3 Sustaining Economic Growth in Asia
3 Sustaining Economic Growth in Asia
ECONOMIC
GROWTH
IN ASIA
JÉRÉMIE COHEN-SETTON
THOMAS HELBLING
ADAM S. POSEN
CHANGYONG RHEE
editors
Washington, DC
December 2018
SUSTAINING
ECONOMIC
GROWTH
IN ASIA
JÉRÉMIE COHEN-SETTON
THOMAS HELBLING
ADAM S. POSEN
CHANGYONG RHEE
editors
Washington, DC
December 2018
Jérémie Cohen-Setton is research fellow at the Printed in the United States of America
Peterson Institute for International Economics. 20 19 18 5 4 3 2 1
This publication has been subjected to a prepublication peer review intended to ensure analytical quality.
The views expressed are those of the authors. This publication is part of the overall program of the Peterson Institute for
International Economics, as endorsed by its Board of Directors, but it does not necessarily reflect the
views of individual members of the Board or of the Institute’s staff or management.
The Peterson Institute for International Economics is a private nonpartisan, nonprofit institution for rigorous, intellectually open,
and indepth study and discussion of international economic policy. Its purpose is to identify and analyze important issues to make
globalization beneficial and sustainable for the people of the United States and the world, and then to develop and communicate
practical new approaches for dealing with them. Its work is funded by a highly diverse group of philanthropic foundations, private
corporations, and interested individuals, as well as income on its capital fund. About 35 percent of the Institute’s
resources were provided by contributors from outside the United States. A list of all financial supporters is
posted at https://piie.com/sites/default/files/supporters.pdf.
Contents
Preface vii
1 Introduction: Toward a New Long-Term Growth Model 1
for Asia
Jérémie Cohen-Setton, Thomas Helbling, Adam S. Posen, and
Changyong Rhee
2 Secular Stagnation: History and Reality 9
Joel Mokyr
3 Is Asia at Risk of Growing Old before Becoming Rich? 33
Serkan Arslanalp, Jaewoo Lee, Minsuk Kim, Umang Rawat,
Jacqueline Pia Rothfels, Jochen Markus Schmittmann, and
Qianqian Zhang
4 Invention, Productivity, and the Evolution of East Asia’s 73
Innovation Systems
Lee Branstetter and Namho Kwon
Comment: Jong-Wha Lee
5 Secular Stagnation and Asia: International Transmission 103
and Policy Spillovers
Olivier Jeanne
6 Getting Out of Secular Stagnation: Turning Japanese May 129
Be a Good Thing Now
Adam S. Posen
7 Secular Stagnation and the Labor Market in Japan 139
Kyoji Fukao
Comment: Jonathan Woetzel
8 Declining Potential Growth in Korea 165
Dongchul Cho and Kyooho Kwon
9 A New Macroeconomic Policy Framework for Prudence 181
and Higher-Quality Growth in China
Ma Jun
10 Do India’s Exports Reflect the New Normal? 193
Prachi Mishra and Siddhartha Nath
Comment: Kenneth Kang
11 How Has Indonesia Fared in the Age of Secular Stagnation? 235
Mitali Das
Comment: Muhamad Chatib Basri
12 Twenty-Five Years of Global Imbalances 269
Maurice Obstfeld
13 Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies for Sustained 285
Growth in Asia
Joseph E. Gagnon and Philip Turner
14 Monetary Policy in the New Mediocre 315
Rania Al-Mashat, Kevin Clinton, Benjamin Hunt,
Zoltan Jakab, Douglas Laxton, Hou Wang, and
Jiaxiong Yao
15 Avoiding a New Mediocre in Asia: What Can Fiscal 343
Policy Do?
Ana Corbacho, Dirk Muir, Masahiro Nozaki, and Edda Zoli
16 Global Imbalances and the Trade Slowdown: Implications 387
for Asia
Caroline Freund
Comment: Davin Chor
17 Toward a “New” Asian Model 407
Subir Gokarn
Index 413
Preface
Asia largely avoided the worst of the global financial crisis of 2008–10 and
remains one of the most dynamic regions of the world economy. Yet, signs
of secular stagnation in the form of depressed levels of economic growth
and low interest rates are now appearing in emerging Asia, not just Japan.
Demographic trends and declining openness to trade in the advanced econ-
omies mean that Asian policymakers must prepare now to prevent such
stagnation taking hold.
In this volume, scholars affiliated with the International Monetary
Fund (IMF), the Peterson Institute for International Economics (PIIE), and
other institutions around the world explore the relevance and implications
of the secular stagnation hypothesis in Asia. The volume contains research
focused by subject area (demographics, innovation, imbalances, spillovers,
trade, and fiscal and monetary policies) and by country (China, South Korea,
India, Indonesia, and Japan). This two-pronged comparative approach yields
a compelling and multifaceted case for getting ahead of developments.
A major finding of this book is that in a secular stagnation environment,
the highly successful Asian growth model of the past few decades is unlikely
to remain the blueprint for future growth or for further convergence among
emerging and developing economies in the region. Instead, economic inte-
gration within the region is likely to become the critical source for steady
demand and productivity improvements. This regional opening should be
accompanied by structural reforms aimed at offsetting some of the predict-
able forces of demographic change to keep the growth engine powerful. Ad-
vii
aptation of macroeconomic frameworks to be ready to undertake aggressive
stimulus when necessary will be needed in Asia as well.
The Bank of Korea and the Korean Ministry of Strategy and Finance
sponsored and hosted a conference in Seoul in September 2017, where the
earlier versions of the research included in this volume were initially present-
ed. We would like to express our sincere gratitude to economists from the
Bank of Korea, IMF, PIIE, and the other organizations who have contribut-
ed their research to this ambitious project. We would also like to especially
thank the IMF Asia and Pacific Department’s Thomas Helbling and PIIE’s
Jérémie Cohen-Setton, who jointly managed and coordinated the project.
The IMF’s Nadine Dubost and Medha Madhu Nair and PIIE’s Madona
Devasahayam, Egor Gornostay, Susann Luetjen, and Steven R. Weisman
together made possible the publication of this volume, with full documen-
tation disclosure. Finally, we would like to acknowledge the generous finan-
cial support for the whole project by the Korean Ministry of Strategy and
Finance. We believe that this highly forward-looking book will be a valuable
resource for analysts, investors, and policymakers in Asia and beyond.
***
The Peterson Institute for International Economics is a private nonpartisan,
nonprofit institution for rigorous, intellectually open, and indepth study
and discussion of international economic policy. Its purpose is to iden-
tify and analyze important issues to making globalization beneficial and
sustainable for the people of the United States and the world and then to
develop and communicate practical new approaches for dealing with them.
The Institute’s work is funded by a highly diverse group of philanthropic
foundations, private corporations, and interested individuals, as well as
income on its capital fund. About 35 percent of the Institute resources in
our latest fiscal year were provided by contributors from outside the United
States. A list of all our financial supporters for the preceding year is posted
at www.piie.com/supporters.cfm.
The Executive Committee of the Institute’s Board of Directors bears
overall responsibility for the Institute’s direction, gives general guidance and
approval to its research program, and evaluates its performance in pursuit
of its mission. The Institute’s President is responsible for the identification
of topics that are likely to become important over the medium term (one
to three years) that should be addressed by Institute scholars. This rolling
agenda is set in close consultation with the Institute’s research staff, Board
of Directors, and other stakeholders.
The President makes the final decision to publish any individual In-
stitute study, following independent internal and external review of the
viii
work. Interested readers may access the data and computations underly-
ing Institute publications for research and replication by searching titles at
www.piie.com. The Institute hopes that its research and other activities will
contribute to building a stronger foundation for international economic
policy around the world. We invite readers of these publications to let us
know how they think we can best accomplish this objective.
***
The International Monetary Fund’s Asia and Pacific Department is one of
the IMF’s five area, or regional, departments. It is responsible for advising
member countries in the Asia Pacific Region on macroeconomic policies
and the financial sector, putting together, when needed, financial arrange-
ments to support economic reform programs, and capacity building, mainly
through its regional technical assistance centers. To accomplish its mission,
the Department seeks to engage in policy debates in the Asia-Pacific and to
distill lessons from the experience in the region. In this mission, it collabo-
rates with experts from and outside region.
ix
PETERSON INSTITUTE FOR INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS
1750 Massachusetts Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 20036-1903 USA
+1.202.328.9000 www.piie.com
Jérémie Cohen-Setton is research fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics. Thomas Helbling
is a division chief in the International Monetary Fund’s Asia and Pacific Department, covering Australia and
New Zealand. Adam S. Posen is the president of the Peterson Institute for International Economics. Changyong
Rhee is the director of the Asia and Pacific Department at the International Monetary Fund. The views ex-
pressed in this chapter are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive
Board, or its management.
1
the G-7 economies, is real and approaching. This threat is not just the result
of the difficulties experienced through trade and financial linkages with the
advanced economies, their low growth and inflation, and the resultant very
low interest rates. When considering the broader macroeconomic picture,
several of the symptoms associated with secular stagnation are already
prominent in several Asian economies. Growth, for example, while strong in
cross-national comparison, has remained below the rates recorded before the
global financial crisis in Asia as well as the West. More troublingly, average
productivity growth has declined relative to precrisis rates in many countries
in the region, as it has elsewhere. Rapid population aging and lower popu-
lation growth are already shaping the demographics in many countries of
the region; turning points toward rising dependency ratios and shrinking
workforces will soon be a reality well beyond Japan. Inflation has been below
target for an unusually long period in several countries in the region, while
interest rates, nominal and real, have declined to very low levels in many
economies, even in countries with still high real growth. Therefore, risks of
nominal policy interest rates reaching the effective lower bound after a large
shock and related problems of macroeconomic adjustment might be likely
rather than tail risks.
For this reason, the Asia and Pacific Department of the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) and the Peterson Institute for International Econom-
ics launched a joint research project to explore the relevance of the secular
stagnation hypothesis for Asia and the policy implications. The papers
published in this volume were presented at a conference organized jointly
with the Korean Ministry of Strategy and Finance and the Bank of Korea
in September 2017. The project combined research organized by econom-
ic themes and by countries. For the country case studies, the project dis-
tinguishes three groups of countries in Asia. The first category consists of
Japan, a country in which symptoms of secular stagnation have already been
present for some years. The second group includes Korea and other mid-
dle-income economies in which the reversal of the demographic dividend is
imminent and which are already exhibiting some of the features of secular
stagnation but not yet to an extent that would support wide recognition
of the problem. In these transitionally threatened economies, fundamentals
point to increasing risks of stagnation over the next few years but also some
advance warning, meaning time to prepare and change policy. Finally, in
many of the emerging and lower-income economies in Asia, the exposure
to secular stagnation is primarily through international spillovers to date,
but these spillovers are likely to last and to constrain growth and policy in
an ongoing way.
INTRODUCTION 3
growth will be driven by demographics, environmental costs, and changing
consumer preferences. Altogether, these factors are expected to slow annual
growth by 2 percentage points in the coming decade. While ongoing tech-
nological innovations and reforms can partially cushion this deceleration, a
further slowdown in growth appears inevitable over the medium term. This
trend, together with the growing financial risks due to a high macro leverage
ratio, calls urgently for a new macroeconomic management framework that
is less growth-centric but focuses more on macro and financial stability.
In chapter 10 Prachi Mishra and Siddhartha Nath write that India’s
merchandise exports have undergone a quiet revolution with new-age engi-
neering, electronic, and pharmaceutical exports gradually replacing India’s
traditional exports of leather, textiles, gems, and jewelry. But structural ri-
gidities are still holding back diversification and thus make India vulnerable
to global risks. The contrast with Indonesia is striking as it has progressively
turned inward. This retrenchment, writes Mitali Das in chapter 11, has in-
sulated Indonesia against the vicissitudes of global developments but at the
price of a reduction in productivity-enhancing spillovers. In fact, potential
output growth has declined in recent years despite strong demographic tail-
winds and steady capital accumulation.
In reviewing the past 25 years of global imbalances, Maurice Obstfeld
emphasizes in chapter 12 that excessive imbalances declined after the global
financial crisis but are still present. Monocausal explanations for excessive
global imbalances rarely apply. Instead, such imbalances usually reflect
global forces and multiple distortions in many countries, notably diverse
financial sector distortions. Notwithstanding the need for collective action,
excess surplus countries still face little that would force them to adjust—
outside of the threat of protectionist responses—whereas most deficit coun-
tries face the risk that lenders will withdraw. Reducing global imbalances
should be a collective effort based on a shared appreciation of the roles indi-
vidual countries need to play.
In chapter 13 Joseph Gagnon and Philip Turner study the implications
of a slowdown in growth for monetary policy. A first implication is the
importance of keeping core inflation at or above 2 percent. A second impli-
cation is that central banks should not shy away from using balance sheet
policies. The view that central banks should stick to setting the overnight
rate is unhistorical. If anything, balance sheet policies have more poten-
tial today than before given the increased size and importance of domestic
Asian bond markets in influencing financial conditions. Rania Al-Mashat
et al. make the case in chapter 14 for a risk avoidance approach to monetary
policy that heavily penalizes large deviations of the target variables (output
and inflation) from their preferred values. In a world of secular stagnation
where the probability of entering low-inflation traps is higher, a prudent
INTRODUCTION 5
research program was conceived, and the global expansion has continued
in the months since, the best tradition of Asian economic policymaking to
plan with a long time horizon was affirmed. In particular, the profound chal-
lenges from the impending demographic transitions in many Asian econo-
mies to rapidly aging populations and lower population growth resonated
with participants. The demographic dividend has already started to reverse
in many countries in the region, including in China, the engine of growth
for the region and the world in the past two decades.
Recent experience in Japan and in Western Europe suggests that aging
and lower population growth could reduce growth in per capita incomes
and productivity, not just aggregate growth in output and investment.
There are strong hypotheses suggested by Japan and Western Europe as
well that there might even be negative feedback loops from demographics
to technical progress: Lower rates of innovation in the frontier economies
and eroding intellectual property rights could interact with aging to slow
diffusion of progress within and across countries (Posen 2012); aging could
change the structure of household demand toward less capital-intensive
services, providing yet another reason for lower investment, thus limiting
positive productivity spillovers; structural reforms are needed to strengthen
domestic innovation capacity and productivity in service sectors.
The reversal of the demographic dividend would therefore likely result
in more than just persistent even if small declines in aggregate demand.
So, even absent macroeconomic imbalances, which arguably made the
problems more acute in the G-7 economies, Asian policymakers are right
to be concerned about the negative impact of the demographic transition
on productivity and medium-term growth. The conference participants
emphasized that the transition reinforced the need to change the Asian
growth paradigm.
Similarly, the international dimension of the challenges facing Asia for
sustaining growth go well beyond the cyclical and direct immediate spill-
overs from insufficient demand and low growth in advanced economies
since the global financial crisis. After a decade of very low growth since the
global financial crisis, external demand growth from advanced economies
outside Asia is unlikely to return to providing the momentum it had before
the global financial crisis. An implication is that manufacturing exports are
unlikely to be the motor for growth and development that they were over
the past few decades. This development intensifies the phenomenon of “pre-
mature deindustrialization” identified by Dani Rodrik (2016). Moreover,
the trade tensions taking shape between the United States and many of its
largest trading partners in Asia and elsewhere are further eroding the room
for export-led growth. Even if these conflicts are resolved or at least stepped
down, legitimate doubts about the wisdom of relying on access to advanced
INTRODUCTION 7
The broad outlines of such a model for sustaining growth are applicable
for all Asian economies and should be put in place without undue delay.
n Undertake a structural reform agenda—including making better use of
the female labor force, promoting innovation and technological diffu-
sion internally, and encouraging productivity gains in service sectors—
that can robustly offset some of the predictable forces of demographic
change.
n Pursue international economic integration within the Asian region,
and openness to South-South trade and investment more broadly, to
maintain the benefits for productivity and steady demand that go with
export competition.
n Prepare macroeconomic frameworks to be ready to undertake aggres-
sive stabilizing stimulus when needed in the likely-to-persist global
low interest rate environment. This preparation requires a recognition
both of the risks of excessively anti-inflationary monetary policy and
of the need to build up fiscal space in advance of problems.
References
Gordon, Robert J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the
Civil War. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Posen, Adam S. 2012. What the Return of 19th Century Economics Means for 21st Century
Geopolitics. Lecture, Chatham House, London, January 17. Available at www.chatham-
house.org/sites/default/files/public/Meetings/Meeting%20Transcripts/170112aposen.
pdf (accessed on September 7, 2018).
Rodrik, Dani. 2016. Premature Deindustrialization. Journal of Economic Growth 21, no. 1: 1–33.
Summers, Lawrence H. 2013. Remarks at the IMF Fourteenth Annual Research Conference
in Honor of Stanley Fischer, Washington, DC, November 8. Available at http://larry-
summers.com/imf-fourteenth-annual-research-conference-in-honor-of-stanley-fischer/
(accessed on September 7, 2018).
Joel Mokyr is Robert H. Strotz Professor of Arts and Sciences and Professor of Economics and History at North-
western University and Sackler Professor (by special appointment) at the Eitan Berglas School of Economics,
Tel Aviv University. He is indebted to Ashish Aggarwal for research assistance, Jérémie Cohen-Setton and Deir-
dre McCloskey for helpful comments, and Madona Devasahayam for outstanding editing. The Balzan Founda-
tion and Northwestern’s Center for Economic History provided financial support.
1. For powerful, if somewhat overstated, descriptions of this absence of growth, see Clark
(2007) and Galor (2011). There were some exceptions to the rule of stagnation in northwest
Europe and Italy, where growth had already raised living standards significantly by 1800, but
even that growth had been slow and uneven, and it affected a tiny part of humanity.
9
But what was normal for most of human history is not normal in the
20th and 21st centuries. Growth has been the norm in the more recent past,
despite two world wars, a wave of totalitarian regimes, repeated genocide,
a nuclear arms race, and other assorted disasters. In what follows, I explain
how the modern era was different from everything that came before, which
will give us a unique perspective to assess the chances of past conditions
returning. Needless to say, all such assessments need to be phrased in the
conditional and subjunctive modes, since the entire point of this chapter
is to argue that we are still in the midst of a phase transition in economic
history, and hence all bets are off. But some scenarios can still be assigned
a low probability.
2. Simple regressions of mortality rates on log GDP per capita for 168 nations still show a
significant negative coefficient. However, once we limit the sample to the top 60 countries,
the significance vanishes and the adjusted R-square is essentially zero (author’s calculations;
all data from CIA World Factbook, www.cia.gov/library/publications/resources/the-world-
factbook/index.html).
3. The evidence for the existence of Malthusian checks in which disasters occur as a result
of overpopulation is scant. Nineteenth century writers believed that the Irish Famine was a
clear-cut example, but the evidence for overpopulation as a clear cause of the famine is far
from persuasive (Mokyr 1985).
4. The most striking land-augmenting inventions were fertilizers and pesticides, the most
dramatic of which by all accounts was the Haber-Bosch nitrogen-fixing process. According
to Vaclav Smil (2001, 204), by the end of the 20th century at least 2.4 billion people were alive
because the proteins in their bodies could be synthesized from amino acids whose nitrogen
originated in this invention.
5. A notorious example was the French merchant and entrepreneur Jacques Cœur (1395–
1456), an immensely rich and powerful merchant who basically monopolized France’s
Mediterranean trade and was wealthy enough to bankroll many of Charles VII’s triumphs in
the final stages of the Hundred Years’ War against England. His wealth and power attracted
the greed and envy of many, including eventually the king. Cœur was arrested and tried on
what historians have deemed were trumped-up charges; his possessions were confiscated and
distributed among the king and his cronies. Two centuries later, a similar fate befell Nicolas
Fouquet (1615–1680), the fabulously wealthy tax collector who had enriched himself during
the ministry of Mazarin during Louis XIV’s minority. He was arrested in 1661 by Louis XIV
and imprisoned for life, and the king’s servants stripped his sumptuous chateau.
7. The World Bank indices are Voice and Accountability, Political Stability and Absence
of Violence, Government Effectiveness, Regulatory Quality, Rule of Law, and Control of
Corruption. See http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home.
8. The pairwise correlation coefficients of three of the measures that are closest to rent-
seeking are especially high: between “control of corruption” and “government effectiveness”:
R = .909; between “control of corruption” and “rule of law”: R = .962; and between “govern-
ment effectiveness” and “rule of law”: R = .940 (author’s calculations).
9. Lin (1995) points out that the difference between Chinese and modern Western technology
was that both Chinese and pre-1700 Western technological progress were experience-based
and advanced through learning by doing and trial and error. The growth of what he calls
knowledge-based technological change changed the historical balance in favor of the West.
This was already realized in the 18th century. Condorcet, in his famous 1795 essay on human
progress, argued that although “isolated nations long influenced by despotism and supersti-
tion” (he means in all likelihood Asia) had been the origin of many important new technolo-
gies in textiles, ceramics, and metal, they were being surpassed by Europe in his age because
there is nothing these countries did that “announces the presence of genius—all improve-
ments there appear as the slow and painstaking work of a long routine” (Condorcet 1796, 51).
10. The famous paper was by Vandermonde, Berthollet, and Monge (1786).
11. Another example is hydrostatics needed for ship design, with which 18th century scien-
tists struggled mightily. Isaac Newton’s theory on hydrostatics, known later as impact
theory, was embraced by many contemporaries, but it turned out to be unsatisfactory and
was corrected by Leonhard Euler and the Bernoullis, who designed a theory that could deal
with the physical state variables in the whole domain of fluid. See Nowacki (2008).
12. Another paradigmatic example of how practical invention stimulated the underlying
science rather than the reverse can be found in the evolution of aerodynamics. The formal
theory of aerodynamics was laid out in 1918 by Ludwig Prandtl, 15 years after Kitty Hawk
(Constant 1980, 105; Vincenti 1990, 120–25). Even then, the ancient method of trial and
error was still widely used in airplane design. The search for the best use of flush riveting
in holding together the body of the plane or the best way to design landing gear remained
highly experimental (Vincenti 1990, 170–99; Vincenti 2000).
Secular Stagnation?
If the three factors described above accounted for a substantial part of
secular stagnation in the past, they provide us with a way to reassess the
likelihood of secular stagnation as a normal condition in the foreseeable
future. As far as the specter of a Malthusian curse is concerned, the notion
that the human race is facing some risk of overpopulation (still popular-
ized by Paul Ehrlich’s Population Bomb, first published in 1968, followed
unrepentantly in 1990 by his Population Explosion) has been thoroughly
discredited. Even without the huge increase in effective and available
natural resources due to technological progress, this doomster prediction
is doomed itself by the astonishing slowdown in fertility rates worldwide.
Fertility rates in developing economies in Asia and Latin America are mostly
hovering around replacement. Fertility is declining in the most popu-
lated economies in Asia and is approaching or has fallen below replace-
ment levels. In Indonesia and Bangladesh, for instance, fertility rates today
are down to 2.11 and 2.17 births per woman, from 5.7 and 6.7 in 1960,
respectively (CIA 2017, World Bank 2017), while fertility in both China
and Iran is now significantly below replacement levels. The region where
Malthusian pressures may remain a serious limitation to growth is Africa.
African fertility rates have remained stubbornly high, and the resource base
in most of the continent is being eroded by overuse and mismanagement.
For the rest of the world, the demographic transition, whatever its exact
microeconomic foundations, is steering toward zero population growth
now predicted for some point in the 21st century.
Indeed, it is no small irony that if demography is any concern today,
it is that zero or negative population growth, coupled with the continuing
rise in the average age in most economies, is seen as a source of secular stag-
nation (Hansen 1939). Globally, the old-age dependency ratio is expected to
rise from 13 percent in 2015 to 38 percent by the end of the 21st century.14
13. For a more recent restatement of Zilsel’s ideas, see, for instance, Roberts and Schaffer
(2007).
14. “The New Old,” Economist, July 8, 2017, 3. The median age in the United States has
increased from 28.1 in 1970 to 37.6 in 2015 (Statista 2017) and is projected to rise to 41 by
2050. This is relatively moderate compared with projected rises in median age in other indus-
trialized countries: In Germany it will rise from 38 in 2010 to 51 in 2050, in China from 35 to
46, and in South Korea from 38 to 53 (Pew Research Center 2014, chapter 2).
15. Research suggests that in repetitive work, productivity declines with age, but in knowl-
edge-based jobs age makes no difference in performance and in jobs that require “social
skills” productivity rises with age (“The New Old,” Economist, July 8, 2017, 6). As automa-
tion and the increased use of artificial intelligence replace repetitive work but not the kind
of work that requires knowledge or social skills, labor market bias against workers over 50
may be doomed. Elderly workers will be increasingly able to participate in the “gig economy”
by, for instance, driving Uber cars, letting rooms through Airbnb, or providing babysitting
services through such sites as sitters.com. Technology also allows the elderly to cope with
many of the handicaps of old age, including on-demand services and smart appliances. As
the generation that is comfortable with smart phones and computers enters their 60s and
70s, such technologies will become easier to implement.
18. Indeed, there are two separate books entitled The Last Man Who Knew Everything. One of
them (Findlen 2004) places the title on the Jesuit scholar Athanasius Kircher (1601–80), a
German-born polymath of prodigious scholarly productivity who wrote important books
on topics as different as natural history, mathematics, geology, and the history of ancient
Egypt. The other book (Robinson 2007) is about Thomas Young (1773–1829), a physician
who established the wave theory of light, discovered a formula for the elasticity of materials,
and helped decipher the Rosetta Stone.
19. A good example is Temple Croker’s three-volume Complete Dictionary of Arts and Sciences
(1764–66), which explicitly promised its readers that in it “the whole circle of human learning
is explained and the difficulties in the acquisition of every Art, whether liberal or mechanical,
are removed in the most easy and familiar manner.” In close to 2,000 pages, the collection
contained detailed essays on diverse topics such as architecture, botany, and hydrostatics.
20. According to one estimate (Goldman 2013), in 1981 a Macintosh storage drive cost
approximately $700,000 per gigabyte. In July 2013, a Western Digital My Book external hard
drive cost $0.06 per gigabyte. The cost of flash memory, introduced in 2003, was $8,000 per
gigabyte, which fell to $0.94 in 2013 and about $0.40 in 2016.
Conclusion
Secular stagnation was a defining feature of most of recorded history and
has turned into sustained growth only in recent centuries. However, if the
technological frontier does not keep moving ahead, modern economies
will indeed not be able to avoid the secular stagnation that Alvin Hansen
feared. An examination of what drove the technological frontier in the past
References
Acemoglu, Daron, and James Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity,
and Poverty. New York: Crown.
Alfani, Guido, and Cormac Ó Gráda. 2017. Famines in Europe: An Overview. In Famine in Eu-
ropean History, ed. Guido Alfani and Cormac Ó Gráda. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Ashraf, Quamrul, and Oded Galor. 2011. Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch.
American Economic Review 101 (August): 2003–41.
Béaur, Gérard, and Jean-Michel Chevet. 2017. France. In Famine in European History, ed. Guido
Alfani and Cormac Ó Gráda. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Black, Dan A., Natalia Kolesnikova, Seth G. Sanders, and Lowell J. Taylor. 2013. Are Children
‘Normal’? Review of Economics and Statistics 95, no. 1: 21–33.
Bloom, Nicholas, Charles I. Jones, John Van Reenen, and Michael Webb. 2017. Are Ideas
Harder to Find? Unpublished working paper. Stanford University.
Boserup, Ester. 1965. The Conditions of Agricultural Growth. Chicago: Aldine.
Boserup, Ester. 1981. Population and Technological Change. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Boussingault, J. B. 1821. On the Presence of Silicia Platina and Its Presence in Steel. Repertory
of Arts, Manufactures and Agriculture, 2nd series, volume 39: 366–73.
CIA (Central Intelligence Agency). 2017. Country Comparison: Total Fertility Rate. The
World Factbook. Available at www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/
rankorder/2127rank.html.
Clark, Gregory. 2007. A Farewell to Alms. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Condorcet, Marie J. A. N. C. 1796. Outlines of an Historical View on the Progress of Human Mind.
Philadelphia: Lang and Ustick.
Constant, Edward W. 1980. The Origins of the Turbojet Revolution. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
Press.
Croker, Temple Henry. 1764–66. The Complete Dictionary of Arts and Sciences. London: Printed
for the authors.
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Robert D. Tollison. 1981. Mercantilism as a Rent-Seeking Society. Col-
lege Station: Texas A&M University Press.
Findlen, Paula, ed. 2004. Athanasius Kircher: The Last Man Who Knew Everything. New York: Rout-
ledge.
Galor, Oded. 2011. Unified Growth Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Gelderblom, Oscar. 2013. Cities of Commerce: The Institutional Foundations of International Trade in
the Low Countries, 1250–1650. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Goldman, Cooper. 2013. What’s the True Cost of Big Data? Available at www.gooddata.com/
blog/whats-true-cost-big-data.
Guthrie William P. 2003. The Later Thirty Years War: From the Battle of Wittstock to the Treaty of
Westphalia. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.
Serkan Arslanalp is deputy division chief, Jaewoo Lee is an advisor, Minsuk Kim, Umang Rawat, and Jochen
Markus Schmittmann are economists, and Qianqian Zhang is a research assistant at the International Mon-
etary Fund (IMF). Jacqueline Pia Rothfels is an economist at the German Ministry of Finance. All authors were
in the IMF’s Asia and Pacific Department when the chapter was written. The chapter draws on chapter 2 of the
2017 IMF Asia and Pacific Regional Economic Outlook (IMF 2017), which includes additional analysis
on Japan’s experience with adverse demographic trends in recent decades and fiscal implications of aging for
Asia, along with details on the data, methodology, and results. The views expressed in this chapter are those of the
authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management.
1. The chapter analyzes developments in the 13 largest Asian economies: Australia, China,
Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, New Zealand, the Philippines, Singa-
pore, Thailand, and Vietnam.
33
Figure 3.1 Fertility, life expectancy, and population growth in
Asia, 1950–2050
percent years
7 90
80
6
70
5
60
4 50
3 40
30
2
20
1
10
0 0
1950 1958 1966 1974 1982 1990 1998 2006 2014 2022 2030 2038 2046
Fertility
Population growth rate
Life expectancy (right axis)
2. Population projections in this chapter are based on the United Nations’ World Population
Prospects: 2015 Revision (medium-fertility scenario with unchanged net migration flows).
Projections of the various fertility scenarios do not differ much until 2030, but uncertainty
increases with the projection horizon, primarily because of different assumptions about
future fertility rates (World Bank 2015).
3. China began relaxing its one-child policy in 2013; since 2016 it has allowed all couples to
have two children. Demographers expect a positive but limited impact of the policy change
on fertility (Basten and Jiang 2015). The 2015 UN population projections see the fertility
rate gradually rising from 1.5 children per woman in 2010 to 1.7 by 2030 (UN 2015).
IS ASIA- CHAPTER
GRAPHICS AT RISK OF GROWING OLD
3—SUSTAINING BEFORE BECOMING
ECONOMIC ASIA 351
RICH?
