 1999, http://www.frontline.in/
static/html/fl1609/16090160.htm, accessed 26 November 2015).
8. It is a political cliché in India to view a person’s caste as an important deter-
minant of the party he/she will vote for. In her eponymous book, Chandra
(2004) asks why ethnic parties succeed. The Bahujan Samaj Party (BSP)
is the main Indian political party which espouses the cause of the Scheduled
Castes—who comprise 17 percent of India’s population—against that of
the upper castes. It employs the same methods of caste mobilisation in
every state—all of which have the same electoral system—but meets with
different degrees of success in different states. In one, Uttar Pradesh, it has
formed governments; in a second group of states, it obtains moderate lev-
els of support, but not enough to form a government; in a third group of
states, it draws a blank. Chandra’s answer is that the elites amongst the
Scheduled Castes weigh the advantages, in terms of access to the state
patronage system, of voting for their ‘own’ party, the BSP, against voting
for another party. If the BSP falls short in this calculation, then it fails to
attract votes from even its own ethnic group, the Scheduled Castes. The
conclusion of her analysis is that the caste basis for voting cannot be taken
for granted—it depends upon the circumstances.
9. As happened with the BJP when, on the eve of the 2015 Bihar Assembly
elections, one of its senior leaders asked for a rethink on the policy on res-
ervation: he suggested that a ‘non-political committee’ be set up to exam-
ine who needs the benefit of reservation and for how long (NDTV, 22
September 2015, http://www.ndtv.com/india-news/rss-chief-mohan-
bhagwats-statement-on-reservation-sparks-debate-1220171, accessed 26
November 2015)
10. For example, Vishnu (2015) reports that in the academic year 2014–15
the elite Indian Institutes of Technology admitted 2,029 students from the
Scheduled Castes and 856 students from the Scheduled Tribes of whom
only 432 and 80, respectively, would have secured admission in an open
competition based on examination performance.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
14 V.K. BOROOAH
11. There are convoluted attempts to define the Indian concept of secularism.
Bhargava (2010), for example, defines a secular state as ‘not anti-religious
but existing and surviving only when religion is no longer hegemonic…it
allows freedom of religion but is itself free from religion’. It is difficult to
see how such a platitudinous definition distinguishes the Indian version of
secularism from the French type.
12. The Guardian, 13 October 2015, ‘Pork or Nothing: How School Dinners
are Dividing France’, http://www.theguardian.com/world/2015/
oct/13/pork-school-dinners-france-secularism- children-religious-
intolerance, accessed 30 November 2015.
13. First Post, http://www.firstpost.com/india/no-scope-of-change-in-triple-
talaq-system-says-all-india-muslim-personal-law-board-2419482.html,
accessed 27 November 2015.
14. The Hindu, http://www.thehindu.com/thehindu/2003/08/10/sto-
ries/2003081000221500.htm, accessed 27 November 2015.
15. In 1865, Napoleon III gave Algerian Muslims the right to be governed, in
non-criminal cases, by Islamic law rather than the French Civil Code with
the result that Muslims ‘had no control or stake in the country in which
they lived’ (Hussey 2014).
16. Deutsche Welle, 10 April 2014, http://www.dw.com/en/muslims-to-
play-key-role-in-indian-elections/a-17558549, accessed 28 November
2015.
17. Srinagar, Ladakh, Baramulla, Anantnag, Jammu, and Udampur
18. The Preventive Detention Act (1950), Armed Forces (Special Powers) Act
(1958), Unlawful Activities (Prevention) Act (1967), Prevention of Insults
to National Honour Act (1971), Maintenance of Internal Security Act
(1971), National Security Act (1980), Terrorism and Disruptive Activities
(Prevention) Act (1985), Prevention of Terrorism Act (2002), and the
Unlawful Activities (Prevention) Amendment Act (2004).
REFERENCES
Anderson, P. (2012). After Nehru. The London Review of Books, 34, 21–36.
Banerjee, M. (2014). Why India votes? New Delhi: Routledge.
Bhargava, R. (2010). India’s secular constitution. In A. Vanaik & R. Bhargava
(Eds.), Understanding contemporary India: A critical perspective (pp. 19–48).
New Delhi: Orient Blackswan.
Chandra, K. (2004). Why ethnic parties succeed: Patronage and ethnic head counts
in India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Corbridge, S., Harriss, J., & Jeffrey, C. (2013). India Today: Economics, politics,
and society. Cambridge: Polity Press.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INTRODUCTION 15
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Chapter 2
2.1 Introduction
In elections to India’s lower house of parliament (the Lok Sabha), a single
representative for each of 543 constituencies is elected—on the basis of
obtaining the largest number of votes of all the candidates contesting that
constituency—as the Member for that constituency. This system of elec-
tion is known as the First-Past-The-Post (FPTP) system. In this chapter,
we examine features of the system of elections to India’s lower house of
parliament (hereafter, the Lok Sabha) with respect to the size of the elec-
torate, the percentage of voters that turned out to cast their vote, and the
candidates that offer themselves to the voters’ judgement. Using recently
available data, we examine the consequences of voters being able, under
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
18 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 19
1. ‘No party or candidate shall include in any activity which may aggra-
vate existing differences or create mutual hatred or cause tension
between different castes and communities, religious or linguistic’.
2. ‘Criticism of other political parties, when made, shall be confined to
their policies and programme, past record and work. Parties and
Candidates shall refrain from criticism of all aspects of private life, not
connected with the public activities of the leaders or workers of other
parties. Criticism of other parties or their workers based on unverified
allegations or distortion shall be avoided’.
3. ‘There shall be no appeal to caste or communal feelings for securing
votes. Mosques, Churches, Temples or other places of worship shall
not be used as forum for election propaganda’.
4. ‘All parties and candidates shall avoid scrupulously all activities which
are “corrupt practices” and offences under the election law such as
bribing of voters, intimidation of voters, impersonation of voters, can-
vassing within 100 meters of polling stations, holding public meetings
during the period of 48 hours ending with the hour fixed for the close
of the poll, and the transport and conveyance of voters to and from
polling station’.
5. ‘The right of every individual for peaceful and undisturbed home life
shall be respected, however much the political parties or candidates
may resent his political opinions or activities. Organizing demonstra-
tions or picketing before the houses of individuals by way of protesting
against their opinions or activities shall not be resorted to under any
circumstances’.
6. ‘No political party or candidate shall permit its or his followers to make
use of any individual’s land, building, compound wall etc. without his
permission for erecting flag-staffs, suspending banners, pasting notices,
writing slogans etc.’.
7. ‘Political parties and candidates shall ensure that their supporters do
not create obstructions in or break up meetings and processions orga-
nized by other parties. Workers or sympathisers of one political party
shall not create disturbances at public meetings organized by another
political party by putting questions orally or in writing or by distribut-
ing leaflets of their own party. Processions shall not be taken out by
one party along places at which meetings are held by another party.
Posters issued by one party shall not be removed by workers of another
party’.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
20 V.K. Borooah
As Singh (2012) points out, the MCC was first developed in the 1960s
in the state of Kerala following a broad consensus amongst politicians
about the need for ethical ballast to the electoral vessel. Despite the fact
that it has no statutory basis, the MCC has progressed from a voluntary
agreement between political parties to a set of prescriptive rules, codified
and implemented by the ECI with the acquiescence (however, grudgingly
given) of all the political parties involved.
In 2013, the Supreme Court directed the ECI to frame guidelines with
regard to the contents of election manifestos in consultation with all the
recognised political parties. Broadly, the ECI expects that manifestos will
not seek to beguile voters by containing promises which cannot be met
and, indeed, which the party concerned has no intention of meeting. In
particular, the ECI expects that “manifestos also reflect the rationale for
the promises and broadly indicate the ways and means to meet the finan-
cial requirements for it”.
The MCC also constrains the ruling party, in particular, its govern-
ment’s ministers, from using public resources—cars, planes, helicopters,
and government personnel—for campaign purposes or to seek to influence
voters by announcing new grants (e.g., increases in pensions) and new
projects (like roads, hospitals, and schools), or to make strategic appoint-
ments (like university vice chancellors or chairpersons of public bodies).
Such constraints that the ECI places on the pre-election behaviour of the
ruling party—and, in respect of bribing and intimidating voters, also on
other parties—blunts the use of ‘vote banks’ for electoral purposes.
In the Indian context, Srinivas (1955) coined the term ‘vote banks’ to
mean the exchange of benefits and favours to groups of citizens in return
for their political support. Vote banks had three essential features: political
parties which, at the time Srinivas was writing, was essentially the INC; a
village ‘middleman’, usually a high caste landowner who was a party mem-
ber and who had an agency over groups of voters; and voter groups. There
was then a patron-client relationship between party and ‘middleman’, and
the middleman and voters, based on a system of reciprocal favours.
Favours to voters took essentially two forms: the provision of local pub-
lic goods targeted at particular groups, say a paved road or a school in a
locality in which people from a group were concentrated; the provision of
private benefits to targeted groups of (usually poor) voters, often in the
form of cash payments or gifts in kind like cycles, sewing machines, and
so on; and illegally supplying below poverty line (BPL) cards to voters
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 21
who do not qualify for these (Breeding, 2011). This raises the interesting
question, addressed by Schedler and Schaffer (2007), of how one should
distinguish between favours granted through the public purse (‘local’
public goods) and payments in cash and in kind. Indeed, even when direct
payments are made, they should not necessarily be viewed as purely com-
mercial transactions; instead, they may reflect a sociocultural relationship
between the patron and client, embodying ‘obligation and reciprocity’
and an egalitarian transfer of resources from rich to poor (Srinivas, 1955).
However, the efficacy of vote banks as an electoral instrument has been
severely blunted by the MCC in respect of its strictures on bribing and
intimidating voters. An important consequence of the MCC has, there-
fore, been that the reliance of parties in India on vote banks to deliver
electoral approval is based more on hope than on expectation since fall-
ing foul of the ECI’s strictures risks severe penalties including disquali-
fication.4 Today in India, not least because of the efforts of the ECI, as
Breeding (2011) observes, ‘vote banks are social displays of wealth on the
part of political parties to attract primarily low-income citizens; they are
gestures, historical remnants of a system in which the rules governing the
game have changed’ (p. 77).5
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
22 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 23
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
24 V.K. Borooah
just under 50,000, was smaller than the UK’s largest constituency—the
Isle of Wight with an electorate of 108,000. Malkajgiri in Andhra Pradesh
had an electorate of over 3 million, and nine constituencies had electorates
between 2 million and 3 million.8 The turnout in Indian elections is also
high: 67 percent of voters exercised their franchise in the 2014 Lok Sabha
elections—compared to 66 percent in the 2015 UK General Election—
and the average turnout, over the 14 Lok Sabha elections between 1962
and 2014, was 58.6 percent.9 In 2014, the turnout of voters was greater
than 80 percent in 69 constituencies, and it fell below 50 percent in only
11 constituencies.
Table 2.2 shows, for each Lok Sabha election between 1962 and 2014,
the average size of the electorate, the percentage of voters who voters in
these constituencies, and also inter-constituency inequality in the distri-
bution of these sizes and turnouts. Inequality is measured by the Gini
coefficient which is one of the most commonly used inequality measures.
If N represents the total number of constituencies and Ei and Ej are the
electorate sizes in constituencies i and j, the Gini coefficient is defined as:
Table 2.2 Average constituency size and turnout and inequality in the distribu-
tion of Inter-constituency size and turnout: 1962–2014
Year Constituency size Gini coefficient on Turnout Gini coefficient on
size (%) turnout
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 25
1 N N
G= ∑∑ Ei − E j
2 N 2 µ i =1 j =1 2.1
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
26 V.K. Borooah
India and, indeed, throughout the world, it is clear that people do take
the trouble to vote.
One reason why people vote is because of ‘group identity’ voting which
has been analysed, for elections in Israel, by Hillman et al. (2014). In
the Indian context, the existence of vote banks goes some way towards
explaining why large numbers of people in India turn out to vote. Downs’
(1957) argument was based on the belief that the costs of voting—gather-
ing information about parties and candidates, registration, and time spent
to/from/at the polling station—were specific to the voter and were likely
to exceed the benefits from voting. The latter are in the form of collective
goods, and their benefit to a specific voter is likely to be zero.10Besley
et al. (2012) suggest that in the context of Indian villages, residents in the
Gram Pradhan’s village had greater access to public goods than residents
in other villages. However, in the context of ‘vote banks’, many of the
benefits of voting may be private benefits paid to groups of voters for their
electoral support and may be quite substantial.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 27
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
28 V.K. Borooah
argues, ‘for many Indian voters…voting is not just a means to elect a gov-
ernment. Rather, the very act of voting is seen by them as meaningful, as
an end in itself, which expresses the virtues of citizenship, accountability
and civility that they wish to see in ordinary life, but rarely can’ (p. 3).
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 29
1962 and 1977 rising to about 14 per constituency for the three elections
of 2004, 2009, and 2014.
As Table 2.4 shows, this increase is partly due to the increase in the
number of independent candidates in a constituency (up from an average
of one per constituency in 1962 to six per constituency in 2014) but it is
partly also due to the increase in the number of political parties (up from
an average of three per constituency in 1962 to 10 per constituency in
2014). In 1962, of an average of four candidates per constituency, one was
an independent and three were party candidates; in 2014, of an average of
16 candidates per constituency, six were independents and ten were party
candidates. What is undoubtedly true is that the ratio of independent to
party candidates has shifted in favour of the former: in 1962, there were
three party candidates for every independent candidate, but in the elec-
tions between 1984 and 1996, party candidates were outnumbered by
independents, and in 2004 and 2009, there was approximately one inde-
pendent candidate for every party candidate.
One possibility for the rise in independent candidates is not that they
expect to win, but that they want to undermine the vote of a party can-
didate. In a closely fought election (discussed in the next chapter), the
presence of independent candidates can erode support sufficiently to have
an appreciable impact on the outcome.11 Another reason for the rise in the
number of independent candidates could be pique at being denied a party
nomination. Since being a Lok Sabha member is a rewarding job—offering,
inter alia, a good salary, generous pension benefits, government-provided
housing in the capital, and free travel across India—there is considerable
competition to be adopted as a major party’s candidate for a constituency
(‘getting a ticket’, as it is termed in India). Alas, many are called, but few
are chosen. Some of those not chosen seek to exact revenge by standing
against the official candidate who deprived them (unfairly, in their eyes)
of their opportunity.