GROWTH IN
2
Table 3.2 Old-age dependency ratios in Asia, 2000–50 (percent)
Country 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
36 GRAPHICS
Japan 25.2 29.9 36.0 43.3 48.3 50.6 53.1 57.0 63.8 68.1 70.9
Hong Kong 15.3 16.5 17.2 20.6 26.5 35.1 43.7 50.1 55.6 60.4 64.6
Korea 10.2 12.7 15.0 18.0 22.2 29.4 37.6 46.1 54.4 60.7 65.8
SUSTAINING- ECONOMIC
Singapore 10.3 11.3 12.2 16.1 21.4 28.6 36.5 43.7 51.1 57.2 61.6
Thailand 9.5 11.0 12.4 14.6 18.4 23.4 29.2 35.8 42.3 48.2 52.5
New Zealand 18.0 18.1 19.6 22.9 26.3 30.2 34.9 38.0 40.6 40.5 40.7
China 9.7 10.4 11.1 13.1 17.1 20.4 25.3 32.7 39.6 43.0 46.7
Australia 18.5 19.2 20.0 22.7 25.3 28.3 31.3 32.8 34.8 35.3 37.3
CHAPTER 3—SUSTAINING
Vietnam 10.4 9.9 9.4 9.6 11.7 14.8 18.3 21.8 25.6 29.5 34.1
GROWTH IN ASIA
Malaysia 6.1 6.7 7.2 8.4 10.0 12.2 14.5 16.7 18.7 21.0 25.3
Indonesia 7.3 7.4 7.5 7.7 8.6 10.4 12.4 14.7 17.0 19.2 21.3
India 7.2 7.7 8.0 8.6 9.8 11.1 12.5 14.0 15.8 17.8 20.5
Philippines 5.5 5.8 6.7 7.2 8.0 9.1 10.3 11.5 12.5 13.5 14.5
Note: The old-age dependency ratio indicates the size of the population 65 years of age and older as a share of
the working-age population (15–64 years old).
Source: IMF Staff calculations and projections based on United Nations, World Population Prospects: 2015 Revision
(medium-fertility scenario).
Europe
United States
New Zealand
Australia
Hong Kong
Philippines
Malaysia
India
Indonesia
Korea
Japan
Vietnam
China
Thailand
Singapore
0 10 20 30 40 50 60
number of years
Note: The old-age dependency ratio indicates the population 65 years and older as a share
of the working-age population (15–64 years). Data shown in darker shading reflect historical
data, while economies in lighter shading reflect projections.
Source: IMF Staff calculations based on United Nations, World Population Prospects: 2015
Revision (medium-fertility scenario).
lower levels than reached by mature advanced economies at the same stage
of the aging cycle. This trend underscores the need to sustain high growth
rates in these economies.
Asia’s demographic evolution has important global implications,
because of the region’s contribution to global growth, current account bal-
ances, and capital flows, as well as relative wage levels and competitiveness.
Figure 3.4 presents absolute changes in the working-age population for
different demographic country groups in Asia and the rest of the world.
Between 1970 and 2010, Asia contributed more to the growth of the global
working-age population than the rest of the world combined.
This situation is changing. Over the coming decades, rapidly aging
East Asian economies are projected to see their working-age populations
drop substantially. The largest absolute decline will be in China, where
the working-age population will fall by 170 million over the next 35 years.
Substantial absolute declines are also projected for Japan, Korea, and
Thailand. In contrast, Africa will account for most of the growth in the
global working-age population (IMF 2015a).
percent
2008
100
1987 1993 2009 1987 2009 1992
80 1950
2014 2009 2056
60 2020
2040
40 2031 2013
2011
20 2014
0
a a a a
es y ly d a ce m lia an ea nd s ia a ia nd na m
t an Ita o a a e s di hi
ta m na an tr ap or al in ay In es ila C tna
S a Fr gd us J K on a ie
d er C in Ze pp al d Th V
te G K A ili M In
ni d ew Ph
U te N
ni
U
a. Based on IMF Staff projection. For Malaysia, the income level relative to the United States is calculated from the April 2017
World Economic Outlook projection for 2020. For India, Indonesia, and the Philippines, the income levels are calculated by
applying the projected purchasing power parity per capita income growth rate in 2022, starting from 2023 and up to the year
in which the working-age population share is projected to peak.
Note: For the countries shown in the figure, the working-age population (15–64 years) share of the total population has peaked, or
is projected to reach the peak, in the year indicated in parentheses.
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; IMF Staff calculations based on United Nations, World Population Prospects:
39
Figure 3.4 Change in working-age population in Asia and the
rest of the world
millions
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
–100
–200
–300
1970–90 1990–2010 2010–30 2030–50
Early-dividend
Late-dividend
Post-dividend
Rest of the world
TFPt β Kt β ∑ (3.1)
4. This assumption means that investment adjusts over time to the labor force, where labor
is expressed in efficiency units (i.e., incorporating TFP). If, for example, the capital stock
is 300 percent of GDP and the effective labor force growth declines by 1 percentage point,
the investment ratio will fall by 3 percentage points of GDP. As some substitution between
capital and labor is likely, this assumption creates an upper bound on the growth impact.
5. The drag on growth is broadly stable for Japan over the next three decades, near 1.0
percentage point in each decade. In contrast, the drag for China rises over time, from 0.4
percentage point in the first decade to about 1.1 percentage points in the last decade.
1.5
1.0
0.5
–0.5
–1.0
–1.5
–2.0
al s
a
do ia
us ia
N Vie alia
Ze am
H gap d
g re
ai g
K d
C a
na
l i an
ct
M ine
si
e
n
Th on
n
In Ind
A es
pa
on o
or
hi
ba Jap
Si ala
la
ay
n
tr
K
n
pp
ew t
m
ili
n
Ph
lo
G
0.4
–0.4
–0.8
al ia
N Vie sia
Ze am
us d
ai ia
nd
ap n
C e
H Ko a
l i ng
ct
a
n
G ong re
or
ng a
A an
In Ind
M es
Th ral
pa
in
Si ap
hi
la
ba Ko
ay
n
al
n
pp
t
ew t
m
J
ili
Ph
lo
Note: The baseline estimates are based on the assumptions of unchanged labor
force participation by age-gender cohort, constant capital-to-labor ratio, and total
factor productivity growth unchanged from historical average. Migration projections
follow historical trends. Global impact indicates the purchasing power parity–
weighted average as a percent of global GDP.
Sources: IMF Staff projections based on Amaglobeli and Shi (2016); United Nations,
World Population Prospects: 2015 Revision (medium-fertility scenario); and Penn
World Tables 9.0.
Figure 3.5, panel b, shows the growth impact on a per capita basis. The
country ordering changes slightly. The drag from demographics is smaller
for Japan but larger for Hong Kong and Singapore, because the positive
impact of immigration is partially eliminated.
We next relax several assumptions in this stylized exercise—in partic-
ular the assumptions of unchanged TFP growth and labor force partici-
pation rates—and discuss why we keep the capital-to-effective-labor ratio
assumption.
6. Long-term demographic projections are uncertain. Compared with the United Nations’
medium-fertility scenario, average annual growth is about 0.2 percentage point higher in
the high-fertility scenario and about 0.2 percentage point lower in the low-fertility scenario.
7. This effect is driven only by an increase in the size of the workforce. In addition, Jaumotte,
Koloskova, and Saxena (2016) estimate that a 1 percentage point increase in the share of
migrants in the working-age population can raise GDP per capita over the long term by up to
2 percent, by increasing labor productivity and, to a lesser extent, boosting investment. This
second-round effect is not shown in panel a of figure 3.5. The long-term UN assumptions on
net migration rates for these countries range from 2.5 percent in New Zealand to 6 percent
in Australia.
15
10
0
s
do ia
a
am
us a
Th lia
Ze d
ng ea
on ore
g
e
di
si
pa
n
an
on
s
in
or
hi
la
ay
ne
In
tn
ap
tr
al
Ja
K
pp
ai
K
al
ie
g
ili
A
In
Ph
Si
ew
H
N
EU-28
Australia
Singapore
Japan
Korea
Hong Kong
Malaysia
Thailand
Vietnam
0 20 40 60 80 100
percent of total workforce, latest available
Increases
Neutral
Decreases
Not classified
where i indicates the country, t the decade, YW real output per worker,
w55 the share of the workforce aged 55–64, DR the dependency ratio, ui
the country fixed effect, ht the decade fixed effect, and eit the error term.
Correcting for various econometric pitfalls—such as reverse causality—the
𝑟𝑟�� � 𝛽𝛽� � 𝛽𝛽� 𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌�� � 𝛽𝛽� �𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌�� ∗ 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶�� � � 𝛽𝛽� 𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂�� � 𝛽𝛽� �𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂�� ∗ 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶�� � � 𝛽𝛽� 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴�� �
approach measures the impact of workforce aging on output per worker.
𝛽𝛽� �𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴�� ∗ 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶�� � � 𝛽𝛽� 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅� � 𝛾𝛾𝐶𝐶𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾𝑟𝑟𝛾𝛾𝑙𝑙𝛾𝛾�� � �� ����
(3.3) To address the endogeneity issue, the model also instruments the workforce
share variable and the dependency ratio with lagged birth rates (of 10, 20,
30, and 40 years), as in Jaimovich and Siu (2009).
9. Female LFPRs increased in the region’s advanced economies but declined in China, India,
Thailand, and Vietnam; male LFPRs declined in most countries. LFPRs for workers 15–24
declined in all countries by up to a third, reflecting longer schooling. LFPRs for workers
55–64 increased in most countries, most notably Australia, New Zealand, and Singapore.
- CHAPTER
Workforce share –0.612*** 0.187*** –0.0589*** –0.740*** –0.502***
AT RISK OF
aged 55–64 (–5.309) –4.144 (–2.896) (–4.714) (–5.643)
–0.122 –0.105 0.0382 –0.0549 0.279**
Dependency ratio
(–0.695) (–1.532) –1.232 (–0.229) –2.057
Observations 571 571 571 571 571
3—SUSTAINING
Number of countries 33 33 33 33 33
GROWING OLD
PWT 9.0 = Penn World Tables 9.0; TFP = total factor productivity
a. All regressions include both country
log
log 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
log 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 𝑟 and time effects.
ɑɑ 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
ECONOMIC
log
log �
�log
log �𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
�𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟
BEFORE BECOMING
GROWTH INRICH? 3
ASIA 47
Figure 3.8 Impact of aging on total factor productivity
on alia
Ze g
d
na
a
am
do d
es
ng ea
us n
an
si
di
si
or
pa
n
ew Ko
in
or
hi
la
tr
ay
ne
al
In
tn
ap
Ja
pp
C
ai
K
al
ie
g
Th
A
ili
M
In
Ph
Si
H
N
Note: Estimated impact of workforce aging on total factor productivity
growth follows Aiyar, Ebeke, and Shao (2016) based on a sample of Asian
and European economies.
Sources: IMF Staff estimates based on United Nations, World Population
Prospects: 2015 Revision (medium-fertility scenario) and Penn World
Tables 9.0.
us n
ia
Th na
Ze d
d
am
ne
di
si
si
or
pa
on
an
al
or
hi
ew ila
ay
ne
In
tn
ap
tr
pi
Ja
al
K
C
K
a
al
do
ie
lip
ng
g
M
V
on
A
i
In
Ph
Si
H
2015
1990
do ia
us a
ia
Ze m
re
Th ng
nd
ea
na
n
si
si
pa
Si lan
d
al
ew tna
o
in
or
hi
o
la
ay
ne
In
ap
tr
Ja
K
pp
C
a
ai
K
al
ie
ng
g
ili
V
A
on
In
Ph
H
N
Note: The rising labor force participation rates scenario is based on the
experience of Japan from 1990 to 2015.
Source: IMF (2017).
Within the region, LFPRs increased the most in Japan, the world’s oldest
country, rising by almost 6 percentage points since 1990.
What if the LFPR of other Asian economies were to rise by as much as
it did in Japan? Figure 3.10 shows the impact of such a scenario on growth.
Annual GDP growth rises 0.2–0.3 percentage point, offsetting the lower
TFP growth that results from workforce aging. Such changes in the LFPR
are unlikely to counter the baseline growth effects induced by changes in
the overall labor force, however.10
10. The impact on growth for small changes in LFPRs is close to linear. A more ambitious
scenario, in which the employment gender gap is eliminated, could add 0.25 percentage point
to annual GDP growth for Japan and up to 1 percentage point for India by 2050 (Elborgh-
Woytek et al. 2013, Cuberes and Teignier 2016, Khera 2016). Gonzales et al. (2015) show that
reducing a broader measure of gender inequality in education, political empowerment, the
LFPR, and health could lower income inequality and boost growth: A 10 percentage point
reduction in the gender inequality index is associated with almost 1 percentage point higher
per capita GDP growth.
11. Following the EBA model, the working-age population is defined as people 30–64, which
captures the prime-age population. As 15-year-olds are not routinely in the employed popu-
lation, the prime-age population is considered a better choice for examining savings-invest-
ment relationships. Accordingly, the old-age dependency ratio indicates people 65 and over
as a share of the prime-age population.
12. In the EBA model, population growth is a proxy for the fertility rate or youth depen-
dency ratio. Aging speed is a measure of the “probability of survival” or longevity, reflecting
the prospects of population aging; old-age dependency captures the outcome of population
aging so far (IMF 2017).
13. Grigoli, Herman, and Schmidt-Hebbel (2014) provide a comprehensive survey of saving
determinants. They find that both youth and old-age dependency lower savings in both the
theoretical and the empirical literature.
14. As people expect to live longer, they are induced to save more, counterbalancing the
effects of higher old-age dependency (Li, Zhang, and Zhang 2007). The impact of aging on
saving behavior is subject to model uncertainty, depending on whether this forward-looking
element is accounted for.
Aging speed h i h
Source: Authors’ illustration.
15. The impact of population growth (or youth dependency) on investment is less certain than
on savings. Some studies (e.g., Higgins 1998) find a positive effect; others (e.g., Williamson
2001, Bosworth and Chodorow-Reich 2007) find a negative effect.
4 GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
IS ASIA AT RISK3—SUSTAINING
OF GROWING OLD BEFORE
ECONOMIC BECOMING
GROWTH RICH? 51
IN ASIA
Lawson, and Radziwill (2010), who find that increased longevity is associ-
ated with higher savings.
Empirical results based on the EBA model support our priors on the
effect of population growth and aging speed. Higher population growth
leads to lower current account balance (as in Jaumotte and Sodsriwiboon
2010), but the effect is not empirically significant. Aging speed is strongly
associated with higher current account balances, reflecting aging-related
precautionary savings (as in Li, Zhang, and Zhang 2007 and Barnes, Lawson,
and Radziwill 2010). Higher old-age dependency is positively associated
with the current account balance when aging speed is higher than the world
average.
What changes in regional current accounts does the EBA model predict
as a result of demographic transition in the coming decade?16 By 2020
Australia, Japan, and New Zealand will have higher old-age dependency
ratios than the (GDP-weighted) world average. By 2030 Hong Kong, Korea,
and Singapore will also have higher old-age dependency ratios than the
world average.17 Several economies in the region—most notably Hong Kong,
Japan, Korea, and Singapore (advanced economies) and China, Thailand,
and Vietnam (emerging markets)—will experience very rapid aging until
2030 (IMF 2017). In contrast, some advanced economies (Australia and
New Zealand) will have lower speeds of aging than the world average.
Over 2020–30, the EBA model suggests that, all else equal, demo-
graphic trends are likely to exert upward pressure on current account bal-
ances in surplus countries, such as Thailand, Korea, and Japan given the
increase in their aging speeds between 2020 and 2030 (figure 3.11). Among
deficit countries, demographic trends are likely to exert downward pressure,
particularly in New Zealand, given its falling aging speed. Overall, demo-
graphics are projected to materially increase current account balances in
only a few economies in Asia. The total impact of demographics on global
imbalances is limited.
What will be the effect on capital flows? All else equal, demographic
factors are likely to strengthen the current dynamics of capital flows. Over
2020–30, changes in the current account as a result of demographic trends
are likely to be positively correlated with 2015 current account balances
16. The rest of this section focuses on old-age dependency and aging speed as the main
drivers of the current account because changes in population growth between 2020 and
2030 are expected to be relatively small. The contribution of population growth to changes
in current account is less than 0.1 percent of GDP for the sample period.
17. Demographic variables are expressed relative to the (GDP-weighted) world average,
reflecting the fact that countries need to be at different stages of the demographic transition
in order for it to have an impact on their external positions.
ia
do a
es
nd
ea
a
si
si
di
si
pa
an
al
in
or
hi
la
ay
ne
A
In
tr
al
Ja
pp
C
ai
K
us
al
Ze
Th
ili
M
A
In
Ph
ew
N
18. For example, aging may affect fiscal balance through higher pension and healthcare
spending. As public health spending is included as a control variable in the EBA, the estimates
(figure 3.11) account for this channel based on health spending projections (Amaglobeli and
Shi 2016). The estimates do not account for the role of generosity of pension systems, which
could be an important factor behind private saving behavior.
1
Philippines Thailand
India
0 Indonesia China
Malaysia
–1 Australia
–2
New Zealand
–3
–6 –2 2 6 10
current account balance (percent of GDP, 2015)
om
es
ea
lia
Th m
nd
na
a
si
si
an
or
pa
a
at
ra
or
hi
la
ne
ay
tn
gd
ap
m
Ja
St
C
t
ai
K
us
al
do
ie
er
ng
in
M
V
d
A
G
In
te
Si
d
ni
te
U
ni
U
Sources: Haver Analytics; Bloomberg LP; CEIC Asia database; IMF Staff calculations.
percent
6
–1
1985 1989 1993 1997 2001 2005 2009 2013
19. Other drivers of the secular decline in natural interest rates can be a slowdown in trend
productivity growth, shifts in saving and investment preferences (rising inequality), precau-
tionary saving in emerging markets, a fall in the relative price of capital goods, and a prefer-
ence away from public investment (Rachel and Smith 2015). This section focuses on real
percentage points
4.0
1990–99
3.5
2000–07
3.0 2014–16
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0
United Japan Korea Australia Indonesia China Malaysia
States
Note: For Indonesia, China, and Malaysia, 1990–99 data are not available.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; Haver Analytics; IMF Staff estimates.
Aging Speed h i i
Source: Authors’ illustration.
and thereby interest rates, primarily through youth dependency, old-age de-
pendency, and aging speed (table 3.5):20
n Youth dependency. In principle, as the youth dependency ratio rises, the
working-age cohort saves less (to cover the rising expenditure on chil-
dren), the capital-to-labor ratio falls, and interest rates rise. Youth de-
pendency is expected to fall drastically in early-dividend countries, such
as the Philippines and India (figure 3.16, panel a).
interest rates. Low interest rates may also reflect low steady-state inflation as a result of
similar demographic pressures that weaken growth and drive up savings.
20. The previous section was based on the EBA model, which uses population growth as a
proxy for youth dependency. As youth dependency is a more direct measure of population
dynamics (and a complement to the old-age dependency ratio), we use it in this section.
ew Ja ia
Ze an
ng nd
K e
ai a
C d
do na
ie a
M nam
pp a
es
ro es
ea
Th e
V esi
si
ili di
or
A on
n
al
in
Eu tat
or
ar
p
In hi
Si ala
la
ay
Ph In
ap
tr
K
n
t
S
al
g
d
on
te
H
ni
N
U
Note: Youth dependency ratio indicates the size of the population
14 years of age and younger as a share of the prime working-age
population (30–64 years old).
Sources: United Nations, World Population Prospects: 2015 Revision
(medium-fertility scenario); IMF, World Economic Outlook; IMF Staff
projections.
20
15
10
0
Ze nd
ie a
A am
ia
do an
M sia
pp a
es
ro s
ea
g
e
Th ea
Eu ate
n
si
i
an
al
Ph Ind
or
in
on
ar
hi
p
ew aila
ne
ay
tn
or
tr
al
Ja
C
St
ap
K
us
al
K
ili
ng
V
g
d
In
on
te
Si
ni
H
Note: Old-age dependency ratio indicates the size of the population 65 years of
age and over as a share of the prime working-age population (30–64 years old).
Sources: United Nations, World Population Prospects: 2015 Revision (medium-
fertility scenario); IMF, World Economic Outlook; IMF Staff projections.
ea
al n
a
ie a
do m
ili sia
K s
ai a
nd
ng na
us e
N ng lia
Ze ng
ro es
e
si
Th e
A or
pa
an
d
In tna
in
Eu tat
o tra
ar
or
i
la
o
ay
Ph ne
Si Ch
In
ap
Ja
al
ew K
pp
S
M
d
te
H
ni
U
Note: Aging speed is the projected change in the old-age dependency
ratio over the next 20 years. Old-age dependency ratio indicates the
size of the population 65 and older as a share of the prime working-
age population (30–64 years old).
Sources: United Nations, World Population Prospects: 2015 Revision
(medium-fertility scenario); IMF, World Economic Outlook; IMF Staff
projections.
J
log
Yt log TFPt 1 log K t log N t j LFPt j Et j wtj (3.1)
n Aging speed. Higher aging speed implies a higher probability
j 1 of survival,
which, if not matched by later retirement, is likely to have a positive
impact on life-cycle savings. Higher aging speed also lowers current
investment, thereby reducing interest rates. Aging speed is high and
expected to fall in countries in late stages of the demographic transi-
tion (figure
∆𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙3.16, panel c). Japan, where aging speed (3.2)
�� � �� 𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤�� � �� 𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷�� � �� � η� � ���
will continue to
increase in the next decade, is an exception.
. (3.3a)
21. Given the low-frequency variation in demographic variables, annual real interest rates may
introduce substantial noise to any relationship with a demographic structure. To account
for this problem, we also considered three- and five-year rates for nonoverlapping periods,
as explained in IMF (2017). Such multiperiod rates emphasize the low-frequency variation
in real interest rates. The results are broadly similar to the results for the baseline scenario.
22. Rachel and Smith (2015) find that demographic factors, public investment, and a global
savings glut explain about 2 (out of 4.5) percentage points of the decline in global neutral
rates between 1980 and 2015.
6
60 GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
SUSTAINING ECONOMIC3—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
GROWTH IN ASIA
Figure 3.17 Selected Asia: Impact of demographics on 10-year
real interest rates
nd
na
es
ea
lia
a
di
si
si
s
in
ra
or
hi
la
ay
ne
A
In
pp
C
t
ai
us
al
do
Th
ili
M
A
In
Ph
Note: The figure for Asia reflects the nominal GDP-weighted average.
Source: IMF Staff projections.
–0.5
–1.0
Korea
–1.5 Philippines
China
India
–2.0 Malaysia
Thailand
–2.5
2020 2022 2024 2026 2028 2030
Aging speed i h i i
Source: Authors’ illustration.
23. By definition, expected stock returns are equal to the sum of the risk-free rate and the
equity risk premium.
24. If the correlation between labor income and stock returns is sufficiently low, a labor
income stream acts as a substitute for risk-free bond holdings, implying that investors
should hold a declining share of stocks in their portfolio as they get older (Jagannathan and
Kocherlakota 1996).
62 GRAPHICSECONOMIC
SUSTAINING - CHAPTER GROWTH
3—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
IN ASIA 7
Table 3.8 Panel regression: Demographics and asset returns
Percent growth
Percent growth in real property
Dependent variables in stock return price
67.28*** –11.32***
Youth dependency ratio
(23.66) (3.96)
–31.01** 0.67
Youth dependency ratio * capital openness
(14.22) (4.00)
–32.69 –53.18*
Old-age dependency ratio
(82.26) (31.77)
138.26* –5.37
Old-age dependency ratio * capital openness
(75.02) (26.99)
315.31* –100.95***
Aging speed
(163.18) (34.05)
–317.04** 60.79*
Aging speed * capital openness
(142.92) (31.86)
–1.18 –1.48***
World interest rate
(2.17) (0.53)
4.75*** 0.3
Growth in labor productivity
(0.98) (0.20)
Observations 406 716
Number of groups 14 56
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. P denotes the p-value as the probability of ob-
taining a result equal to or more extreme than that observed. The regression controls
for the country fixed effect.
Source: IMF Staff estimates.
ables that Mankiw and Weil (1989) find for the United States does not hold
for Canada. Takáts (2010) finds that an increase in the change of old-age
dependency lowers real housing price growth by about 66 basis points in a
group of 22 advanced economies.
We find that lower youth (or higher old-age) dependency is associ-
ated with lower stock returns (i.e., the interest rate channel dominates),
but the relationships are not statistically strong (table 3.8). Moreover, as
with interest rates, the impact of domestic demographic factors is partially
offset in more financially open countries.
For real estate, the relationship with demographic variables is even
more difficult to identify, because of the asset’s dual role as a durable good.
Conceptually, a fall in interest rates, triggered by a fall in youth depen-
dency (or a rise in old-age dependency), would raise housing prices. At the
same time, these trends are expected to reduce demand for housing, as
they are associated with declines in household formation.25 Empirically, we
25. Furthermore, because the housing stock responds with lags, subsequent downward price
adjustments may mask an initial price increase caused by a positive demand shock (Poterba
8 GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
IS ASIA AT RISK3—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC
OF GROWING OLD BEFOREGROWTH IN ASIA
BECOMING RICH? 63
find weak links between these variables and real estate prices. The degree
of openness plays an insignificant role, likely reflecting the local nature of
housing markets.
Macroeconomic Policies
Japan’s experience shows that it is important to adapt macroeconomic
policies before aging sets in. Fiscal policy may include introducing a cred-
ible medium-term fiscal framework to secure debt sustainability, shifting
the burden of taxes from labor to consumption, and revamping the social
safety net.26 Monetary policy may involve studying how monetary trans-
mission may change with aging. If, for example, monetary transmission
works more through asset prices and household wealth than through
corporate borrowing costs, the interest rate sensitivity of output and infla-
tion may decline (Miles 2002, Bean 2004). To the extent that aging leads
to declines in the natural interest rate, regular assessment of the neutral
monetary stance by central banks is needed to avoid a potential tightening
bias. Prolonged low interest rates may also call for a strong macropruden-
tial framework to mitigate related financial stability risks.
1984, Lindh and Malmberg 2008). Moreover, higher demand for housing could manifest
itself more prominently through the rental rate, which may not always move together with
housing prices (Hamilton 1991).
26. At the same time, with a credible medium-term fiscal framework, fiscal policy can be used
more actively in the short run, given its higher potency in a low interest rate environment,
including to support aging-related structural reforms.
27. IMF research finds that key to harnessing the long-term gains of foreign workers are
actions that facilitate their integration into the labor market, including language training
and job search assistance, better recognition of migrants’ skills through the recognition of
credentials, and lower barriers to entrepreneurship (IMF 2017).
28. Financial integration in Asia remains low, especially given its high degree of trade inte-
gration. About 60 percent of Asia’s exports and imports go to, or originate from, elsewhere
within the region; only 20–30 percent of cross-border portfolio investment and bank claims
are intraregional (IMF 2015b).
References
Acemoglu, D., and P. Restrepo. 2017. Secular Stagnation? The Effect of Aging on Economic Growth
in the Age of Automation. NBER Working Paper 23077. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Adler, G., R. Duval, D. Furceri, S.K. Çelik, K. Koloskova, and M. Poplawski-Ribeiro. 2017. Gone
with the Headwinds: Global Productivity. IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/17/04. Washing-
ton: International Monetary Fund.
Aiyar, S., C. Ebeke, and X. Shao. 2016. The Impact of Workforce Aging on European Productivity.
IMF Working Paper 16/238. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Amaglobeli, D., and W. Shi. 2016. How to Assess Fiscal Implications of Demographic Shifts: A Granu-
lar Approach. Fiscal Affairs Department How to Note 2/2016. Washington: International
Monetary Fund.
Arbatli, E., C. Feher, J. Ree, I. Saito, and M. Soto. 2016. Automatic Adjustment Mechanisms in Asian
Pension Systems? IMF Working Paper 16/242. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Barnes, S., J. Lawson, and A. Radziwill. 2010. Current Account Imbalances in the Euro Area: A Com-
parative Perspective. Economics Department Working Paper ECO/WKP(2010)82. Paris: Or-
ganization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Basten, S., and Q. Jiang. 2015. Fertility in China: An Uncertain Future. Population Studies 69
(Supplement1): 97–105.
Bean, C. 2004. Global Demographic Change: Some Implications for Central Banks. Paper pre-
sented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Annual Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY.
Bloom, D.E., D. Canning, and G. Fink. 2010. Implications of Population Ageing for Economic
Growth. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 26, no. 4: 583–612.
Bloom, D.E., D. Canning, G. Fink, and J.E. Finlay. 2007. Fertility, Female Labor Participation, and
the Demographic Dividend. NBER Working Paper 13583. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Bloom, D.E., D. Canning, and J. Sevilla. 2003. The Demographic Dividend: A New Perspec-
tive on the Economic Consequences of Population Change. Population Matter Series. Santa
Monica, CA: RAND.
Japan’s rapid growth from the 1950s through the early 1970s had many
drivers, but most impressive was its rapid productivity growth (Denison
and Chung 1976). Economic growth slowed in all advanced economies in
the 1970s, but Japan grew more rapidly than the other rich Western econo-
mies, and its measured productivity growth remained higher than theirs.
In the 1970s and early 1980s, Japan’s industrial structure quickly shifted
from resource- and labor-intensive manufacturing toward knowledge- and
technology-intensive industries. Japanese manufacturers of steel, autos,
industrial machines, and, increasingly, electronics began displacing long-
established Western manufacturers worldwide. Japan’s research and devel-
opment (R&D) intensity and the number of patents held by Japanese firms
at home and abroad surged.
By the early 1980s, Japanese firms, long derided as “copycat” imitators
of Western technology, managed to outengineer their Western rivals in a
range of iconic industries.1 By the late 1980s, prestigious bodies like the
US National Research Council were glumly concluding that Japanese firms
were ahead of their American rivals in 25 out of 34 “critical” areas of tech-
Lee G. Branstetter is nonresident senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics and profes-
sor of economics and public policy at Carnegie Mellon University. Namho Kwon is an associate fellow at the Ko-
rea Institute of Public Finance. The authors thank their discussant, Jong-Wha Lee, for insightful comments and
suggestions. We also acknowledge the helpful input of Jérémie Cohen-Setton, Kyoji Fukao, Ken Kang, and Adam
Posen. This paper builds on research funded by the National Science Foundation (SciSIP grant 136170) and the
Carnegie Mellon Portugal Program. However, the views expressed in this chapter are those of the authors, and
we take responsibility for all errors and omissions.
1. Mansfield (1988a, 1988b, 1988c) documented the high productivity of Japan’s corporate
R&D spending.
73
nology (National Research Council 1992), and in 1987, the president of the
US Semiconductor Research Corporation conceded, “We may never match
Japan’s R&D efficiency.”
By the end of the 1980s, South Korea and Taiwan appeared to be fol-
lowing in Japan’s footsteps. At the beginning of that decade, both nations
were regarded as low-wage manufacturers of labor-intensive goods. By
its end, both were rapidly increasing their patenting in the United States
(Branstetter and Kwon 2018), and their export mix was quickly shifting
toward labor- and knowledge-intensive goods. Analysts began predicting
that the innovation leadership in electronics and information technology
was in the early stages of a permanent shift to East Asia.
The degree to which those prophecies of innovation leadership remain
unfulfilled suggests that the East Asian approach to R&D, pioneered by
Japan and adopted by South Korea and Taiwan, had both strengths and
weaknesses (Okimoto and Rohlen 1988). This system was arguably better
than the American system at applied research, hardware, miniaturization,
process equipment and technology, product variety, and process engi-
neering, whereas the American system was stronger in basic research, soft-
ware, creating new products, high-technology systems, and creation of new
industries.2 It was perhaps natural that engineers and firms in late-devel-
oping states would focus their efforts on a technological frontier largely
defined by prior foreign invention, rather than on fundamental innovation
(Gerschenkron 1962).
Once Japan and its former colonies reached the technological frontier,
and lost their longstanding cost advantages, however, the firms based in
these economies had to shift from an innovation system appropriate for
their “catch-up” periods to one that could generate its independent frontier
innovations. This chapter argues that the policies pursued during the high
growth eras of these economies may well have contributed to the difficulties
their firms have experienced in this transition. In Japan, South Korea, and
Taiwan, the evidence suggests that public policy choices during their years
of rapid growth concentrated R&D in particular activities, industries, and
firms. And these choices have slowed the ability of these countries to adapt
to current circumstances, imposing a drag on growth.3 Other nations in the
region seeking to follow in the footsteps of these economies should learn
from these policy missteps. (See box 4.1.)
2. Okimoto and Saxonhouse (1987) viewed these differences as reflecting intelligent adapta-
tion to the circumstances in which Japanese firms found themselves in the postwar era, and
some of the observations in their essay anticipate the arguments in this chapter.
3. Nelson (1992) influenced our thinking about the evolution of these economies’ innova-
tion systems.
EVOLUTION
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER OF EAST ASIA’S
4—SUSTAINING INNOVATION
ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA 751
SYSTEMS
Box 4.1 Radical innovation, pro-incumbent/pro-
incremental bias, and the decline in innovation
productivity (continued)
Empirical evidence and theory also suggest that established
incumbents often resist investment in experiments that render
existing business models obsolete, highlighting the importance
of making capital available to newcomers and fostering competi-
tion. Christensen (1997), for example, points out that successful
incumbents face a double bind when seeking to engage in radical
innovation. They typically arrive at their position after years, even
decades, of successful refinement of existing products and busi-
ness practices but are then ill equipped to succeed in a radically
different approach to the same product class or service.
New industry creation in the 21st century is more science-based
and more closely connected to frontier university research than
in the past, thereby highlighting the importance of labor mobility
and connections between the academic and industry sectors. The
development of successful products based on these discoveries
often requires “human bridges”—entrepreneurial faculty and grad-
uate students conversant in the new technology who can partner
with experienced managers and engineers to embed the new
ideas in successful firms and products (Agrawal and Henderson
2003; Zucker, Darby, and Brewer 1998).
In the United States, strong protection of intellectual property
rights and the willingness of American courts to levy significant
damages or even issue injunctions when inventions are infringed
by financially stronger manufacturers have strengthened the
potential for innovation (Hochberg. Serrano, and Ziedonis 2018;
Jaffe and Lerner 2004). Strong intellectual property rights also
enable holders of patents to bargain with contract manufacturers
and other business partners without fear of expropriation (Hall and
Ziedonis 2001). These protections raise the chances of success
by loosening the historical requirement that firms excel in both
product and process innovation. America’s open capital markets
allow new startups to offer outsized returns to investors willing
to take high risks, further upping the odds of success. The histori-
cally open US market for consumer and industrial goods enables
new innovators to compete with established sellers. In America’s
fluid labor markets for top managers and engineers, past asso-
ciation with an ambitious startup—even if it fails—is viewed as a
useful career experience. By contrast, the repeated downsizing
and chronic competitive woes of traditional American manufac-
turers in more technologically quiescent industries have lessened
the appeal of spending an entire career as an engineer or manager
in an established firm. For talented young American managers and
engineers, the balance of risks and rewards tilts toward smaller
firms in technologically dynamic sectors.
76 GRAPHICS
2 SUSTAINING- ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
CHAPTER 4—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
Japan
Human Capital
In a world of globalized supply chains, where it is commonplace for compo-
nents of even the most sophisticated manufactured products to be assem-
bled in low-wage developing countries, it is easy to forget what a novelty
Japan was in the early postwar era. It had been the first and only nonwestern
nation to acquire modern manufacturing capabilities on a significant
scale in the years prior to World War II. In the postwar era, it continued to
grow with surprising vigor, rapidly becoming the first nonwestern nation
to join the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD). These achievements were, in part, the result of Japan’s exception-
ally successful, decades-long strategy of investing in the acquisition of both
general human capital and specific technical capabilities.
The strategy took shape after Japan’s Meiji Restoration of 1868, when
the new imperial state created a modern educational system and brought
Western expertise into its leading firms and government ministries.4 The
government subsidized study abroad for thousands of Japanese students
and imported foreign instructors, consultants, and experts. Jones (1980)
describes how, in these early years, half of the Ministry of Education’s
budget and two-thirds of the national public works budget was spent on
foreign experts. As Japan’s educational system expanded, these expensive
foreigners were quickly replaced with qualified locals. Japan exported its
educational system and philosophy to its colonies, Taiwan and Korea,
which benefited from the investment.
All three economies committed themselves to educational excellence
in the postwar era. By the mid-1960s, Japanese students were outscoring
Europeans and Americans on international standardized tests of math-
ematics and science. By the 1980s, Japan graduated more than twice as
many engineers per capita as the United States, and its ordinary workers
had dramatically more competence in science and math than their Amer-
ican counterparts (Rohlen 1983). Today, standardized tests of science and
mathematics skills suggest that the average levels of skill mastery and
the fraction of students scoring one standard deviation above the OECD
average are extremely high in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan (Hanushek
and Woessman 2015). In chapter 7, Kyoji Fukao documents the almost
embarrassing degree to which the basic skills of the average Japanese
worker exceed those of his or her American counterpart.
4. Branstetter (2017) also highlights the importance of Japan’s early investment in educa-
tion. This section draws on that earlier study.
Intellectual Property
Prewar Japan imported the patent system of Bismarck-era Germany in the
19th century, which remained the basis of Japanese intellectual property
policy throughout the 20th century. The Japanese system, like the German
one, provided limited intellectual property protection for even modest,
Exchange Rates
Japan began reintegrating into the postwar global economy with a high
level of human capital, impressive manufacturing skills, and—given the
extent of wartime devastation—much lower factor costs than Western
rivals. Japan’s economy quickly recovered, but low inflation, rapid produc-
tivity convergence, and participation in the postwar system of fixed
exchange rates and limited capital flows kept Japan’s cost of production
relatively low when measured in Western currencies, especially the US
dollar (Ito 1992). Despite episodic protectionism, Japan generally found
open Western markets for its ever-expanding range of export goods. As
5. Branstetter (2017) also stressed the role of relatively weak, narrow patents in shaping the
Japanese style of innovation focused on relatively incremental invention.
Financial Markets
Japan’s industrial evolution required access not just to skilled workers but
also to capital. An extensive literature describes the evolution of Japan’s
highly regulated postwar capital markets (Hoshi and Patrick 2000, Hoshi
and Kashyap 2001) from wartime capital controls and industrial planning.
Postwar regulatory barriers sharply limited the issuance of stocks and
bonds into the 1980s.
For most firms, it was simply not practical to obtain significant external
financing through direct sales of equity or bonds to investors. Instead,
Japan’s postwar financial system was dominated by a highly regulated
banking cartel. This cartel operated under deposit and commercial lending
rates that were set by government fiat rather than the supply and demand
of financial capital. To access sufficient external finance in Japan’s booming
postwar economy, most large Japanese manufacturing firms forged a close
connection with one of the main commercial banks.
This system provided large amounts of financial capital to a limited
set of “insider” firms at reasonably low interest rates (Hoshi, Kashyap, and
Scharfstein 1991; Hoshi and Kashyap 2001). New firms outside this system
Competition
Japan’s postwar development is often mischaracterized as “export-led.” In
fact, Japan did not start running consistent and significant current account
surpluses until the 1970s, and these surpluses remained limited in size rela-
tive to GDP until the first half of the 1980s. Instead, Japanese growth was
driven predominantly by domestic sources of demand.
One of the first legal changes the Japanese government instituted when
it regained full sovereignty from its American occupiers was to substantially
weaken the Anti-Monopoly Law it inherited from the New Deal govern-
ment of Harry Truman (Eads and Yamamura 1987, Uekusa 1987, Weinstein
1995). The Japanese government regularly created legal cartels when indus-
tries experienced cyclical downturns, with the government itself playing
the role of cartel enforcer (Uekusa 1987, Weinstein 1995). The market was
effectively divided up on the basis of pre-recession market shares, a policy
that—to the extent that it worked—benefitted established incumbents.
The postwar Japanese distribution system was, by contrast, fragmented
and dominated by small-scale, “mom and pop” style stores. These small
establishments could not resist efforts by much larger manufacturers to tie
them into exclusive dealing contracts. Foreign consumer goods sellers in
the 1980s regularly cited the difficulty of breaking into the Japanese retail/
distribution system as one of the most important barriers to their expan-
sion in the Japanese market (Flath 2002). Of course, this barrier was even
greater for small, startup Japanese firms trying to enter or expand into the
market for consumer goods.
Strong alliances between traditional business partners in Japan also
impeded entry of both foreign and domestic firms. So-called keiretsu
networks dominated the market for industrial goods, at least in key sectors
like automobiles. In Japan’s complicated systems of interfirm alliances
82 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
(Gerlach 1992), would-be entrants had no recourse given the relatively
weak antitrust law and practice.
Finally, in much of Japan’s service economy, heavy-handed govern-
ment regulation strictly restricted entry and competition well into the
1980s. This was true in banking, securities trading, insurance, construc-
tion, telecommunications, intercity freight transportation, and airlines. As
elsewhere in the industrialized world, regulatory capture limited competi-
tion and ensured rents for incumbents, at the expense of consumers and
would-be entrants. All of these factors tended to reinforce the pro-incum-
bent bias in the Japanese innovation system.
where, nit is innovation, rit is the firm’s own R&D investment, the Ds are
dummy variables to control for differences in the propensity to generate
new knowledge across technological fields (indicated by the subscript c),
the Ts are year dummies, and e is an error term. Branstetter and Nakamura
proxy innovation with patents and present the patterns sketched out by
their year dummies as a statistical description of trends in the productivity
of industrial R&D. The results reproduced in figure 4.1 report the coeffi-
cients of time dummies obtained from a version of equation (3) that incor-
porates firm-level fixed effects. Results are estimated separately for firms
in the electronics sector and other manufacturing firms. Measured R&D
productivity of other Japanese firms rose sharply through the 1980s, then
gradually declined through the late 1990s. R&D productivity in the elec-
tronics sector continued to increase through the mid-1990s, but began to
reverse in the late 1990s.6 These results are qualitatively robust to the use of
data on Japanese patent applications, to the weighting of US patent grants
by forward citations, and to the use of firm fixed effects.
These developments were linked to important structural changes in the
nature of private sector R&D in Japan (Branstetter and Nakamura 2003).
6. Several other scholars have also highlighted adverse shifts in the relative performance of
the Japanese innovation system since the early 1990s (Goto 2000, Goto and Odagiri 2003,
Nagaoka 2007).
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
Electronics firms
0 Firms in other manufacturing
industries
–0.2
1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996
As Japanese firms reached the natural limits of an R&D strategy that was
focused on adapting foreign technology—a focus on process and incre-
mental innovation and convergence with a technology frontier rather than
an effort to go beyond it—they were forced to change their approach to
R&D. They had to build larger central R&D laboratories with more ambi-
tious agendas and focus on more fundamental, science-based research.
Unfortunately, the Japanese innovation system was itself still insufficiently
developed to make this new emphasis successful and, at least initially, the
structural changes within Japanese firms were unable to forestall a decline,
or, at best, a stagnation, in research productivity.
In the early 1990s, Japanese stock and real estate markets plunged,
inducing a significant and persistent macroeconomic slowdown. Five years
into the decade, the internet revolution was well under way in the United
States, but Japanese firms were conspicuously absent from the group of
firms—many of them new entrants—that were introducing fundamental
new innovations in IT. Even in less technologically dynamic sectors like
autos, Japanese firms seemed to be losing ground in the 1990s.
By the mid-1990s industrialists and policymakers in Japan increasingly
recognized these shortcomings. The so-called Science and Technology Basic
Law, implemented in late 1995, clearly articulated the need for fundamental
reform of the nation’s innovation system. Since the passage of this law, Japan
has not only strengthened its intellectual property system (Sakakibara and
Branstetter 2001) but also fundamentally reformed its national university
South Korea
Korea spent roughly the first half of the 20th century as a colony of the
Japanese Empire. Shortly after achieving its independence, it was devastated
by civil war. Economic upheaval and political turmoil followed in the wake
of this bloody conflict. The South Korean economic miracle really dates
from the military coup that brought General Park Chung-hee to power
in the early 1960s. For better and for worse, General Park left a stamp on
Korea’s political economy that endures to this day (Yi 2006).
7. For an in-depth analysis of the loss of competitiveness of Japan’s IT sector, see Arora,
Branstetter, and Drev (2013).
8. The five largest chaebols—Samsung, LG, Daewoo, Hyundai, and SK—accounted for 20
percent of all outstanding debt and 75 percent of all new borrowing in 1998 (Economist, 1999,
“Survey of South Korea,” originally appeared June 3, 1995 issue, pp. 10–17).
9. The Samsung Group accounts for more than one-fifth of the value of the South Korean
stock exchange. See Steven Borowiec and Paresh Dave, “South Koreans live in ‘the Republic of
Samsung,’ where the Galaxy Note 7 crisis feels personal,” Los Angeles Times, October 11, 2016,
www.latimes.com/business/technology/la-fi-tn-samsung-note-7-korea-20161011-snap-
story.html; Zahra Ullah, “How Samsung dominates South Korea’s economy,” CNN.com,
February 17, 2017, http://money.cnn.com/2017/02/17/technology/samsung-south-korea-
daily-life/index.html.
Note: This figure measures the fraction of total US patent grants awarded to
South Korean inventors that are accounted for by Samsung Electronics and
by firms affiliated with the top 10, top 30, and top 50 chaebols. Patents are
assigned a date based on year of application. South Korean patent data also
indicate a significant concentration of patenting in the portfolios of these
chaebols. Samsung Electronics alone accounts for more than 50 percent of
all US patent grants received by South Korean firms.
Source: US Patent and Trademark Office.
would be destabilizing to jail the head of the firm, even if he were guilty of
crimes. Lee Kun-hee has since transferred effective control of Samsung to
his son, Lee Jae-yong. The younger Lee was recently convicted of bribing
Lee Myung-bak’s successor (and General Park’s daughter), Park Gyeun-hye,
who was the first South Korean president to be impeached and removed
from office. However, that sentence was suspended in February 2018, and
many observers expect the younger Lee will escape the legal consequences of
his crime. The tangled state of South Korean politics attests to the extreme
degree of pro-incumbent bias that Park’s industrial policies generated.
Note: This figure uses data on total R&D expenditure, as reported by the
publicly traded firms listed on South Korean equity markets, to calculate the
fraction of annual expenditure accounted for by Samsung Electronics and
the top 10, top 30, and top 50 chaebols. In 2010, Samsung Electronics
accounted for more than 50 percent of total R&D expenditure reported
by these firms.
Source: Korean Listed Companies Association (KLCA).
But South Korea’s educational system also has some of the same weak-
nesses as Japan’s. Like their Japanese counterparts, South Korea’s elite
universities are better known for the intensive competition for admission
than for the quality of research or even instruction. The same institu-
tional neglect of graduate education, lack of research funding, unwilling-
ness of the education ministry or the universities to concentrate research
resources in the hands of innovative scholars rather than senior scholars,
and indifference to immigrants have historically limited the research capa-
bilities of South Korean universities.10 While leading chaebols can set up
R&D facilities in Silicon Valley, the relative weakness of Korean universi-
ties drastically limits the access of South Korean startups to world-class
faculty entrepreneurs and graduate students capable of translating labora-
tory breakthroughs into new products and services.
South Korea inherited the Japanese patent system and, even after inde-
pendence, the evolution of the Korean system followed that of Japan’s.
After a long period of weak and narrow protection with indifferent enforce-
ment by courts, reforms in the 1980s led to stronger patents and enforce-
ment, and patent practices began converging with Western standards in
10. Only one university from South Korea is on the list of “Top 200 Universities in the
World,” www.4icu.org/top-universities-world.
11. In 1993, Samsung produced more DRAM chips than any other firm. In the same year,
Hyundai and LG (formerly Lucky GoldStar) ranked ninth and tenth on the list of top global
DRAM producers (Cho, Kim, and Rhee 1998).
12. Seth Fiegerman, “Supreme Court sides with Samsung in Apple patent case,” CNN.
com, December 6, 2016, http://money.cnn.com/2016/12/06/technology/samsung-apple-
supreme-court/index.html.
13. Lance Whitney, “Samsung selling more of its cheaper smartphones,” Cnet.com, November
2, 2015, www.cnet.com/news/samsung-selling-more-phones-at-cheaper-prices-says-new-re-
search.
Taiwan
Like Korea, Taiwan was a colony of the Japanese Empire from 1895 until
the defeat of Imperial Japan in 1945. While brutal, exploitative, and author-
itarian in many ways, Japanese colonial rule was markedly less harsh in
Taiwan than in Korea. The Japanese left Taiwan with the physical and insti-
tutional infrastructure of a modern economy. When it was ceded to Chiang
Kai-shek’s Republic of China by the Allied Powers at the end of World
War II, it was the richest province in his nation by a large margin. Initially
welcomed by the Taiwanese, Chiang’s army and provincial government
quickly demonstrated a remarkable combination of corruption, brutality,
and incompetence. A popular uprising against mainland authority in
1947 was brutally suppressed, and when Chiang Kai-shek relocated his
Nationalist government to Taiwan in 1949, he presided over an authori-
tarian regime characterized by martial law, systematic oppression of any
14. Samsung’s share of global smartphone shipments decreased after 2013. However, the
share was still over 20 percent in 2016 (data from Statista.com, www.statista.com/statis-
tics/271492/global-market-share-held-by-leading-smartphone-vendors/).
15. The market shares of Chinese phone makers such as Huawei, Xiaomi, Oppo, and Vivo
have been increasing. See Scott Cendrowski, “How China’s Smartphone ‘Big Four’ Are
Fighting for Global Customers,” Fortune, January 25, 2017, http://fortune.com/2017/01/24/
china-smartphones-oppo-vivo-huawei-xiaomi.
16. This practice of sublicensing could mean that our plant-level data fail to capture all
“effective” foreign technology purchases.
17. In contrast, the Japanese government began the postwar period with a policy of limiting
foreign technology purchases (Wakasugi 1997). As the Japanese economy developed and
the potential benefits of technology imports became clear to government authorities, these
limits were progressively relaxed. Wakasugi (1997) has argued that the government allowed
proportion of patents
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014
Note: This graph uses data from the US Patent and Trademark Office to calculate
the share of patents awarded to Taiwanese inventors that are in patent classes
associated with electronics and IT hardware. Software-related patents are omitted.
Since the late 1990s, patents in these classes have accounted for more than 60
percent of the total. Taiwanese patents and data on Taiwanese R&D spending also
point to a strong concentration of activity in the electronics industry.
Source: Branstetter and Chen (2006).
only “favored” firms to bid for foreign technology to prevent competition among potential
Japanese purchasers from driving up the price of the license. This may have lowered the price
of foreign technology for these firms, but it effectively increased the price (to infinity) for the
firms that were not favored, and, in Wakasugi’s view, it is unlikely that this intervention was
welfare-enhancing.
18. See Saxenian and Hsu (2001) for a typical positive assessment of the venture.
Conclusion
Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan have successfully climbed the development
ladder, yet, when measured by their own past performance, one cannot
help but be struck by the degree to which they have each fallen short of
what might have been reasonably expected a decade or two ago. Compared
with the United States, Japan’s overall total factor productivity has actu-
ally declined substantially over the past 20 years, even as it has become a
much more R&D-intensive economy than the United States (IMF 2017).
Despite emerging as the most R&D-intensive nation in the OECD, South
Korea’s level of productivity relative to the United States has essentially
remained the same over the past 20 years—stuck at around 60 percent of
the US aggregate TFP level.
The three countries have suffered, to varying degrees, from declining
R&D productivity because the national innovation systems designed for
their high growth periods are no longer as effective in their maturing econ-
omies. The pro-incremental and pro-incumbent biases that government
policies created or reinforced in these countries have made it difficult to
change these innovation systems. Other nations in the region, including
China, seeking to emulate the success of these three nations should avoid
reinforcing the same kinds of biases in their own emerging innovation
systems. The costs of not doing so appear to be high. Once these biases
penetrate the fabric of an economy’s innovation system, they are difficult
to eliminate.
References
Agrawal, A., and R. Henderson. 2003. Putting Patents in Context: Exploring Knowledge
Transfer from MIT. Management Science 48, no. 1: 44–60.
Amano, I., and G. Poole. 2005. The Japanese University in Crisis. Higher Education 50: 685–711.
Jong-Wha Lee is a professor of economics and director of the Asiatic Research Institute at Korea University. He
was chief economist and head of the Office of Regional Economic Integration at the Asian Development Bank
and an economist at the International Monetary Fund.
References
Lee, Jong-Wha. 2016. Korea’s economic growth and catch-up: Implications for China. China
& World Economy 24, no. 5: 71–97.
Bloom, Nicholas, Charles I. Jones, John Van Reenen, and Michael Webb. 2017. Are ideas get-
ting harder to find? NBER Working Paper 23782. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Eco-
nomic Research.
Depressed economic growth and interest rates are the two main symptoms
of secular stagnation. Low interest rates can have problematic side effects,
such as liquidity traps or unsustainable booms in credit and asset prices.
The relationship between these symptoms and their underlying causes are
a matter of debate. If secular stagnation were a health condition, it would
more likely be called a syndrome than a disease.1
To extend the medical metaphor, this chapter explores the contagion
of secular stagnation across countries. The symptoms of secular stagna-
tion have not been limited to a particular group of countries. Many coun-
tries at different stages of economic development and in different regions
have displayed these symptoms. The concomitance of the symptoms could
reflect domestic factors that would have appeared independently in many
countries, but it may suggest that some form of international transmission
or contagion has been at work, raising the question of the mechanisms
and processes by which secular stagnation can spread from a country to
its neighbors.
In a globally integrated economy it is not difficult to imagine channels
of international transmission of secular stagnation. In a financially inte-
grated world a surplus of savings in one part should depress interest rates
Olivier Jeanne is senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics and professor of economics
at Johns Hopkins University. He thanks the conference participants and in particular the chapter’s discussant,
Heenam Choi, for their insightful comments, as well as Medha Nair for her research assistance.
1. A syndrome is a set of correlated symptoms that may or may not be associated with a well-
defined disease.
103
globally. A country attempting to resist lowering its interest rate would be
doing so at the cost of currency appreciation. In a world integrated via trade
a negative demand shock in one part of the world may reduce growth in the
rest of the world. Textbook macroeconomic theory does not say much about
spillovers in productivity growth, but channels of transmission related to
international finance and international trade can explain such spillovers.
This chapter first provides a quick review of the literature on secular
stagnation. It then tries to better understand the channels by which low pro-
ductivity growth can spill over across countries. In principle this spillover
can occur through several channels, related to finance or trade. For example,
if efficient financial intermediation is important for firms to finance pro-
ductivity-enhancing expenditures, then an internationally contagious
banking crisis could depress productivity growth in many countries at the
same time. Or if learning-by-exporting is important for firms to adopt more
efficient foreign technologies, then a slowdown in international trade could
explain a general decrease in productivity growth.
The chapter then investigates how the other symptom of secular stagna-
tion—low interest rates—was transmitted across countries. A simple open-
economy model is presented to set a benchmark for what one should look
for in the data. The model features a country that is an “innocent bystander”
affected by secular stagnation in the rest of the world. Secular stagnation
abroad takes the form of lower real interest rates and lower demand in the
rest of the world. The model shows that the domestic response must involve
a fall in the domestic real rate of interest and net capital inflows. These spill-
overs are part of the natural adjustment process of the domestic economy
to secular stagnation abroad and should not a priori be resisted. However,
they may have problematic side effects, such as drawing monetary policy
closer to the zero lower bound or increasing domestic credit. The chapter
then looks for these side effects in the data for emerging-market economies
as a whole and for the Asian region, taking the global financial crisis as a
watershed event.
Although secular stagnation is by definition a protracted phenom-
enon, the crisis was an important step in its diffusion. Furthermore it is an
event in which the direction of transmission is not ambiguous: The impulse
originated in the advanced economies at the epicenter of the banking crisis
and was transmitted to the rest of the world.2 This chapter is an attempt to
learn something about the transmission of secular stagnation from differ-
2. This is not to say that secular stagnation is in general transmitted from advanced econo-
mies to the rest of the world. For example, many have argued that China has been an impor-
tant source of excess saving in the global economy.
Literature
The literature on secular stagnation has been growing since Lawrence
Summers popularized the concept in 2013. A large part of this litera-
ture considers this topic in a closed-economy context—see, for example,
Andrews, Criscuolo, and Gal (2016) or IMF (2017a) for recent discussions
of internal factors of stagnation such as the information technology revo-
lution, population aging, slowing human capital accumulation, or fading
structural reform efforts. These factors may exercise their effects concomi-
tantly, which could explain why the symptoms of secular stagnation have
affected many countries at the same time without its being the result of con-
tagion. This chapter is related more to the literature that considers interna-
tional transmission of secular stagnation in an open economy. One part of
that literature has focused on the financial channels by which excess saving
in some countries can depress the real interest rate in others. That litera-
ture is mostly theoretical. Eggertsson et al. (2016) and Caballero, Farhi, and
Gourinchas (2015) study global equilibria in which negative spillovers can
spread secular stagnation worldwide.3 In the model of Caballero, Farhi, and
Gourinchas (2015) secular stagnation results from a shortage of safe assets.
Corsetti et al. (2017) build on the model of Eggertsson et al. (2016) to study
the behavior of exchange rates and capital flows in a global liquidity trap.
On the empirical side there is a large literature on the channels of con-
tagion during the global financial crisis. This literature has found it surpris-
ingly difficult to relate the strength of contagion to conventional measures
of economic openness. Rose and Spiegel (2011) considered a wide range of
indicators in the precrisis data that might predict the cross-country inci-
dence of the Great Recession and generally found no significant link between
these indicators and a variety of financial and real manifestations of the 2008
crisis. Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2011) find similar results. Kalemli-Ozcan,
Papaioannou, and Perri (2013) find that economies with stronger financial
ties to the United States were more affected by the global financial crisis
but establish this result only for developed economies. Hausmann-Guil,
van Wincoop, and Zhang (2016) present a model of self-fulfilling crises to
explain that integration did matter for contagion beyond some threshold.
There is a large literature on the determinants of productivity growth
and some involve international transactions. I am not aware of any studies
3. Earlier papers had studied the international propagation of liquidity traps; see, for example,
Fujiwara et al. (2013), Devereux and Yetman (2014), Cook and Devereux (2013), and Acharya
and Bengui (2016).
that have harnessed the theoretical insights from that literature to explore
the international transmission of secular stagnation. I discuss the relevant
literature in the next section. Adler et al. (2017) also discuss these channels
and present empirical evidence.
Productivity Spillovers
The main feature of secular stagnation is a persistent fall in productivity
growth. Total factor productivity (TFP) growth fell at about the same
time in countries with very different levels of economic development (see
table 5.1 for the sample of Asian countries). This concomitance is not
just a feature of the last ten years: De Gregorio (2017) shows that the TFP
growth of emerging-market economies has been correlated with that of
advanced economies since the 1960s, suggesting the existence of spill-
overs from advanced to less developed economies. However, there is no
well-established theory of international spillovers in productivity growth.
This section first discusses the theoretical channels through which secular
106 SUSTAINING
GRAPHICS ECONOMIC
- CHAPTER GROWTH IN ASIA
5—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA 1
stagnation in the rest of the world could affect productivity growth in a
country and then looks for evidence on these spillovers in the data.
Theory
Development economists distinguish between advanced economies that
are at the world technology frontier and less advanced economies that are
catching up to this frontier. Innovation determines productivity growth at the
frontier, while away from the frontier it is determined by the diffusion of the
technologies and processes that are used at the frontier. Technopessimists
such as Gordon (2016) or Fernald (2015) attribute secular stagnation to a
slowdown in productivity growth caused by a natural exhaustion of econ-
omies’ innovative potential. This view does not explain why productivity
growth also slowed down in countries that are catching up to the frontier
by adopting existing technologies rather than by innovating. Moreover, it
does not explain why productivity growth in these countries slowed during
the global financial crisis.
One possible explanation for the general slowdown in productivity
growth is that financial frictions may have spilled over across countries.
Financial frictions can bias business investment toward more liquid, low-
risk/low-return projects, which may in turn slow technological progress
embodied in new capital goods or resulting from risky investments. For
example, Caballero, Hoshi, and Kashyap’s (2008) model shows how banking
problems in Japan may have persistently depressed Japanese productivity
growth. Anzoategui et al. (2016) propose a model in which an increase in
demand for liquidity, as observed during the crisis, decreases investment
and productivity growth. In a financially integrated world, lower produc-
tivity growth could be transmitted across countries through financial
channels. This is a plausible channel of transmission for the global finan-
cial crisis, where global banks seem to have played a significant role in the
transmission of the crisis from advanced to emerging-market economies
(Cetorelli and Goldberg 2011).
Secular stagnation could also be diffused via international trade in
goods and services. Economic researchers have often noted the simulta-
neous slowing of productivity growth and of trade integration after the
global financial crisis (IMF 2016). According to the learning-by-exporting
hypothesis, export participation improves productivity. A firm’s expected
profits from process or product innovation rise with the size of the final
market so that increased exports allow firms to bear higher fixed costs
of research and development (Rodrik 1988, Yeaple 2005). Alternatively,
trade flows might facilitate international knowledge spillovers and thus
contribute to the adoption of new technologies (Coe and Helpman 1995).
If this is true, the fact that many advanced economies reduced their demand
INTERNATIONAL TRANSMISSION AND POLICY SPILLOVERS 107
for imports after the global financial crisis could result in lower produc-
tivity growth in the rest of the world.
Finally, the spillovers could result from the fact that productivity is
endogenous to demand—consistent with the hysteresis view that cyclical
changes in demand have a permanent impact on output. For example,
Benigno and Fornaro (2017) present a model in which low demand leads
to low productivity growth because firms spend less on productivity-
enhancing activities. A fall in global demand could thus lead to a gener-
alized decrease in productivity growth even in a model where there is no
learning-by-exporting.
Evidence
Several branches of empirical literature are relevant to quantify the theo-
retical mechanisms discussed above, but they have not been systematically
harnessed to analyze the international transmission of secular stagnation.