Table 2.5 shows, for the 2014 Lok Sabha elections, the average number
of candidates in a constituency in the 20 major Indian states. The smallest
number of candidates in a constituency were in the three eastern states of
Orissa (10.3 candidates), West Bengal (12.2 candidates), and Assam (12.6
candidates) and in the northern state of Himachal Pradesh (10.5 candi-
dates). These states had also the smallest number of independent candi-
dates per constituency: 1.5 in Orissa, 2 in West Bengal, 2.8 in Himachal
Pradesh, and 4.2 in Assam. At the other extreme, the newer states of
Chhattisgarh and Jharkhand had a large number of candidates per constit-
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
30 V.K. Borooah
uency (20.2 in Chhattisgarh and 18.1 in Jharkhand), and they were joined
in this plethora of candidates by Tamil Nadu (22.7 candidates per con-
stituency), Punjab (20.5 candidates per constituency), and Maharashtra
(19.7 candidates per constituency).
Although there has been a rise in the number of independent candi-
dates over time, this has not been matched by the number of independent
members of the Lok Sabha. Figure 2.1 shows that the number of indepen-
dent members in the Lok Sabha fell from 35 in 1967 to just three—one
from Assam (Kokrajhar) and two from Kerala (Chalakudy and Idukki,
respectively)—in 2014.
Between them, independent candidates received a total of nearly 17
million votes in the 2014 Lok Sabha elections which represented 3 percent
of the total of nearly 554 million votes cast in that election. Figure 2.2,
which charts the share of independent candidates in the total of votes cast,
shows that notwithstanding the increase in the number of independent
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 31
Fig. 2.1 Independent members of the Lok Sabha, 1962–2014 (Source: Own cal-
culations from Lok Sabha election data)
candidates between 1962 and 2014 (noted in Table 2.4), the propor-
tion of the total votes going to independent candidates has seen a secular
decline from 13 percent in the Lok Sabha elections of 1962 to 3 percent in
the Lok Sabha elections of 2014.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
32 V.K. Borooah
Fig. 2.2 Share of votes received by independent candidates in the total vote:
1962–2014 (Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
number of NOTA votes were: the Nilgiris (Tamil Nadu) with 46,559
votes comprising 5 percent of the total votes cast in the constituency;
Nabarangpur (Orissa) with 44,408 votes comprising 4.3 percent of the
total votes cast in the constituency; and Bastar (Chhattisgarh) with 38,772
votes comprising 5 percent of the total votes cast in the constituency.
The state with the largest number of NOTA votes was Uttar Pradesh
(592,211 votes), followed by Tamil Nadu (582,062 votes), Bihar (581,011
votes), and West Bengal (568,276 votes). These four states, collectively,
accounted for 39 percent of the total of NOTA votes.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 33
have been three Lok Sabha elections—2004, 2009, and 2014: informa-
tion on the ‘criminal status’ of all the candidates in the 2004 and 2009
Lok Sabha elections was collected by Golden (2014) and made available
through the Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research
(ICPSR) at the University of Michigan; and information on the criminal
status of candidates in the 2014 Lok Sabha elections was available from the
Association for Democratic Reforms (2014).14
Figure 2.3 shows that in the 2004 election, 8.7 percent of the candi-
dates (475 out of 5435) reported a criminal charge (hereafter, ‘CC candi-
dates’); in the 2009 election, 11 percent were CC candidates (893 out of
8070); and in the 2014 election, 17 percent were CC candidates (1401
out of 8180). Consequently, there would appear to be strong evidence
that the proportion of CC candidates in the total of candidates for Lok
Sabha elections is on the rise.
The proportion of CC candidates was, however, unevenly distributed
over the states. Table 2.6 shows the proportion of CC candidates, in the
total number of candidates, for every state in India. The outlier states in
this table were Bihar and Jharkhand—remembering that Jharkhand was
Fig. 2.3 The criminal charge status of candidates in the 2004 and 2009 Lok
Sabha elections (Source: Own calculations from Golden (2014) for the 2004
and 2009 elections and Association for Democratic Reforms (2014) for the
2014 election)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
34 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 35
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
36 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 37
Table 2.8 Party affiliation of members to the 14th Lok Sabha with reported
criminal charges
Party Total number Number of
of members CC members
Lok Sabha saw the number of CC members rise to 187 which comprised
34 percent of the total strength of the House.16
The election of candidates with reported criminal charges to the Lok
Sabha raises the further question of how they performed as legislators.
This issue has been examined, with respect to the 14th Lok Sabha, by
Gehring et al. (2015). Their first conclusion was that compared to non-
CC members of the Lok Sabha, the attendance record of CC members was
about 5 percent lower. There was, however, no difference in the amount of
‘parliamentary activity’—raising questions and participating in debates—
between CC and non-CC members of the 14th Lok Sabha.
The Indian government operates a Member of Parliament Local Area
Development (MPLAD) Scheme under which members of the Lok Sabha
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
38 V.K. Borooah
Table 2.9 Party affiliation of members to the 15th Lok Sabha with reported
criminal charges
Party Total number of Number of CC
members members
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 39
Table 2.10 Party affiliation of members to the 16th Lok Sabha with reported
criminal charges
Party Total number of Number of CC
members members
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
40 V.K. Borooah
tion and management, elections in May 2014 to the 16th Lok Sabha were
organised in nine phases beginning on 7 April 2014 and concluding on 12
May 2014 with the results being declared on 16 May 2014. Nearly 815
million persons were eligible to vote, of whom nearly 550 million voted,
using 930,000 voting centres deploying 1.4 million Electronic Voting
Machines (EVM). All this required the ECI to engage 2 million workers
to oversee the electoral process.
Mozaffar and Schedler (2002) argue that ‘good elections are impos-
sible without effective electoral governance’, and it is precisely such gover-
nance that the ECI seeks to provide. So much so that, Rudolf and Rudolf
(2002) place the ECI alongside the Supreme Court and the Presidency as
an enforcer of rules that ‘safeguard the legitimacy of the political system’
and suggest that the cabinet and parliament have ceded pride of place to
these three regulatory institutions.
While many of the duties of the ECI are technical and administrative,
the MCC provides a moral compass for the conduct of electoral politics
in India. In so doing, the ECI has mutated from a referee enforcing rules,
agreed to by others, to a regulatory body which makes rules which others
have to obey (Singh, 2012). In assuming this role, it has been aided by
the Supreme Court ruling that under Article 324(2) of the Constitution,
the ECI has ‘a reservoir of powers where the law was silent’ (Singh, 2012).
Some find the authoritarian nature of the ECI’s mode of operation to
be troubling. For example, Chaterjee (2006) feels that by riding rough-
shod over local culture and practices, the ECI has gone too far in the
direction of sanitising and cleaning politics. Yet others feel that at critical
moments, the ECI has proved toothless. After his alleged ‘hate speech’ in
the Pilibhit constituency in March 2009, the ECI advised the BJP not to
adopt Varun Gandhi as its parliamentary candidate in that constituency for
the Lok Sabha elections of 2009; this advice was ignored and Mr Gandhi
went on to become the Lok Sabha member for Pilibhit. More generally, the
ECI has proved impotent in arresting an unsavoury trend in Indian poli-
tics where candidates with reported criminal charges are elected to legisla-
tive office: as the previous section noted, one in three of members to the
16th Lok Sabha reported criminal charges against him/her. Unfortunately,
there is nothing in the MCC to prevent this trend from continuing.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 41
Notes
1. Article 342(2) states that the Election Commission shall consist of the
Chief Election Commissioner and such number of other Election
Commissioners, if any, as the President may from time to time fix and the
appointment of the Chief Election Commissioner and other Election
Commissioners shall, subject to the provisions of any law made in that
behalf by Parliament, be made by the President.
2. See McMillan (2012) for a detailed account of the formation of the ECI.
3. See http://eci.nic.in/eci_main/MCC-ENGLISH_28022014.pdf,
accessed 5 November 2015.
4. As a consequence of employing over 2 million workers during elections,
the ECI’s observers are ubiquitous and, since they are drawn from the
ranks of those in civilian employment, cannot be easily identified. In addi-
tion, the Indian media seizes upon any infractions of the MCC and affords
them considerable publicity.
5. Indeed, it is a moot point whether the fact that ‘vote buying’ is virtually
unknown in Western countries is due more to the difficulty of doing so
than to any innate moral superiority. Wang and Kurzman (2007) detail the
planning, organisation, and sheer expenditure required for a widespread
vote buying in the 1993 elections in Taiwan. Vote buying required an
extensive network of brokers who would each control small groups of vot-
ers. In order to be effective, such a network was predicated on: detailed
local knowledge; relationships of trust between party brokers and voters; a
large budget; and legal circumspection in conjunction with, possibly, judi-
cial protection. To compound these problems, 45 percent of voters did not
deliver on their promises to vote appropriately.
6. Press Information Bureau, Election Commission of India, http://pib.nic.
in/newsite/PrintRelease.aspx?relid=104537, retrieved 6 November 2015.
7. Press Information Bureau, Election Commission of India, http://pib.nic.
in/newsite/PrintRelease.aspx?relid=104537, retrieved 6 November 2015.
8. Chevella (erstwhile Andhra Pradesh, now Telengana), North West Delhi, West
Delhi, Bangalore North, Bangalore Rural, Indore (Madhya Pradesh), Thane
(Maharashtra), Ghaziabad (Uttar Pradesh), and Unnao (Uttar Pradesh)
9. Though turnout in the UK General Elections exceeded 80 percent in the
1950 and 1951 elections and remained above 70 percent for all elections
between 1945 and 1997.
10. Though turnout in the UK General Elections exceeded 80 percent in the
1950 and 1951 elections and remained above 70 percent for all elections
between 1945 and 1997.
11. This point is developed by Praveen Chakravarty, ‘Independent
Candidates: party-poopers in disguise’, Business Standard, 28 November
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
42 V.K. Borooah
2013, http://www.business-standard.com/article/opinion/praveen-
chakravar ty-independent-candidates-par ty-poopers-in-disguise-
113112800936_1.html, accessed on 29 September 2015.
12. Before NOTA, voters wishing to reject all the candidates were required to
enter their names in a register and cast their vote on a separate paper
ballot.
13. Union of India versus Association for Democratic Reforms. In a subsequent
judgement in 2003—Union of India versus People’s Union for Civil
Liberties—the Supreme Court mandated the compulsory declaration of
candidates’ financial assets. Details in Sen (2012).
14. The difference between the two sources was that while the Golden (2014)
data was available for individual candidates, the Association for Democratic
Reforms (2014) data was available only in aggregated form and only for
winners.
15. For reasons set out in the previous note, we were unable to present state-
wise information for the Lok Sabha elections of 2014.
16. It should be cautioned that the numbers from Golden (2014) and the
Association for Democratic Reforms (2014) are not entirely consistent.
For example, according to Golden (2014), there were 129 CC members in
the 15th Lok Sabha while the Association for Democratic Reforms (2014)
put this figure at 158.
17. See Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, Government of
India, http://mplads.nic.in/, accessed 7 November 2015. This facility is
also available to members of the Upper House, the Rajya Sabha.
References
Association for Democratic Reforms. (2014). Analysis of criminal background,
financial, education, gender and other details of winners, Lok Sabha elections
2014. New Delhi: Association for Democratic Reforms (www.adrindia.org).
Banerjee, M. (2014). Why India votes? New Delhi: Routledge.
Besley, T., Pande, R., & Rao, V. (2012). Just rewards? Local politics and public
resource allocation in South India. World Bank Economic Review, 26,
191–216.
Breeding, M. (2011). The micro-politics of vote banks in Karnataka. Economic
and Political Weekly, XLVI, 71–77.
Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision: The pure theory of
electoral preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.
Gehring, K., Kauffeldt, T. F., & Vadlamannati, K. C. (2015). Crime, incentives
and political effort: A model and empirical application for India. Discussion
paper no. 170. Germany: Georg-August-Universität Göttingen.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Anatomy of Indian Parliamentary Elections 43
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Chapter 3
3.1 Introduction
In this chapter, we begin a comparison between the two major protago-
nists in Indian elections—the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) and the Indian
National Congress (INC). The comparison relates to the relative effi-
ciency of the two parties in winning constituency battles and in convert-
ing votes into seats. This chapter places emphasis on the probability of
winning elections. It provides estimates of such probabilities and shows
how these differ between the BJP and the INC. In so doing, the first port
of call is the ‘marginal constituency’: a constituency where the margin of
victory between the winner and the runner-up is so small that the result
could have been reversed with a small shift in votes from the winner to the
loser. In the context of such constituencies, we first estimate the separate
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
46 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 47
percentage points or less. The corresponding figures for the INC “land-
slide” election of 1984 were 154 constituencies at the 10-point level and
80 constituencies at the 5-point level: respectively, 29 and 15 percent of
the total of 537 constituencies. Table 3.1 shows the number of marginal
constituencies for each of the elections between 1962 and 2014.
The important point that emerges from Table 3.1 is the growing pres-
ence of marginal constituencies in the total of constituencies. In 1971,
when the INC won 352 seats, one in four constituencies was a ‘10-point’
marginal and ‘5-point’ marginal comprised 12 percent of total constitu-
encies. By 1984, when the INC won 414 seats, ‘10-point’ marginal and
‘5-point’ marginal comprised, respectively, 28 and 15 percent of total con-
stituencies, and in the elections since 1998, marginal seats have come to
dominate reaching an apotheosis in 2009 of 63 percent of all constituen-
cies decided on a margin of 10 percent or less and 36 percent of all constit-
uencies decided on a margin of 5 percent or less. This would suggest that
targeting key groups of voters is (or should be) an increasingly important
part of the electoral strategy in India since small swings in support can,
more than ever before, make the difference between forming a govern-
ment or sitting in opposition.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
48 V.K. Borooah
Table 3.2 Marginal constituencies by major Indian states in the 2014 Lok Sabha
elections
State Total number of Number of marginal Number of marginal
constituencies constituencies at ≤ 10 constituencies at ≤ 5
points difference points difference
Andhra Pradesh 42 26 15
Assam 14 6 4
Bihar 40 18 9
Chhattisgarh 11 4 4
Gujarat 26 2 0
Haryana 10 3 1
Himachal 4 1 0
Pradesh
Jammu and 6 3 1
Kashmir
Jharkhand 14 7 4
Karnataka 28 17 8
Kerala 20 16 13
Madhya Pradesh 29 5 2
Maharashtra 48 8 4
Orissa 21 7 5
Punjab 13 9 6
Rajasthan 25 5 2
Tamil Nadu 39 5 1
Uttarakhand 5 0 0
Uttar Pradesh 80 19 7
West Bengal 42 17 4
Total 517 178 90
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 49
Pr [ yi = 1] K
1 − Pr [ y = 1] ∑
log = β k Xik + ui = Z i (3.1)
i k =1
e zi
Pr [ yi = 1] = (3.2)
1 + e zi
where, the term ‘e’, in the above equation, represents the exponential
term.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
50 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 51
Table 3.3 Logit estimates for the probability of the INC winning marginal
constituencies
1 2 3 4 5
(continued)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
52 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 53
Table 3.4 Logit estimates for the probability of the BJP winning marginal
constituencies
1 2 3 4 5
(continued)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
54 V.K. Borooah
it passes through the sample mean, the overall predicted probability, from
the logit model, of winning a marginal constituency will be the same as the
overall sample proportion of marginal constituencies in which the party
was victorious. However, while the estimated model passes through the
overall sample mean, it does not pass through the means of the different
sample subgroups. This is illustrated in Table 3.5 which compares, for
each year and in aggregate, the predicted probabilities and the sample
averages. The two quantities differ for each election (though they follow
each other closely over the elections) but are the same when aggregated
over all the elections.