There is a large empirical literature on the link between exporting and
productivity growth based on firm-level evidence.4 Whereas Keller’s (2004)
review of the literature concluded that there is little evidence of a strong
learning-by-exporting effect, recent research was more supportive of such
effects (see Bustos 2011, De Loecker 2007, Lileeva and Trefler 2010). One
problem with applying this research to the analysis of secular stagnation is
that the results from studies based on firm-level data are often difficult to
translate to the aggregate level.5
One line of literature investigates the financial channels of contagion
during the global financial crisis and in the global financial cycle, but it
does not make the link to productivity (Hausmann-Guil, van Wincoop,
and Zhang 2016). Another line of literature has investigated how produc-
tivity is determined by the efficiency of factor allocation and in particular
the quality of financial intermediation. For example, Adler et al. (2017)
report that TFP growth fell more in companies with weaker balance sheets
prior to the global financial crisis than in their counterparts with stronger
balance sheets. But to the best of my knowledge this literature has not
quantified the extent to which secular stagnation is transmitted interna-
tionally through financial channels.
The remainder of this section investigates the channels of international
2 GRAPHICSINTERNATIONAL
- CHAPTER 5—SUSTAINING
TRANSMISSION AND POLICY
ECONOMIC IN ASIA 109
SPILLOVERS
GROWTH
of de jure financial openness. This index is based on binary variables that
codify the tabulation of restrictions on cross-border financial transactions
reported in the International Monetary Fund’s Annual Report on Exchange
Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions (AREAER). The other indicators are
measures of de facto financial integration. The explanatory variable used in
the second column of the table is the ratio of the sum of total foreign assets
plus total foreign liabilities to GDP based on the data in Lane and Milesi-
Ferretti (2017)—a measure that has often been used in the literature. The
last measure is similar to the second one but is limited to the “other invest-
ments” category in foreign assets and liabilities in an attempt to capture
international banking integration. All the indicators of financial integra-
tion are taken in 2007, the year before the crisis erupted.
Several observations can be made from the regression results in table
5.2. First, trade integration has a negative impact on TFP growth in all
three specifications and the point estimates are economically significant.
For example, the coefficient reported in the second column implies that,
other things equal, having a 10 percent larger exports-to-GDP ratio in 2007
lowered postcrisis TFP growth by about 0.14 percent per year. However,
this relationship is not statistically significant in any of the regressions.
Second, the impact of de jure financial integration is statistically signif-
icant whereas the impact of de facto integration is not. The impact of de
jure financial openness seems to be large. Based on my estimates, increasing
de jure financial openness from the Chinese to the US level is associated
with a 1.8 percent reduction in TFP growth after the crisis. However, this
effect seems too large to be interpreted as reflecting causality from finan-
cial openness to productivity growth and it is difficult to understand given
that the main channel through which de jure openness should matter is by
fostering de facto integration, and I find that de facto integration itself has
no impact on productivity growth.
To summarize, postcrisis TFP growth seems orthogonal to most mea-
sures of international economic integration (with the exception of de jure
financial openness). The weakness of the relationship between postcrisis
TFP growth and economic openness is robust to changes in the regression
specification. I tried many variants of the regressions reported in table 5.2.
For example, I looked at the impact on productivity growth of a decrease in
the demand for each country’s exports, where demand was measured based
on postcrisis growth in the country’s regional export markets. The country
sample was changed in different ways, for example, by excluding oil export-
ers or including only emerging-market and developing economies. Extreme
observations were excluded. I used growth in GDP per capita (instead of
TFP), which yielded several more years of data after the crisis. Standard
The main variables are the net foreign assets at, the net trade balance xt, the
real exchange rate qt, and the domestic and foreign real rates of interest rt
lim 𝑟𝑟�∗is�denoted
and rt*. The derivative of a variable 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ and lim with𝑦𝑦a�∗ dot.
� 𝑦𝑦� ∗
���� ����
The first equation is the balance-of-payments equation: the rate of
increase in net foreign assets at is equal to the trade balance xt plus the
return on foreign assets. The trade balance is an increasing function of the
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦� ∗ � � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ 𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ � � �
real exchange rate qt and of foreign demand yt*. The real exchange rate is
defined in such a way that an increase in q corresponds to a real deprecia-
tion. A real depreciation shifts domestic and foreign spending toward the
home good. 𝑟𝑟̅ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗
The second equation describes𝑎𝑎� � � the , 𝑦𝑦�∗ � � 𝑟𝑟�∗ 𝑎𝑎of
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�dynamics � foreign assets. Foreign
∗� �
assets converge toward a desired� 𝑎𝑎� �level
� 𝜎𝜎�𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟 , which
� � 𝑎𝑎� a function of the return
is
∗
𝑟𝑟
on these assets. The desired stock� of net � 𝑟𝑟 � 𝑞𝑞� /𝑞𝑞
foreign wealth is an increasing
𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟��∗ � � �𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�� , 𝑦𝑦�∗ �
function of the interest rate. This is a shortcut to capture the foreign asset
dynamics resulting from open-economy models with overlapping genera-
tions such as Coeurdacier, Guibaud, and Jin (2015) or Eggertsson et al.
lim 𝑟𝑟�∗ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ and lim 𝑦𝑦�∗ � 𝑦𝑦� ∗
(2016) (although the dynamics of net foreign 𝑞𝑞 � � 𝑞𝑞
�� assets are more complicated ����
����
��
in these models).
( � � �)The third equation is interest parity. The domestic real rate of interest
��
is equal to the foreign rate plus the rate of real exchange rate depreciation. 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦� ∗ � � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ 𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ � � �
∗
𝑟𝑟 � 𝑟𝑟
As a starting point perfect financial integration is assumed, implying that
� �
𝑞𝑞� � 𝑞𝑞��
𝑎𝑎� � � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞� , 𝑦𝑦�∗ � � 𝑟𝑟�∗ 𝑎𝑎�
exports, yt . The question
∗
� 𝑎𝑎� � � 𝜎𝜎�𝑎𝑎of ∗
��𝑟𝑟interest
� � � 𝑎𝑎� � is how capital flows, the real interest
∗
� 𝑟𝑟�∗ 𝑎𝑎� 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟� �
rate, and the real exchange rate𝑞𝑞� � /𝑞𝑞
must
� respond to ensure full employment
� 𝑎𝑎� � at home.
𝑎𝑎
/𝑞𝑞
� Let us summarize a few key properties of the model, starting with the
�
long run. 𝑎𝑎� � � I𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞
assume ∗ that ∗ foreign variables converge
𝑟𝑟�∗ 𝑎𝑎� 𝑟𝑟toward
𝑎𝑎� � � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞� , 𝑦𝑦�∗ � � lim ∗ long-run values
� , 𝑦𝑦� � � 𝑟𝑟� 𝑎𝑎� ∗ ∗
�∗
� � 𝑟𝑟̅ and lim 𝑦𝑦� � 𝑦𝑦
denoted
∗ �� 𝑎𝑎� ∗with
𝑎𝑎� � � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞� , 𝑦𝑦� � 𝑟𝑟�� � bars: ∗�
𝑎𝑎� 𝜎𝜎�𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟� � 𝑎𝑎� � ∗ ����
� 𝑎𝑎� � � 𝜎𝜎�𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟� � � 𝑎𝑎� � ����
� 𝑎𝑎� � � 𝜎𝜎�𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟
lim
∗
� � 𝑟𝑟� ∗ 𝑎𝑎𝑟𝑟�� �
∗
∗ 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑞𝑞� � /𝑞𝑞� ∗
� ∗. 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟�∗ � 𝑞𝑞� � /𝑞𝑞�
∗ � �� 𝑟𝑟̅ and lim 𝑦𝑦� � 𝑦𝑦
𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟�����
� 𝑞𝑞� � /𝑞𝑞� ����
∗
lim 𝑟𝑟� � ∗
In𝑟𝑟̅the and 𝑦𝑦�∗ the
limrun
long � 𝑦𝑦� ∗country’s foreign assets converge
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦� ∗ � �to
𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ 𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ �. �
It �then
���� ����
follows from the balance-of-payments equation that the real exchange rate
lim 𝑟𝑟�∗ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ and lim 𝑦𝑦�∗ �lim𝑦𝑦� ∗ 𝑟𝑟�∗ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ and lim 𝑦𝑦�∗ � 𝑦𝑦� ∗
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦� ∗ � and
is constant � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ 𝑎𝑎
��𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ � � � ∗
satisfies ∗
����
∗ ∗
���� ���� ����
lim 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟̅ and lim 𝑦𝑦� � 𝑦𝑦�
���� ����
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦� ∗ � � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ 𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ � � �. 𝑟𝑟̅ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗
lim
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞 �, 𝑟𝑟
𝑦𝑦
�∗∗
�
� � 𝑞𝑞∗𝑟𝑟̅�and
𝑟𝑟̅ ∗� 𝑞𝑞
𝑎𝑎
��𝑟𝑟̅ ��∗ �lim � �𝑦𝑦 ∗
� 𝑦𝑦
� ∗
���� That is, the domestic
�
����
� interest rate decreases by the ∗same 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟�∗
amount as the
lim 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ and lim 𝑦𝑦�∗ � 𝑦𝑦� ∗
foreign interest rate in the long run. This is 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞 an implication
�𝑦𝑦� �,𝑞𝑞���𝑦𝑦�� �𝑟𝑟̅�𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅
𝑞𝑞��,𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞
���� ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ of
∗ perfect
∗
� ����
𝑟𝑟̅ 𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅ ���� � finan-
𝑞𝑞� � 𝑞𝑞��
𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟�∗ �cial � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞 integration.
� , 𝑦𝑦 ∗�
� 𝑟𝑟 � � 𝑟𝑟 ∗
� 𝑞𝑞 � 𝑞𝑞
��
lim 𝑟𝑟�∗ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ and �� � limtransition 𝑦𝑦 ∗ � 𝑦𝑦�∗ ∗ dynamics ��
� it = rt + π.
���� ( �,
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞 The
�𝑦𝑦�𝑟𝑟̅∗�)
���� ���� 𝑟𝑟̅𝑟𝑟̅∗ �∗𝑟𝑟𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅
∗ � � � ( � �are �) different. Assume that foreign secular
�� � � 𝑟𝑟 � � �
( � � �) stagnation is�“announced” at time t = 0 in an equilibrium 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦�∗ ∗ �where
� ∗ the
��𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ � initial
�� it = rt + π. ∗ 𝑟𝑟̅ 𝑎𝑎 ��
a ∗𝑟𝑟̅ �𝑟𝑟̅𝑟𝑟̅� 𝑟𝑟̅
foreign
𝑞𝑞� � 𝑞𝑞�� assets are equal to zero ( 0
= 0 ). Then, 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟 � 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟�∗
it =∗ rt + π. ∗ 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟� ∗
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦� ∗ �𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎
���𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟̅ ∗�∗𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅
� �𝑟𝑟̅�𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞 � 𝑟𝑟̅��∗, 𝑦𝑦� �.
�
it = rt +∗π. ∗ 𝑟𝑟̅ � ∗
∗ 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ �
it = rt + π.
The impact of foreign secular stagnation (lower 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎
���𝑟𝑟 �� � �𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞
and � , 𝑦𝑦��)�, 𝑦𝑦on
� 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞 � the real
i t = rt + π.
∗
𝑟𝑟exchange
� � 𝑟𝑟�∗ rate is ambiguous in the short run. On one hand, the lower
𝑟𝑟̅ � 𝑟𝑟̅ 𝑞𝑞
𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟��∗demand
foreign ���𝑞𝑞��𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞� , 𝑦𝑦�∗ �should be offset by a real depreciation (an increase in
q ). On the other hand, the lower foreign interest rate 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟�∗ �leads � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞to ∗
��
� , 𝑦𝑦capital
it =0 rt + π. 𝑞𝑞� � 𝑞𝑞�𝑞𝑞��� 𝑞𝑞��
inflows that have an expansionary effect on the domestic economy. The
𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟�∗real exchange
� � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞 ,��𝑦𝑦� �∗�
�(𝑞𝑞 rate
��� �𝑞𝑞��� �) depreciates only if the impact of lower foreign demand
𝑟𝑟 �� �� 𝑟𝑟(∗���) 1
dominates � �that of higher domestic demand. In general the real exchange
𝑞𝑞� � 𝑞𝑞��
rate depreciates less in the short run than in the long 𝑟𝑟 �
run,
𝑟𝑟 ∗ ∗
1 � 𝑟𝑟� �� 𝑟𝑟�
�� �
𝑞𝑞� � i𝑞𝑞t��=. rt + π. (�� � �)
1 𝑟𝑟 � 𝑟𝑟 ∗
� �
it = ritt =+ rπ.t + π. ∗
1 𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟� 1
it = rt + π. 1
𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟�∗ INTERNATIONAL TRANSMISSION AND POLICY SPILLOVERS 113
it = rt + π.
𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟� � � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞� , 𝑦𝑦� �
lim 𝑟𝑟�∗ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ and lim 𝑦𝑦�∗ � 𝑦𝑦� ∗
���� ����
𝑞𝑞� � 𝑞𝑞��
∗�
� 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗implies
𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞�, 𝑦𝑦� This 𝑎𝑎��𝑟𝑟̅ ∗ � �that
� the real exchange rate must depreciate over time (�� � � �)
��
so that by interest parity
𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟�∗.
𝑟𝑟̅ � 𝑟𝑟̅ ∗
In the short run the domestic rate of interest decreases by less than the
= rt + π. rate—the interest rate pass-through is less than one-for-one.
itforeign
It is important to observe that foreign secular stagnation must lead
𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎��𝑟𝑟�∗ � � 𝑥𝑥�𝑞𝑞� , 𝑦𝑦�∗ �
initially to a boom in capital inflows and an expansion in domestic
demand. These spillovers are part and parcel of the adjustment process to
secular stagnation abroad. Low foreign interest rates are expansionary and
𝑞𝑞� � 𝑞𝑞�� demand must increase to offset the fall in foreign demand.
domestic
However, this adjustment process may have problematic side effects.
The first one comes from the zero bound on the nominal interest rate. The
analysis has been in real terms so far but it is not difficult to introduce
𝑟𝑟� � 𝑟𝑟�∗ policy. The home central bank determines the nominal interest
monetary
rate i, which is equal to the real interest rate plus inflation
1
it = rt + π..
Let us assume that inflation is equal to the inflation target, π, which is exog-
enously determined. In general nothing guarantees that the natural rate of
interest should be positive. If the inflation target is too low, the implied
nominal interest rate may hit the zero lower bound. Then the economy falls
into a liquidity trap with some unemployment.
The second side effect is related to the booms in capital inflows and
domestic demand. These developments may lead to excessive growth in
domestic credit and asset prices. The associated risks could in principle be
kept in check by using macroprudential policy, but not all countries have
the appropriate policy instruments and frameworks in place.
1 So far the analysis here has assumed perfect financial integration, but
the analysis can easily be extended to the case where the arbitrage between
foreign and domestic bonds is limited by financial frictions, risk premia,
or capital controls. For that, one simply needs to replace rt∗ by rt∗ + τt in the
model, where the wedge τt could be interpreted as a risk premium or a tax
on capital inflows. Then it is easy to see that the country can insulate its
interest rate from foreign secular stagnation by increasing τt as the foreign
interest rate rt∗ goes down. This policy can prevent the country from falling
into a liquidity trap. However, it could be viewed as mercantilist as it
requires the real exchange rate to depreciate earlier and by a larger amount
as the country keeps foreign capital out. The real interest rate can be insu-
lated at the cost of a larger response in the real exchange rate.
15
10
0
2000−07 2008–16 2000−07 2008−16 2000−07 2008−16
Advanced non-Asia Emerging and Emerging and
developing Asia developing non-Asia
Note: The figure compares the level of the interest rate before the crisis
(2000–07) and after the crisis (2008–16). Country classification is from the IMF
World Economic Outlook and averages are GDP-weighted.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.
Interest Rates
Having established a theoretical benchmark for the macroeconomic spill-
overs associated with secular stagnation, this section looks at interest rates
in the data.
Figure 5.1 compares the levels of interest rates before the global finan-
cial crisis (2000–07) and after the crisis (2008–16). The upper and lower
panels, respectively, show the nominal policy rate and the real interest rate.
The figure compares non-Asian advanced economies with emerging-market
and developing economies, both in Asia (middle bars) and outside Asia
(right bars).
The figure shows several interesting facts. First, the zero bound con-
straint on the nominal interest rate has not prevented advanced economies
from lowering the real interest rate into negative territory after the crisis as
2008−16 (percent)
15
Advanced
Emerging and developing
MNG
MMR
10
VNM
IND IDN
PNG
5 BGD
PHL
CHN
MYS AUSNZL
THA
TWN
NPL
KOR
JPN SGP HKG
0
0 5 10 15
2000−07 (percent)
Note: The figure does not include countries that had a precrisis interest rate
in excess of 15 percent. Most countries are located below the 45 degree line
because their policy rate was reduced after the crisis. See table 5.1 for country
key.
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.
6. Bulgaria has a currency board with the euro. No other emerging-market economy had a
policy rate below 0.5 percent in any year after 2008.
Credit
Real interest rates have gone down in emerging-market and developing
economies. What was the impact on credit conditions? Rebalancing the
economy from foreign to domestic demand is a natural adjustment to
foreign secular stagnation, as shown in the model presented earlier. This
rebalancing could be accompanied by an increase in domestic credit. At
the same time, this expansion is problematic if it is excessive and leads to
a boom-bust cycle. The buildup of excessive credit features prominently in
discussions about financial crises. Importantly, from a policy perspective,
large credit expansions have been found to be a reliable early warning indi-
cator of banking crises or severe distress. Some models, such as Eggertsson
and Krugman (2012), explain secular stagnation in advanced economies by
the deleveraging in the private nonfinancial sector that took place after the
crisis. An excessive expansion of credit in emerging-market and developing
economies might generate concerns about a delayed transmission of secular
stagnation from advanced economies.
I look into this question by using the credit gap measures produced
by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS). BIS measures the credit-
to-GDP gap as the deviation of the credit-to-GDP ratio from its long-run
trend. This measure takes account of all sources of credit to the private
nonfinancial sector, rather than just bank credit. Drehmann (2013) finds
that total credit developments predict the risk of systemic crises better
than indicators based solely on bank credit.
Figure 5.3 shows the credit gap in advanced and emerging-market econ-
omies between 2000 and 2016. Advanced economies witnessed a sharp ex-
pansion of credit, followed by a sharp restriction after the global financial
crisis. By contrast, the credit gap expanded continuously in emerging-mar-
ket and developing economies. The magnitude of this development reflects
primarily the expansion of credit in China (the credit gap of emerging-mar-
ket economies is heavily influenced by China because the average is GDP-
weighted). But the credit gap did not expand just in China. In Asia, Hong
Kong, Singapore, and to a lesser extent Thailand, Indonesia, and Malaysia
also experienced large increases in their credit gaps.
Why do some countries have credit booms while others do not? I
found no significant cross-country correlation between credit booms and
INTERNATIONAL TRANSMISSION AND POLICY SPILLOVERS 119
Figure 5.3 Credit gap, 2000–16
percent
15 Emerging-market and
developing economies—Asia
10
5 Emerging-market
and developing
economies
−5
Advanced economies
−10
2000 2005 2010 2015
Note: The figure shows the credit gaps as measured by the Bank for International
Settlements. Country classification is from the IMF’s World Economic Outlook
(see table 5.1 for Asian countries). Averages are GDP-weighted.
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; Bank for International Settlements.
low real or nominal interest rates in the data (the regression results are
not reported here). In the case of China the expansion in credit was driven
by administrative measures rather than lower market interest rates. As
shown in figure 5.4 the intensity of macroprudential measures significantly
increased after the crisis in emerging-market economies and especially in
Asia. Macroprudential policy thus appropriately leaned against the wind
but without fully containing the underlying pressure. Anecdotal evidence
suggests, in the case of China, that macroprudential restrictions often
moved the credit growth pressure from one area of the economy to another
without having serious effects on total credit.
The model presented earlier suggests that domestic financial develop-
ments may be related to the rebalancing of the economy toward domestic
demand associated with a decrease in the current account balance, i.e., an
increase in net capital inflows. Indeed, one variable that is clearly corre-
lated with credit is the current account balance. Figure 5.5 plots the change
in the credit gap between 2007 and 2016, on the vertical axis, against the
change in the current account balance over the same period, on the hori-
zontal axis. All variables are in share of GDP. There is very significant nega-
tive correlation between the two variables.
120 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
Figure 5.4 Intensity of macroprudential policies, 2000–13
intensity
5
Emerging-market and
developing economies—Asia
Emerging-market and
3 developing economies
2
Advanced economies
On average the countries that had credit booms also saw an increase in
net capital inflows (or a decrease in net capital outflows). The line of best fit
implies that a 1 percent increase in net capital inflows is associated with a
3.7 percent increase in the credit gap. Several Asian emerging-market econo-
mies are in the upper-left quadrant of the figure—countries that had both a
decrease in the current account balance and an increase in domestic credit.
One might interpret this correlation as a manifestation of the global
financial cycle, with credit booms being financed by capital inflow surges.7
But there are several reasons why this is probably not the main explanation
for the correlation observed in figure 5.5. First, the current account balance
measures net capital outflows, not the much larger gross capital flows that
analysts have focused on in recent discussions of the global financial cycle.
Second, the figure focuses on a relatively long period (nine years), which
is the appropriate frequency to study secular stagnation but probably too
long for the global financial cycle. Third, several countries close to the
7. Studies on the correlation between capital inflows and credit include Magud, Reinhart,
and Vesperoni (2014) and Avdjiev et al. (2017).
50
MYS THA
SGP
CHN
HKG JPN
IDN
0 KOR
IND AUS
NZL
−50
−100
−20 −10 0 10 20
change in current account balance (percent)
regression line were not severely affected by the global financial cycle. For
example, it is clear in the case of China that the decrease in its current
account balance and the concomitant increase in domestic credit are not
the result of a surge in capital inflows. Rather, the Chinese authorities had
to compensate for the decrease in foreign demand by raising domestic
demand, which they did through a credit stimulus.
An interpretation of figure 5.5 that is more in line with the model
presented earlier is that changes in credit reflect demand rebalancing that
followed the global financial crisis. The crisis was followed by a contrac-
tion in current account surpluses and deficits. The countries in the upper-
left quadrant of the plot are countries that, like China, had to stimulate
domestic demand in order to offset the reduction in foreign demand. The
countries in the lower-right quadrant of the plot are advanced economies
that, like the United States, had to reduce their current account deficits
and their domestic demand after the crisis (in Asia this group includes
Australia and New Zealand). The main takeaway from the figure is that
changes in domestic demand were strongly correlated with changes in
domestic credit during that period.
Conclusion
This analysis revolved around two symptoms of secular stagnation, low
productivity growth and low interest rates. Productivity growth and interest
rates have decreased everywhere since the early 1990s, with the global finan-
cial crisis marking a watershed in these developments. During the crisis,
spillovers went from the advanced economies that were at the epicenter of
the banking crisis to the rest of the world. Thus this chapter uses the global
financial crisis as a “natural experiment” that can shed light on the mecha-
nisms of international transmission of secular stagnation.
Productivity growth has decreased in advanced economies as well as
countries that are far from the technology frontier. This is puzzling because
the determinants of growth should not be the same in the former and in
the latter. The chapter discussed several channels involving trade and finan-
cial flows by which low productivity growth could spill over from advanced
to developing economies. However, the analysis of the data in this chapter
does not support the importance of these channels, and the reason why TFP
growth fell in so many countries at about the same time remains a mystery. I
doubt that much more information can be obtained from the type of cross-
country regressions presented in this chapter and believe that more efforts
should be put into extracting information from firm-level evidence, along
the lines of Adler et al. (2017).
Nominal interest rates hit the zero lower bound in most advanced
economies at the time of the global financial crisis, whereas they did not
seem to change very much in the rest of the world. However, this analysis
found that real interest rates decreased by the same amount in emerging-
market economies as in advanced economies. There is no evidence that
countries that were more closed financially were willing or able to insulate
their interest rates from foreign secular stagnation.
INTERNATIONAL TRANSMISSION AND POLICY SPILLOVERS 123
Low interest rate environments can have a number of adverse effects.
One is to push the economy into a liquidity trap where monetary policy
loses a lot of its traction. Another potential problem is the emergence of
unsustainable booms in capital inflows, credit, and asset prices. To some
degree credit and asset price increases should be expected as they are part
of the natural process of adjustment to foreign secular stagnation. But
these developments, if excessive and left unchecked, can also lead to costly
financial crises down the road.
Asian advanced economies behaved similarly to advanced economies
elsewhere. They had relatively low levels of inflation and nominal interest
rates before the crisis and were pulled toward liquidity traps at the time
of the crisis. Leaving Japan aside, nominal interest rates fell closest to zero
in Hong Kong and Singapore, followed by Korea and Taiwan. Australia
and New Zealand were somewhat less affected because these countries had
higher real and nominal interest rates before the crisis.
Emerging-market and developing economies generally remained at a
safe distance from liquidity traps (with Thailand perhaps an exception in
Asia). These countries were protected not so much by lower levels of inter-
national financial integration as by the fact that they had higher levels of
nominal interest rates before the crisis. This is due in part to higher infla-
tion than in advanced economies but also to higher real interest rates. Thus
what could be construed as a cost of low financial integration (a higher
cost of capital) became somewhat of a blessing in an environment of global
secular stagnation.
As for the other potential cost of low interest rates—the risk of unsus-
tainable credit booms—evidence shows that the credit boom that turned
to a bust in advanced economies was replaced by a credit boom of even
greater magnitude in emerging-market economies. Excessive expansion of
credit generates concerns of a delayed transmission of secular stagnation
from advanced economies. Global secular stagnation could enter a new
phase if the emerging-market credit boom turned into a bust.
References
Acharya, Sushant, and Julien Bengui. 2016. Liquidity Traps, Capital Flows and Currency
Wars. University of Montreal. Photocopy.
Adler, Gustavo, Romain Duval, Davide Furceri, K. Sinem, Ksenia Koloskova, and Marcos
Poplawski-Ribeiro. 2017. Gone with the Headwinds: Global Productivity. IMF Staff Discussion
Note 17/04. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Andrews, Dan, Chiara Criscuolo, and Peter N. Gal. 2016. The Best versus the Rest: The Global
Productivity Slowdown, Divergence across Firms and the Role of Public Policy. OECD Productiv-
ity Working Paper 5. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Anzoategui, Diego, Diego Comin, Mark Gertler, and Joseba Martinez. 2016. Endogenous Tech-
nology Adoption and R&D as Sources of Business Cycle Persistence. NBER Working Paper 22005.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Economists used to play a game asking which country was turning Japa-
nese. Back in 2003, I wrote a paper playing off this game, where I assessed
whether Germany might fall into a Japan-like trap of persistent low growth
(Posen 2003). Today, the fear of suffering Japan’s fate persists for advanced
economies, including those in Asia (see chapter 8 by Dongchul Cho and
Kyooho Kwon in this volume). But the analogy is mistaken. Rather than
focusing on the risk of turning Japanese in the late 1990s sense, it would be
better for countries in Asia to learn how Japan got itself off the growth floor
from 2003 to 2018. It is true that both productivity growth and labor force
growth have slowed in most of the advanced economies and an increasing
number of emerging markets, even in Asia.
There is a popular but incorrect characterization of Japan as having suf-
fered two lost decades. Japan lost one decade, where the effect of an asset
price collapse was prolonged and deepened by a set of idiosyncratic Japan-
specific factors, many of which were due to policy (Posen 2010, Kuttner
and Posen 2002). The lost decade ended with the Koizumi administration
and the cleanup of the country’s banks in late 2002/early 2003. Since then,
per capita GDP growth in Japan has actually been quite good, especially in
comparison to the rest of the G-7 nations, even leaving aside the global fi-
nancial crisis. Productivity growth has been decent. If anything, the macro-
economic challenges that Japan faced in failing to increase inflation and to
Adam S. Posen is the president of the Peterson Institute for International Economics.
129
reduce government debt have been faced simultaneously by other countries
and so are no longer Japan-specific. The puzzling failure of inflation to in-
crease, despite best-practice aggressive monetary policy, remains troubling
but should not obscure the progress in the real economy.
Japan’s growth and productivity performance stands out against demo-
graphic decline at home and increasing stagnation and even crisis among
many of its trading partners. The eventual cleanup of the financial system
and reversal of mistaken contractionary macroeconomic policies were nec-
essary to end the decline (Posen 2010). But they are not sufficient to explain
the long and resilient subsequent recovery. Instead, Japan took major steps
to address the sources of secular stagnation that were open to domestic ame-
lioration: using the fiscal room still available to smooth exogenous shocks
like the Fukushima natural disasters and the spillovers from the global fi-
nancial crisis; partially offsetting the demographic-driven shrinkage of the
labor force by increasing female labor force participation and employment
flexibility; and in recent years, under Prime Minister Shinzō Abe, pursu-
ing greater economic integration with the world, notably via the Compre-
hensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP)
and EU-Japan trade agreements. These steps were taken slowly and did not
fulfill all the promises of Abenomics, let alone the free market fantasies of
some Western commentators. These three initiatives, however, when accel-
erated by Abe, did materially improve Japan’s real economic performance
and resilience. As such, this three-part framework—fiscal stabilization, labor
market reform, and trade integration—provides a useful model for emerg-
ing Asia today.
Reconsidering the Japanese experience along these lines raises three
questions. First, has recent underperformance in Japan been a puzzle for
modern macroeconomics? In other words, since Abenomics has basically
done many of the things that we were all calling for—including aggressive
monetary stimulus with a forward-looking positive inflation target—why
has it not resulted in consistently positive inflation near the target? I believe
that this can in part be explained by the overemphasis on a credibility-cen-
tered view of macroeconomic policy (Posen 2012) and by a failure to prop-
erly account for the effects of nonmonetary factors on inflation.
Second, does the apparent failure to raise the inflation rate in Japan
matter for economic performance? My sense is that it does, but much less
significantly than many of us initially thought. Despite consistently failing
to reach its inflation target, Japan never fell into the much feared deflation
spirals that the United States, for example, experienced in the 1930s. For
this reason, the growth and welfare costs of low inflation are much lower
than we initially believed, although they are not negligible.
References
Daly, Mary C., Bart Hobijn, and Benjamin Pyle. 2016. What’s Up with Wage Growth? FRBSF
Economic Letter 2016-07 (March 7). San Francisco, CA: Federal Reserve Bank of San Fran-
cisco.
Friedman, Milton. 1963. Inflation: Causes and Consequences. Bombay: Asian Publishing House.
Koo, Richard. 2003. Balance Sheet Recession: Japan’s Struggle with Uncharted Economics and Its Glob-
al Implications. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley and Sons.
Krugman, Paul. 1998. It’s Baaack: Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity 29, no. 2: 137–206. Washington: Economic Studies Program,
Brookings Institution.
Kuttner, Kenneth N., and Adam S. Posen. 2002. Fiscal Policy Effectiveness in Japan. Journal of
the Japanese and International Economies 16, no. 4 (December): 536–58.
Posen, Adam S. 1998. Restoring Japan’s Economic Growth. Washington: Institute for Interna-
tional Economics.
Posen, Adam S. 2003. Is Germany Turning Japanese? Working Paper 03-2. Washington: Institute
for International Economics.
Japan has been suffering from secular stagnation since the economic bubble
burst in 1989–90. Its labor productivity stopped catching up with that
of the United States around 1990 (figure 7.1). In fact, labor productivity
(measured in purchasing power parity [PPP]) in Japan today is much lower
than in other major OECD countries except South Korea (figure 7.2). This
chapter examines the structural causes of Japan’s secular stagnation, focus-
ing on labor market issues.
A number of studies have attempted to identify the causes of Japan’s
secular stagnation. Most scholars seem to agree that there are two major
structural causes of the stagnation, and they are related to each other: in-
sufficient final demand (excess saving problem) and slow total factor pro-
ductivity (TFP) growth.1 When TFP growth is slow, fixed capital formation
becomes sluggish, which reduces final demand. On the other hand, when
there is excess supply, firms are reluctant to invest in intangibles, which
reduces TFP growth.
Based on this diagnosis, in early 2013 the Japanese government em-
barked on so-called Abenomics, which consists of three arrows: aggressive
monetary easing, fiscal stimulus, and a growth strategy (structural reforms)
to tackle the twin problems of insufficient demand and slow TFP growth
Kyoji Fukao is professor at the Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University, and president of the
Institute of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organization.
1. For a more general discussion of these structural causes, see Fukao (2013) and Fukao et
al. (2016b).
139
Figure 7.1 Labor productivity in Japan and the United States,
1947–2012
Korea
Japan
OECD—total
European Union
(28 countries)
Italy
United Kingdom
Canada
Euro area
(19 countries)
Australia
G-7
Germany
France
United States
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
US dollars in constant prices, 2010 PPP
index (1995 = 1)
1.02
1.01
1.00
0.99
0.98
0.97
0.96
0.95
1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015
simultaneously. The first two arrows seem to have resolved the problem of
insufficient demand to some extent. The recovery of major economies such
as the United States and China has helped gradually shrink the GDP gap,
which the Cabinet Office estimated had declined to minus 0.4 percent by
the fourth quarter of 2016. Japan’s labor market has also been tightening,
with the ratio of job openings to applicants reaching 1.45 in March 2017,
the highest since November 1990.
Major structural reforms of the third arrow are (1) stimulating private
investment in targeted sectors such as medical services, renewable energy,
and agriculture; (2) promoting female labor participation; (3) pushing for
the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP); and (4) deregulating targeted sectors,
such as healthcare, agriculture, and energy. Despite these reforms, the TFP
of Japan’s macroeconomy has hardly changed since 2013 (figure 7.3), and
private investment has not accelerated.
The disappointing results of the structural reforms prompted the
Japanese government in October 2015 to introduce Abenomics 2.0, labeled
“All 100 Million Playing an Active Role” [Ichi-Oku Sou-Katsuyaku], which
consists of four pillars: (1) a strong economy (continuation of active mone-
tary and fiscal stimulus); (2) support for child rearing; (3) improvement of
the social security system; and (4) introduction of an “equal work, equal
pay” rule. The government also introduced life-work balance policies in
an attempt to reduce overtime work. These reforms focus more on labor
market and social policy issues than did the first round of reforms. This
change seems to partly reflect the new strategy of the ruling parties, the
Liberal Democratic Party and Komeito, to incorporate traditional policies
of the opposition party, the Democratic Party. At the same time, it also
Japan
Australia
Canada
Average
Korea
England/Northern
Ireland (United Kingdom)
Germany
United States
Austria
France
Italy
0.4
0.2
–0.2
–0.4
–0.6
–0.8
–1.0
Male Female Male Female Male Female
Note: The average and the standard deviation are calculated from all the microdata
of about 10,000 adults (both males and females) in the three countries.
Source: Kawaguchi (2017).
reflects the widespread view in Japan that labor market issues are the key
to Japan’s revitalization.
The OECD’s Survey of Adult Skills (PIAAC) ranks Japan at the top
among OECD countries in terms of adult proficiency in key information-
processing skills such as literacy, numeracy, and problem solving in tech-
nology-rich environments (figures 7.4 and 7.5 show results on literacy).
Note: Based on the item response theory (OECD 2013), Kawaguchi estimated these
scores from responses to questions on use of literacy proficiency at work. The
average and the standard deviation are calculated from all the microdata of about
10,000 adults (both males and females) in the three countries.
Source: Kawaguchi (2017).
Japan’s problem is that it does not fully utilize its labor, especially female
workers, whose proficiency is barely utilized at work (figure 7.6).
Greater utilization of workers’ proficiency would raise Japan’s productiv-
ity and labor efficiency. Since one of the main causes of insufficient demand
in Japan is the stagnation of capital formation, which is partly caused by
the shrinking working-age population and low TFP growth, labor market
reforms will also contribute to relieving Japan’s two structural problems.
This chapter analyzes two key issues in Japan’s labor market—nonreg-
ular employment and productivity and wage gaps between large and small
firms (dual labor market problem)—and derives policy implications.
2. In Japan, a regular employee “is generally considered as an employee who is hired directly
by his/her employer without a predetermined period of employment, and works for sched-
uled hours…. Consequently, a ‘nonregular employee’ is an employee who does not meet one
of the conditions for regular employment” (Asao 2011).
3. Nonmarket economy comprises general government and nonprofit institutions of educa-
tion, medical services, and other services.
percent
30
Nonmanufacturing (nonmarket economy)
25 Nonmanufacturing (market economy)
Manufacturing
Primary sector
20
15
10
0
1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010
Source: Japan Industrial Productivity Database 2015, Hitotsubashi University and Research
Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI).
is around 30 percent (figure 7.7). The wage gap between nonregular and
regular employees is large (figure 7.8). Wages of regular workers increase as
they get older and accumulate experience in the workplace.
Labor economists have argued that two factors are behind this upward
slope of the age-wage profile. First, as workers accumulate human capital,
their marginal contribution to production increases, which raises their
wages. Second, to enhance worker loyalty and incentivize them, firms defer
compensation until workers are older. Japanese firms provide active on-the-
job training and some off-the-job training for regular employees (Fukao et
al. 2009) but not much for nonregular employees. This may be why the age-
wage profile of regular employees in Japan is steeper than that in other de-
veloped countries (Fukao et al. 2006).
If the upward slope of the age-wage profile is mainly caused by an
increase in the marginal productivity of regular employees through the
accumulation of human capital, then the wage gap between regular and
nonregular workers in figure 7.8 can be regarded as representing the differ-
ence in labor quality between the two, meaning that the recent increase in
nonregular workers has important implications. Using the Japan Industrial
Productivity (JIP) Database,4 one can estimate the impact of the increase
percent
140
Regular
120 Nonregular
100
80
60
40
20
0
20–24 25–29 30–34 35–39 40–44 45–49 50–54 55–59 60–64 65–69
age group
Source: OECD (2017). The original data are from Ministry of Health, Labour, and
Welfare, Basic Survey on Wage Structure 2015. Overtime payments and bonuses
are not included.
5. Suppose that Japan is on the kind of balanced growth path assumed in standard neoclas-
sical growth models. An 8 percent improvement in labor quality will raise Japan’s real GDP by
8 percent. Since the labor income share in Japan is about two-thirds, 5.3 percentage points of
the increase in GDP will be due to the increase in (quality-adjusted) labor input and 2.7 per-
centage points will be due to the increase in capital input induced by the labor input increase.
6. The Japanese employment system for regular workers is also changing. Using microdata
from the Basic Survey on Wage Structure, Hamaaki et al. (2012) found that the age-wage profile
has become flatter in recent years.
7. Matsuura, Sato, and Wakasugi (2011) constructed a theoretical model in which trade liber-
alization encourages firms to reduce the number of products, which raises uncertainty about
the demand firms face. This change will increase firms’ demand for temporary workers. They
empirically test their model using microdata for Japanese manufacturing plants and find
moderate support for the model’s predictions.
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
15–19 20–24 25–29 30–34 35–39 40–44 45–49 50–54 55–59 60–64 65–69 70–
age group
b. Women
percent
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
15–19 20–24 25–29 30–34 35–39 40–44 45–49 50–54 55–59 60–64 65–69 70–
age group
Regular employees
Nonregular employees
Other
9. General Survey on Diversified Types of Employment 2014 conducted by the Ministry of Health,
Labour and Welfare (MHLW).
10. Andrews, Criscuolo, and Gal (2015) report that TFP differences between frontier firms,
which tend to be large and internationalized, and nonfrontier firms have been widening in
many OECD countries since the 2000s. However, since their data do not cover the 1990s, one
cannot judge whether such widening in TFP differences started in the 1990s like Japan or not.
value added
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0 O ny
Sl lan d
ov ds
Sp en
us n
Fr enia
ng nd
Tu ary
Ja ico
ec itz ree n
Un h R erla ce
ite ep nd
D ta ic
ite P nm es
d or ark
Be do l
G lgi m
er um
et o D
ed ia
A at ia
a
or ia
Sl Ita y
ov ly
nl e
to d
a
Is ey
ex l
ng ga
M rae
A ai
us vi
Fi nc
Cz Sw G pa
r n
ni
Es an
N P EC
S l
Sw ak
tr
N tral
e t
d ub
w
he la
Hu ela
rk
Ki tu
a
L
Ir
Un
percent
100
SMEs share of BERD
90 SMEs share of government-funded BERD
SMEs share of government-funded BERD, 2003
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
s
k
a
y
n
d
d
g
ic
ia
al
ia
ia
l
ry
lia
ile
ay
es
da
nd
nd
ce
ai
ar
um
re
om
tr
ur
e
nd
an
an
an
pa
an
ak
w
en
ra
la
ug
l
Ita
at
ga
na
Ch
an
gi
t
r
la
al
m
re
l
Sp
us
n
nl
gd
Ko
Ja
bo
or
nm
i
St
c
ov
e
Po
lo
G
n
Fr y
l
A
I
or
us
ze
E
e
er
Ca
F
N
m en
Z
Be
S
S
d
Hu ce
he
P
it
Re nia
A
D
G
Ki
xe
te
et ubl
d
ew ela
Sw
ch sto
N
ni
Lu we
N
ite
U
Cz
Un
151
matrices, we converted statistics by amount of paid-in capital into statistics
by number of workers. Data on labor input and wage rates by firm size and
by industry are obtained from MHLW’s Basic Survey on Wage Structure, which
provides information on wage rates by age, sex, education, and employment
status and working hours by firm size within each industry. One caveat re-
garding these statistics is that they do not cover firms with fewer than 10
employees.
For each year and industry, Fukao et al. (2014) decompose labor produc-
tivity differences between firm-size group s and s’ using the following equa-
tion:
V V 1 K K
ln s ln s ln qs ln qs s s ln s ln s
s
H s
H 2 s s
q H qs H s
ln RTFPs , s '
where
Vs: Nominal value added of firm-size group s,
Hs: Total hours worked in firm-size group s,
qs: Labor quality of firm-size group s,
νs: Cost share of capital in firm-size group s,
Ks: Capital service input of firm-size group s,
RTFPs,s’: Relative TFP level of firm-size group s compared with that of firm-
size group s’.
To calculate Jorgenson-Griliches-type labor quality indices, qs, our
study uses the industry average wage premium of each category of workers.
Therefore, the study assumes that there are no differences in labor quality
among the same type of workers across different firm-size groups—for
instance, male university-educated full-time workers aged 30–34 years in
large automobile firms and their counterparts in small automobile firms.
The results of our analyses for the total market economy are summa-
rized in figure 7.12a, which shows that there are huge wage and labor
productivity differences between large (with more than 999 employees) and
small firms (with fewer than 100 employees). Differences in capital-labor
ratios mainly cause labor productivity differences. However, TFP differences
also play an important role. The contribution of labor quality differences
is declining. Figure 7.12b shows that wage and productivity differences
between medium-sized firms (with 100 to 999 employees) and small firms
(with fewer than 100 employees) are not so large. Therefore, subsequent
figures show the results for wage and productivity differences between large
firms and small firms.
0.3
Total factor productivity
0.2 Capital-labor ratio
0.1 Labor quality
Labor productivity gap
0 Wage gap
1975 1980 1990 2000 2010
a. Light industry
log value
1.0
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
1975 1980 1990 2000 2010
b. Chemical industry
log value
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
Total factor productivity
Capital-labor ratio
0.2
Labor quality
Labor productivity gap
0 Wage gap
1975 1980 1990 2000 2010
(figure continues)
differences in education. The labor quality gap has declined over time and
was 7 percent in 2010. The decline was mainly caused by the increase in
nonregular employees in large firms (in figure 7.15, this factor is included
in “employment status”).
It is important to note that although the wage gap between the two
firm groups is more than 50 percent (figure 7.12a), measured labor quality
explains only 7 percentage points of this gap in 2010. Rebick (1993) reports
that in the United States, about one-third of firm-size wage differences are
explained by labor characteristics, such as education, experience, etc., while
154 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
Figure 7.13 Wage and productivity differences: Firms
with more than 999 employees/firms with
up to 99 employees, by manufacturing
sector, 1975–2010 (continued)
c. Machinery
log value
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.4 0.6
0.3 0.4
0.2
0.2
0.1
0 0
1975 1980 1990 2000 2010
–0.2
1975 1980 1990 2000 2010
1.0 0.6
0.5
0.8
0.4
0.6 0.3
0.4 0.2
0.1
0.2
0
0 1975 1980 1990 2000 2007
1975 1980 1990 2000 2010
11
–1
–3
–5
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
157
Source: Fukao et al. (2014).
Figure 7.16 Off-the-job training expenses (including opportunity
costs) by firm size, total market sector, 1975–2010
ratio
6
Firms with more than 999 employees/
5 firms with 30–99 employees
Firms with 100–999 employees/
firms with 30–99 employees
4
0
1975 1980 1990 2000 2010
GRAPHICS
Japan United States
SECULAR
2001 2006 2001 2006
Firm size (number Number of Percent Number of Percent Number of Percent Number of Percent
of employees) employees of total employees of total employees of total employees of total
- CHAPTER
1 to 4 1,486,150 4 1,574,110 5 5,866,666 5 6,262,490 5
5 to 9 2,176,265 7 1,993,335 6 6,844,090 6 7,274,534 6
STAGNATION
10 to 19 2,954,728 9 2,736,690 9 8,369,988 7 8,794,210 7
20 to 49 4,442,234 13 4,188,269 13 11,767,978 10 12,260,057 10
50 to 99 3,300,383 10 3,166,835 10 8,442,216 7 8,868,873 7
7—SUSTAINING
100 to 249 4,177,981 13 4,144,598 13 9,813,665 9 10,497,066 9
250 to 499 2,832,588 9 2,794,966 9 6,258,633 5 6,762,233 6
500 to 999 2,528,727 8 2,573,958 8 5,866,407 5 6,063,319 5
AND THEECONOMIC
1,000+ 9,274,478 28 8,935,484 28 51,128,895 45 52,125,133 44
Total 33,173,534 100 32,108,245 100 114,358,538 100 118,907,915 100
LABOR MARKET
Source: Fukao et al. (2016a). Original data are from the Establishment and Enterprise Census for Japan and
GROWTH
the Business Dynamics Statistics for the United States.
IN JAPAN
IN ASIA1591
References
Andrews, Dan, Chiara Criscuolo, and Peter Gal. 2015. Frontier Firms, Technology Diffusion and
Public Policy: Micro Evidence from OECD Countries. The Future of Productivity: Main Back-
ground Papers. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Asano, Hirokatsu, Takahiro Ito, and Daiji Kawaguchi. 2013. Why Has the Fraction of Non-
standard Workers Increased? A Case Study of Japan. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 60,
no. 4: 360–89.
Asao, Yutaka. 2011. Overview of Non-Regular Employment in Japan. In Non-Regular Employ-
ment–Issues and Challenges Common to the Major Developed Countries. JILPT Report, no. 10:
1–43. 2011 JILPT Seminar on Non-regular Employment. Tokyo: Japan Institute for La-
bour Policy and Training.
Bank of Japan. 2017. Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices, July 2017. Tokyo.
Belderbos, René, Kenta Ikeuchi, Kyoji Fukao, YoungGak Kim, and Hyeog Ug Kwon. 2013.
Plant Productivity Dynamics and Private and Public R&D Spillovers: Technological, Geographic and
Relational Proximity. CEI Working Paper Series, no. 2013-05. Center for Economic Institu-
tions, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University.
Brinton, Mary C. 2015. Japanese Low Fertility and the Low Labor Force Participation of Mar-
ried Women: The Role of Rigid Labor Markets and Workplace Norms. Perspectives from
Around the World, no. 56. Tokyo: Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry.
Fukao, Kyoji. 2013. Explaining Japan’s Unproductive Two Decades. Asian Economic Policy Re-
view 8, no. 2 (December): 193–213.
Fukao, Kyoji, and Hyeog Ug Kwon. 2006. Why Did Japan’s TFP Growth Slow Down in the
Lost Decade? An Empirical Analysis Based on Firm-Level Data of Manufacturing Firms.
Japanese Economic Review 57, no. 2: 195–228.
Fukao, Kyoji, Ryo Kambayashi, Daiji Kawaguchi, Hyeog Ug Kwon, YoungGak Kim, and Izumi
Yokoyama. 2006. Deferred Compensation: Evidence from Employer-Employee Matched
Data from Japan. Hi-Stat Discussion Paper Series, no. 187. Institute of Economic Research,
Hitotsubashi University.
Fukao, Kyoji, Tsutomu Miyagawa, Kentaro Mukai, Yukio Shinoda, and Konomi Tonogi.
2009. Intangible Investment in Japan: Measurement and Contribution to Economic
Growth. Review of Income and Wealth 55, no. 3: 717–36.
Fukao, Kyoji, Tatsuji Makino, Kenta Ikeuchi, Hyeog Ug Kwon, and YoungGak Kim. 2014.
Productivity and Wage Differences by Firm Size [in Japanese]. Japanese Journal of Labour
Studies, no. 649: 14–29.
Fukao, Kyoji, Kenta Ikeuchi, YoungGak Kim, and Hyeog Ug Kwon. 2016a. Why Was Japan
Left Behind in the ICT Revolution? Telecommunications Policy 40, no. 5: 432–49.
Fukao, Kyoji, Kenta Ikeuchi, HyeogUg Kwon, YoungGak Kim, Tatsuji Makino, and Miho
Takizawa. 2016b. The Structural Causes of Japan’s Lost Decades. In The World Economy,
Growth or Stagnation? ed. Dale W. Jorgenson, Kyoji Fukao, and Marcel P. Timmer. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Genda, Yuji. 1996. “Ability” or “Training”: Ability Difference Hypothesis on Firm-Size Wage
Differences [in Japanese]. Japanese Journal of Labour Studies, no. 430: 17–29.
Hamaaki, Junya, Masahiro Hori, Saeko Maeda, and Keiko Murata. 2012. Changes in the Japa-
nese Employment System in the Two Lost Decades. Industrial and Labor Relations Review
65, no. 4: 810–46.
Higuchi, Yoshio. 1994. University Education and Income Distribution [in Japanese]. In Income
and Wealth Distribution in Japan, ed. Tsuneo Ishikawa. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.
Jonathan Woetzel is director of the McKinsey Global Institute and a senior partner in McKinsey & Company’s
Shanghai office.
Since the global financial crisis in 2008, “secular stagnation” has become a
catchword for the economic conditions of advanced countries (see Summers
2014, among many others). Recovery from the crisis has been slow, and in-
flation has remained low, despite unprecedentedly aggressive monetary
policies. Asia has maintained relatively rapid growth, but the pace has been
slower than it was before the crisis. Japan is struggling to escape from a defla-
tion trap, and China is suffering from the aftereffects of the overinvestment
it pushed to counter the negative shocks from the global financial crisis.
The economic performance of Korea, the third-largest economy in East
Asia, has been weak. The average rate of growth over the past five years was
less than 3 percent, the lowest since the 1960s. The unfavorable global envi-
ronment undoubtedly affected Korea, but its growth rate has been on a
secular decline since the 1990s, well before the global crisis. The weakening
of its growth momentum has raised concerns that Korea may be following
in Japan’s footsteps, that “lost decades” may lie ahead. What factors underlie
Dongchul Cho is a member of the Monetary Policy Board of the Bank of Korea. Kyooho Kwon is a fellow at
the Korea Development Institute. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Bank of Korea or the Korea Development Institute. The authors are grateful to Shinwook Woo for
research assistance.
Figure 8.9 and table 8.2 in this chapter were produced using simulations of the overlapping generations model
from Kwon (2017b) published by the Korea Development Institute (KDI) Journal of Economic Policy. The au-
thors employed a Fortran code for their model that may be difficult to use to replicate the authors’ results without
their assistance. Accordingly, this chapter does not provide the Fortran code as part of the normal replication
package required by PIIE. PIIE does not assume responsibility for the calculations underlying figure 8.9 and
table 8.2 in this chapter. Anyone seeking further information should contact the authors at dccho@bok.or.kr
and kwonkh@kdi.re.kr.
165
the secular decline of Korea’s growth? What policies are needed to reverse,
or at least mitigate, the trend?
This chapter addresses these questions. The first section presents the
results of growth accounting and speculates on the likely path of the Korean
economy based on recent empirical evidence on total factor productivity
(TFP). The second section touches on the possibility of Korea’s “Japaniza-
tion,” by comparing Korea of today with Japan two decades ago. The third
section examines the decline in the natural interest rate (a result of the
decline in potential growth rate) and its implications for monetary policy.
The last section summarizes the chapter’s main results.
1. Korea’s fertility rate has been about 1.3 since 2000, lower than the rate in Japan and Germany.
2. It is sometimes argued that massive immigration or reunification with North Korea could
substantially change the demographic projections for Korea. This chapter does not consider
such scenarios.
10
–5
Korea
World
–10
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
rate can mitigate the downward trend for a while).3 Inasmuch as growth in
output slows as a result of labor contraction, the pace of aggregate capital
accumulation will also decline, assuming that Korea’s capital-to-output
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
ratio
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0 Korea
United States
1.5 Germany
Japan
1.0
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
ratio has reached a steady-state level. This argument can be concisely ex-
plained using the standard growth accounting formula:
4. Since Barro (1991) and Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992), the convergence argument—that
lower-income countries tend to grow faster than higher-income countries, conditional on
their fundamentals—has become a standard notion in the empirical growth literature.
5. The negative effects of population aging on TFP have been found over a wide range of
data. For European countries, for example, Aiyar, Ebeke, and Shao (2016) project that the
current age structure could lead to a reduction in TFP growth by an average of 0.2 percentage
points every year over the next two decades. Using prefectural data from Japan for 1990–
2007, Liu and Westelius (2016) find that aging of the working-age population has had a
significant negative impact on TFP.
6. Korea ranked 30th out of 33 member countries on the 2013 Product Market Regulation
Index of the OECD (2014).
0.5
–0.5
–1.0
1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070 2080 2090 2100 Korea
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070 2080 Japan
Canada Germany
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
Japan Korea
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
2 2
1 1
0 0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
Notes: Revealed comparative advantage is defined as the ratio of the share of the
item in the country’s exports to its share in world exports. The 1-digit Standard
International Trade Classification (SITC) codes on the horizontal axis are 0: Food
and live animals, 1: Beverages and tobacco, 2: Crude materials, inedible, except
fuels, 3: Mineral fuels, lubricants and related materials, 4: Animal and vegetable
oils, fats and waxes, 5: Chemicals and related products, n.e.s., 6: Manufactured
goods classified chiefly by material, 7: Machinery and transport equipment,
8: Miscellaneous manufactured articles, and 9: Commodities and transactions not
classified elsewhere in the SITC.
Source: UN Comtrade Database.
Korea’s per capita income also trails Japan’s by 20 years. Figure 8.6,
panel a, overlaps the trend of Korea’s nominal GDP growth rate with that of
Japan with a 20-year lag. The two series are almost indistinguishable. After a
similar pace of rapid growth for several decades, in 2010 Korea attained per
capita income of about $30,000—the level Japan reached in 1990.
Insofar as demography, industrial structure, and per capita income are
the crucial determinants of a country’s social and economic landscape, it
seems natural to study Japan’s history in order to draw a picture of Korea’s
future. An issue of interest is whether Korea will fall into chronic deflation,
16
12
–4
1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Korea
1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Japan
HP = Hodrick-Prescott filter
Sources: Bank of Korea; Cabinet Office of Japan (reproduced from
Cho and Kwon 2014).
as Japan did. Panel b of figure 8.6, which extends the Korean data to 2016,
appears to send a relieving signal. Unlike in panel a, Korea’s trend growth
in nominal GDP began deviating from that of Japan in the 2010s, implying
that Korea is not replicating Japan’s deflation. Korea’s inflation rate has
fallen to a worrisome level since 2013, but the pace of disinflation has been
slower than Japan faced after the bursting of its bubble in the 1990s.
The divergence between the two economies in terms of inflation/defla-
tion seems to stem from a difference in their real estate markets. Entering
the 1990s, Japan’s real estate market was in a bubble, the bursting of which
triggered a deflationary spiral that was too abrupt for the Bank of Japan to
a. Japan
index (2010=100)
230
Consumer price index
Land (residential) price index
180
130
80
30
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
b. Korea
index (2010=100)
120
110
100
90
80
70
7. For the debate on Japan’s monetary policy in the 1990s, see Hayami (2000), Kuttner and
Posen (2001), and Ito and Mishkin (2004), among many others.
8. Cho (2017) extracts the market’s capital gains expectations from the data on the unique
rental system of Korea, called chonsei, which cannot be assessed as “excessive” compared with
macroeconomic variables such as inflation and interest rates.
9. Cho (2017) compares Korea’s monetary policy with Japan’s, arguing that the Bank of
Korea responded passively to inflation/deflation pressures.
percent
25
Nominal interest rate
20 Real interest rate
15
10
–5
1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014
10. The effect of population aging on inflation is not as clear as its negative impact on
growth, because aging should reduce both aggregate demand and aggregate supply at the
same time. The empirical results are mixed. IMF researchers Yoon, Kim, and Lee (2014) and
Liu and Westelius (2016) present evidence from various data sets that aging operates as a
disinflationary factor. Using a larger data set, Juselius and Takáts (2015), of the Bank for
International Settlements, find that population aging is inflationary.
and 2015; over the same period, it dropped by about 1–2 percentage points
in advanced countries (Williams 2017).
To assess how much of the decline in (real) interest rates is attributable
to changes in real sector fundamentals, we conducted experiments similar to
those in Eggertsson, Mehrotra, and Robbins (2017) by using the overlapping
generations model of Kwon (2017b) for Korea.11 Table 8.2 summarizes the
effects of the counterfactual scenarios that the mortality rate, fertility rate,
rate of TFP progress, and relative price of capital goods have not changed
since 1990. Of the 4.3 percentage point decline in the natural interest rate
generated by the model between 1990 and 2015, 3.1 percentage points are
attributed to changes in these fundamental variables: 1.2 percentage points
to the lower mortality rate, 1.0 percentage points to the TFP slowdown, 0.5
percentage point to the reduced fertility rate, and 0.4 percentage point to
the lower price of capital goods. The remaining 1.2 percentage point decline
reflects the prolonged effects of changes in fundamentals that occurred
before 1990. It takes an extremely long time before the effects of demo-
graphic changes are fully realized (figure 8.9). The effect of the fertility rate,
for example, begins to show up after 10 years; it attains its maximum only
after almost half a century. Changes in the fertility rate since 1990 lowered
the real interest rate by 0.5 percentage point through 2015; an additional
impact of 1.3 percentage points is expected to kick in by 2040. Similarly, the
11. This model is composed of 80 overlapping generations from ages 20 to 99 in any calendar
year, reflecting all demographic changes of the past and the projected future. As there is no
money in the model, the marginal productivity of capital determines the (real) interest rate
(see Kwon 2017b for details).
176 GRAPHICS
2 - CHAPTER
SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
8—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
Figure 8.9 Effects on real natural interest rate of changes in fundamental
variables
percentage points
0.5
–0.5
–1.0
–1.5
Mortality rate
Fertility rate
–2.0
Total factor productivity
Relative price
–2.5
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Note: The underlying simulation model is based on Kwon (2017b), which has 80 generations from
ages 20 to 99. Each row measures the difference between the baseline interest rate and the
counterfactual rate that would have been realized if the respective parameter had not changed
since 1990.
Source: Kwon (2017b).
Concluding Remarks
Korea’s potential growth has declined since the 1990s. Given demographic
trends and capital deepening, it is projected to decline further for the next
two to three decades unless overall efficiency (or TFP) is substantially
enhanced. To reverse (or at least mitigate) this trend, bold structural reforms
in the labor, financial, and product markets are warranted. Successful
reforms to enhance market efficiency would boost TFP, which could raise
the natural interest rate as well as potential growth, reducing the danger of
Korea falling into the deflation trap that Japan experienced. Reforms always
confront resistance by vested interest groups. The real policy task may be to
convince Koreans of the pressing need for reforms in order to gain political
momentum for them.
12. Kim and Park (2013), among others, estimate the natural interest rate of Korea using
various versions of the Laubach-Williams (2003) methodology.
13. According to Wynne and Zhang (2017), Japan’s natural interest rate fluctuated around
zero beginning in the early 1990s, falling significantly below zero after the global financial
crisis.
China’s economic growth potential will slow in the coming decade for struc-
tural reasons that cannot easily be reversed. Technological innovation and
reforms can cushion the deceleration, but it calls for a macroeconomic man-
agement framework that is more consistent with a slower, quality-driven
growth model.
Reining in the buildup of macroeconomic leverage (measured by the
M2/GDP ratio) will be key. There is a consensus that high and growing
macroeconomic leverage has been the main cause for rising financial sector
risks. According to the Bank for International Settlements, China’s nonfi-
nancial credit-to-GDP ratio stood at 256.8 percent in the third quarter of
2017, the highest ratio among the Group of Twenty (G-20) economies. This
ratio grew at an annual average pace of 11 percentage points over the past
decade, the highest rate among G-20 countries. China’s leadership has em-
phasized that prevention of financial sector risks is its top priority.
The targeting or pursuit of an aggressive GDP growth rate has contrib-
uted to the excessive growth of monetary aggregates and thus the rapid
buildup in leverage. In 2009–10, the period after the global financial crisis,
for example, the government targeted a GDP growth rate of 8 percent. It
achieved 9.4 percent in 2009 and 10.6 percent in 2010. M2 growth acceler-
ated to 27.7 percent in 2009, 11.2 percentage points higher than the annual
Ma Jun is director of the Center for Finance and Development, Tsinghua National Institute of Financial Re-
search, and member of the People’s Bank of China Monetary Policy Committee. The author thanks Wang Lish-
eng, Zhu Shouqing, He Xiaobei, Qi Xing, Yang Xiaohai, and Wang Tianyu for their contributions to this research
and Changyong Rhee and Alfred Schipke of the IMF for arranging the author’s presentation at the conference.
181
average M2 growth during 2000–08. During 2011–16, the M2/GDP ratio
continued to rise by 6.9 percentage points a year, as the government aimed
for GDP growth of around 7 percent.
Environmental Costs
China’s traditional growth model, led by investment and heavy manufac-
turing, resulted in serious environmental degradation. This deterioration is
beginning to limit potential growth and may threaten social stability.