The general methodology for computing the predicted probabilities
was to calculate, for each of the observations (1989 for the INC; 1009
for the BJP), the probability of winning the election under a hypothetical
situation (Scenario 1) in which some of the independent variables took
specified values (e.g., the variable ‘year’ was set to 1967), the values of the
other independent variables (turnout, etc.) being as observed. This then
yielded 69.2 percent as the predicted probability of winning a marginal
constituency in 1967.
In order to obtain the predicted probability of winning in 1971, the
variable ‘year’ was set to 1971, the values of the other independent vari-
ables being as observed. This then yielded Scenario 2. The difference in
the average probability of winning between the scenarios could then be
ascribed to the change in the value of the independent variable(s), in this
case between the years 1967 and 1971.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 55
3.3.2 Incumbency Effects
Table 3.7 shows that the average likelihood of the INC winning marginal
constituencies was 53.5 percent if it was the incumbent party and 46.7
percent if it was the non-incumbent, and this difference was significantly
different from 0. For the BJP, on the other hand, the likelihood of win-
ning marginal constituencies was 54.5 percent if it was the incumbent
party and 58.2 percent if it was the non-incumbent, but this difference
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
56
Table 3.5 INC and BJP predicted probabilities of winning marginal constituencies
INC BJP
V.K. Borooah
Probability of Sample proportion Total number of Probability of Sample proportion Total number of
winning of marginal marginal winning of marginal marginal
marginal constituencies won constituencies marginal constituencies won constituencies
constituency contested constituency contested
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
1998 0.507 0.515 163 0.516 0.554 168
1999 0.355 0.382 178 0.516 0.592 169
2004 0.447 0.421 164 0.557 0.558 138
2009 0.569 0.592 218 0.537 0.525 143
2014 0.358 0.302 86 0.676 0.728 92
Total 0.499 0.499 1989 0.566 0.566 1009
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
58 V.K. Borooah
Table 3.7 INC and BJP predicted probabilities of winning marginal constituen-
cies as the incumbent and non-incumbent parties
INC BJP
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 59
Fig. 3.1 INC and BJP predicted probabilities of winning marginal constituen-
cies with no independent candidates or just two parties contesting (Source: Own
calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
60 V.K. Borooah
Fig. 3.2 INC and BJP predicted probabilities of winning marginal constituen-
cies at different rates of voter turnout (Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha
election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 61
Fig. 3.3 INC and BJP predicted probabilities of winning marginal constituen-
cies at different vote shares (Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election
data)
Computed over all the eight elections between 1989 and 2014, the pre-
dicted probability of winning marginal constituencies, at each of the three
vote shares, 35, 40, and 45 percent, was always higher for the BJP than for
the INC: with a 35 percent vote share, the INC had a 34.4 percent chance
of winning a marginal constituency compared to the BJP’s 56.3 percent.
The next section examines the relative performance of the INC and the
BJP in greater depth.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
62 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 63
Fig. 3.4 Total number of seats contested by the INC and the BJP: 1984–2014
(Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
3.4.1 Econometric Methodology
In order to assess the relative electoral performance of the INC and the
BJP, we estimated a two-equation probit (bivariate probit) model over
the sample of constituencies—in the 20 major states of India (listed in
Tables 3.3 and 3.4) and over the nine Lok Sabha elections from 1984
to 2014—which were contested by both the INC and the BJP.8 The first
equation related to the INC: the dependent variable in this equation took
the value 1 (yi = 1) if the INC won the election for constituency i, i = 1,…N,
and 0 if it did not (yi = 0). The second equation related to the BJP: the
dependent variable in this equation took the value 1 (zi = 1) if the BJP won
the election for constituency i, i = 1,…N, and 0 if it did not (zi = 0).
This system of two probit equations (bivariate probit) is the discrete
choice analogue of the Seemingly Unrelated Regression Equations (SURE)
method of estimation with continuous dependent variables (Greene,
2003, pp. 710–19). Like SURE estimates, the estimates from the bivariate
probit system are more efficient than those obtained from estimating each
equation as a single equation because the correlation between the error
terms of the two equations is explicitly taken into account. In addition,
and more importantly for the purpose of this analysis, the fact that the
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
64 V.K. Borooah
(i) The share of the total votes received by the party in that
constituency;
(ii) Whether the party held the constituency in the previous election
(i.e., it was the ‘incumbent’ party);
(iii) The percentage of the electorate voting in that election (‘turnout’);
(iv) The number of independent candidates in the election;
(v) The number of ‘other’ (i.e., other than the INC and the BJP) party
candidates in the election;
(vi) The year of the election; and
(vii) The state in which the constituency was located.
The comparison between the electoral performance of the INC and the
BJP, in constituencies where both parties were contestants, was made with
respect to two parameters:
Table 3.10 compares the predicted probabilities of the INC and the
BJP winning Lok Sabha elections between 1989 and 2014 in constituen-
cies, in the 20 major Indian states, which they both contested. Aggregated
over all these elections, the first row of Table 3.10 shows that the INC
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Table 3.9 Bivariate probit estimates for the likelihood of the INC and the BJP winning constituency elections
INC BJP
INC vote share 0.064 0.023 2.79 0.01 0.161 0.033 4.82 0.00
INC vote share 0.001 0.000 2.59 0.01 0.000 0.000 −1.05 0.30
squared
INC incumbent 0.358 0.084 4.24 0.00 0.050 0.087 0.58 0.57
Turnout −0.042 0.027 −1.53 0.13 0.041 0.040 1.02 0.31
Turnout squared 0.000 0.000 1.31 0.19 0.000 0.000 −1.16 0.25
Number of 0.017 0.013 1.33 0.18 −0.002 0.014 −0.12 0.90
independents
Number of 0.000 0.000 −1.24 0.22 0.000 0.000 −0.26 0.79
independents squared
Number of ‘other’ 0.102 0.055 1.87 0.06 0.143 0.054 2.64 0.01
parties
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Number of ‘other’ −0.002 0.003 −0.75 0.46 −0.005 0.003 −1.79 0.07
parties squared
Year [Reference: 1989]
1991 0.451 0.154 2.92 0.00 −0.254 0.177 −1.44 0.15
1996 0.456 0.165 2.76 0.01 0.226 0.200 1.13 0.26
1998 0.503 0.166 3.03 0.00 −0.198 0.176 −1.12 0.26
1999 0.047 0.170 0.27 0.78 −0.239 0.178 −1.35 0.18
2004 0.391 0.168 2.33 0.02 −0.193 0.175 −1.10 0.27
2009 0.753 0.166 4.53 0.00 −0.291 0.184 −1.58 0.12
2014 −0.359 0.223 −1.61 0.11 0.314 0.250 1.26 0.21
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary...
(continued)
Table 3.9 (continued)
66
INC BJP
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Orissa −0.160 0.206 −0.78 0.44 0.455 0.446 1.02 0.31
Punjab −0.203 0.321 −0.63 0.53 −0.114 0.602 −0.19 0.85
Rajasthan −0.689 0.213 −3.24 0.00 −0.048 0.361 −0.13 0.89
Tamil Nadu −0.490 0.277 −1.77 0.08 0.065 0.421 0.16 0.88
Uttarakhand −0.307 0.427 −0.72 0.47 −0.008 0.537 −0.01 0.99
Uttar Pradesh 0.538 0.214 2.51 0.01 1.381 0.349 3.95 0.00
West Bengal −0.745 0.218 −3.42 0.00 0.147 0.476 0.31 0.76
Intercept −3.709 0.899 −4.12 0.00 −7.626 1.294 −5.89 0.00
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
68 V.K. Borooah
Table 3.11 INC and BJP likelihood of winning at different constituency vote
shares
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
All years
35 0.226 0.315 −0.089 0.020 −4.49 0.00
40 0.396 0.508 −0.112 0.024 −4.62 0.00
45 0.602 0.690 −0.088 0.040 −2.22 0.03
1989
35 0.152 0.333 −0.181 0.058 −3.10 0.00
40 0.301 0.530 −0.230 0.071 −3.23 0.00
45 0.506 0.712 −0.206 0.072 −2.87 0.00
1991
35 0.255 0.263 −0.009 0.044 −0.20 0.85
40 0.438 0.451 −0.012 0.053 −0.23 0.82
45 0.650 0.642 0.008 0.052 0.16 0.88
1996
35 0.256 0.400 −0.144 0.057 −2.54 0.01
40 0.440 0.600 −0.160 0.062 −2.57 0.01
45 0.651 0.767 −0.116 0.072 −1.60 0.11
1998
35 0.269 0.278 −0.010 0.049 −0.20 0.84
40 0.455 0.468 −0.013 0.057 −0.23 0.82
45 0.666 0.658 0.008 0.053 0.15 0.89
1999
35 0.161 0.267 −0.106 0.045 −2.36 0.02
40 0.314 0.455 −0.141 0.057 −2.48 0.01
45 0.521 0.646 −0.125 0.059 −2.13 0.03
2004
35 0.239 0.280 −0.040 0.049 −0.83 0.41
40 0.419 0.470 −0.051 0.060 −0.85 0.39
45 0.631 0.659 −0.028 0.058 −0.48 0.63
2009
35 0.339 0.254 0.085 0.047 1.80 0.07
40 0.536 0.439 0.097 0.056 1.74 0.08
45 0.737 0.631 0.106 0.053 2.01 0.04
2014
35 0.093 0.427 −0.334 0.064 −5.25 0.00
40 0.208 0.626 −0.419 0.071 −5.90 0.00
45 0.390 0.786 −0.396 0.100 −3.94 0.00
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 69
Fig. 3.5 Seats contested by the INC and the BJP in Hindi-speaking states
(Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
70 V.K. Borooah
Fig. 3.6 Seats contested by both the INC and the BJP in Hindi-speaking states
(Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 71
As in the previous section, the first equation in each of the two bivariate
probit models related to the INC: the dependent variable in this equation
took the value 1 (yi = 1) if the INC won the election for constituency i,
i = 1,…N, and 0 if it did not (yi = 0). The second equation related to the
BJP: the dependent variable in this equation took the value 1 (zi = 1) if
the BJP won the election for constituency i, i = 1,…N, and 0 if it did not
(zi = 0). The control variables in the non-HS and the HS models were the
same as those used in the previous section: the share of the total votes
received by the party in that constituency; whether the party held the
constituency in the previous election (i.e., it was the ‘incumbent’ party);
the turnout in that election; the number of independent candidates in the
election; the number of ‘other’ (i.e., other than the INC and the BJP)
party candidates in the election; the year of the election; and the state in
which the constituency was located.
The comparison between the electoral performance of the INC and the
BJP, in constituencies where both parties were contestants, was made—
separately for non-HS and HS major states—with respect to two parame-
ters: (i) the overall probability of winning the constituency with the values
of the conditioning variables taking their observed constituency values;
and (ii) the overall probability of winning the constituency when each
party obtained a particular vote share; 35, 40, and 45 percent.
Table 3.12 shows that in terms of the overall predicted probability of
winning a constituency—computed over all the eight elections between
1989 and 2014, with the conditioning variables taking their observed
constituency values—the electoral performances of the INC and the BJP,
in constituencies they both contested, differed according to whether
these constituencies were in non-HS or in HS states. The INC was much
stronger in the non-HS states—at 40.7 percent, its average probability of
winning in these states was significantly higher than the BJP’s 28.2 per-
cent—and the BJP, however, was much stronger in the HS states—at 55.5
percent, its average probability of winning in these states was significantly
higher than the INC’s 18.7 percent.