Most of the environmental costs China is facing arise from air and water
pollution, soil contamination, and CO2 emissions. Future generations will
bear these costs, the benefits of which were reaped by people who enjoyed
very high income and wealth growth in the past several decades. Remediation
costs in China during 2000–10 accounted for 6.5 percent of GDP for air, 2.1
percent for water, and 1.1 percent for land pollution/degradation, according
1.5
10.0
1.0
9.5
0.5
9.0 0
–0.5
8.5
–1.0
8.0 –1.5
0
12
16
20
24
28
32
36
40
44
48
0
0
0
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
to estimates by the RAND Corporation (Crane and Mao 2015). Water pollu-
tion and land contamination costs are likely to rise. According to Zhuang
Guotai, deputy director general of the Ministry of Environment, the reme-
diation costs for land contamination will be far greater than the costs for air
and water pollution and could amount to many trillions of renminbi.3
These costs will significantly increase the costs of producing goods and
services. For example, carbon prices may rise by a factor of 10 to 15 in the
coming decade, according to the World Bank (2017), reaching $50 to $100
a ton by 2030.
Higher input costs should lead to lower profitability and thus less pro-
duction and lower economic growth. Our dynamic CGE model shows that
China’s annual GDP growth may slow 0.5 percentage point during the
energy transition in 2017–2030 assuming clean energy is 30 percent more
expensive than dirty energy.4 Rising water and food costs may have a similar
3. See He Gwangwei, “The Soil Pollution Crisis in China: A Cleanup Presents Daunting
Challenge,” Yale Environment 360, July 14, 2014, https://e360.yale.edu/features/the_soil_
pollution_crisis_in_china_a_cleanup_presents_daunting_challenge.
4. The author employed the GEMPACK software to calculate this estimate of GDP growth
slowdown during the energy transition period. Replicating this estimate may be difficult
without the author’s assistance. Accordingly, this chapter does not provide the GEMPACK
code as part of the normal replication package required by PIIE. PIIE does not assume
responsibility for the calculations underlying this estimate. Anyone seeking further infor-
mation should contact the author at maj@pbcsf.tsinghua.edu.cn.
5. “Manufacturing” is used as shorthand for “manufacturing, construction, and mining.”
percent
60
50
40
30
20
10
Manufacturing, construction, and mining
Services
0
90
92
94
96
98
10
12
14
16
0
0
0
0
0
20
20
20
20
19
19
19
20
19
20
19
20
20
20
decline by 11 million people, obviating the need to create net new jobs by
2028.6
6. Rural labor migration is projected at about 8 million people in 2028, almost the same as
the net reduction in the urban labor force that year.
7. Yawen Chen and Ryan Woo, “Another Chinese city admits ‘fake’ economic data,” Reuters,
January 16, 2018, www.reuters.com/article/us-china-economy-data/another-chinese-city-
admits-fake-economic-data-idUSKBN1F60I1.
8. The author was an advisor to the “balance sheeting working group” of a provincial-local
government a few years ago and was involved in many technical discussions on definitions,
scope, and valuations of local government balance sheet items. His experience suggests that
these issues are not as problematic as many people perceive.
Even at somewhat lower rates, China’s growth will still be among the
highest in the world in the coming decade—and the declining size of its labor
force will allow it to tolerate a more moderate GDP growth rate without
causing serious unemployment. Hence there is no convincing reason to be
obsessed about reaching an annual GDP growth target. By reducing the
probability of financial crises and large disruptions to growth, the new mac-
roeconomic management framework described in this chapter should help
China better achieve its sustainable development objectives in the medium
and long terms.
References
Cai, Fang, and Yang Lu. 2013. Population Change and Resulting Slowdown in Potential GDP
Growth in China. China & World Economy 21, no. 2: 1–14.
Crane, Keith, and Zhimin Mao. 2015. Costs of Selected Policies to Address Air Pollution in China.
Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation.
Gordon, Robert J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the
Civil War. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
India’s merchandise exports underwent a quiet revolution over the last two
decades, with exports of engineering goods, electronics, and pharmaceuti-
cals gradually replacing India’s traditional exports of leather, textiles, gems,
and jewelry. This chapter uses sectoral and firm-level data to examine what
drives India’s exports. It answers the following questions: How has India
fared since the global financial crisis? Is India a closed economy? Has it been
insulated from global shocks? The first two sections examine how open
India’s economy is and how the composition of its exports has changed.
The next two sections analyze the determinants of India’s exports (global
growth, the real effective exchange rate, supply bottlenecks) at the aggre-
gate and firm levels. The last section summarizes the chapter’s conclusions
and identifies their policy implications.
Prachi Mishra is deputy division chief in the Western Hemisphere Department at the International Monetary
Fund. Siddhartha Nath is research officer at the Reserve Bank of India. They would like to thank Medha Madhu
Nair for excellent research assistance. The views expressed in this chapter are those of the authors and do not
necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management, nor the views of the institu-
tions to which they belong.
193
Figure 10.1a India’s exports and imports, 2000–16
percent of GDP
60
55
50
45
40
35
30
25
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
percent of GDP
28
25
22
19
16
13
10
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
exports have grown as a share of GDP and how sensitive they are to changes
in partner-country growth. The larger the share of exports in GDP and the
more elastic/cyclical they are to changes in global economic conditions, the
more vulnerable the economy is.
India’s exports as a share of GDP more than doubled between 2000
and 2013, rising from 12 percent to 25 percent. This share declined in
recent years (figure 10.1b), broadly mirroring changes in emerging markets
(figure 10.1c). Despite the slowdown, however, India’s exports still repre-
sented almost 20 percent of GDP in 2017. This share is almost twice what
it was 15 years ago and almost as large as in Indonesia.
Complementing this openness is the fact that until recently, India’s
export basket had become progressively more sensitive to global growth.
Although the relationship between growth in the advanced economies and
exports in India has softened in recent years, elasticity to partner-country
growth remains high (Aziz and Chinoy 2012, Rangarajan and Mishra 2013).
It is the primary driver of export volumes, eclipsing the role of the exchange
rate and supply bottlenecks.
The growing role of exports in India’s growth process can be appreci-
ated by recognizing the contribution of slowing exports to slowing headline
GDP growth (figure 10.2). India’s much-celebrated 9 percent growth in the
2000s came largely as a result of surging export growth, as global growth
rose and India plugged into the global export market. Exports underpinned
India’s 8.8 percent GDP annual growth in 2003–07 (nearly 18 percent a year
in real terms).
In contrast, over 2012–16, export growth slowed to just 2.6 percent a
40
30
20
10
–10
–20
–30
–40
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
India
Average of emerging-market economies
9
GDP growth = 6.9 percent
6
6.7
5.4
3
2.6
0
2003–07 2012–16
Exports
Private consumption
basis points
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
Reduction in growth Attributable to exports
after series adjustment
percent percent
16 2.0
14 1.8
1.6
12
1.4
10 1.2
8 1.0
6 0.8
0.6
4
0.4
2 0.2
0 0
Ju r 2 01
Ja p 20 1
O ua il 2 02
ob 2 9
Ju 20 0
Ja p y 2 0
O ua il 2 11
ob 2 2
Ju r 2 13
Ja Ap 20 13
O ua il 2 14
ob 2 5
Ju r 2016
ly 16
17
ob 2 3
Ju r 2004
Ja Ap 20 4
O a 20 5
ob 2 6
Ju r 2 07
Ja pr 20 7
nu il 2 08
ly 00
A ly 0
ct ry 01
ct ry 01
nu ril 0
ct ry 00
ct ry 0
ct ry 0
ly 0
er 01
l 1
n r 0
20
e 0
ly 0
e 0
e 0
e 0
0
O a 0
e 0
ob 2
ct ry
r
n r
O ua
A
A
n
n
Ja
percent of total
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2003 2007 2015
10
–5
–10
Engineering Textiles Gems Leather
goods
1. Break dates vary widely. They are 2005 for engineering and pharmaceuticals, 2008–09 for
electronics, and 2013–14 for leather, textiles, and chemicals.
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
–1.3*** –0.8 0.6 –0.7 0.6 5.2*** 2.2** 2.5***
10
Log of partner exchange rate
(0.2) (0.9) (0.6) (1.8) (0.8) (0.7) (1.1) (0.5)
DO INDIA’S
Log of partner exchange Rate * 1.7*** 1.9 –3.3*** 2.3 –2.7*** –6.7*** –0.1 –2.7***
Structural break dummy (0.3) (2.3) (0.6) (2.2) (0.8) (0.9) (2.1) (0.6)
0.1** 0.1 –0.2 0.0 –0.1 0.0 0.2***
Log of number of stalled projects
(0.0) (0.1) (0.1) (0.1) (0.2) (0.0) (0.0)
79.1* 72.0 –18.1 93.5 47.6 3.5 120.1* 71.3
Volatility of dollar/rupee exchange rate
(41.4) (70.0) (67.4) (118.5) (33.6) (25.0) (64.8) (59.7)
3.0** –2.3 20.7*** 7.9 18.0*** 34.9*** 19.2 –6.2
Structural break dummy
(1.3) (11.1) (4.5) (10.7) (4.6) (4.4) (11.9) (4.8)
Model properties
Sample period 2002Q4 to 2016Q3
Number of observations 56 56 56 56 56 56 56 56
Structural break date 2005Q1 2005Q1 2013Q4 2005Q1 2014Q1 2005Q1 2008Q2 2005Q4
Max Wald-F: Quandt-Andrews test for
59.8*** 48.4*** 176.0*** 45.6*** 79.4*** 91.6*** 73.7*** 77.0***
structural break
203
���
��� ���
�����ln�𝑌𝑌 �����This
ln�𝑌𝑌����� �𝐷𝐷 section
ln�𝑌𝑌����
�𝐷𝐷�� ∗∗ln�𝑌𝑌 ����draws on
����ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸
ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 the
���� �
literature
������𝐷𝐷 ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸�(see,
�𝐷𝐷�� ∗∗ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 ���
��� e.g.,
���
�� �Berman,
�� � ��
���� � �𝐷𝐷�Martin,
��𝐷𝐷 ������� and
� ���
Mayer 2012) and granular firm-level data for India in order to answer these
questions.
We estimate the following specification:
ln�𝐹𝐹������ ���
ln�𝐹𝐹 ��� ��� ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸�����
���ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 ��𝑋𝑋
�𝑋𝑋�� �
����� �
���
�� �
���
������ (10.2)
(10.2)
(10.2)
where firms are indexed by i; time is indexed by t; Fit is a firm-level outcome
that includes the value of exports, imported raw materials, total sales
(domestic and foreign), total costs, and profits; ERt is the average annual
��
exchange rate; and Xt are additional��� time-varying controls, which include
���
world GDP growth (to measure external demand conditions) and the
volume of stalled projects (as a proxy for domestic supply constraints). All
regressions include firm fixed effects (si) and therefore use variation within
firms over time to identify the responses to exchange rate movements. The
regressions also control for a time trend (t).2 Standard errors are clustered
at the firm level.
The main findings from the empirical analysis include the following:
n There is little evidence that appreciation of the exchange rate reduced
the value of exports. In fact, the elasticity of exports with respect to the
exchange rate was positive after 2009 and in the smaller sample of firms;
an appreciation of the exchange rate was associated with a higher value
of average exports at the firm level. The long-run effect was also positive
and stronger than the short-run effect (table 10.3).3
n The value of imported intermediates rises sharply in response to an ap-
preciation of the rupee (table 10.4). The finding is robust across several
specifications. A 1 percent increase in the real effective exchange rate
(REER) was associated with a 0.4 percent increase in the value of im-
ported intermediates. The magnitude of the effect was much larger after
2009, for the balanced panel of firms, and in the long run.
ln�𝑋𝑋� � ���
n ���
The �� � �
� ln�𝑌𝑌
effect � �𝐷𝐷
of � ∗ ln�𝑌𝑌� �� � ��of
appreciation the� �rupee
ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 � �� �𝐷𝐷� ∗ ln�𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸
varied � �� � ��
across � � ��� There
sectors. � �𝐷𝐷� ���
is ��
some evidence that exports of firms in sectors with high domestic value
added (top 25th percentile) declined following appreciation of the
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
3
4
Table 10.3 Firm outcomes and exchange rates: Value of exports (millions of rupees) (continued)
[7] [8] [9] [10] [11] [12] [13] [14] [15]
Variable REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs
Balanced panel of firms Dynamic effects Dynamic effects: Post-2009
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
–0.002 0.003 0.006 0.016 –0.012 0.008^ –0.012 0.002 0.013^
World growth (one-year lag)
[0.007] [0.005] [0.004] [0.015] [0.010] [0.005] [0.022] [0.014] [0.008]
Volume of stalled projects (one-year –0.253*** –0.207*** –0.163*** –0.313** –0.537*** –0.337*** –0.21 –0.339* –0.315^
lag, in logs) [0.049] [0.041] [0.041] [0.136] [0.085] [0.047] [0.169] [0.205] [0.196]
Value of exports (one-year lag, in 0.325*** 0.325*** 0.325*** 0.227*** 0.227*** 0.227***
logs) [0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.027] [0.027] [0.027]
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
5
Table 10.4 Firm outcomes and exchange rates: Value of imported raw materials (millions of rupees)
(continued)
[7] [8] [9] [10] [11] [12] [13] [14] [15]
Variable REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs
Balanced panel of firms Dynamic effects Dynamic effects: Post-2009
1.166*** 1.063*** 0.766*** 0.405 3.345*** 1.326*** 2.859** 2.369** 1.046**
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
Exchange rate (one-year lag, in logs)
[0.358] [0.264] [0.171] [0.983] [0.737] [0.282] [1.112] [0.921] [0.407]
–0.003 0.005 0.008^ 0.02 –0.024** 0.006 –0.040^ –0.014 0.009
World growth (one-year lag)
[0.008] [0.006] [0.005] [0.020] [0.012] [0.006] [0.026] [0.016] [0.009]
Volume of stalled projects (one-year –0.148** –0.074 –0.02 –0.138 –0.503*** –0.199*** 0.12 –0.139 –0.091
lag, in logs) [0.071] [0.061] [0.060] [0.182] [0.107] [0.060] [0.230] [0.280] [0.268]
0.095*** 0.145*** 0.107*** 0.081^ 0.401*** 0.177*** 0.013 0.240** 0.131^
Time trend
[0.022] [0.026] [0.022] [0.050] [0.076] [0.032] [0.060] [0.122] [0.087]
Long-run effect 0.497 4.099 1.611 3.009 2.494 1.101
Number of observations 8,643 8,643 8,643 14,308 14,308 14,308 9,530 9,530 9,530
Number of firms 1,173 1,173 1,173 3,723 3,723 3,723 3,192 3,192 3,192
Dependent variable: Value of imported raw materials (in logs).
REER = real effective exchange rate; NEER = nominal effective exchange rate
Note: All regressions include firm fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. An increase in all measures of the ex-
change rate denotes an appreciation. ***, **, *, and ^ denote statistical significance at 1, 5, 10, and 15 percent levels, respectively.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
211
Figure 10.8 Market share of exports over time: Selected sectors with high foreign
212
value added
80 1.0 80 0.2
75 0
75 0
2007 2009 2011 2013 2007 2009 2011 2013
Sources: Ministry of Statistics and Program Implementation, Government of India; authors’ calculations.
8
Table 10.6 Firm outcomes and exchange rates: Total sales (millions of rupees)
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
Variable REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
Full sample Post-2009 sample
0.675*** 0.586*** 0.402*** 0.748** 0.620** 0.274**
Exchange rate (one-year lag, in logs)
DO INDIA’S
[0.136] [0.104] [0.069] [0.372] [0.308] [0.136]
0.002 0.006*** 0.009*** –0.006 0.001 0.007**
World growth (one-year lag)
[0.003] [0.002] [0.002] [0.009] [0.005] [0.003]
Volume of stalled projects (one-year –0.077*** –0.021 0.014 0.242*** 0.174* 0.187**
lag, in logs) [0.023] [0.020] [0.021] [0.084] [0.097] [0.094]
Total sales (one-year lag, in logs)
0.119*** 0.142*** 0.118*** 0.029 0.089** 0.060**
Time trend
[0.008] [0.009] [0.008] [0.022] [0.041] [0.030]
Number of observations 27,542 27,542 27,542 15,186 15,186 15,186
Number of firms 6,488 6,488 6,488 5,186 5,186 5,186
(continues on next page)
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
9
10
Table 10.7 Firm outcomes and exchange rates: Total expenses (millions of rupees)
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
Variable REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
Full sample Post-2009 sample
10
0.761*** 0.685*** 0.490*** 1.287*** 1.066*** 0.471***
Exchange rate (one-year lag, in logs)
[0.114] [0.086] [0.056] [0.314] [0.260] [0.115]
DO INDIA’S
–0.001 0.004** 0.006*** –0.017** –0.005 0.005**
World growth (one-year lag)
[0.003] [0.002] [0.002] [0.007] [0.004] [0.002]
Volume of stalled projects (one-year –0.125*** –0.063*** –0.021 0.192*** 0.076 0.097
lag, in logs) [0.020] [0.016] [0.017] [0.068] [0.080] [0.077]
Total expenses (one-year lag, in
logs)
0.141*** 0.167*** 0.140*** 0.051*** 0.154*** 0.104***
Time trend
[0.006] [0.007] [0.006] [0.018] [0.034] [0.025]
Number of observations 27,891 27,891 27,891 15,375 15,375 15,375
Number of firms 6,558 6,558 6,558 5,245 5,245 5,245
(continues on next page)
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
11
12
Table 10.8 Firm outcomes and exchange rates: Profits (millions of rupees)
REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs
Variable Full sample Post-2009 sample Balanced panel of firms
0.093 –0.074 –0.124 –0.703 –0.583 –0.257 0.824^ 0.427 0.187
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
Exchange rate (one-year lag, in logs)
[0.431] [0.316] [0.209] [1.797] [1.489] [0.658] [0.531] [0.381] [0.249]
10
–0.003 –0.001 0.00 0.025 0.019 0.013 –0.021* –0.012^ –0.01
World growth (one-year lag)
[0.009] [0.006] [0.006] [0.042] [0.026] [0.014] [0.011] [0.008] [0.008]
DO INDIA’S
0.221*** 0.235*** 0.228*** –0.273 –0.209 –0.221 0.07 0.147* 0.173**
Volume of stalled projects (one-year lag, in logs)
[0.083] [0.069] [0.069] [0.347] [0.429] [0.410] [0.107] [0.088] [0.086]
0.02 0.015 0.016 0.137^ 0.081 0.108 0.051^ 0.063^ 0.042
Time trend
[0.026] [0.030] [0.026] [0.091] [0.194] [0.135] [0.033] [0.039] [0.033]
Number of observations 14,635 14,635 14,635 8,041 8,041 8,041 6,142 6,142 6,142
Number of firms 4,802 4,802 4,802 3,552 3,552 3,552 1,213 1,213 1,213
Dependent variable: Profits (in logs).
REER = real effective exchange rate; NEER = nominal effective exchange rate
Note: All regressions include firm fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. An increase in all measures of the ex-
change rate denotes an appreciation. Firms with negative profits are dropped from the regressions. ***, **, *, and ^ denote statistical
significance at 1, 5, 10, and 15 percent levels, respectively.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
13
14
Table 10.9 Firm outcomes and exchange rates: Salaries and wage expenses (millions of rupees) (continued)
[7] [8] [9] [10] [11] [12] [13] [14] [15]
Variable REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs
Balanced panel of firms Dynamic effects Dynamic effects: post-2009
1.287*** 1.034*** 0.673*** –0.304 0.358* 0.173** 0.254 0.211 0.093
Exchange rate (one-year lag, in logs)
[0.108] [0.082] [0.052] [0.245] [0.201] [0.077] [0.310] [0.257] [0.113]
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
–0.021*** –0.011*** –0.007*** 0.020*** 0.008** 0.011*** 0.003 0.006 0.008***
World growth (one-year lag)
[0.003] [0.002] [0.002] [0.005] [0.003] [0.002] [0.007] [0.005] [0.003]
Volume of stalled projects (one-year –0.127*** –0.035** 0.021 0.059 –0.042 –0.012 0.132** 0.109^ 0.114*
lag, in logs) [0.019] [0.015] [0.015] [0.046] [0.029] [0.016] [0.056] [0.069] [0.066]
Value of exports (one-year lag, in 0.553*** 0.553*** 0.553*** 0.458*** 0.458*** 0.458***
logs) [0.023] [0.023] [0.023] [0.034] [0.034] [0.034]
0.152*** 0.197*** 0.156*** 0.027** 0.078*** 0.056*** 0.018 0.038 0.028
Time trend
[0.005] [0.007] [0.005] [0.012] [0.022] [0.010] [0.014] [0.032] [0.022]
Number of observations 10,295 10,295 10,295 20,521 20,521 20,521 13,588 13,588 13,588
Number of firms 1,288 1,288 1,288 5,444 5,444 5,444 4,713 4,713 4,713
Dependent variable: Value of salaries and wage expenses (in logs).
REER = real effective exchange rate; NEER = nominal effective exchange rate
Note: All regressions include firm fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. An increase in all measures of the ex-
change rate denotes an appreciation. ***, **, * and ^ denote statistical significance at 1, 5, 10, and 15 percent levels, respectively.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
15
16
Table 10.10 Firm outcomes and exchange rates: Investment (millions of rupees) (continued)
[7] [8] [9] [10] [11] [12] [13] [14] [15]
Variable REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs REER NEER US$/Rs
Balanced panel of firms Dynamic effects Dynamic effects: Post-2009
–3.774 1.645 1.003 –2.197 3.281 1.791* 2.489 2.063 0.911
Exchange rate (one-year lag, in logs)
[2.999] [2.630] [1.004] [2.361] [2.600] [1.020] [3.264] [2.705] [1.195]
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER 10
0.094^ –0.008 0.001 0.069^ –0.033 –0.015 –0.066 –0.043 –0.023
World growth (one-year lag)
[0.061] [0.042] [0.020] [0.048] [0.048] [0.027] [0.078] [0.049] [0.028]
Volume of stalled projects (one-year 1.118* 0.227 0.33 0.356 –0.434 –0.175 1.148** 0.923 0.965^
lag, in logs) [0.598] [0.440] [0.233] [0.442] [0.346] [0.165] [0.524] [0.657] [0.623]
Value of exports (one-year lag, in –0.225*** –0.225*** –0.225*** –0.234*** –0.234*** –0.234***
logs) [0.052] [0.052] [0.052] [0.065] [0.065] [0.065]
–0.292* 0.05 –0.025 –0.044 0.387^ 0.211** –0.237* –0.038 –0.134
Time trend
[0.166] [0.298] [0.127] [0.121] [0.268] [0.105] [0.137] [0.323] [0.216]
Number of observations 8,017 8,017 8,017 11,778 11,778 11,778 9,673 9,673 9,673
Number of firms 1,286 1,286 1,286 3,750 3,750 3,750 3,443 3,443 3,443
Dependent variable: Value of investment (in logs).
REER = real effective exchange rate; NEER = nominal effective exchange rate
Note: All regressions include firm fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. An increase in all measures of the
exchange rate denotes an appreciation. ***, **, * and ^ denote statistical significance at 1, 5, 10, and 15 percent levels, respectively.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
References
Acharya, Viral, Prachi Mishra, and N. R. Prabhala. 2017. The Anatomy of India’s Credit Cycle.
Photocopy. Reserve Bank of India.
Ahmed, Swarnali, Maximiliano Appendino, and Michele Ruta. 2015. Global Value Chains and
the Exchange Rate Elasticity of Exports. IMF Working Paper 15/252. Washington: Interna-
tional Monetary Fund.
Aziz, Jahangir, and Sajjid Chinoy. 2012. India: More Open Than You Think. JP Morgan Note.
Berman, Nicolas, Philippe Martin, and Thierry Mayer. 2012. How Do Different Exporters
React to Exchange Rate Changes? Quarterly Journal of Economics 127, no. 1: 437–92.
Dekle, Robert, Hyeok Jeong, and Heajin Ryoo. 2009. A Re-Examination of the Exchange Rate Dis-
connect Puzzle: Evidence from Firm Level Data. Los Angeles: University of Southern Califor-
nia.
Engel, Charles. 2009. Exchange Rate Policies. Staff Paper. Dallas: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Imbs, Jean, and Isabelle Méjean. 2009. Elasticity Optimism. CEPR Discussion Paper 7177. Lon-
don: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Ministry of Finance. 2012. Seizing the Demographic Dividend. In Economy Survey. New Delhi:
Government of India.
Rajan, Raghuram. 2016. India in the Global Economy. Ramnath Goenka Lecture, March 13.
Rangarajan, C., and Prachi Mishra. 2013. India’s External Sector: Do We Need to Worry? Eco-
nomic and Political Weekly 48, no. 7: 52–59.
Quarterly GDP data in current prices come from the CEIC. They cover
about 105 of India’s export partners, representing more than 92 percent of
Firm-Level Data
We compile an annual firm-level panel dataset that spans 2007–14, based
on the Prowess database, collected by the CMIE. It covers about 6,500
publicly listed exporting firms across 143 industries whose export earnings
represent roughly 40 percent of total exports (based on the 2013 balance
GRAPHICS
THE NEW
Structural break dummy * Log of partner
1.9 2.4 1.9 2.4 –2.7** –3.8*** –2.6 –3.7***
exchange rate
Structural break dummy * Log of partner
0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
exchange rate * High rupee appreciation
- CHAPTER
(continues on next page)
17
NORMAL?10 227
18
Table 10A.1 Determinants of India’s manufacturing and services exports: Check for nonlinearity (continued)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Manufacturing exports Services exports
228 GRAPHICS
Nonlinearity Nonlinearity Nonlinearity Nonlinearity
Linear in partner in exchange Linear in partner in exchange
SUSTAINING
Variable model GDP rate (2) + (3) model GDP rate (6) + (7)
Dependent variable: Log of exports (2010 prices) in US dollars
Dummy variables:
- CHAPTER
Structural break –2.3 –4.7 –2.4 –4.1 –6.2 –4.5 –7.0 –4.7
ECONOMIC
High partner growth –0.8 –0.9 1.7 1.1
High rupee appreciation 3.0 1.2 0.5 0.5
Sample period 2002Q4 to 2016Q3
Observations 56 56 56 56 56 56 56 56
Structural break date 2005Q1 2005Q4
10 GROWTH IN ASIA
Maximum Wald-F stat: Quandt-Andrews
48.4*** 97.0***
test
Durbin-Watson d-statistic 2.8 2.6 2.6 2.6 1.9 2.1 2.1 2.1
Ljung-Box Q-stat for first order
8.5*** 4.9** 5.4** 5.2** 0.0 0.2 0.2 0.1
autocorrelation
Notes: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10, 5, and 1 percent, respectively. High partner growth is a dummy variable that
assumes a value equal to 1 when the quarter-over-quarter change in partner GDP is more than 2 percent. High rupee appreciation is a
dummy variable that assumes a value equal to 1 when the quarter-over-quarter change in partner exchange rate is more than 2 percent.
Regression uses heteroskedasticity-consistent robust standard errors.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Comment
Kenneth Kang
Kenneth Kang is the deputy director of the Asia and Pacific Department at the International Monetary Fund.
The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive
Board, or its management.
percent
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
a il ey and ina xico rica esia ssia nes ysia eru ore
di az rk i
In Br Tu ai
l Ch Me A
f
on Ru lipp ala
P ap
Th th Ind i M ng
u P h Si
So
2015
2000
Note: For countries where 2015 data are not available, 2013 or 2014
data are used.
Source: World Bank, World Integrated Trade Solution database.
billions of US dollars
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Primary goods
Intermediate goods
Final goods
states (if India’s most populous state, Uttar Pradesh, were a separate country,
it would be the fifth largest country in the world by population, just after
Brazil). Leemput and Wiencek (2017) find that internal trade barriers in
India account for up to 40 percent of total trade barriers on average but vary
substantially by state. According to them, reducing trade barriers across
Indian states could lead to real GDP gains of more than 4 percent.
India’s competitiveness may also be a factor behind weak export response.
India’s nominal effective exchange rate has steadily declined since the global
financial crisis, especially against Indonesia and China. In real effective
terms, however, India’s exchange rate appreciated by more than 20 percent
since 2008, more so than that of Brazil or Russia. This appreciation largely
reflects India’s higher average rate of inflation, highlighting the need to keep
inflation under control and pursue reforms to enhance competitiveness.
The legacy of the credit bubble of the mid-2000s in the corporate and
banking sectors may be holding back credit allocation. Credit growth and
real investment are closely correlated. It is perhaps not coincidental that
14
12
10
0
2012–13
2013–14
2014–15
2015–16
2012–13
2013–14
2014–15
2015–16
2012–13
2013–14
2014–15
2015–16
2012–13
2013–14
2014–15
2015–16
Public sector Private sector Foreign banks All banks
banks banks
the post-2005 decline in exports elasticity coincides with the peak of the
credit and investment bubble. Nonfinancial corporate debt in India is low
(about 50 percent of GDP) compared with other emerging-market countries
(among which it averages 90 percent). But the level of nonperforming loans
is high, at about 12 percent for all banks—significantly higher for public
banks—and rising (figure 10C.3). Nonperforming loans are concentrated in
metals and mining, construction and engineering, and transportation and
infrastructure—sectors closely tied with exports. High corporate leverage
and nonperforming loans may be hindering efficient resource allocation,
preventing the exit of nonviable zombie firms, the entry of new firms, and
the growth of productive ones. Forthcoming research by the IMF finds that
the misallocation of resources in India is much greater than in the United
States and that it varies widely across Indian states. Credit availability is one
of the key drivers of resource misallocation in India, suggesting that remov-
ing structural rigidities in key input markets and improving credit alloca-
tion across firms would help reduce distortions and boost competitiveness.
India is an open economy with a young and growing population
subject to spillovers from stagnation elsewhere, particularly through trade
References
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2016. World Economic Outlook (Fall). Washington.
Van Leemput, Eva, and Ellen A. Wiencek. 2017. The Effect of the GST on Indian Growth. IFDP
Notes (March 24). Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Mitali Das is deputy division chief of the Strategy, Policy and Review Department of the International Mon-
etary Fund. She thanks Luis Breuer, Jérémie Cohen-Setton, Thomas Helbling, Ken Kang, and Adam Posen
for their overall guidance on this chapter and Agnes Isnawangsih, Yinqiu Liu, Toh Seng Guan, Medha Nair,
Ranil Salgado, Jongsoon Shin, and participants at the Peterson Institute for International Economics confer-
ence on “The New Mediocre and Asia” held in May 2017 and the conference on “Prospects and Challenges for
Sustained Growth in Asia” organized by the Bank of Korea, the Korean Ministry of Strategy and Finance, the
International Monetary Fund, and the Peterson Institute for International Economics in Seoul on September
7–8, 2017, for their helpful comments. Special thanks to M. Chatib Basri, whose insights and discussion of this
chapter improved both its contents and presentation, and to Egor Gornostay, for his outstanding assistance with
the empirical section. The views expressed in this chapter are those of the author and do not necessarily represent
the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management. Any remaining errors are the author’s.
235
ambitious growth objectives and generate good-quality jobs for its expand-
ing labor force, Indonesia will require higher investment and technological
innovations that may be best facilitated by greater global integration.
1. Lawrence Summers, “Why Stagnation Might Prove to Be the New Normal,” Financial Times,
December 15, 2013, http://larrysummers.com/commentary/financial-times-columns/why-
stagnation-might-prove-to-be-the-new-normal; Lawrence Summers, “Reflections on the
New ‘Secular Stagnation Hypothesis,’” VoxEU, October 30, 2014, https://voxeu.org/article/
larry-summers-secular-stagnation.