These probabilities of winning varied when they were computed on
an election-by-election basis. For example, the superior performance of
the INC in non-HS states withered in the 2014 election when there was
no significant difference between the INC and the BJP in their respective
probabilities of winning in the non-HS major states (26.2 percent versus
29.1 percent) but the superior performance of the BJP over the INC in
HS states was magnified (8.2 percent versus 74.3 percent). In the 1996
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
72 V.K. Borooah
Table 3.12 INC and BJP likelihood of winning by year, non-Hindi and Hindi-
speaking major states
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
All years
NHS 0.407 0.282 0.126 0.014 9.25 0.00
HS 0.187 0.555 −0.368 0.015 −24.50 0.00
1989
NHS 0.388 0.231 0.157 0.055 2.83 0.01
HS 0.104 0.630 −0.526 0.056 −9.34 0.00
1991
NHS 0.446 0.271 0.175 0.044 4.00 0.00
HS 0.177 0.496 −0.319 0.044 −7.26 0.00
1996
NHS 0.416 0.341 0.076 0.040 1.88 0.06
HS 0.251 0.585 −0.334 0.062 −5.41 0.00
1998
NHS 0.441 0.273 0.169 0.042 4.04 0.00
HS 0.204 0.561 −0.357 0.050 −7.14 0.00
1999
NHS 0.341 0.264 0.077 0.043 1.77 0.08
HS 0.145 0.539 −0.394 0.045 −8.84 0.00
2004
NHS 0.405 0.286 0.118 0.043 2.75 0.01
HS 0.207 0.498 −0.291 0.052 −5.65 0.00
2009
NHS 0.489 0.273 0.216 0.038 5.63 0.00
HS 0.294 0.479 −0.184 0.054 −3.42 0.00
2014
NHS 0.262 0.291 −0.029 0.053 −0.55 0.58
HS 0.082 0.743 −0.660 0.063 −10.53 0.00
(when the INC won 139 seats to the BJP’s 161) and 1999 (when the INC
won 114 seats to the BJP’s 182) elections, too, there was no significant
difference between the two parties in their respective likelihoods of win-
ning in non-HS states.11 In general, however, the pattern of the various
elections was that in constituencies contested by both parties, the average
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 73
Table 3.13 INC and BJP predicted likelihood of winning at different constitu-
ency vote shares: Hindi- and non-Hindi-speaking major states
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
All years
NHS:35 0.187 0.165 0.022 0.024 0.90 0.37
HS:35 0.292 0.482 −0.190 0.034 −5.65 0.00
NHS:40 0.349 0.346 0.003 0.039 0.09 0.93
HS:40 0.458 0.682 −0.224 0.036 −6.26 0.00
NHS:45 0.578 0.579 −0.001 0.145 −0.01 1.00
HS:45 0.628 0.833 −0.205 0.031 −6.67 0.00
1989
NHS:35 0.169 0.078 0.091 0.060 1.53 0.13
HS:35 0.137 0.582 −0.445 0.095 −4.67 0.00
NHS:40 0.327 0.208 0.120 0.103 1.16 0.25
HS:40 0.273 0.768 −0.495 0.096 −5.14 0.00
NHS:45 0.561 0.429 0.132 0.134 0.99 0.32
HS:45 0.447 0.890 −0.444 0.091 −4.86 0.00
1991
NHS:35 0.226 0.134 0.092 0.062 1.48 0.14
HS:35 0.273 0.384 −0.111 0.071 −1.56 0.12
NHS:40 0.406 0.305 0.101 0.097 1.03 0.30
HS:40 0.449 0.594 −0.146 0.079 −1.86 0.06
NHS:45 0.642 0.544 0.098 0.137 0.72 0.47
HS:45 0.631 0.769 −0.138 0.069 −1.99 0.05
1996
NHS:35 0.196 0.286 −0.090 0.078 −1.15 0.25
HS:35 0.410 0.512 −0.102 0.106 −0.97 0.33
NHS:40 0.366 0.506 −0.141 0.113 −1.25 0.21
HS:40 0.596 0.712 −0.116 0.100 −1.15 0.25
NHS:45 0.602 0.721 −0.120 0.438 −0.27 0.79
HS:45 0.761 0.854 −0.093 0.078 −1.19 0.23
1998
NHS:35 0.221 0.137 0.084 0.056 1.51 0.13
HS:35 0.323 0.477 −0.154 0.087 −1.76 0.08
NHS:40 0.400 0.311 0.089 0.079 1.13 0.26
HS:40 0.506 0.681 −0.175 0.087 −2.02 0.04
NHS:45 0.637 0.550 0.087 0.122 0.71 0.48
HS:45 0.684 0.833 −0.149 0.070 −2.14 0.03
1999
(continued)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
74 V.K. Borooah
likelihood of the INC winning, compared to that for the BJP, was signifi-
cantly higher in non-HS states and significantly lower in HS states.
As the results in Table 3.13 show, the thrust of these results was not
altered when the likelihood of winning was computed at different vote
shares. For a 40 percent vote share in an HS state constituency (row
HS:40 in Table 3.13), the predicted probability of a BJP victory would
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Estimating the Likelihood of Winning Parliamentary... 75
be 68.2 percent compared to the INC’s 45.8 percent; with the same vote
share in a non-HS state (row NHS:40 in Table 3.13), however, the INC
would win with probability 34.9 percent compared to the BJP’s 34.6 per-
cent, a difference which was not statistically significant. The pattern was
repeated under a hypothetical 45 percent share of the total vote: both
likelihoods of winning would rise further, but the BJP advantage in terms
of a significantly higher winning probability in HS states would remain
(83.3 percent versus 62.8 percent in row HS:45 of Table 3.13); in non-
HS states, the difference between the parties in their respective likelihoods
of winning remained statistically insignificant (57.8 percent for the INC
versus 57.9 percent for the BJP in row NHS:45 of Table 3.13).
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
76 V.K. Borooah
Notes
1. Note that ‘observations’ are distinguished by constituency name and by
year of election: for example, Adilabad in the 1989 and 1991 Lok Sabha
election is treated in the analysis as two distinct constituencies and, there-
fore, as two separate observations.
2. The focus was on constituencies in which the winning margin was 10
points or less in order to harvest the largest number of constituencies from
the data while remaining within the ambit of marginal constituencies.
3. See Long and Freese (2014), pp. 126–28 for a discussion of measures of fit
in binary models.
4. By implication, we do not consider marginal constituencies in which the
INC or the BJP was neither the winner nor the runner-up.
5. Over the elections from 1962 to 2014, there were 113 constituencies in
total in which there was only one party candidate, the rest being indepen-
dents. The most recent of such these was Kokrajhar (Assam) in 2004 when
the INC unsuccessfully fought the seat alongside three independents.
6. The effects of incumbency are analysed in detail in the next chapter. Here
incumbency is simply used as a variable determining electoral outcome.
7. This is also the figure reported in the last row, second column, of Table 3.5.
8. The difference between a logit and a probit model, both of which deal with
binary outcomes, is in the assumption made about the distribution of the
error term. In a logit model, the error term is assumed to be logistically
distribution while in a probit model, it is assumed to follow a normal
distribution.
9. Listed in Table 3.9 which mirrors the listing in Tables 3.3 and 3.4.
10. After the creation in November 2000 of the states of Uttarakhand and
Jharkhand from, respectively, the erstwhile states of Uttar Pradesh and
Bihar, the former lost five constituencies while the latter lost 14
constituencies.
11. Notwithstanding the fact that, compared to the BJP, the likelihood of win-
ning was greater for the INC.
References
Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis (5th ed.). Upper Saddle River:
Prentice Hall.
Long, J. S., & Freese, J. (2014). Regression models for categorical dependent vari-
ables using Stata. College Station: Stata Press.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Chapter 4
4.1 Introduction
A major issue in the study of elections is whether, and to what extent, the
chances of a candidate or a party being elected from a constituency are
improved or damaged by virtue of the fact that he/she/it is the incum-
bent in that constituency (i.e., had won the previous election from that
constituency). The literature on US elections suggests that incumbents
enjoy a considerable advantage over their challenger rivals: they are not
only much more likely to be re-elected, but also their margin of victory
has increased significantly over time (Alford and Hibbing 1981; Collie
1981; Garand and Gross 1984). By contrast, a recurring theme in the
literature on Lok Sabha elections in India since the 1990s is that of ‘anti-
incumbency’: it is alleged that at every election since 1991, voters have
cut a swathe through incumbent members of parliament and chosen to
replace many of them with a fresh set of faces.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
78 V.K. Borooah
P(A | T )
P (T | A ) = × P (T ) (4.1)
P ( A)
where: P(T)represents the prior belief that the hypothesis is true before
the data has been observed; P(A) is the probability of observing the data,
regardless of whether the hypothesis is true or not; P(A|T) is the probability of
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 79
P (T | A ) P ( A | T ) P (T ) P ( A | T ) P (T ) P (T )
ρ= = × = × =Φ (4.2)
P (T | A ) P ( A | T ) P (T ) P ( A | T ) 1 − P (T ) 1 − P (T )
P(A |T ) ρ P (T )
where: Φ = , where λ =
= is (OR) that the ratio of the
P(A |T ) λ 1 − P (T )
likelihood of winning, to the likelihood of losing, the election.
The term Φ in Eq. 4.2 is the so-called Bayes Factor (BF) applied to
incumbent parties. The BF is a measure of whether the data (A: the party
is the incumbent) is more likely to be observed under one outcome (T:
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
80 V.K. Borooah
the party wins) than under the alternative outcome ( T : the party loses):
Φ > 1 ( < 1) signifies that the likelihood of being an incumbent is higher
(lower) when the party wins compared to when the party loses. It tells us
by how much we should alter our prior belief that the party will win with
probability, P(T), and lose with probability, P (T ) = 1 − P (T ) , in the light
of the data that the party is an incumbent.3
P (T | A ) P ( A | T ) P (T ) P ( A)
σ= = ×
P (T | A ) P ( A) P ( A | T ) P (T )
P ( A | T ) P ( A) P ( A)
= × =Ψ (4.3)
P ( A | T ) P ( A) P ( A)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 81
P(A |T ) σ P ( A)
where: Ψ = = where µ = is the inverse odds ratio (IOR):
P(A |T ) µ P ( A)
the ratio of the likelihood of contesting a seat as a challenger party to
that of contesting it as the incumbent party. The term Ψ in Eq. 4.3 is the
inverse Bayes Factor (IBF) applied to the party that won that constituency.
The IBF is the odds of the null hypothesis being true (the party wins)
under one set of data (the party was the incumbent), against it being
true (the party wins) under the obverse set of data (the party was a chal-
lenger). If Ψ > 1 ( < 1) then, given that the hypothesis is true (the party
wins), we are more (less) likely to observe one set data (A: the party is the
incumbent party) than the complementary set of data (A: the party is a
challenger).
Table 4.1 Winning and incumbency outcomes for the INC and the BJP:
1962–2014
INC BJP
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
82 V.K. Borooah
Table 4.1 shows the winning and incumbency outcomes for seats con-
tested by the INC and the BJP in Lok Sabha elections. The INC results
pertain to the 14 successive Lok Sabha elections in India from 1962 (3rd
Lok Sabha) to 2014 (16th Lok Sabha); since the BJP only made its elec-
toral debut in the 1984 Lok Sabha election, its results pertain to the nine
Lok Sabha elections between 1984 and 2014.
If there were no constituency changes between elections, then the
number of seats won by a party (say, the INC) in one election should
be the number of seats in which it was the incumbent in the subsequent
election. However, boundary changes mean that constituencies disap-
pear between elections and, sometimes, even reappear. A case in point
is the number of changes that occurred between the 2004 and 2009
Lok Sabha elections. The INC won 145 Lok Sabha seats in the General
Election of 2004 but in the 2009 election, it was the incumbent in only
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 83
119 constituencies. Similarly, the BJP won 138 Lok Sabha seats in the
General Election of 2004, but, in the 2009 election, it was the incumbent
in only 103 constituencies.4
Tables 4.2 and 4.3 show, respectively, the losses and gains by the INC
and the BJP depending upon whether they were the incumbent or a chal-
lenger party. So, when the 2009 elections were announced, the INC, as
Table 4.2 shows, was the incumbent in 120 constituencies. However, in the
2009 elections, it decided to contest only 116 of its ‘incumbent’ constitu-
encies, and of these, it won 70 and lost 45.5 In the constituencies where
it was not the incumbent party, it won 136 and lost 189. Consequently, a
total of 181 seats changed hands between the INC and the other parties
(45 INC incumbents lost and 136 INC challengers won)6 which repre-
sented an ‘electoral turnover’ for the INC of 41 percent of the 440 seats
it contested in 2009.
Similarly, as Table 4.3 shows, in 2009, the BJP, as the incumbent party,
won and lost, respectively, 52 and 50 seats while, as a challenger party, it
won and lost, respectively, 64 and 267 seats. As a consequence of this, a
total of 114 seats changed hands in 2009 between the BJP and the other
parties7 (50 BJP incumbents lost and 64 BJP challengers won) which was
an ‘electoral turnover’ for the BJP of 26 percent of the 433 seats it con-
tested in 2009.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
84 V.K. Borooah
Fig. 4.1 Net migration of seats (losses less gains) from the INC and the BJP
positive values represent a net outflow; negative values a net inflow (Source: Own
calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 85
Table 4.4 RR and BF calculations for the INC in Lok Sabha elections
Number of Number of RRa Number Number ORb BF c (Φ)
seats won by seats lost by (ρ) of seats seats lost (λ)
incumbent incumbent won
b
OR = Number of seats won to number of seats lost, by the INC
BF = RR/OR
c
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
86 V.K. Borooah
Table 4.5 RR and BF calculations for the BJP in Lok Sabha elections
Number of Number of RRa Number Number ORb BF c (Φ)
seats won by seats lost by (ρ) of seats seats lost (λ)
incumbent incumbent won
b
OR = Number of seats won to number of seats lost, by the BJP
BF = RR/OR
c
Fig. 4.2 The RR for the INC and the BJP compared (Source: Own calculations
from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 87
tion governments, the RR for the BJP was slightly over unity, meaning
that the chance of the BJP winning a seat in which it was an incumbent
was just greater than that of losing it. In other elections, the RR for the
BJP was comfortably over unity, and most spectacularly, the BJP’s RR in
the 2014 election was 7.92: the chances of the BJP winning an incumbent
seat were eight times than that of losing it.9 Figure 4.2 compares the RRs
for the INC and the BJP from the 1991 election onwards.
The OR, λ, is the ratio of the total number of seats won, to the total
number of seats lost, by the INC and is the empirical equivalent of the
term P (T ) / P (T ) in Eq. 4.2. Figure 4.3 compares the ORs for the INC
and the BJP from the 1991 election onwards with the lowest and high-
est ORs being recorded for the 2014 elections: in this election, the INC
and the BJP won 0.1 and 1.9 seats, respectively, for every seat that they
lost.
The RR (ρ) when compared to the OR (λ) yields the BF defined as the
term Φ = P ( A | T ) / P ( A | T ) in Eq. 4.2.10 If the RR is greater than the OR
ρ
(BF = > 1), it means that in the light of the information that the party is
λ
an incumbent, we should revise upwards—by the amount suggested by the
BF—our prior belief that the party will win with probability, P(T), and lose
Fig. 4.3 The OR for the INC and the BJP compared (Source: Own calculations
from Lok Sabha election data
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
88 V.K. Borooah
Fig. 4.4 BF values for the INC and the BJP compared (Source: Own calculations
from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 89
1977 and 10 percent in 1989) than the likelihood of an INC win being an
incumbent victory.
For the BJP, too, the RR was always greater than the OR (meaning that
the BF value entered in the last column of Table 4.5 was greater than one).