2. Ben Bernanke, Why Are Interest Rates So Low? Brookings Institution Blog, March 30,
2015, www.brookings.edu/blog/ben-bernanke/2015/03/30/why-are-interest-rates-so-low/.
3. IMF, World Economic Outlook June 2017 database, measured in purchasing power parity
(PPP) terms and PPP weights, respectively.
4. The growth rate in the United States is taken as a proxy for the growth rate of the global
economy.
percent
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2 Real GDP growth 2005–08
1990–97 2009–12
1
2000–04 2013–16
0
90
94
8
92
96
10
12
14
16
0
0
0
0
0
20
20
20
20
19
20
19
19
20
19
20
20
20
5. As predicted by theory (see Cesa-Bianchi, Imbs, and Saleheen 2016), in response to common
global shocks, business cycle synchronization increases when financial integration declines.
240
percent
10
–4 Indonesia
United States
–6
Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
percent
10
8
6
4
2
0
–2
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
Indonesia
Thailand
Malaysia
Philippines
percent
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
ela
a
sia
a
nd
ile
sia
il
ia
ey
ne
az
in
bi
ric
in
xic
an
ss
Ch
rk
a
ne
lay
zu
nt
Ch
m
Br
pi
Af
Ru
l
ail
Me
Po
Tu
lo
ge
do
ne
ilip
Ma
Th
h
Co
Ar
Ve
In
ut
Ph
So
Channels of Transmission
A large body of work has analyzed the channels through which economic
developments and policies in the North spill over to countries in the South
(IMF 2013, 2014c). Eggertsson, Mehrotra, and Summers (2016) find that
monetary and fiscal policy spillovers are stronger in the context of secular
stagnation and more likely to be persistent. The channels of transmission
do not necessarily act independently; they can be either reinforcing or
offsetting.
Trade Channel
Trade linkages are a direct source of transmission of the spillovers of secular
stagnation. Deceleration of demand in advanced economies lowers import
demand from emerging markets. Indeed, the global trade slowdown is
commonly viewed as symptomatic of secular stagnation in advanced econo-
mies (IMF 2016a). The impact of weaker external demand from advanced
economies can be amplified if it is accompanied by highly accommodative
monetary policy in advanced economies, leading to larger capital outflows
to emerging markets and an appreciation of their nominal exchange rates.
Financial Channel
Financial linkages are a second source of transmission, directly or indirectly.
Emerging markets’ financial linkages to advanced economies include the
net inflows of foreign capital that supply credit and finance investment in
their financial, nonfinancial, and official sectors and their stocks of external
assets and liabilities.
Financial spillovers of secular stagnation can come from the weakness
in demand in advanced economies, which generally leads to lower exchange
rates abroad as a result of weaker demand for exports (Eggertsson, Mehrotra,
and Summers 2016). Weaker exchange rates may benefit trade, but they can
have large and deleterious balance sheet effects and adverse growth conse-
quences when the foreign currency exposure of external liabilities is high
(Eichengreen, Hausmann, and Panizza 2007).10 Both the size of the external
balance sheet and its foreign currency denomination are important: For a
8. Basri and Rahardja (2010) note that the impact of the global crisis on the Indonesian
economy was relatively limited in part because of the strong demand from China and India,
in particular for primary commodity exports. As natural resources account for the majority
of Indonesia’s exports, the composition of exports stabilized external demand.
9. External demand in countries that are more exposed to the sectors slowing most sharply
in advanced economies (such as construction and manufacturing) may be more affected
than exporters of consumption goods (IMF 2016a).
10. By contrast, external assets denominated in foreign currency would improve in local
currency value. For a net creditor, the net impact of a depreciation on the external balance
may be to raise the value of the net international investment position (NIIP). For a net debtor
(like Indonesia), the negative revaluation of liabilities would likely exceed the positive revalu-
ation of assets, leading to a lower NIIP.
Trade-Related Exposure
Three indicators can shed light on Indonesia’s trade-based exposure to
secular stagnation: the size of the external sector in relation to the overall
economy, the diversity of exposure to exports and imports across regions,
and the contribution of net exports to output growth.
The size of Indonesia’s external sector as a share of the economy has
steadily declined since the early 2000s (figure 11.4a).11 Exports were 40
percent and imports 32 percent of GDP in 2000; both had declined to less
than 20 percent by 2016. Except for a short-lived uptick in 2003–05, these
declines were steady through the domestic business cycles, the commodity
price boom before the financial crisis, the commodity price bust starting in
2013, and the expansion of global value chains in Asia since the early 2000s.12
11. The change is not just a reflection of the rapid expansion of the economy. Growth rates
of exports and imports have been on a trend decline (in both nominal and real terms) since
the global financial crisis; in 2016 they registered negative growth rates.
12. These trends suggest that deeper structural factors lie behind the rise in insularity. By
some accounts, they reflect long-standing institutional weaknesses in the regulatory frame-
work, the legal and judiciary system, and tax administration, which have dissuaded private
investors, particularly in export sectors (IMF 2005).
percent of GDP
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
Imports
5 Exports
0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
percent of GDP
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
o
Th nd
es
M nd
om l
a
Tu a
In key
M a
en ica
la
Po e
a
zi
bi
tin
si
si
si
l
ic
Ph zue
hi
in
ra
hi
la
la
ne
us
ay
fr
ex
C
r
en
pp
B
ai
A
al
do
e
rg
ol
ili
ut
C
V
So
Figure 11.4b illustrates how these trends compare with average open-
ness among emerging-market peers. The data reveal two facts. First, there
is tremendous heterogeneity in external exposure across emerging econo-
mies. Second, although Indonesia is more closed than all its regional peers,
it is more exposed than other large economies, including Brazil and Turkey.
A natural question is whether the extent of Indonesia’s declining
external exposure is heterogenous across its trading partners. To shed light
on this question, figures 11.4c and 11.4d show the evolution of Indonesia’s
export and import shares by region. All of the decline in Indonesia’s external
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015
Advanced economies
Emerging-market and developing
economies, excluding China
China
Emerging-market Asia
Advanced economies
Emerging-market and developing
economies, excluding China
China
Emerging-market Asia
12
Domestic demand
10 Net exports
Real GDP (percent change)
–2
2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015
13. China did not drive the rise in trade with emerging Asia, as shown in figures 11.4c and
11.4d.
14. IMF, World Economic Outlook June 2017 database.
percent of GDP
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015
Financial Exposure
Both stock and flow indicators shed light on the channels through which
secular stagnation abroad can transmit to the domestic economy. A key
stock indicator is the size and (currency) composition of its external balance
sheet. The main flow indicators are the volume and volatility of nonofficial
international capital flows, which supply credit and finance investment to
the domestic economy.
In the years between the Asian financial crisis and the global financial
crisis, Indonesia steadily reduced its financial integration with the global
economy, as reflected in the declining sum of external assets and external
liabilities (figure 11.5a). By this measure, financial integration fell from 118
percent of GDP in 2001 to 80 percent of GDP in 2007.15 This evolution lies
in marked contrast with one of the major trends of the last quarter century
in the world economy (as well as in newly industrialized Asian economies
and developing Asia), which has seen record cross-border transactions and
a concomitant rise in financial integration (Obstfeld 2015).
One reason for the low and declining exposure to external liabilities
is a regulatory environment that has impeded foreign direct investment
(FDI). On the FDI Regulatory Restrictiveness Index of the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Indonesia has among
15. The trough of the sum of foreign assets and liabilities in ratio to GDP is 42 percent in
2008. However, the 2008 level may well be sui generis, reflecting large valuation effects from
both the steep depreciation of the rupiah and the large drops in asset prices.
percent of GDP
300
150
100
50
d
a
sia
ey
zil
ia
ile
lan
an
ne
in
bi
xic
ss
a
Ch
rk
ne
nt
ail
Br
pi
Po
Ru
Me
Tu
lo
ge
do
ilip
Th
Co
Ar
In
Ph
18. Indonesia is not unique in this respect. The decline in “original sin” (as Eichengreen,
Hausmann, and Panizza [2007] call the foreign currency exposure of liabilities) has been
observed in emerging markets across the world.
percent of GDP
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
a
na
nd
es
le
ia
nd
a
zi
di
si
si
e
s
hi
ra
in
rk
hi
la
la
ne
us
ay
In
C
pp
B
C
Po
ai
Tu
R
al
do
Th
ili
M
In
Ph
19. In the estimation of the VAR, the key restriction is that shocks to the external block
are assumed to be exogenous to shocks to the internal block. The external variables thus
basis points
1,200
Average 1998–2001
1,000 Average 2002–08
Average 2009–16
800
600
400
0
1 1 1 12 13 13 14 5 6 16
98 99 00 0 0 02 03 04 04 05 06 07 07 08 09 10 10 01 1 1
r 19 19 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 r 2 20 20 20 20 20 20 20
e e r e h e r r e r r e h r r e h e e h r
b b n rc b e n c h e e n c e e n rc b
r e ne ch er er
b u r b b n rc be
e m em Ju Ma em mb Ju ar mb mb Ju ar mb mb Ju Ma em em J Ma em em Ju Ma em
t e M ce te M e te t
ec p ec t e p ec p ec p ec pt ec
D Se D Sep D Se D Se D Se D Se D
Table 11.1 displays the correlations between domestic real GDP growth
in Indonesia and external and domestic factors over the entire period (2000–
16) and the period after the global financial crisis (2009–16). The correla-
tion between real GDP growth in the United States and Indonesia was negli-
gible over the entire period (consistent with figure 11.2) but strengthened
considerably after the global financial crisis. This finding provides prima
facie evidence that secular stagnation in advanced economies may have been
transmitted to domestic output dynamics since the global financial crisis.
The VAR estimates are used to compute what fraction of Indonesia’s
real GDP growth (relative to its estimated average growth over the sample
period) can be attributed to external versus domestic factors. The results
show that domestic factors explain more than three-fourths of the deviation
of Indonesia’s growth from the estimated sample mean between 1999 and
the end of 2002 (figure 11.6). The contribution of external factors to devia-
tions from average growth started rising intermittently in 2003, making
positive contributions for most quarters in 2006 through the first quarter
of 2009. External factors strongly dominated growth dynamics during the
do not respond to the internal variables contemporaneously. Within the external factors,
identification of the shocks is based on a recursive scheme: US growth affects all variables
within a quarter, whereas shocks to other variables can affect US growth only with a lag of at
least one quarter. US inflation shocks may affect all variables other than US growth within
a quarter; the one-year US Treasury rate is placed last in the recursive ordering, implying
that it responds contemporaneously to all external factors but not to any of the domestic
shocks. Within the internal block, shocks are not explicitly ordered. These assumptions
follow closely the VAR exercise in IMF (2014a).
HOWGRAPHICS
HAS INDONESIA FARED
- CHAPTER IN THE AGE OF
11—SUSTAINING SECULARGROWTH
ECONOMIC IN ASIA2531
STAGNATION?
254
Figure 11.6 Contribution of domestic and global factors to Indonesia’s real GDP growth deviations,
1999Q1–2016Q4
percent
3
Domestic
–2
Global
Deviation of growth from
estimated mean
–3
Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
percent
6.5
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
Potential output growth rate
3.5 Average 2000–04
3.0 Average 2005–08
Average 2009–16
2.5 Projected 2017–22
2.0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
21. The decomposition is of potential growth rate into the actual capital growth rate and
the potential employment growth rate reflecting the working-age population, as described
in IMF (2014c).
percent
7
0
2001–04 2006–08 2009–14
The decline in potential output growth rate since the global financial
crisis is attributable largely to the decline in the growth of TFP. The contri-
bution of employment and capital growth helped offset some of the decline
in TFP growth, thanks partly to the modest stimulus Indonesia imple-
mented as external demand softened in 2009. For emerging markets as a
whole, TFP has been found to account for the entire postcrisis decline in
potential growth rates (see Cubeddu et al. 2014, IMF 2015b).
Trade Restrictions
Restrictions on trade (such as import tariffs) result in inefficient alloca-
tion of the factors of trade, reducing TFP. A large body of empirical work
corroborates this theoretical prediction (e.g., Caselli, Esquivel, and Lefort
1996; Hall and Jones 1999).
Data from the World Bank’s Temporary Trade Barriers database show
a steady increase in protectionism in Indonesia. The rise in protectionism
is evident in both average tariff rates and nontariff barriers (Basri and
Patunru 2012). Protectionist measures were on a downward trend before
the global financial crisis but rose sharply thereafter (figure 11.10). They
have since edged down but remain high relative to the precrisis years.
22. In traditional growth decomposition, TFP traditionally accounts for factor utilization—
such as hours worked, capacity utilization, and the quality of labor and capital inputs, as
distinct from the volume of labor and capital inputs—rather than labor or capital inputs.
23. Data on human capital accumulation are from the Barro-Lee dataset, which go only
through 2010.
Higher education
Of which: Higher education, with diploma
Of which: Higher education, with postgraduate
or higher degree
percent of population
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Institutions
The quality of institutions—such as labor regulations, the legal and judi-
cial system, and accountability—can play a key role in a country’s ability to
adopt superior technologies, and thus raise TFP, income, and living stan-
dards (McGuiness 2007, Acemoglu 2008).
Indonesia ranks poorly on several measures of the ease of doing busi-
ness (World Bank 2017). International financial institutions have noted
structural impediments, including a weak investment climate, complex reg-
ulations, and shallow financial markets (IMF 2016b). After improvements
between the Asian financial crisis and global financial crisis, the regulato-
HOW HAS INDONESIA FARED IN THE AGE OF SECULAR STAGNATION? 259
Figure 11.10 Temporary trade restrictions on Indonesian imports,
1996–2015
percent of total imports
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
percent
73
72
71
70
69
68
Indonesia
67 EU-28
OECD
66
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
The future paths for labor are derived from demographic projections and
assumptions about labor force participation rates. Indonesia has the oppor-
tunity to reap large demographic dividends, given the projected increase in
the working-age population through 2060 (figure 11.12a). However, labor
force participation rates, which were rising steadily before the financial
crisis, have been volatile since 2010, registering negative average growth rate
in 2010–13 (figure 11.12b). Taking the working-age projections as given, the
scenario analysis assumes that the labor force participation rate reverts to
percent
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
2001–08 2009–14 2015–18 2019–2022
Capital stock
Employment
Total factor productivity
Potential output
its precrisis growth rate and stabilizes at the level in the OECD and EU-28
(as shown in figure 11.12b).
The capital stock is assumed to continue to grow at its postcrisis
average rate. This assumption is more optimistic than the scenario analysis
in IMF (2015b), which notes that less favorable external financing condi-
tions, infrastructure bottlenecks, and softer or flat commodity prices will
likely lead to a decline in emerging-market capital growth over the medium
term.
TFP growth is assumed to rise to its precrisis mean, thanks to an
increase in human capital accumulation, the removal of trade restrictions,
greater foreign participation in industry through FDI, and a better busi-
ness climate (achieved by simplifying regulations and increasing financial
depth).
Under this scenario, medium-term potential growth in Indonesia in-
creases from about 6 percent under the baseline to 7 percent (figure 11.13).
Potential growth could evolve differently for several reasons, such as an
upward revision to the forecast of commodity prices (which could spur in-
vestment and capital growth), a more rapid easing of barriers to FDI inflows
(which could raise TFP), or a downward revision to global growth.
References
Acemoglu, Daron. 2008. Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni-
versity Press.
Amman, E., and S. Virmani. 2015. Foreign Direct Investment and Reverse Technology Spill-
overs: The Effect on Total Factor Productivity. OECD Journal: Economic Studies. Available at
www.oecd.org/eco/growth/Foreign-direct-investment-and-reverse-technology-spillovers-
The-effect-on-total-factor-productivity-OECD-Journal-Economic-Studies-2014.pdf.
Basri, M. Chatib, and A. Patunru. 2012. How to Keep Trade Policy Open: The Case of Indone-
sia. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 48, no. 2.
Basri, M. Chatib, and S. Rahardja. 2010. The Indonesian Economy amidst the Global Crisis:
Good Policy and Good Luck. ASEAN Economic Bulletin 27, no. 1: 77–97.
Bénétrix, Agustin S., Philip R. Lane, and Jay C. Shambaugh. 2015. International Currency
Exposures, Valuation Effects and the Global Financial Crisis. Journal of International Eco-
nomics 96: 98–109.
Blanchard, Olivier J., Mitali Das, and Hamid Faruqee. 2010. The Initial Impact of the Crisis on
Emerging Market Countries. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): 263–307. Avail-
able at www.brookings.edu/wpcontent/uploads/2010/03/2010a_bpea_blanchard.pdf.
Muhamad Chatib Basri, former minister of finance of Indonesia, is chairman of the Advisory Board of the Man-
diri Institute and chairman of Indonesia Infrastructure Finance. He teaches at the Department of Economics,
University of Indonesia, and is cofounder of Creco Research Institute, a Jakarta-based economic consulting firm.
The modern floating exchange rate era that began in 1973 falls into two
stages. The first, which ended in the mid-1990s, was a period of adjustment
to the new international monetary regime. Financial markets underwent lib-
eralization, internationally as well as domestically, and international trade
expanded, while central bankers learned how to manage inflation in a world
of national fiat currencies. The period’s end is marked by the foundation
of the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the 1994–95 Mexican crisis,
which Michel Camdessus, the managing director of the International Mon-
etary Fund (IMF) at the time, labeled “the first 21st century crisis.”
The second 21st century crisis arrived even before the 21st century did,
in the form of the 1997–98 Asian crisis. The Asian crisis was notable in
that several of its victims succumbed despite the absence of garden-variety
macroeconomic imbalances—such as big public deficits—that IMF econo-
mists and others viewed as red flags. This facet of the crisis certainly influ-
enced academic thinking (witness the celebrated Kaminsky and Reinhart
1999 analysis of twin banking and currency crises), but it also pointed to
the dawn of a new, second stage of the post-1973 era.
Maurice Obstfeld is director of the Research Department at the International Monetary Fund. This chapter is
based on remarks made at the conference on “Prospects and Challenges for Sustained Growth in Asia” orga-
nized by the Bank of Korea, the Korean Ministry of Strategy and Finance, the International Monetary Fund,
and the Peterson Institute for International Economics in Seoul on September 7–8, 2017. The author is grate-
ful for suggestions and assistance from Gustavo Adler, Eugenio Cerutti, Luis Cubeddu, Thomas Helbling, and
Haonan Zhou. The views expressed in this chapter are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the
views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management. All errors and interpretations are the author’s alone.
269
That stage, covering roughly the last 25 years, is characterized by hyper-
financialization, greater exchange rate flexibility on the part of many emerg-
ing-market economies, and a decisive shift of Asian growth leadership from
Japan to China, especially after China’s accession to the WTO. Subrama-
nian and Kessler (2013) characterize developments in international trade,
including rapidly expanding global value chains, as “hyperglobalization.”
The forces unleashed after the mid-1990s led to the global financial crisis of
2008–09, a crisis with long-lived repercussions that are still being felt.
One notable feature of the second period of floating was a significant
widening of global current account imbalances, which roughly tripled in
the decade after 1995 and remained higher, albeit at lower levels than the
peak they reached before the global financial crisis (figure 12.1). That global
imbalances had the potential to widen is not surprising, given financial
market development, including further financial opening, after the mid-
1990s. Controversy remains, however, over both the causes of these imbal-
ances and their potential causal role in the global financial crisis. On one
side is the view, expressed by US Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson as he was
leaving office in 2009, that global imbalances originating in the emerging
markets were the root cause of the global crisis.1 Others (such as Obstfeld
and Rogoff 2009) have argued that this view deflects too much blame from
other critical factors.
The debate raises at least four questions, which this chapter tries to
answer:
n Why did global imbalances expand after the mid-1990s?
n What circumstances and concomitant factors provide clues about the
origins of the global financial crisis?
n If one accepts that a monocausal story about the global financial crisis
based on global imbalances is inaccurate, how should one view the
potential threats from excessive global imbalances today?
n What policy implications follow?
1. See Krishna Guha, “Paulson says crisis sown by imbalance,” Financial Times, January 1,
2009, www.ft.com/content/ff671f66-d838-11dd-bcc0-000077b07658.
percent
8
United States
6 Japan
United Kingdom
Canada
4 Euro area
–2
Asian crisis Global financial crisis
1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017
Sources: Consensus Forecasts; Haver Analytics. For the euro area, the period
before 2003 is based on German data.
percent
4
–1
Asian crisis Global financial crisis
United States
United Kingdom
Canada
Euro area
rising global oil prices, however (figure 12.5).2 As US real activity, financial
conditions, and domestic oil production are critical determinants of con-
ditions in the world oil market, it seems implausible that changes in oil
prices emanated entirely from outside US borders to influence its current
account. Instead, the US deficit reflected domestic as well as global forces—
global forces coming from other advanced economies, not just EMDEs—all
of which helped set the stage for the global financial crisis.
2. In the early 2000s, measured world surpluses surged above world deficits; a substantial
global discrepancy—a “missing deficit”—emerged. Missing deficits tend to be positively corre-
lated with oil prices. The discrepancy could be related to some countries understating the cost
of oil imports.
a. World
percent of world GDP
1.0
0.5
–0.5
b. East Asia
percent of world GDP
1.0
0.6
0.2
–0.2 China
Japan
–0.6 Other East Asian
advanced economies
Other East Asian
–1.0 EMDEs
Asian crisis Global financial crisis
–0.2 20
–0.4 0
97
11
13
15
91
93
95
99
17
0
0
0
0
0
20
20
20
20
19
20
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
15
10
–5
–10
–15
–25
1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017
100
50
0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
10
–10
–20
–30
2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017
3. In the cases of oil exporters with exchange rate pegs (e.g., Saudi Arabia), causality clearly
ran from the price of oil through the current account to reserve accumulation. In Asian econ-
omies—notably China, with its capital control regime—intervention likely had some causal
impact on the current account, to different degrees in different economies.
MYS
SWE
40 KORRUS
THA y = 0.4108x + 8.2883
ISR JPN R2 = 0.4173
20 HUN
IRL
PHL
AUT CHN
–80
–150 –100 –50 0 50 100 150 200
net international investment positions
(2010, percent of GDP)
Note: Vertical axis measures cumulated nominal current accounts between 2010 and 2017,
adjusted to reflect the path of nominal income growth.
Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook; IMF Staff calculations.
100
NLD
DNK y = 0.1697x + 8.2267
50 HUN DEU R2 = 0.0666
TUN CZE ZAF KORRUS ISR
ESP POL ITA AUT
PRT GRC BRA THA SWE
NZL AUS IDN ARG CHN
MEX PHLGBR
FRA
IND
MYS JPN CHE
0 TUR PAK GTM CHL
MAR PER FIN BEL
COL
CRI USA
–50
–100 IRL
–150
–150 –100 –50 0 50 100 150 200
net international investment positions
(2010, percent of GDP)
Policy Implications
This analysis yields four main implications for policy:
n Excess global imbalances usually reflect global forces and multiple
distortions in many countries, including diverse financial sector dis-
tortions. Monocausal explanations rarely apply. Reducing global im-
balances should therefore be a collective effort based on a shared appre-
ciation of the roles individual countries need to play. To promote that
objective, the IMF monitors external excess imbalances annually and
makes its findings public through the External Sector Report.
n Notwithstanding the need for collective action, excess surplus countries
still face little that would force them to adjust (outside of the threat
of protectionist responses). In contrast, most deficit countries face the
risk that lenders will withdraw. The trend of diverging net international
investment positions thus looks unsustainable. Its end is likely to origi-
nate with external debtors.
n That endgame could be messy. Gross capital flows far exceed the
minimal needs of current account financing. These flows can give rise
References
Acharya, V., and P. Schnabl. 2010. Do Global Banks Spread Global Imbalances? Asset-Backed
Commercial Paper During the Financial Crisis of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review 58, no.
1: 37–73.
Adler, G., and D. Garcia-Macia. 2018. The Stabilizing Role of Net Foreign Asset Returns. IMF Work-
ing Paper WP/18/79 (March). Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Bayoumi, T. 2017. Unfinished Business: The Unexplored Causes of the Financial Crisis and the Lessons
Yet to Be Learned. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Bénétrix, A., P. Lane, and J. Shambaugh. 2015. International Currency Exposures, Valuation
Effects, and the Global Financial Crisis. Journal of International Economics 96, no. S1: S98–
S109.
Bernanke, B. 2005. The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit. Sandridge
Lecture to the Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond, VA, March 10.
Bernanke, B., C. Bertaut, L. DeMarco, and S. Kamin. 2011. International Capital Flows and
the Returns to Safe Assets in the United States, 2003–2007. Financial Stability Review
(Banque de France) 15: 13–26.
Gourinchas, P.-O., and H. Rey. 2007. International Financial Adjustment. Journal of Political
Economy 114, no. 4: 665–703.
Hale, G., and M. Obstfeld. 2016. The Euro and the Geography of International Debt Flows.
Journal of the European Economic Association 14, no. 1: 115–44.
Holston, K., T. Laubach, and J. Williams. 2017. Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: Inter-
national Trends and Determinants. Journal of International Economics 108, no. S1: S59–S75.
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2005. Globalization and External Imbalances. In World
Economic Outlook (April). Washington.
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2017. External Sector Report (July). Washington.
Kaminsky, G., and C. Reinhart. 1999. The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-
of-Payments Problems. American Economic Review 89, no. 3: 473–500.
Lane, P. and G. Milesi-Ferretti. 2015. Global Imbalances and External Adjustment After the
Crisis. In Global Liquidity, Spillovers to Emerging Markets and Policy Responses, ed. C. Raddatz,
D. Saravia, and J. Ventura. Santiago: Central Bank of Chile.
Lane, P., and G. Milesi-Ferretti. 2018. The External Wealth of Nations Revisited: International
Financial Integration in the Aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis. IMF Economic Review
66, no. 1: 189–222.
The more advanced economies in Asia are experiencing slower growth rates.
Structural reforms are the most important policies for keeping growth rates
up, but this chapter takes the growth slowdown as given and focuses on
implications for monetary policy. The key policy implication is the impor-
tance of keeping core inflation at or above 2 percent to avoid prolonged
periods of economic slack.
Flexible inflation targeting has provided a successful and adaptable
framework for monetary policy worldwide.1 It is hard to overstate the im-
portance for monetary policy of keeping inflation within the central bank’s
policy mandate. Such mandates typically specify some target for average
inflation in the medium term, either a single number or some range. In
our view, such a target should be no less than, and possibly greater than, 2
percent.
Forecasts at the time of writing (January 2018) suggest strong global
growth in 2018. The threat of deflation has faded in most countries. But
with inflation expectations still comparatively low, monetary policy should
react promptly to any significant negative shocks to growth or to inter-
Joseph E. Gagnon is senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics. Philip Turner is visiting
lecturer at the University of Basel and former deputy head of the Monetary and Economic Department at the
Bank for International Settlements. This chapter reflects the views of the authors and should not be interpreted
as reflecting the views of the Institute or the Bank or any members of the boards or staffs of those institutions.
1. Graeme Wheeler, “Reflections on 25 years of inflation targeting,” speech at Reserve Bank
of New Zealand and International Journal of Central Banking conference, Wellington,
December 1, 2014.
285
national financial markets (e.g., a new taper tantrum). In Thailand, core
inflation remains well below 2 percent and there is a case for additional
monetary ease already.
Japan failed to keep inflation above zero after a severe financial crisis
and suffered two decades of excess unemployment and forgone output.
The longer inflation is allowed to remain below target, the harder it is to
raise inflation to target. When inflation expectations settle at low levels,
central banks have less scope to use conventional monetary policy to stabi-
lize cyclical fluctuations. Central banks, however, can still expand their
balance sheets (so-called unconventional policy) when the conventional
policy rate is near zero.
We rebut three possible criticisms of our advice.
First, it is argued that monetary policy has only a weak impact on infla-
tion as reflected in declining estimates of the slope of the Phillips curve. We
suggest that the Phillips curve slope is nonlinear in both the output gap and
the level of inflation. When inflation is close to zero, a negative output gap
has very little effect on inflation because of downward rigidities in nominal
wages and prices. But a positive output gap is expected to have a significant
effect, and this effect is likely to grow as the gap becomes larger.
Second, it is argued that central banks should stick to setting the over-
night rate and should avoid the so-called unconventional balance sheet
policies of the kind implemented by the Federal Reserve, European Central
Bank (ECB), Bank of Japan (BOJ), and Bank of England. This view is unhis-
torical. Central banks have used their balance sheets to advance their objec-
tives since their inception more than 300 years ago. In Asia, the accumula-
tion of foreign exchange reserves and related policies to stabilize financial
markets and control any excess liquidity in domestic banks were major
planks of monetary policy in the years during and after the Asian financial
crisis. What is new is that the substantial development of domestic financial
markets in emerging-market economies has widened the possibilities for
balance sheet policies. Because bond markets have become more important
in monetary policy transmission in Asia, and because the liquidity of such
bond markets can be especially fragile when global markets are disturbed,
balance sheet policies should be on the policy agenda. This would be rein-
forced if weak growth and low inflation were to push the policy rate to zero.
Third, it is argued that easy monetary policy encourages risky behavior
in financial markets. We argue that the evidence for such an effect is very
weak. Moreover, ultra-low inflation and persistent negative output gaps
themselves raise risks to financial stability. Prudential regulatory policies
are far more potent at preserving financial stability than monetary policy.
Regulatory policy includes tools such as bank capital and liquidity require-
ments; rules on currency and maturity mismatches in banks; limits to
interest rate exposures; and enhanced stress tests to make sure the balance
sheets of financial intermediaries are resilient to any eventual tightening of
monetary policy. New macroprudential policy tools (such as loan-to-value
and debt-to-income ratios for house mortgages) give the central bank new
ways of limiting risks to financial stability arising from low interest rates.
5 5 5
0
0 0
5 5 10
5
0 0 0
1985 1995 2005 2015 1985 1995 2005 2015 1985 1995 2005 2015
2. Nakaso (2001) provides an authoritative account of how it took years for the authorities
in Japan to develop policies to deal with this financial crisis.
3. In the four quarters following each increase in the consumption tax, the inflation rate
shown in figure 13.3 was adjusted downward by the change in inflation in the first quarter
minus the change in inflation in the fifth quarter divided by two. The consumption tax was
increased in 1997Q2 and 2014Q2.
Growth rate of nominal GDP Inflation rate, CPI excluding food and energy
4-quarter change, percent 4-quarter change, percent
20
20
15
10 10
5
0
0
−10 −5
1955 1975 1995 2015 1955 1975 1995 2015
5 5.0
4 2.5
3 0
2 −2.5
1
−5.0
0
1955 1975 1995 2015 1955 1975 1995 2015
4. Note that the BOJ estimates that output is slightly above potential in 2017 with an unem-
ployment rate slightly below 3 percent.
6. Wyplosz (2001) also argues for optimal rates of inflation above 2 percent in major Euro-
pean economies.
0 0 0
−10
−10 −10
Hong Kong India Indonesia
10 10
10
0 0
0
−10 −10 −10
Japan Korea Malaysia
10 10 10
0 0 0
Note: Real interest rate is three-month Treasury bill rate (or closest equ-
ivalent) minus current consumer price index (CPI) inflation rate.