In the 2014 election, the likelihood of a BJP win being an incumbent vic-
tory was more than four as likely (RR/OR = 4.1) as of a BJP loss being
an incumbent defeat. However, as Fig. 4.4 shows, the BF was generally
higher for the BJP than for the INC. For both parties, a win was more
likely to signal an incumbent victory than a defeat was to signal an incum-
bent loss, but this gap was larger for the BJP than the INC.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
90 V.K. Borooah
Table 4.6 IRR and IBF calculations for the INC in Lok Sabha elections
Proportion Proportion IRRa Number Number of IORb IBF c
of seats of seats (σ) of incumbent (μ) (Ψ)
contested by contested by challenger seats
INC INC seats contested
incumbents challengers contested
that were that were
won by them won by
(%) them (%)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 91
Table 4.7 IRR and IBF calculations for the BJP in Lok Sabha elections
Proportion Proportion IRRa Number Number of IORb IBF c
of seats of seats (σ) of incumbent (μ) (Ψ)
contested by contested by challenger seats
INC INC seats contested
incumbents challenger contested
that were that were
won by them won by
(%) them (%)
that the number of constituencies contested by the INC has not fallen
commensurately.
Consequently, post-1991, the INC emerges as a challenger party in the
majority of the seats contested by it, and in 2004, it contested three times
as many constituencies where it was a challenger compared to where it was
the incumbent. For the BJP, the three elections of 1996, 1998, and 1999
were ‘good’ elections when it won, respectively, 161, 182, and 182 seats,
and consequently, it built up a stock of seats in which it was the incumbent
party. This stock, combined with the fact that it contested far fewer seats
than the INC (in 1999 the BJP contested only 339 constituencies com-
pared to the INC’s 453), meant that it had a smaller ratio of challenger to
incumbent seats. Figure 4.6 brings together the values of the IBF for the
INC and BJP from the 1991 election onwards.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
92 V.K. Borooah
Fig. 4.5 The IRR for the INC and the BJP compared (Source: Own calculations
from Lok Sabha election data)
Fig. 4.6 The IOR for the INC and the BJP compared (Source: Own calculations
from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 93
Fig. 4.7 IBF values for the INC and the BJP compared (Source: Own calcula-
tions from Lok Sabha election data)
When the IRR was greater than the IOR ( σ / µ > 1 ), the
chance of a party win being an incumbent victory was greater than
the chance of it being a challenger victory, and this is reflected
in the fact that the IBF, Ψ > 1, implying P ( A | T ) > P ( A | T ) .
When the IRR was less than the IOR ( σ / µ < 1 ), the chance of a party
win being a challenger victory was greater than the chance of it being
an incumbent victory, and this is reflected in the fact that the IBF, Ψ < 1,
implying P ( A | T ) < P ( A | T ) .13 Figure 4.7 brings together the values of
the IBF for the INC and BJP from the 1991 election onwards.
Figure 4.7 shows that the INC’s IBF value was 3.4 for the Lok Sabha
election of 2014. Even though the INC only won 44 seats in this elec-
tion, its constituency victories, as and when they did occur, were 3.4 times
more likely to have been as the incumbent, than as a challenger, party. On
the other hand, the BJP which went into the 2014 election with only 116
incumbent constituencies but ended up winning 282 seats. In the event
of a BJP’s victory in this election, the likelihood that the party was the
incumbent in a constituency was only 60 percent of the likelihood that it
was a challenger.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
94 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Incumbents, Challengers, and Electoral Risk 95
tory in this election, the likelihood that the party was the incumbent in a
constituency was 3.4 times the likelihood that it was a challenger) but an
anti-incumbency effect for the BJP (in the event of a BJP’s victory in this
election, the likelihood that the party was the incumbent in a constituency
was only 60 percent of the likelihood that it was a challenger).
The overall conclusion of this chapter is that there is no obvious way of
measuring the degree of anti-incumbency, or its obverse, pro-incumbency.
There are at least four measures based on the likelihood of winning.
Which measure is appropriate depends on what one is trying to establish.
As Huckleberry Finn advised (in Chap. 28 of Mark Twain’s eponymous
novel): ‘you pays your money and you takes your choice’.
Notes
1. See “In Praise of Bayes”, The Economist, 28 September 2000.
2. The updating factor is the ratio of the probability of observing the data
when the theory is true, to that of observing the data regardless of whether
the theory is true or false: P ( A) = P ( A | T ) P (T ) + P A | T P T ,( ) ( )
T being the event that the theory is false.
3. See Matthews (2000).
4. For example, in Delhi: Sadar, Outer Delhi, and Karol Bagh which were
2004 Lok Sabha constituencies disappeared in 2009.
5. The four constituencies in 2009 which the INC did not contest, even
though it was the incumbent party in these, were: Bombay North East,
Hatkanangale, Namakkal, and Nilgiris.
6. ‘Parties’ include independent candidates.
7. ‘Parties’ include independent candidates.
8. Equation (4.2) is defined in terms of the proportion of contested incum-
bent seats won to the proportion of contested incumbent seats lost, but
NWincum / NWincum + N Lincum NWincum
since the denominators are equal, ρ = =
N Lincum / NWincum + N Lincum N Lincum
where NWincum and NLincum are the number of seats won and lost by a party
as an incumbent.
9. In the 2014 election, the BJP contested 116 seats in which it was the
incumbent party and won 103 of them.
P (T | A ) P ( A | T ) P (T ) P(A |T ) ρ
10. Proof: ρ = = ⇒ = =Φ
P (T | A ) P ( A | T ) P (T ) P(A |T ) λ
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
96 V.K. Borooah
11. In other words, if BF > 1, it means that a party is more likely to have been
the incumbent in a constituency if it won, than if it lost, from
( )
there: P ( A | T ) > P A | T . Conversely, if BF < 1, it means that a party is
more likely to have been the incumbent in a constituency if it lost, than if
(
it won, from there: P ( A | T ) < P A | T . )
12. In 1999, for example, INC incumbents lost 88 of the 140 seats they
contested.
P (T | A ) P ( A | T ) P ( A) P(A |T ) σ
13. Proof: σ = = ⇒ = =Ψ
P (T | A ) P ( A | T ) P ( A) P(A |T ) µ
References
Alford, J., & Hibbing, J. R. (1981). Increasing incumbency advantage in the
house. The Journal of Politics, 43, 1042–1061.
Collie, M. (1981). Incumbency, electoral safety, and turnover in the house of rep-
resentatives, 1952–1976. The American Political Science Review, 75, 119–131.
Garand, J. C., & Gross, D. A. (1984). Changes in the vote margins for congres-
sional candidates: A specification of historical trends. The American Political
Science Review, 78, 17–30.
Linden, L. L. (2003). Are candidates really advantaged? The preference for non-
incumbents in Indian elections. Massachusetts Institute of Technology (mimeo),
Cambridge (Mass).
Matthews, R. J. (2000). Facts versus factions: The use and abuse of subjectivity in
scientific research. In J. Morris (Ed.), Rethinking risk and the precautionary
principle (pp. 247–282). Oxford: Butterworth Heniemann.
Yadav, Y. (2004). The elusive mandate of 2004. Economic and Political Weekly, 39,
5383–5398.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
CHAPTER 5
5.1 INTRODUCTION
The analysis in the previous chapter focused on the effects of being an
incumbent or a challenger on the probability of winning. An alternative
mode of analysis would be to examine the effects of incumbency on vote
share: regardless of whether they win or lose, are incumbent parties in a
constituency, on average, more likely to get a larger vote share than parties
that are challenging? In order to examine this hypothesis, we estimated,
using constituency data, two equations: the first had as its dependent vari-
able the vote share of the INC in a constituency (i.e., the votes received by
the INC in the constituency as a percentage of the total votes cast in that
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
98 V.K. BOROOAH
constituency) and the second had as its dependent variable the vote share
of the BJP in that constituency.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 99
Table 5.1 Seemingly unrelated regression estimates for vote shares of the INC
and the BJP
INC
INC won 13.64 0.41 32.88 0.00
INC incumbent −4.92 2.01 −2.45 0.01
Year [Reference: 1989]
1991 −4.40 1.98 −2.22 0.03
1996 −7.81 2.00 −3.91 0.00
1998 −13.39 1.98 −6.77 0.00
1999 −8.52 2.00 −4.27 0.00
2004 −10.29 1.98 −5.18 0.00
2009 −8.25 1.96 −4.20 0.00
2014 −15.59 1.99 −7.82 0.00
Incumbent × year
1991 5.56 2.27 2.45 0.01
1996 2.77 2.21 1.26 0.21
1998 9.92 2.28 4.35 0.00
1999 5.18 2.33 2.23 0.03
2004 6.91 2.32 2.98 0.00
2009 5.96 2.26 2.63 0.01
2014 11.39 2.15 5.30 0.00
Turnout 0.43 0.15 2.97 0.00
Turnout squared 0.00 0.00 −2.96 0.00
Number of independents −0.18 0.03 −5.67 0.00
Number of independents squared 0.00 0.00 4.46 0.00
Number of ‘other’ parties −1.20 0.25 −4.87 0.00
Number of ‘other’ parties squared 0.05 0.01 3.46 0.00
State [Reference: Andhra Pradesh]
Assam −1.01 1.18 −0.85 0.39
Bihar −9.62 1.07 −8.98 0.00
Chhattisgarh 10.51 1.59 6.63 0.00
Gujarat 6.30 1.05 6.01 0.00
Haryana −2.88 1.33 −2.16 0.03
Himachal Pradesh 8.16 1.88 4.33 0.00
Jammu and Kashmir −3.92 2.30 −1.71 0.09
Jharkhand −4.67 1.86 −2.51 0.01
Karnataka 3.33 0.90 3.68 0.00
Kerala 5.33 1.02 5.24 0.00
Madhya Pradesh 4.92 0.92 5.34 0.00
Maharashtra 3.36 0.97 3.44 0.00
Orissa 0.61 1.06 0.58 0.57
Punjab 4.66 1.86 2.51 0.01
Rajasthan 4.55 0.99 4.59 0.00
Tamil Nadu −3.22 1.23 −2.62 0.01
(continued)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
100 V.K. BOROOAH
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 101
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
102 V.K. BOROOAH
The predictions for the vote shares for the INC and the BJP, for an
individual election (say, the 2014 election), were made under the hypothet-
ical scenario that all the 2684 observations related to the 2014 election.
In other words, in computing the predicted INC and BJP vote shares for
this prediction, the coefficient pertaining to the 2014 election (shown in
Table 5.1) was applied to all 2684 observations, the coefficients pertaining
to the other elections being ignored. Similarly, in computing the predicted
INC and BJP vote shares for another election (say, the 2009 election),
the coefficient pertaining to the 2009 election (shown in Table 5.1) was
applied to all 2684 observations, the coefficients pertaining to the other
elections being ignored. The difference between the predictions, of the
INC and BJP vote shares, represents the election effect on vote shares:
since these two sets of predictions differ only in the fact that the first set
of predictions related to the 2014 election and the second set related to
the 2009 election, without any change in the values of the explanatory
variables underpinning the two sets of predictions, the difference between
them must be entirely due to the effect of differences between the 2014
and 2009 elections, that is to the ‘election effect’.
The predictions from the SURE model are compared to actual out-
comes in Table 5.3. When the elections are considered in their entirety
(row: ‘All years’ in Table 5.3), the predictions and the outcomes are iden-
tical since the regression ‘passes through the mean’.2 The predicted and
a
Constituencies relate to those in the 20 major states (listed in Table 5.1) which were contested by both
the INC and the BJP
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 103
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
104 V.K. BOROOAH
Table 5.4 Vote shares of incumbents and challengers: BJP and INC
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
All years
INC 33.5 31.8 1.7 0.4 4.2 0.0
BJP 35.5 30.4 5.2 0.6 9.4 0.0
1989
INC 36.6 41.5 −4.9 2.0 −2.5 0.0
BJP 44.3 26.4 17.9 6.1 2.9 0.0
1991
INC 37.8 37.1 0.6 1.1 0.6 0.5
BJP 32.0 24.3 7.7 1.3 6.0 0.0
1996
INC 31.6 33.7 −2.2 1.0 −2.3 0.0
BJP 29.2 24.0 5.1 1.1 4.8 0.0
1998
INC 33.2 28.1 5.0 1.1 4.6 0.0
BJP 35.8 34.2 1.7 1.0 1.7 0.1
1999
INC 33.3 33.0 0.3 1.2 0.2 0.8
BJP 36.4 35.1 1.2 1.0 1.2 0.2
2004
INC 33.2 31.3 2.0 1.2 1.7 0.1
BJP 34.8 31.1 3.7 1.0 3.7 0.0
2009
INC 34.3 33.3 1.1 1.0 1.0 0.3
BJP 31.9 26.9 5.0 1.0 5.2 0.0
2014
INC 32.4 25.9 6.5 0.8 8.0 0.0
BJP 41.0 36.5 4.5 0.9 5.3 0.0
Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data using SURE estimates of Table 5.1
Table 5.4 shows that considering all the eight elections between 1989
and 2014 collectively, the average predicted vote shares of INC incum-
bents and challengers were, respectively, 33.5 and 31.8 percent, and read-
ing across the columns of that row, this difference of 1.7 points (column
4) was significantly different from zero.3 The next row does the same for
the BJP: the average predicted vote shares of BJP incumbents and chal-
lengers were, respectively, 35.5 and 30.4 percent, and using the preceding
argument, this difference, too, was significantly different from zero.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 105
Table 5.5 Differences in vote shares between BJP and INC incumbents and
challengers
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data using SURE estimates of Table 5.1
In terms of the individual elections, the vote share for BJP incumbents
always exceeded that for BJP challengers, except in the 1998 and 1999
elections (in both of which the BJP did particularly well, relative to the
INC, winning 182 seats in each election to the INC’s 141 in 1998 and
114 in 1999) when the difference in vote shares between incumbents and
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
106 V.K. BOROOAH
challengers was not significantly different from zero. On the other hand,
the vote share of INC incumbents was significantly smaller than that of
INC challengers in the 1989 and 1996 elections and significantly larger
in the 1998 and 2014 Lok Sabha elections. This would suggest that in
elections which went against the INC (e.g., 1998 and 2014) it was left to
the incumbent constituencies to produce the votes while, in elections that
went in favour of the INC (e.g.,1991 and 2009), incumbents and chal-
lengers were on an equal footing. A similar picture emerges with respect to
the BJP: when it did well, as in 1998 and 1999, incumbents and challeng-
ers got similar vote shares; when it did badly, as in 1991 and 2009, BJP
incumbents obtained a larger vote share than BJP challengers.
Table 5.5 compares the vote shares of INC and BJP candidates. In
particular, Table 5.5 compares: (i) the predicted vote shares of all INC
candidates with all BJP candidates (labelled I + C in Table 5.5); (ii) the
predicted vote shares of INC and BJP incumbents; and (iii) the predicted
vote shares of INC and BJP challengers. Columns 2 and 3 show, respec-
tively, the relevant INC and BJP vote shares with the difference in column
4 and the its standard error in column 5; column 6 shows the z-value
(computed as the difference divided by the standard error), and column
7 records the probability of obtaining, under the null hypothesis that the
difference is zero, a value greater than the observed z.
Aggregating over all candidates, incumbents and challengers, and over
all eight elections from 1989 to 2014, there was no significant difference
between the vote shares obtained by INC (32.3 percent) and BJP candi-
dates (31.5 percent) in the 2684 constituencies, in the 20 major states,
contested by both parties. In terms of the individual elections, however,
the vote share of INC, compared to that of BJP, candidates was signifi-
cantly larger in the 1989, 1991, and 2009 elections and significantly lower
in the 1998, 1999, and 2014 elections.
In terms of comparing the INC and BJP in terms of the vote shares
of their incumbent and challenger candidates, aggregating over all eight
elections from 1989 to 2014, with respect to the 2684 constituencies (in
the 20 major states) that were contested by both the INC and the BJP, the
vote share of INC incumbents (33.5 percent) was significantly lower than
that of BJP incumbents (35.5 percent); however, compared to that of BJP
challengers (30.4 percent), the vote share of INC challengers (31.8 per-
cent) was significantly higher. In terms of individual elections, BJP incum-
bents had a significantly higher vote share than INC incumbents.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 107
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
108 V.K. BOROOAH
Table 5.6 INC and BJP vote shares in Lok Sabha constituencies in Hindi-
speaking and non-Hindi-speaking states
Vote share in Hindi- Vote share in non-Hindi- All India vote
speaking states (%) speaking states (%) share (%)
the HS and non-HS states, some of which were not contested by one or
both of the two parties: in the 2014 Lok Sabha election, the INC contested
158 of the 204 constituencies (77 percent) in HS states and 306 of the
339 constituencies (90 percent) in non-HS states; by contrast, in that same
election, the BJP contested 192 of the 204 constituencies (94 percent) in
HS states and 236 of the 339 constituencies (70 percent) in non-HS states.
In order to compare the performances of the INC and the BJP in
the HS and non-HS states, in respect of the vote shares of incumbents
and challengers, we estimated two separate SURE models (of the type
described in the earlier section and controlling for the variables, noted in
Table 5.1): the first SURE model was estimated on data for constituencies,
which were contested by both the INC and BJP, in the 13 major non-HS
states, and the second SURE model was estimated on data for similar con-
stituencies in the seven major HS states. In total, over the seven elections
between 1989 and 2014, there were 1456 such constituencies in the non-
HS states and 1228 constituencies in the HS states.4
Table 5.7 shows that considered over all the elections between 1989 and
2014, for constituencies in HS states which were contested by both the INC
and the BJP, the vote shares of INC and BJP incumbents (respectively, 29
and 40 percent) were significantly larger than that of their correspond-
ing challengers (respectively, 25 and 37 percent). However, as Table 5.8
shows, for similar constituencies in non-HS states, INC incumbents did
not have any advantage, in terms of significantly higher vote shares, over
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 109
Table 5.7 Vote shares of incumbents and challengers: BJP and INC in Hindi-
speaking states
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
All years
INC 29.1 25.1 4.0 0.8 5.4 0.0
BJP 40.0 37.1 2.9 0.5 5.8 0.0
1991
INC 32.2 29.1 3.1 2.2 1.4 0.2
BJP 38.9 32.0 6.9 1.5 4.6 0.0
1996
INC 21.2 20.3 0.9 1.6 0.6 0.6
BJP 38.3 36.9 1.4 1.3 1.1 0.3
1998
INC 28.8 22.3 6.5 1.8 3.6 0.0
BJP 41.1 38.0 3.1 1.3 2.4 0.0
1999
INC 31.6 29.1 2.5 1.8 1.4 0.2
BJP 38.7 38.3 0.4 1.4 0.3 0.8
2004
INC 31.2 24.9 6.3 1.8 3.5 0.0
BJP 37.2 34.3 2.9 1.3 2.2 0.0
2009
INC 29.9 26.2 3.7 1.9 2.0 0.0
BJP 36.2 32.2 4.0 1.3 3.1 0.0
2014
INC 28.6 22.6 5.9 1.2 5.1 0.0
BJP 45.5 43.3 2.2 1.1 1.9 0.1
Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data using SURE estimates of equation for non-Hindi-
speaking states
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
110 V.K. BOROOAH
Table 5.8 Vote shares of incumbents and challengers: BJP and INC in non-
Hindi-speaking states
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
All
years
INC 37.4 36.8 0.6 0.5 1.2 0.2
BJP 31.5 25.8 5.7 0.7 8.2 0.0
1991
INC 42.5 42.2 0.3 1.3 0.2 0.8
BJP 26.5 19.7 6.9 2.2 3.1 0.0
1996
INC 36.4 42.6 −6.3 1.2 −5.3 0.0
BJP 25.1 18.1 7.0 1.9 3.6 0.0
1998
INC 37.2 33.3 3.9 1.3 2.9 0.0
BJP 32.0 30.6 1.4 1.5 0.9 0.4
1999
INC 36.0 35.5 0.4 1.5 0.3 0.8
BJP 36.2 32.3 3.9 1.5 2.7 0.0
2004
INC 35.8 37.1 −1.3 1.5 −0.9 0.4
BJP 33.2 28.2 5.1 1.4 3.6 0.0
2009
INC 38.8 38.1 0.7 1.2 0.6 0.6
BJP 28.7 22.2 6.5 1.4 4.5 0.0
2014
INC 36.8 29.4 7.5 1.1 7.0 0.0
BJP 37.2 30.2 7.0 1.2 5.8 0.0
Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data using SURE estimates of equation for Hindi-
speaking states
of INC and BJP challengers. Columns 2 and 3 show, respectively, the rel-
evant INC and BJP vote shares with the difference in column 4 and the
its standard error in column 5; column 6 shows the z-value (computed as
the difference divided by the standard error); and column 7 records the
probability of obtaining, under the null hypothesis that the difference is
zero, a value greater than the observed z.
Aggregating over all candidates, incumbents and challengers, and over
all eight elections from 1989 to 2014, Table 5.9 shows that the average
predicted vote share of BJP candidates was significantly larger than that
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 111
Table 5.9 Differences in vote shares between BJP and INC incumbents and
challengers, Hindi-speaking states
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data using SURE estimates of equation for Hindi-
speaking states
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
112 V.K. BOROOAH
Table 5.10 Differences in vote shares between BJP and INC incumbents and
challengers, non-Hindi-speaking states
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Source: Own calculations from Lok Sabha election data using SURE estimates of equation for non-Hindi-
speaking states
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
ANALYSIS OF VOTE SHARES 113
NOTES
1. Note that these are weighted means, the weights being the proportions of
the constituencies’ vote to the total vote.
2. Note that these predictions relate only to those constituencies, in the 20
major states, contested by both the INC and the BJP.
3. Since dividing this difference by its standard error of 0.41 (column 6)
yielded a z-value of 4.2 (column 6), the p-value of column 7 shows that the
probability of observing a z-value of this magnitude, under the null hypoth-
esis that the difference was zero, was absurdly small, and so, this hypothesis
could be ‘rejected’.
4. In presenting the results, the 1989 election was omitted since there were
only two BJP incumbents in this election, and both constituencies were in
non-HS states: Hanamkonda in Andhra Pradesh (won by C.J. Reddy) and
Mehsana in Gujarat (won by A.K. Patel).
REFERENCE
Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis (5th ed.). Upper Saddle River:
Prentice Hall.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Chapter 6
6.1 Introduction
As noted earlier, in Lok Sabha elections, a single representative for each of
543 constituencies is elected—on the basis of obtaining the largest num-
ber of votes of all the candidates contesting that constituency—as a mem-
ber of the Lok Sabha for that constituency. This system of election is called
the First-Past-the-Post (FPTP) system. The disjoint, under this system,
between the votes obtained and the seats won by a party frequently causes
consternation. Unlike a proportional electoral system, in which a party’s
share of the total vote is a good predictor of its share of parliamentary
seats, the relation between seats and votes in an FPTP system often works
in mysterious ways.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
116 V.K. Borooah
For example, in the Lok Sabha elections of 2014, the Bharatiya Janata
Party (BJP) won 282 seats with 31 percent of the vote while the INC with
nearly 20 percent of the vote could manage only 44 seats; in the same elec-
tion, the All India Anna Dravida Munnetra Kazhagam (AIADMK) won 37
seats with just 3.3 percent of the vote. Nor is this anomaly between votes
and seats confined to India: in the UK General Election of May 2015, the
Scottish National Party won 56 seats in the House of Commons on the
back of just under 1.5 million votes, while in the same election, the UK
Independence Party received nearly 4 million votes and were rewarded
with just one seat.
In this chapter, we attempt to understand some of these mysteries in
respect of General Parliamentary Elections in India. This chapter is con-
cerned with analysing the fortunes of India’s two largest political parties,
the INC and the BJP, and in the context of the above remarks, this chapter
examines, in some detail, the relationship between the votes obtained and
the seats won by the INC and the BJP.
The starting point of the analysis is the Law of the Cubic Proportion
according to which, in a two-party contest, ‘the proportion of seats won
by the victorious party varies as the cube of the proportion of votes cast
for that party over the country as a whole’ (Kendall and Stuart, 1950,
p. 183).1 In this chapter, we take a different approach to this ‘law’ by
separately computing for the INC and BJP the coefficient which equates
the proportion of their votes to the proportion of their seats. We term this
the amplification coefficient and show that its value is very different for the
two parties. Since the BJP gained political traction only from the 1989
General Election—when it won 85 seats, having won just two seats in the
previous General Election of 1984—the analysis in this chapter is confined
to eight General Elections: 1989, 1991, 1996, 1998, 1999, 2004, 2009,
and 2014.
Table 6.1 presents a summary account of election outcomes for the INC
and the BJP for the eight Indian Lok Sabha elections held between 1989
and 2014. This highlights two features of the electoral performance of
the INC and the BJP. First, the BJP always contested fewer seats than the
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Table 6.1 BJP and INC election results for eight Lok Sabha elections: 1989–2014
BJP INC
Year Lok Seats Constituencies Vote Votes Votes per Seats Constituencies Vote Votes Votes per
Sabha contested share seat won contested share seat won
2014 16 282 428 31.3 171,657,552 608,715 44 464 19.5 106,938,240 2,430,415
2009 15 116 433 18.8 78,435,352 676,167 206 440 28.6 119,110,824 578,207
2004 14 138 364 22.2 86,371,560 625,881 145 417 26.5 103,408,952 713,165
1999 13 182 339 23.8 86,562,208 475,617 114 453 28.3 103,120,328 904,564
1998 12 182 388 25.6 94,266,192 517,946 141 477 25.8 95,111,128 674,547
1996 11 161 469 20.3 67,697,336 420,480 139 526 28.8 96,034,448 690,895
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
1991 10 121 478 20.0 55,953,668 462,427 244 504 35.7 102,059,792 418,278
1989a 9 85 225 11.4 34,171,476 402,017 197 510 39.5 118,894,704 603,526
INC though, with the INC’s acceptance of the exigencies of seat adjust-
ment under coalition government, the number of seats it contested fell
from a high of 526 in 1996 (97 percent of the total of 543 Lok Sabha
seats) to a low of 417 in 2004 (77 percent of Lok Sabha seats). Second,
except for the 1991 and 2009 elections, when it won over 200 seats, the
INC has always paid a higher ‘price’ in terms of votes for the seats that
it did win: for example, in 2004, when both parties won roughly the
same number of seats—145 for the INC to the BJP’s 138—the votes
per seat for the INC, at 713,165, was considerably higher than the BJP’s
625,881.
The corollary is that compared to the BJP, the INC is relatively ineffi-
cient in terms of converting votes into seats: in 2004, it won 26.5 percent
of the vote compared to the BJP’s 22.2 percent, but only won seven more
seats on the strength of this four point advantage; in 1996, it obtained a
larger vote share (28.8 percent compared to 20.3 percent), but won fewer
seats (139 compared to the BJP’s 161); and in 1998, the BJP won 41
more seats than the INC (182 compared to 141) with the same share of
the vote as the INC (26 percent).
Given our interest in the two leading protagonists, the INC and the
BJP, the focus of the analysis was those constituencies in which there
was an INC and/or a BJP candidate so that constituencies in which
there was neither an INC nor a BJP candidate were excluded from the
analysis. Table 6.2 shows that of the total of 4323 constituencies in the
eight Lok Sabha elections between 1989 and 2014, there were only 245
Table 6.2 Constituencies contested by the INC and the BJP in Lok Sabha elec-
tions: 1989–2014
1989 1991 1996 1998 1999 2004 2009 2014 Total
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Relationship Between Votes and Seats 119
c onstituencies which neither party contested (5.7 percent of the total) and
2837 constituencies which were contested by both parties (65.6 percent
of the total).2
±
VAt S At
V t = (6.1)
B SBt
±=
(
log S At / SBt ) (6.2)
log (V t
A /V )t
B
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
120 V.K. Borooah
We compute the value of the amplification coefficient, from data for eight
Lok Sabha elections, held between 1989 and 2014 (9th to the 16th Lok
Sabha) for the two main protagonists in these elections—the BJP and the
INC—by mimicking a two-party system. In the first instance, we compare
the INC (party A in the above analysis) with the collective of non-INC
parties, including independent candidates (party B in the above analysis);
in the second instance, we compare the BJP (party A in the above analysis)
with the collective of non-BJP parties, including independent candidates
(party B in the above analysis).
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Relationship Between Votes and Seats 121
for every vote won by the INC, the non-INC collective won 4.2 votes
(=1/0.239), but for every seat won by the INC, the non-INC col-
lective won 11.4 seats (=1/0.088). On the other hand, for the BJP,
= 0.449 and S BJP / S BJP
VBJP / VBJP = 1.08
implying that for every vote won by
the BJP, the non-BJP collective won 2.2 votes (= 1/0.449), but for every
seat won by the BJP, the non-BJP collective won 0.93 seats.5 Furthermore,
V / V = 0.239 ⇒ VINC = 0.239 × VINC
since INC INC ⇒ VINC / VINC + VINC
,( )
= 0.239 / (1.239 )
and since
= 0.088 ⇒ S INC = 0.088 × S INC
SINC / SINC (
⇒ S INC / S INC + S INC
),
= 0.088 / (1.088 )
it follows that in 2014, the INC received 19.3 percent (= 0.239/1.239) of
total votes while winning only 8 percent of seats (= 0.088/1.088), while
Table 6.3 Vote and seat ratios and values of the amplification coefficient in Lok
Sabha elections: 1989–2014
INC/non-INC BJP/non-BJP
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
122 V.K. Borooah
the BJP, with 31 percent ( = 0.449 / 1.449 ) of total vote, won 52 percent
( = 1.08 / 2.08 ) of the seats.
One can verify that the amplification coefficients are correctly calculated
by computing the total number seats that a party would have won and
comparing these with the numbers actually won: these should be identical
if α has been correctly computed. In order to do so, define Á = (VA / VB ) ,
α
^
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Relationship Between Votes and Seats 123
but for every seat won by the BJP, the non-BJP parties won 3.7 seats. Thus,
the essential difference between the BJP and the INC was that compared to
the INC, the BJP was more efficient in translating votes into seats.
In order to understand this, measure of this inefficiency consid-
ers a party which targets, say, 200 (out of a total of 543) seats in the
Lok Sabha. Then, from Eq. 6.2, the vote ratio which will deliver this is:
VA / VB = ( S A / SB ) = ( 0.368) . Excluding the election of 2014—which
1/ ± 1/ ±
was a landslide victory for the BJP and, arguably, an outlier on a scale
unlikely to be repeated—the average of the amplification coefficient over
the seven elections between 1989 and 2009 was 0.96 for the INC and
0.76 for the BJP. Applying these averages, in order to win 200 seats in the
Lok Sabha, the INC and BJP would have required a vote ratio of, respec-
tively, 0.353 and 0.267.
In other words, to win 200 seats in the Lok Sabha, the INC would have
had to receive 35 votes for every 100 votes received by the collective of
non-INC parties (i.e., 26 percent of the total vote), but the BJP would have
had to receive only 27 votes for every 100 votes received by the collective of
non-BJP parties (i.e., 21 percent of the total vote). The value of the amplifi-
cation coefficient, α, is thus a measure of electoral efficiency—the smaller its
value, the greater the ease with which votes are converted into seats.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
124 V.K. Borooah
Table 6.4 Vote and seat ratios and values of the amplification coefficient in Lok
Sabha elections for Hindi-speaking statesa: 1989–2014
INC/non-INC BJP/non-BJP
Table 6.4, which reproduces the all-India results of Table 4.3 for the
collective of HS states, shows that the BJP’s electoral efficiency was far
greater than that of the INC in the HS states. Except for the 2009 elec-
tion, the INC’s seat ratio was always smaller than its vote ratio resulting
in an amplification coefficient that was greater than one. By contrast, the
BJP’s seat ratio was always larger than its vote ratio resulting in an ampli-
fication coefficient that was less than one. Indeed, in the 1996, 1998, and
2014 elections, the BJP secured a majority of the Lok Sabha seats from the
HS states on a minority vote (point 5 above).
In contrast, as Table 6.5 shows, the INC performed much better,
relative to the BJP, in the non-HS states. Its votes and seats ratios (i.e.,
VINC / VINC ) were both higher in the non-HS states than in
and S INC / S INC
the HS states, and its amplification coefficient was more favourable: bear-
ing in mind that as discussed earlier, a lower value of the amplification
coefficient is more desirable than a higher value; the amplification coeffi-
cient for the INC was always lower in the non-HS, than in the HS, states;
and conversely, the amplification coefficient for the BJP was always lower
in the HS, than in the non-HS, states.
In order to gain an appreciation of differences in inter-party elec-
toral performance between the HS and non-HS states, suppose that
the INC and the BJP each targets one in three of the seats from the
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Relationship Between Votes and Seats 125
Table 6.5 Vote and seat ratios and values of the amplification coefficient in Lok
Sabha elections for non-Hindi-speaking statesa: 1989–2014
INC/non-INC BJP/non-BJP
VA / VB = ( S A / SB ) = ( 0.50 )
1/ 0.53 1/ 0.53
= 0.27. In other words, to win one-third
of the seats in the HS states, the INC and the BJP would have required
vote shares of, respectively, 35 (=0.54/1.54) and 21 percent (=0.27/1.27)
in the HS states. On the other hand, to win one in three seats in the non-
HS states, both the INC and the BJP would have needed a vote ratio—of,
respectively, INC to non-INC votes and BJP to non-BJP votes, of 0.48 or
32 percent (=0.48/1.48) of the vote in the non-HS states.7
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
126 V.K. Borooah
Notes
1. Kendall and Stuart (1950) draw attention to the fact that the law was first
proposed by James Parker Smith—who, in turn, attributed it to
P.A. MacMahon—in evidence before the Royal Commission on Systems of
Elections (2010).
2. Bear in mind that ‘observations’ were distinguished by constituency name
and by election year: so, for example, Adilabad in the 1989 Lok Sabha elec-
tion represented a separate observation from Adilabad in the 1991 Lok
Sabha election.
3. Party A: (1/4.4) × 100 = 22.7 and party B: (3.4/4.4) × 100 = 77.3.
4. Another perverse outcome would be when party A obtains more votes than
party B, but wins fewer seats: VAt > VBt but S At < S Bt . In this situation, the
numerator in equation (2) is negative, with the denominator positive, so
that α < 0. This is a situation in which where the party A’s majority in votes
fails to translate into a parliamentary majority.
This implies that in 2014, the INC received 19.3 percent of total votes while
winning only 8 percent of seats while the BJP, with 31 percent of total vote,
won 52 percent of the seats. For the INC, [ 0.239 / 1.239] = 0.193 ; and for
the BJP, [ 0.449 / 1.449] = 0.31 and [1.08 / 2.08] = 0.52
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Relationship Between Votes and Seats 127
6. If the BJP, on a minority vote, had won the same number of seats as the col-
lective of non-BJP parties (i.e., 271 or 272 seats), the value of α would have
been zero.
7. Vote ratios of 0.47 (= (0.5)1/0.93) and 0.48 (= (0.5)1/0.95) which amounts to
32 percent of the vote in the non-HS states
References
Curtice, J., & Steed, M. (1986). Proportionality and exaggeration in the British
electoral system. Electoral Studies, 5(3), 209–228.
Kendall, M. G., & Stuart, A. (1950). The law of the cube proportion in election
results. The British Journal of Sociology, 1(3), 183–196.
Norris, P., & Crewe, I. (1994). Did the British marginals vanish? Proportionality
and exaggeration in the British electoral system revisited. Electoral Studies,
13(3), 201–221.
Rajagopalan, K. R. (1959, December 12). The law of cubic proportions. The
Economic Weekly, 1669–1670.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Chapter 7
7.1 Introduction
The previous chapter analysed the electoral efficiency of the INC and
BJP in terms of their ability to convert votes into seats. A large part of
this ability depends upon the geographical distribution of their vote. An
excessive concentration of the party’s vote in a small area leads to a small
of seats with large majorities. On the other hand, if spread too thinly,
electoral support dissipates resulting in many ‘near misses’, but few elec-
toral successes. This observation leads, in this chapter, to an analysis of
the distribution of the party vote between constituencies and between
states. Within this broad theme, we pursue two topics. Firstly, there is
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
130 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Concentration and Distribution of Votes 131
These considerations raise the question of the degree to which the votes
of the INC and BJP are concentrated in the states. A popular measure of
concentration, used in the industrial economics literature, to measure the
degree of competition in a market, is the HHI.1 Applied to the concen-
tration of a party’s votes across the Indian states, the HHI for party j is
represented by HHIj and defined as:
K
HHI j = ∑ vkj ( )
2
(7.1)
k =1
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Table 7.1 The contributions of the major states to the total Lok Sabha votea
2004 2009 2014
Andhra 9.4 14.9 3.6 10.4 14.5 2.1 9.0 5.4 2.5
Pradesh
Assam 2.7 3.6 2.9 3.0 3.8 2.6 2.8 4.3 3.3
Bihar 7.7 1.3 5.1 6.0 2.2 4.5 6.7 2.9 6.3
Chhattisgarh 1.9 2.9 4.1 2.1 2.8 5.1 2.3 4.6 3.6
Gujarat 4.0 6.7 8.6 4.3 6.7 10.8 4.8 8.3 9.2
Haryana 2.1 3.4 1.7 2.0 3.0 1.3 2.1 2.6 2.4
Himachal 0.7 1.3 1.3 0.7 1.1 1.8 0.6 1.2 1.0
Pradesh
J&K 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.7
Jharkhand 2.5 2.0 3.7 2.3 1.2 3.3 2.4 1.7 3.1
Karnataka 6.6 9.3 10.5 6.1 8.2 13.5 5.8 12.3 8.0
Kerala 4.0 4.9 1.9 4.0 5.7 1.3 3.4 5.4 1.1
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Madhya 4.9 6.3 10.6 4.8 6.9 11.2 5.5 10.1 9.6
Pradesh
Maharashtra 9.0 8.2 9.3 9.2 6.4 8.9 9.1 8.6 8.0
Orissa 4.5 6.9 3.9 4.4 5.2 4.0 4.0 5.4 2.8
Punjab 2.7 3.5 1.3 2.9 4.7 1.6 2.6 4.5 0.7
Rajasthan 4.6 7.2 10.2 4.4 7.5 8.7 5.1 8.0 9.0
Tamil Nadu 7.6 4.1 1.7 7.5 4.1 0.9 7.6 1.7 1.3
Uttar 14.1 6.4 14.1 13.7 9.0 12.8 15.1 5.9 20.6
Pradesh
Uttarakhand 0.7 1.0 1.3 0.8 1.2 1.4 0.8 1.5 1.5
West Bengal 9.8 5.4 3.6 10.6 5.1 3.5 9.6 4.8 5.2
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Total vote 379,076,480 99,695,696 83,489,256 403,313,440 112,695,216 75,491,856 536,140,896 102,771,824 166,309,568
from major
states
Total 389,779,776 103,408,952 86,371,560 417,158,656 119,110,824 78,435,352 553,801,792 106,938,240 171,657,552
all-India vote
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
134
Table 7.2 Values of the Herfindahl, entropy, and dissimilarity indices for the vote contribution of major statesa
V.K. Borooah
Total vote in major states Total INC vote in major states Total BJP vote in major states
Year Number HHI Entropy Dissimilarity HHI Entropy Dissimilarity HHI Entropy Dissimilarity
of major
states
1989 17 0.085 2.562 0.262 0.086 2.554 0.268 0.145 2.159 0.498
1991 17 0.086 2.574 0.261 0.083 2.596 0.239 0.115 2.378 0.368
1996 17 0.084 2.609 0.285 0.086 2.617 0.245 0.119 2.395 0.399
1998 17 0.085 2.606 0.274 0.089 2.571 0.292 0.11 2.458 0.356
1999 17 0.085 2.601 0.281 0.083 2.619 0.263 0.098 2.514 0.341
2004 20 0.075 2.743 0.292 0.072 2.777 0.263 0.081 2.702 0.334
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
2009 20 0.075 2.745 0.286 0.072 2.782 0.253 0.085 2.66 0.361
2014 20 0.076 2.744 0.285 0.069 2.801 0.245 0.094 2.627 0.36
Table 7.2 shows values of the HHI (defined by Eq. 7.1), for each Lok
Sabha election since 1989, with the major states as the vote-generating
units. The values are shown with respect to: (i) the total vote emanating
from the major states; (ii) the total INC vote emanating from the major
states; and (iii) the total BJP vote emanating from the major states. This
table shows that for every election between 1989 and 2014, the BJP had
associated HHI values which were greater than the corresponding HHI
values for the INC: this implied that in the context of the major states,
the BJP’s votes were more concentrated than those of the INC’s. This is
a reflection of the fact that the INC, as the older party, has a significant
presence in parts of India—like Assam, Kerala, and Jammu and Kashmir—
where the BJP, until recently, has been all but invisible.
Also shown are the values with respect to two other indices. The first of
these is Shannon’s entropy index defined as:
( )
E = − ∑vkj log vkj (7.2)
k =1
1 K j 1
D= ∑ vk − K
2 k =1
(7.3)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
136 V.K. Borooah
N * = 1 / HHI (7.4)
where: HHI is the HHI computed from the vote shares of the N par-
ties. If all the N parties received the same share of the total vote, 1/N,
HHI = 1/N, and N* = N: the effective number of parties is same as the
total number of parties. If one party obtained the entire vote, HHI = 1 and
N* = 1: effectively, the electoral system consists of a single party. In general,
the greater the concentration of votes (larger the HHI value), the smaller
will be the number of effective parties.
These ideas can equally be applied to the Indian states which contribute
unequally to the total amount of votes they generate. Consequently, the
effective number of (major) states is smaller than the actual number, 20,
of states. How much smaller can be determined by applying the Laakso
and Taagepera (1979) formula of Eq. 7.4? So, in the 2014 election, the
HHI values for the INC and the BJP were, respectively, 0.069 and 0.094:
consequently, the effective number of states for the INC and the BJP
were, respectively, 14.5 (=1/0.069) and 10.6 (=1/0.094). The effective
number of states differs between the two parties because the concentra-
tion of their votes, within the major states, is different: the number of
effective states was larger for the INC—with a smaller concentration of its
vote—than for the BJP with a greater vote concentration.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Concentration and Distribution of Votes 137
resent, respectively, the total (national) vote (over all parties) and party j’s
total (national) vote. Then the vote share can be decomposed in the terms
of vote supply as follows:
( )(
vk = Vkj / Vk = Vkj / Vk V / V j V j / V )( )
(
= Vk / V
j j
) (V / V ) (V
k
j
) (
/ V = g / nk v j
j
k ) (7.5)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
138 V.K. Borooah
N N
E = ∑ pi h ( pi ) = − ∑ pi log ( pi ) (7.6)
i =1 i =1
N N N
I = ∑ (1 / N ) × h (1 / N )− ∑ pi × h ( pi ) = ∑ log ( pi ) − log (1 / N ) (7.7)
i =1 i =1 i =1
maximum value observed valuue
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Concentration and Distribution of Votes 139
The larger the value of I in Eq. 7.7, the greater will be the disorder or
inequality in the system. If we set the probabilities to the observed vote
shares, so that pi = vi , i = 1…N, and let v represent the mean vote share,
we can obtain Theil’s (1967) Mean Logarithmic Deviation (MLD) index
as:
N
MLD = ∑ log(v / vi / N (7.8)
i =1
Table 7.3 shows the MLD and Gini values for the INC and the BJP
in respect of the inter-constituency distribution of their vote shares for
every Lok Sabha election between 1989 and 2014 with higher values of
both indices representing higher inequality levels.2 These values show that
inequality in the distribution of INC vote shares was at a low in 1989;
thereafter it rose steadily, reaching a peak in 1998; it fell in 1999, remained
fairly steady till 2009 but then rose sharply in 2014. By contrast, the inter-
constituency distribution of the BJP vote was highly unequal in 1989 after
which it fell reaching a low in 1999; then it peaked in 2009 before falling
back in 2014.
Set alongside the values of the MLD and Gini indices are the party vote
shares. These make clear (see Figs. 7.1 and 7.2) that in general, when-
ever overall support for a party was high, inequality in the distribution of
the party’s vote share, between the constituencies, was low: the INC in
1989, 1991, and 2009 and the BJP in 1998, 1999, and 2014. Conversely,
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
140 V.K. Borooah
Fig. 7.1 INC vote shares and vote share inequality: 1989–2014 (Source: Own
calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
Fig. 7.2 BJP vote shares and vote share inequality: 1989–2014 (Source: Own
calculations from Lok Sabha election data)
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Concentration and Distribution of Votes 141
henever overall support for a party was low, inequality in the distribution
w
of the party’s vote share, between the constituencies, was high: the INC in
1998 and 2014 and the BJP in 1989, 1991, 1996, and 2009.
I = A + B
overall ineqality within group inequality between group inequality
When inequality is additively decomposed, then one can say that the
basis on which the constituencies were subdivided (say, by state) contrib-
uted [(B/I) × 100] percent to overall inequality in a party’s vote shares,
the remaining inequality, [(A/I) × 100] percent, being due to inequality
within the states. If one subdivided the constituencies by income (say,
three groups) and by state (20 major states), so that one had 60 c ategories,
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
142 V.K. Borooah
M
I ( v;N ) = ∑I ( v m ;N m ) wm + B = A + B (7.9)
m =1
where: I(v; N) represents the overall level of inequality; I(vm; Nm) repre-
sents the level of inequality within state m; A—expressed as the weighted
sum of the inequality in each state, wm being the weights—and B repre-
sent, respectively, the within-group and the between-group contribution to
overall inequality.
If, indeed, inequality can be ‘additively decomposed’ along the lines of
Eq. 7.9 above, then, as Cowell and Jenkins (1995) have argued, the pro-
portionate contribution of the between-group component (B) to overall
inequality is the income inequality literature’s analogue of the R2 statistic
used in regression analysis: the size of this contribution is a measure of the
amount of inequality that can be ‘explained’ by the factor (or factors) used
to subdivide the sample.
Only inequality indices which belong to the family of Generalised
Entropy Indices are additively decomposable (Shorrocks, 1980). These
indices are defined by a parameter θ, and when θ = 0, the weights are the
constituency shares of the different states (i.e., wm = N m / N ); since the
weights sum to unity, the within-group contribution A of Eq. 7.9 is a
weighted average of the inequality levels within the groups. When θ = 0,
the inequality index is Theil’s MLD, defined in Eq. 7.8 of the previous
section, which, because of its attractive features in terms of the interpreta-
tion of the weights, is used in this chapter to decompose inequality in a
party’s vote shares.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Concentration and Distribution of Votes 143
We hypothesise that the number of seats won (S) by a party at a Lok Sabha
election, given the number of seats contested, depends upon its mean vote
(μ) and the degree of inequality (I) in the distribution of its vote both
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
144 V.K. Borooah
+ ?
S = f µ,I (7.10)
Table 7.4 BJP and INC seats for eight Lok Sabha elections, 1989–2014, under
an equally distributed scenario
BJP INC
Year Seats Seats under Votes per Seats Seats under Votes per seat
won equal seat won equal contested
distribution contested distribution
Elections were not held in Assam because electoral rolls were incomplete.
b
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Concentration and Distribution of Votes 145
of seats the party would have won or lost under this ‘equally distributed’
scenario.
In the six elections after (and including) the 1996 Lok Sabha elections,
Table 7.4 shows that both parties would have lost seats under an equal
distribution scenario. In the 2014 Lok Sabha elections, the BJP, with its
31.3 percent share of the vote (which translated to 401,075 votes per con-
stituency contested), won 282 seats. If it had received exactly 401,075 votes
in each of the 428 constituencies it contested in 2014, it would have won
278 seats, or in other words, the unequal distribution of its vote across the
428 seats it contested enabled it to win an additional four seats. Similarly,
in the 2014 Lok Sabha elections, the INC, with its 19.3 percent share of
the vote (which translated to 230,465 votes per constituency contested),
won 44 seats. If it had received exactly 230,465 votes in each of the 464
constituencies it contested in 2014, it would have won only 18 seats, or
in other words, the unequal distribution of its vote across the 464 seats it
contested enabled it to win an additional 26 seats.
The effect of distribution, on the number seats won, varied by elec-
tion. As Table 7.4 shows, the effect of inequality in the inter-constituency
distribution of the BJP vote, on the number of seats it won, was greatest
in 1989, 1991, 1996, and 2009. In these elections, the distribution of its
vote helped it win a large number of additional seats: 51 seats in 1984;
64 seats in 1991; 89 seats in 1996; and 76 seats in 2009. By contrast, the
effect of distribution on the number of seats won by the INC was more
muted. The most marked effect was in 1998 when its vote distribution
across the constituencies helped it win an additional 91 seats; apart from
this particular election, the INC vote distribution, compared to the BJP
vote distribution, added far fewer seats to what it would have won with an
equal distribution of votes across the constituencies.
7.5.2
Simulation B: Equal Number of Votes Received
In the second simulation (simulation B), it was assumed that the INC and
the BJP received the same number of votes nationally—which was the
average of their respective national vote—but that the distribution of the
vote across the constituencies remained unchanged for both parties. So,
for example, for the 2014 Lok Sabha election, it was assumed that both
the INC and the BJP received 139,297,888 votes—which was an aver-
age of the INC’s 106,938,240 and the BJP’s 171,657,552 votes—and
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
146 V.K. Borooah
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
Table 7.5 BJP and INC seats for eight Lok Sabha elections, 1989–2014, under an equal voters’ scenario
Actual votes Equal votes Equal INC BJP
seats
INC BJP INC & BJP INC & Seats Predicted Seats Predicted seats
BJP won seats won won won
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
2004 103,408,952 86,371,560 94,890,256 142 145 122 138 161
2009 119,110,824 78,435,352 98,773,088 161 206 100 116 184
2014 106,938,240 171,657,552 139,297,888 163 44 122 282 229
Fig. 7.4 INC and BJP under- and over-performance with respect to seats when
each received an equal number of votes* (*Negative and positive values represent,
respectively, under- and over-performance). Source: Own calculations from
Election Commission of India data
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
The Concentration and Distribution of Votes 149
is that even it received the same number of total votes as the BJP, it would
still, because of differences between them in their vote distributions, win
fewer seats. For the INC to nullify the effects of its distributional disad-
vantage, it must raise its electoral popularity substantially above that of
the BJP.
Or else, it must improve its vote distribution. As the previous chapters
have pointed out, the BJP enjoys a considerable advantage over the INC
in the 204 constituencies in the Hindi-speaking states while the INC does
not enjoy, to the same degree, advantage over the BJP in the non-Hindi-
speaking states. This is an area that the INC needs to redress, either on its
own or, more plausibly, with strategic alliances with like-minded parties.
Notes
1. See Hirschman (1964).
2. The Gini coefficient is defined in Chap. 2.
3. While the number of consistencies a party contests sets an upper limit to the
number of seats it can win, it does not follow that that the more seats it
contests, the larger will be the number of seats it wins: in the Lok Sabha elec-
tion of 1999, the INC contested 453 constituencies but won only 114 seats,
while the BJP contested 339 constituencies and won 182 seats.
4. 1.3 = 139, 297,888/106,938,240 and 0.81 = 139, 297,888/171,657,552.
5. The average of the 282 and 44 seats won, respectively, by the BJP and INC.
References
Cowell, F. A., & Jenkins, S. P. (1995). How much inequality can we explain? A
methodology and an application to the United States. Economic Journal, 105,
421–430.
Dunleavy, P., & Bouchek, F. (2003). Constructing the number of parties. Party
Politics, 9, 291–315.
Hirschman, A. O. (1964). The paternity of an index. The American Economic
Review, 54(5), 761.
Laakso, M., & Taagepera, R. (1979). Effective number of parties: A measure with
application to West Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 12, 3–27.
Renyi, A. (1965). On the foundations of information theory. Review of the
International Statistical Institute, 33, 1–14.
Shorrocks, A. F. (1980). A class of additively decomposable measures. Econometrica,
50, 613–625.
Theil, H. (1967). Economics and information theory. Amsterdam:
North-Holland.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
CHAPTER 8
Conclusions
The foundations of this book lay in a set of data which recorded the details
of the election result for each candidate, for all the constituencies, in every
Lok Sabha General Election from 1962 to 2014. The edifice built upon
this foundation, and discussed in the preceding chapters, was the result
of interrogating these data. The central purpose of this interrogation was
to give shape to the notion of ‘electoral efficiency’ by which is meant the
capacity of a party to convert votes into parliamentary seats. Parliamentary
elections in India—and also elections to its state Assemblies—are con-
ducted under the FPTP system: a single representative for each of 543
constituencies is elected—on the basis of obtaining the largest number of
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
152 V.K. BOROOAH
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
CONCLUSIONS 153
None of the analysis presented in this book is intended to imply that the
INC can never win more seats than the BJP. What the analysis does sug-
gest is that compared to the BJP, it will have to do much better at the polls
to obtain a comparable result in terms of seats. The key to this result lies
in the 204 constituencies in the seven Hindi speaking (HS) states of Bihar,
Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan, Uttarakhand, and
Uttar Pradesh. The advantage that the BJP has over the INC in these
states is not nullified by the advantage that the INC has over the BJP in
constituencies in the non-HS states. To put it in perspective, two-thirds of
the nearly 107 million votes obtained by the INC in 2014 were from the
306 constituencies it contested in the non-HS states and one-third came
from the 158 constituencies it contested in the HS states; for the BJP,
on the other hand, 48 percent of its total vote in 2014 was from the 236
constituencies it contested in the non-HS states and 52 percent came from
the 192 constituencies it contested in the HS states.
And yet, on this book’s analysis, single-party majority governments are
unlikely to be seen frequently. The height of the ‘Modi wave’ in 2014
was considerably lower than that of the ‘Indira wave’ in 1971 or the
‘Rajiv wave’ of 1984. The strength of regional parties—in Tamil Nadu,
Andhra Pradesh, West Bengal, and Uttar Pradesh—ensures that elections
are no longer a zero-sum game between two parties. So, notwithstanding
the current BJP majority government, it is difficult not to concur with
Rudolph and Rudolph (2002) when they suggest that coalition govern-
ment has come to stay in India.
It is unlikely that single-party government will be provided by any party
other than the INC or the BJP. For either to win a majority in the Lok
Sabha, they would need to win at least 30 percent of the national vote,
probably more for the INC. Since, between them, they received, on aver-
age, 50–55 percent of the post-1984 national vote, this would require the
vote of the losing party to collapse to about 20 percent (which is close to
the INC’s vote share of 19.5 percent in the 2014 Lok Sabha elections).
This, in turn, implies a large dose of disillusionment with the losing party
which, given that the INC vote share of 19.5 percent, alluded to above,
followed on the heels of its shambolic United Progressive Alliance (UPA)
government of 2009-14, is unlikely to be repeated.
An anxiety to which this prognostication gives rise is that India’s expe-
rience of coalition governments, or minority governments with outside
support, has been largely unfavourable. In terms of stability, only three
governments—The National Democratic Alliance (NDA) government
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
154 V.K. BOROOAH
formed after the Lok Sabha elections of 1999, and the UPA-I and UPA-II
formed after the Lok Sabha elections of, respectively, 2004 and 2009—
completed their five-year parliamentary terms. The others have been
short-lived, either because of rivalries for the job of prime minister (the
1977 Janata Party government) or through constituent parties withdraw-
ing support over ‘issues’ (the BJP withdrawing its support to the 1989
‘National Front’ government and AIADMK withdrawing its support to
the 1998 [BJP-led] NDA government). At the same time, stability per se
has not been a guarantor of good government: the UPA-II government
(2009–2014) was, in its later stages, mired in scandal as coalition ministers
exploited their ministerial positions to make money.
The worrying feature of coalition government in India is that it is pro-
vided in the context of the FPTP system allied to strong regional parties. A
combination of the electoral system and the strength of the regional par-
ties means that such parties can exercise inordinate influence on national
politics, through the strength of their presence in the Lok Sabha even if
this strength is based on a localised vote which, furthermore, is but a
sliver of the national vote. After the 2014 Lok Sabha elections, six regional
parties—the All India Anna Dravida Munnetra Kazhagam, the All India
Trinamool Congress, the Biju Janata Dal, the Shiv Sena, the Telugu Desam
Party, and the Telangana Rashtra Samithi—between them held 136 of the
543 (25 percent) seats in the 16th Lok Sabha on the strength of just 14
percent of the national vote. Under plausible scenarios, any one of these
parties, with such parliamentary strength, would be in a position to topple
a government. So, while one might be sanguine about the prospects for
democracy in India, the prospect of effective government following on the
heels of Lok Sabha elections is less certain.
REFERENCE
Rudolph, S. H., & Rudolph, L. I. (2002). New dimensions in Indian democracy.
Journal of Democracy, 13, 52–66.
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INDEX
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
156 INDEX
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INDEX 157
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
158 INDEX
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
INDEX 159
R
Rao, Narasimha, 6 T
Rashtriya Janata Dal, 10–11 Taagepera, R., 136
Recognised national parties, 22 Terrorism and Disruptive Activities
Representation of the People Acts of (Prevention) Act, 14n18
1950 and 1951, 18 Theil, H., 139
reservation, 7 Turnout, Indian states in 2014 Lok
reserved category, 7 Sabha elections, 26
Rudolph, L. I., 11, 153
Rudolph, S. H., 11, 153
Rushdie, Salman, 9 U
UK General election, 2015, 22, 24,
116
S United Progressive Alliance (UPA), 7
Sachar Committee, 10 UPA-I, 7
The Sachar Committee, 10 UPA-II, 7
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk
160 INDEX
vk.borooah@ulster.ac.uk