Sources: Haver Analytics and IMF International Financial Statistics and
World Economic Outlook databases.
since mid-2011 (graph 2 in Hördahl, Sobrun, and Turner 2016). Rachel and
Smith (2015) attribute about two-thirds of the long-run decline to secular
factors shaping desired saving and investment rates in the global economy.
They argue that the likely persistence of these factors suggests that the
underlying global neutral real rate will settle at around 1 percent in the
medium to long run.7 If this prognosis is correct, central banks will again
grapple with the zero lower bound for the policy rate.
7. Laubach and Williams (2015) also estimate a long-run equilibrium real rate of around 1
percent for the United States. They attribute the decline in the long-run equilibrium real rate
mainly to the decline in the growth rate of potential output.
yield
Emerging Asia
2 United States
Advanced economies
excluding United States
and Japan
0
Note: Vertical lines denote the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008
and the taper tantrum in July 2013. Emerging Asia is the unweighted average of
Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Taiwan, and Thailand. Advanced
economies are the unweighted average of Australia, Canada, euro area, New
Zealand, Sweden, and United Kingdom.
Sources: Bank for International Settlements and Haver Analytics.
percent
1
Short-term interest rate
Core CPI inflation
0
percent
8. The predicted value is from a survey of professional economic forecasters and is provided
by Haver Analytics. The inflation forecast of four quarters earlier should have incorporated
the effects of the gap of four quarters earlier, leaving no systematic prediction error if fore-
casters are efficient. An alternative specification based on the contemporaneous output gap
and forecasted inflation with a four-quarter lag had a lower R2 (0.12) and a much smaller
coefficient on the gap of 0.46.
tion dummy equals zero when inflation is above 3 percent and one when
inflation is below 3 percent.
The results show that the gap has a large and strongly significant effect
when inflation is above 3 percent, but the effect largely disappears when
inflation is below 3 percent. This simple model can explain nearly 60 percent
of the overall variance of inflation, as shown by the R2 statistic. The second
column displays results using an alternative measure of the output gap: the
Federal Reserve’s index of capacity utilization in manufacturing, mining,
and utilities minus its average value since 1967. The effect on inflation of a
1 percentage point gap in capacity utilization is about half as large as that of
a 1 percentage point employment gap, but the explanatory power is essen-
tially identical. As with the employment gap, the effect of the capacity utili-
zation gap declines sharply when inflation is very low.
The remaining columns of table 13.1 display results using a lagged
three-year moving average of inflation as a measure of inflation expecta-
tions (equation 13.2). The regression shown in column 3 has a much longer
sample, back to 1950, and a somewhat lower R2 than column 1. But the
coefficients on the employment gap are reasonably close to those in column
To check whether the Phillips curve slope may have changed over time,
we also ran the regressions of table 13.1 starting in 1992Q1, just after US
inflation fell below 3 percent on a sustained basis. There are only nine quar-
ters with inflation above 3 percent in this subsample (2004Q4–2006Q3 and
2007Q1), yet we obtain estimates of the gap coefficients that are almost
identical to those shown in columns 1 and 2 and moderately smaller than
those in columns 3 to 5.
Figure 13.8 displays the inflation surprises (left-hand sides of equa-
tions 13.1 and 13.2) and employment gaps (right-hand sides of both equa-
tions), where the sample is split between lagged inflation above and below 3
percent. Similar results (not shown) are obtained using capacity utilization.
The greater slope in the high inflation regime is apparent for both measures
of expectations. It also appears that the slope may steepen for the most
positive values of the output gap. However, adding the interacted value of
the output gap and a dummy when the output gap is above its mean value
yields a significant coefficient (at the 10 percent level) in only the first of the
five regressions shown in table 13.1.
8 8
6 6
4 4
2 2
0 0
−2 −2
−4 −4
−6 −6
−5 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 −5 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3
employment gap employment gap
8 8
6 6
4 4
2 2
0 0
−2 −2
−4 −4
−6 −6
−5 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 −5 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3
employment gap employment gap
302GRAPHICS
2 - CHAPTER
SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
13—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
Table 13.3 Scope for quantitative easing, December 2016 (percent of
2016Q4 GDP, seasonally adjusted annual rate)
General
Central bank government Equity market
Country liabilities gross debt Broad moneya capitalization
Australia 10 41 112 100
Bangladesh b
n.a. 33 55 16
China 45 44 202 66
Hong Kongc 60 0 232 560
Indiad 21 70 82 69
Indonesia 8 28 38 45
Japan 88 239 236 104
Korea 28 38 201 92
Malaysia 35 56 128 131
New Zealande 10 29 99 n.a.
Philippines 30 35 62 80
Singapore 37 112 137 221
Taiwan 87 36 238 157
Thailand 46 42 124 103
Vietnamb n.a. 61 n.a. 3
n.a. = not available
a. M3 where available, otherwise M2.
b. Based on 2016 annual GDP.
c. Data exclude assets denominated in foreign currency and shares of mainland com-
panies.
d. Broad money based on April 2017 to avoid effects of demonetization in late 2016.
e. Central government debt.
Sources: Haver Analytics, Hong Kong Monetary Authority, and International Monetary
Fund World Economic Outlook database.
9. This section draws on Turner (2017), which provides fuller details and references.
10. Janet Yellen, “Monetary policy and financial stability,” 2014 Michel Camdessus Central
Banking Lecture, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, July 2, 2014.
11. “Central banks warned on inflation risk: BIS annual report focuses on danger of interest
rates staying low for too long,” Financial Times, June 26, 2017.
12. Vítor Constâncio, “The evolving risk landscape in the euro area,” speech at a Banco do
Portugal conference on financial stability, October 17, 2017.
very high levels of official foreign exchange reserves. In some cases, quasi-
fixed exchange rate regimes encourage foreign-currency borrowing. Neither
macroeconomic nor precautionary needs justify continued accumulation
of foreign exchange reserves by most large Asian economies. The IMF esti-
mates that the aggregate savings ratio of developing Asia has exceeded 40
percent of GDP for many years—far above that prevailing elsewhere. In such
circumstances, and given the chronic shortfall of aggregate demand at the
global level since the global financial crisis, excess reserve accumulation that
supports a current account surplus exerts a powerful negative externality on
the rest of the world.
In some cases, the stock of foreign exchange reserves may fall as offi-
cials seek to prevent unwanted currency depreciation. For example, China’s
reserves fell by roughly $1 trillion over the past three years. The central bank
Note: Net official assets are foreign exchange reserves plus other official
assets (including sovereign wealth funds) minus official borrowing in
foreign currencies.
Source: Bergsten and Gagnon (2017).
Conclusion
Growth in several Asian economies remains disappointing, and there are
downside risks. With inflation declining to very low levels, central banks in
Asia should be ready to use the policy tools at their disposal to sustain aggre-
gate demand to meet medium-term inflation targets. Indeed, for Thailand
at least, conditions already support further monetary ease.
References
Ahearne, Alan, Joseph Gagnon, Jane Haltmaier, and Steven Kamin. 2002. Preventing Deflation:
Lessons from Japan’s Experience in the 1990s. International Finance Discussion Paper 729.
Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Akerlof, George, William Dickens, and George Perry. 1996. The Macroeconomics of Low In-
flation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1–59. Washington: Brookings Institution.
Ball, Laurence, Joseph Gagnon, Patrick Honohan, and Signe Krogstrup. 2016. What Else Can
Central Banks Do? Geneva Reports on the World Economy 18. Geneva: International Center
for Monetary and Banking Studies.
Bank of Canada. 2013. Backgrounders: Measurement Bias in the Canadian CPI. Available at www.
bankofcanada.ca/wp-content/uploads/2010/11/measurement_bias_canadian_cpi.pdf
(accessed July 13, 2017).
Bank of England. 2014. Inflation Report (November). London.
Bayoumi, Tamim, and Joseph Gagnon. 2018. Unconventional Monetary Policy in the Asian
Financial Crisis. Pacific Economic Review 23, no. 1: 80–94.
Benigno, P., and Luca Ricci. 2011. The Inflation-Output Tradeoff with Downward Wage Ri-
gidities. American Economic Review 101, no. 4: 1436–66.
14. Veerathai Santiprabhob, panel remarks at the 2017 Andrew Crockett Lecture: Boom-Bust
Cycles, Interest Rates and the Global Financial System, Bank for International Settlements,
Basel, June 25, 2017.
The global economy has been underperforming for several years. The perfor-
mance of advanced economies has been lackluster since the 2008–09 global
financial crisis. Strong expansion in emerging-market economies boosted
global growth, but growth in these economies has also decelerated since
2011, largely because of weak commodity prices and the transition in China
to a more balanced pattern of growth. Although global growth picked up in
2017, output gaps remain in many economies, and most countries’ inflation
rates were still below official central bank target rates. Interest rates have
been historically low—but evidently not low enough to fuel a normal recov-
ery and strong expansion. Fiscal policies have been inconsistent, with priori-
ties switching between stimulus and consolidation, often without a long-
term strategy, sometimes adding to cyclical instability. Political opposition
has caused long delays to structural reforms that would raise trend growth.
With a still weak global economy and excess capacity, the possibility of
further large negative shocks remains a concern. Financial vulnerabilities
remain evident in various parts of the world. Credit-fueled booms have in-
flated real estate values in many cities. Corporate balance sheets have weak-
Rania Al-Mashat is an advisor at the Research Department of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and
former subgovernor for monetary policy at the Central Bank of Egypt. Kevin Clinton is a former research ad-
viser at the Bank of Canada and a consultant to the IMF. Benjamin Hunt is assistant director at the Research
Department of the IMF. Zoltan Jakab is a senior economist at the Research Department of the IMF. Douglas
Laxton is the chief of the Economic Modeling Division of the Research Department of the IMF. Hou Wang is an
economist at the Research Department of the IMF. Jiaxiong Yao is an economist at the Research Department of
the IMF. The views expressed in this chapter are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of
the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management.
315
ened, with leverage rebounding to high levels. Restructuring in China could
bring disruptive adjustments and financial stress. Governments have been
raising trade barriers, and protectionist sentiment is on the rise.
In Asia demographics are another potential source of chronic demand
shortfalls. Some analysis suggests that a decline in population growth could
reduce aggregate demand, with few or no self-correcting forces. Several Asian
economies, advanced and emerging alike, are in or will soon enter the phase
of the demographic transition in which fertility declines and lower mortality
results in rapidly aging populations and sharply lower population growth.
This demographic change could mean that “the new mediocre” could
become a problem in Asia—a concern that in part motivated this volume.
Gaspar et al. (2016) argue for assertive policy actions following persis-
tent demand weakness. For countries with wide output gaps, low levels of
employment, below-target rates of inflation, and extremely low long-term
rates of interest, the argument in favor of such a response extends beyond
regular cyclical stabilization. Assertive policy action is also called for to avoid
risk, because a negative shock to the global economy could push several
countries into a low-inflation trap, with central banks unable to respond
strongly, as interest rates are already near their effective lower bound.
Another recession could set off a downslide in expectations of inflation,
even a deflation mentality, undermining the nominal anchor that central
bank inflation targets are supposed to provide. The outcome would be a
bad quasi-equilibrium (a “dark corner”): a low-inflation or deflation trap in
which resources lie idle, with no end in sight.1
A comprehensive, consistent, and coordinated approach (which
Gaspar et al. 2016 refer to as “the 3Cs”) is needed across all macroeconomic
instruments. This chapter focuses on monetary policy, with country case
studies of Australia, India, and Japan.
Assertive monetary policy responses to negative output shocks may
lead central banks to overshoot the official inflation target in the medium
term; they can also cause it to undershoot the target, as in India, where the
response to a jump in food prices may mean that a year of above-target
headline inflation is followed by a short period below target. Central banks
should not be averse to such outcomes when a bad equilibrium lies nearby.
In these situations, the prudent policy is to get away from the bad equilib-
rium as quickly as possible. A prolonged period of below- or above-target
inflation is more likely to destabilize the nominal anchor than a cycle that
sees inflation on both sides of the target rate.
1. The term low-inflation trap refers to a situation in which inflation expectations are stuck
significantly below the inflation target and there are significant risks of deflation.
2. For a discussion of the timeline for several inflation-targeting countries, see Clinton et al.
(2015).
In contrast to the Taylor rule, in which the policy rate reacts � to the
contemporaneous output gap and
�
� � ∑��� 𝛽𝛽
𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿inflation �
������������
deviation��� from � the �
� ∗ � target,
� ���� � ����𝑖𝑖��� � 𝑖𝑖����
the
. � � �������� ∗ � � � �. that
�
inflation 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿� � ∑��� 𝛽𝛽 ����
forecast–based reaction
��� � � � �ignores
function ���� � ����𝑖𝑖 ��� � 𝑖𝑖�����
inflation shocks
. are expected to reverse within the three-quarter policy horizon. Although
central banks should not care about small temporary deviations, they
should care a lot about large, long-lasting deviations. A quadratic loss func-
tion, in which the marginal cost of deviations of inflation and output from
desired values increases exponentially as they grow, better captures such
preferences. It is particularly appropriate when a bad equilibrium threatens
to take hold of the economy. Historically, two types of bad equilibrium (in
both of which inflation expectations go adrift) have preoccupied central
banks: a low-inflation trap and an inflation spiral. As a quadratic loss func-
tion would imply aggressive policy actions when confronted with a mate-
3. Indeed, policy modelers design these models to make it impossible to simulate with an
exogenous path (constant or based on market expectations) for the policy rate. Sometimes
these models are simulated by assuming that the interest rate is exogenous over some short-
term horizon but that agents believe that at some point in the future the monetary authority
will start to adjust its instruments sufficiently aggressively to anchor inflation and infla-
tion expectations. In these forward-looking models, this assumption helps anchor inflation
expectations in the short run. Policymakers should be skeptical of forecasts based on exog-
enous paths for the policy rate.
5. For a discussion of the Czech experience with publishing forecasts, see Clinton et al.
(2017).
index
15
13
11
1
1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Country Examples
Three country examples illustrate how a risk-avoidance strategy for mone-
tary policy can be implemented. Australia is a large commodity-exporting
economy closely linked to the rest of the world. Its monetary policy faces
several challenges going forward—challenges that are similar to those that
central banks in other advanced economies have faced. With the comple-
tion of the institutional foundation of a flexible inflation-targeting regime,
India has seen Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation decline markedly, but
it will take time to establish credibility in the new regime. After years of low
growth and near deflation, Japan needs comprehensive policies to achieve a
higher sustainable growth path and anchor inflation to the 2 percent target.
326
3.0 0.5
2.5 0
2.0 –0.5
1.5 –1.0
–1.5
1.0
–2.0
0.5 1 1 1
1 1 1 1 6: 3 :1 3 8: 3 9: :3
3 7: 3 8: 3 3 1 1 6: 17 1 7: 1 18: 1 19
16: 6: 1 1 7: 8: 19: 9: 20 20 20 20
01 20 201 01 01 20 20 20 20
20 2 20 2 20 2
c. Exchange rate d. Headline inflation
Australian dollar per US dollar percent, year over year
1.6 4.0
3.5
1.4 2.5
2.0
1.3 1.5
1.0
1.2 :1 :3 :1 :3 :1 :3 :1 :3
:1 :1 1 1 16 16 17 17 18 18 19 19
16 6 :3 17 7 :3 8: 8:3 1 9: 9:3 20 20 20 20 20
01 20 20 20
20 201 20 201 2 2 01 20 2 01
2.5 0
2.0 –0.5
1.5 –1.0
1.0 –1.5
–2.0
0.5
:1 3 :1 1 3 1 3 :1 :3 :1 :3 :1 :3 :1 :3
16 6: 17 :3 18: 8: 19: 9: 16 16 17 17 18 18 19 19
1 17 1 1 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20
20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20
c. Exchange rate d. Headline inflation
Australian dollar per US dollar percent, year over year
1.6 4.0
3.5
1.5
3.0
1.4 2.5
2.0
1.3
1.5
1.0
1.2
1 3 :1 3 :1 3 1 :3
:1 :3 :1 :3 :1 :3 :1 :3 1 6: 1 6: 17 1 7: 18 1 8: 1 9: 19
16 16 17 7 8 8 9 9 20 20 20 20
20 01 01 01 01 01 20 20 20 20
20 20 2 2 2 2 2
327
with fiscal support and more aggressive monetary policy
–8 0 0
0 8 16 24 32 40 0 8 16 24 32 40 0 8 16 24 32 40
Baseline
Nastier supply shock
Nastier supply shock with delayed policy
rate profits, and lifted actual and expected inflation into positive territory.
The economy reached close to full employment, and base wages increased
modestly.
Despite this progress, the economy was still in a dark corner in early
2017, with interest rates at their floor and long-term inflation expectations
well below 2 percent. Adoption of inflation-forecast targeting should have
provided the basis for more consistent communications to explain how
6. This section is based largely on Arbatli et al. (2016) and Gaspar et al. (2016).
7. Monetary policy in the simulations targets inflation excluding the direct impact of the
VAT increase. As a result, the relevant inflation comparison between the scenarios is the one
excluding the direct impact of the VAT increase.
0.6 –1.0
0.4
–1.5
0.2
0 –2.0
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
130 –2
–3
128
–4
126
–5
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Baseline
Three Arrows Plus policy package
Conclusion
The global economy has underperformed for a decade. There is strong evi-
dence that the real equilibrium level of the interest rate—the rate consis-
tent with the maintenance of full employment and stable inflation—may
be close to zero. Bond yields have fallen to extremely low levels, and nega-
tive output gaps and below-target inflation rates persist, despite near-zero
central bank policy rates. The effective lower bound on rates suggests that
conventional monetary policy may not be able to put up strong resistance
to a future economic downturn.
Current uncertainties suggest that policymakers should prepare for
nasty surprises from a variety of sources, including structural rebalancing
in China; financial sector vulnerabilities in several countries; weakened cor-
porate balance sheets; an asymmetric tightening of monetary conditions;
runaway real estate booms in cities, allied to high levels of household debt;
a low but rising tide of protectionism; and the deleterious effects of de-
mographics. The effect of a large shock from one or more of these sources
could be worse than a short-lived global recession. It could push the world
economy to the dark corner of a low-inflation or deflation trap, in which
resources lie idle with no end in sight. The nominal anchor for the economy
could become unhinged, as the public comes to expect that official inflation
targets will not be met and large-scale unemployment becomes chronic.
Weak growth in nominal incomes would worsen prospects for stabilizing
the uptrend in government debt-to-GDP ratios.
Governments and central banks should have contingency plans for
dealing with such dismal prospects. Despite widespread perception that
monetary and fiscal policies have run out of ammunition, there is room for
maneuver. Transparent, assertive policies must be conducted within a cred-
ible framework for long-term stability. A prudent approach to a recession-
ary shock from a weak starting point may be to take an aggressive stance,
committing to holding the policy rate at the effective lower bound for an
extended period. Such an approach may well lead to a short-run overshoot-
References
Andrle, M., P. Blagrave, P. Espaillat, K. Honjo, B. Hunt, M. Kortelainen, R. Lalonde, D. Laxton,
E. Mavroeidi, D. Muir, S. Mursula, and S. Snudden. 2015. The Flexible System of Global Mod-
els: FSGM. IMF Working Paper 15/64. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Arbatli, E., D. Botman, K. Clinton, P. Cova, V. Gaspar, Z. Jakab, D. Laxton, C. Ngouana,
J. Mongardini, and H. Wang. 2016. Reflating Japan: Time to Get Unconventional? IMF Work-
ing Paper 16/157. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Barro, R., and D. Gordon. 1983. Rules, Discretion, and Reputation in a Model of Monetary
Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, no. 1: 101–21.
Batini, N., and D. Laxton. 2007. Under What Conditions Can Inflation Targeting Be Adopt-
ed? The Experience of Emerging Markets. In Monetary Policy Under Inflation Targeting, ed. F.
S. Mishkin and K. Schmidt-Hebbel. Santiago: Banco Central de Chile.
Benes, J., K. Clinton, A. George, J. John, O. Kamenik, D. Laxton, P. Mitra, G.V. Nadhanael,
H. Wang, and F. Zhang. 2017a. Inflation-Forecast Targeting for India: An Outline of the Ana-
lytical Framework. IMF Working Paper 17/32. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Benes, J., K. Clinton, A. George, P. Gupta, J. John, O. Kamenik, D. Laxton, P. Mitra, G.V. Nad-
hanael, R. Portillo, H. Wang, and F. Zhang. 2017b. Quarterly Projection Model for India: Key
Elements and Properties. IMF Working Paper 17/33. Washington: International Monetary
Fund.
BIS (Bank for International Settlements). 2017. 87th Annual Report (June). Basel.
Charbonneau, K., and L. Rennison. 2015. Forward Guidance at the Effective Lower Bound: Inter-
national Experience. Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper 2015–15. Ottawa: Bank of
Canada.
Clinton, K., C. Freedman, M. Juillard, O. Kamenik, D. Laxton, and H. Wang. 2015. Inflation-
Forecast Targeting: Applying the Principle of Transparency. IMF Working Paper 15/132. Wash-
ington: International Monetary Fund.
Clinton, K., T. Hlédik, T. Holub, D. Laxton, and H. Wang. 2017. Czech Magic: Implementing In-
flation-Forecast Targeting at the CNB. IMF Working Paper 17/21. Washington: International
Monetary Fund.
Dincer, N., and B. Eichengreen. 2014. Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates
and New Measures. International Journal of Central Banking 10, no. 1: 189–259.
Engen, E., T. Laubach, and D. Reifschneider. 2015. The Macroeconomic Effects of the Federal Re-
serve’s Unconventional Monetary Policies. Finance and Economic Discussion Series 2015–005.
Washington: Federal Reserve Board.
Gaspar, V., M. Obstfeld, R. Sahay, D. Laxton, D. Botman, K. Clinton, R. Duval, K. Ishi, Z. Jakab,
L. Jaramillo Mayor, C. Lonkeng Ngouana, T. Mancini Griffoli, J. Mongardini, S. Mursula,
E. Nier, Y. Ustyugova, H. Wang, and O. Wuensch. 2016. Macroeconomic Management When
Policy Space Is Constrained: A Comprehensive, Consistent and Coordinated Approach to Economic
Policy. IMF Staff Discussion Note 16/09. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Helbling, T., P. Karam, O. Kamenik, D. Laxton, H. Wang, and H. Yao. 2017. Inflation Targeting
in Australia: Performance, Challenges, and Strategy Going Forward. IMF Country Report 17/43.
Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Several countries in Asia face the risk of settling into a new mediocre of
lower growth. Rapid population aging and weak productivity are increas-
ingly taking a toll on medium- to long-term economic potential. There is
a lot fiscal policy can do to address the risk of a new mediocre. Investing in
productive public infrastructure, lowering distortionary taxes, and reform-
ing labor markets are prominent avenues through which fiscal policy can
improve productivity and growth paths. These fiscal initiatives can be costly,
however. Countries already experiencing symptoms of the new mediocre
face the double challenge of absorbing higher levels of age-related spending
and coping with low productivity growth.
This chapter analyzes the implications of the new mediocre for
medium- to long-term fiscal sustainability and quantifies the potential of
fiscal reforms to improve growth. It is organized as follows. The first section
examines the effects of the new mediocre on long-term projections of public
debt. The second section examines whether current public spending and
revenue policies are aligned with the challenges of the new mediocre. The
third section illustrates the growth payoff of fiscal reform packages in three
areas: public infrastructure, tax rebalancing, and labor markets. The last
Ana Corbacho is division chief at the Intenational Monetary Fund (IMF). Dirk Muir, Masahiro Nozaki, and
Edda Zoli are senior economists at the IMF. The authors thank Medha Madhu Nair for valuable research as-
sistance; Francis Landicho for coordination of the editing and production; and Thomas Helbling, Kenneth Kang,
Junghun Kim, Changyong Rhee, Markus Rodlauer, and IMF country teams for useful comments and feedback.
The views expressed in this chapter are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF,
its Executive Board, or its management.
343
section discusses the design of fiscal institutions and key reforms to address
the new mediocre and boost growth in Asia.
1. Projections are based on the World Economic Outlook of April 2017 (IMF 2017c).
percent of GDP
250
10–90th percentile band
200 Median
150
100
50
0
Advanced Other Developing Emerging Latin Sub-Saharan Middle East
Asia advanced Asia Europe America Africa and
North Africa
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; IMF Staff calculations.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 345
Figure 15.2 Actual and projected public debt in selected
Asian economies
percent of GDP
120
2016
100 2022
80
60
40
20
0
ia a h s r a d a ia s ia a e
es di es ine ma ore ilan hin ys nam Lao Ind ank por
n bo lad ipp a n K a C la iet L a
do m g il y Th M
a
V i
Sr Sin
g
In Ca Ban Ph M
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; IMF Staff
calculations.
percent of GDP
25
2015
2030
20 2050
15
10
0
a ia s
di es ne sia ka in
a
am re
a nd pa
n
In n pi ay an Ch tn Ko ila Ja
do p al L e a
In ili M Sri Vi Th
Ph
Sources: United Nations (2015); Amaglobeli and Shi (2016); IMF Staff calculations.
ment, little impetus from trade, weaker human capital formation, and the
reallocation of resources to less productive sectors of the economy. The pro-
ductivity slowdown has been most pronounced in the advanced economies
of the region and China (IMF 2017b). The decline in real interest rates ob-
served since the 1980s can be expected to reverse only moderately over the
medium term (IMF 2014c).
This section presents long-term projections for public debt reflecting
the impact of the new mediocre. The analysis covers 10 Asian economies
(chosen based on data availability): Japan (Group 1); China, Korea, and
Thailand (Group 2); and India, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Sri
Lanka, and Vietnam (Group 3). (See box 15.1.)
Methodology
The ratio of public debt to GDP(dt) evolves as follows:
𝑖𝑖��� � ����
𝑑𝑑��� � 𝑑𝑑� � 𝑑𝑑 � �����,,
� � ���� �
CHAPTER
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL 15—GRAPHICS
POLICY DO? 3471
𝑖𝑖��� � �
𝑑𝑑��� � 𝑑𝑑� �
� � ���
where it, gt, and pbt denote the nominal interest rate on public debt (com-
puted as interest payments divided by the previous year’s debt outstanding),
nominal GDP growth, and the primary balance as percent of GDP, respec-
tively. The debt ratio increases at the rate of ���� �����
������ (the interest rate growth
differential [IRGD] divided by (1 + gt+1)) and decreases with the primary
surplus.
Four scenarios are considered, based on extrapolation of the projec-
tions in the IMF’s World Economic Outlook April 2017 database (IMF 2017c)
for 2022–50:2
n Scenario 1: Status quo. The primary balance, nominal GDP growth, and
nominal interest rate for 2023–50 are assumed to remain at 2022 levels.
The IRGD is negative for all countries. The primary balance is in surplus
in Korea, Malaysia, and Sri Lanka and in deficit for the remaining coun-
tries (table 15.1).
n Scenario 2: Historical primary balance. The primary balance for 2023–50
is assumed to reflect its historical average over 2000–15. This scenario
examines cases in which the projected primary balance for 2022 appears
optimistic compared with the historical track.3 GDP growth and the
interest rate for 2023–50 are unchanged at their 2022 levels.
n Scenario 3: Demographics. The primary balance is assumed to worsen
from the 2022 level by the projected increase in pension and healthcare
spending.4 GDP growth from Scenario 1 is adjusted by the impact of
aging on the underlying labor force.5 The interest rate is left unchanged
at the 2022 level.
n Scenario 4: Productivity and interest rates. Productivity growth could con-
tinue to slow. Together with the demographic shift, it could cause the
2. These scenarios correspond to stylized simulations under certain assumptions for the key
parameters that underlie the evolution of the public debt-to-GDP ratio and should not be
considered the baseline projections of the IMF. For the latter, refer to the respective Article
IV Staff Reports.
3. In some countries (e.g., India), the lower primary balance projected by 2022 is supported
by structural reforms driving a decline in primary fiscal spending.
4. Pension and healthcare spending projections are based on United Nations (2015) and
Amaglobeli and Shi (2016). These projections incorporate mainly the impact of demographics
on age-related spending, holding constant the coverage as well as replacement ratios, except
in countries with ongoing parametric reforms. Reforms that improve coverage or benefits
would translate into higher spending. The IMF Fiscal Monitor (www.imf.org/en/publications/
fm) publishes estimates of the net present value of the projected increase in pension and
healthcare spending over 2015–50.
5. The labor force is assumed to grow at the rate of the working-age population, computed
from United Nations (2015).
CHAPTER
Projection for 2022 Historical average for 2000-15
Real Real
interest Interest interest Interest
Primary rate on rate Primary rate on rate
balance Real GDP public growth balance Real GDP public growth
(percent growth debt differential (percent growth debt differential
Country Group of GDP) (percent) (percent) (percent) of GDP) (percent) (percent) (percent)
A 15—GRAPHICS
Japan 1 –2.0 0.6 –0.6 –1.2 –5.8 0.9 1.9 1.0
China 2 –2.1 5.7 –0.3 –6.0 –0.8 9.6 –2.0 –11.6
Korea 2 1.7 3.1 1.9 –1.2 1.5 4.3 2.3 –2.0
Thailand 2 –0.6 3.0 1.7 –1.3 0.4 4.1 0.1 –4.0
India 3 –1.3 8.2 3.4 –4.8 –3.7 7.1 2.2 –4.8
Indonesia 3 –0.8 5.5 2.3 –3.2 1.1 5.4 –3.4 –8.8
Malaysia 3 0.9 4.8 2.2 –2.6 –2.5 5.1 2.0 –3.1
Philippines 3 –0.4 7.0 1.5 –5.5 2.2 5.1 3.7 –1.4
Vietnam 3 –2.2 6.2 –0.7 –6.9 –2.0 6.5 –6.7 –13.2
Sri Lanka 3 1.2 5.3 2.2 –3.1 –1.7 5.7 –1.5 –7.2
Sources: IMF World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; IMF Staff calculations.
Some caveats are in order. First, Scenarios 3, 4a, and 4b assume that the
increase in age-related spending will be fully financed by government bor-
rowing. But governments would likely react by rationalizing spending, mo-
bilizing revenue, or both. Second, an acceleration of problems in later years
makes the response of governments even more uncertain and difficult to
assess. Third, when considering the IRGD, whether sovereign risk premia can
remain contained in countries with a rapid increase in public debt is ques-
tionable and can modify the results. Fourth, the methodology abstracts from
the impact of exchange rate movements on the debt ratio or any fiscal risks.
Results
Countries’ public debt-to-GDP ratios develop as follows under each scenario
(figure 15.4):
n Under Scenario 1, the debt ratio decreases or stabilizes in all econo-
mies, driven by the negative IRGD. The debt ratio is contained well
below 50 percent of GDP in the long term for all economies except
Japan, where the debt ratio is projected to decrease but remain above
200 percent of GDP.
n Under Scenario 2, the debt ratio increases in Japan, India, and Malaysia
and remains flat in Sri Lanka, where the historical primary deficit was
substantially higher than the level projected for 2022.
n Under Scenario 3, pension and healthcare spending impose a signifi-
cant fiscal burden on the rapidly aging Asian economies. In China,
Japan, and Thailand, the debt ratio rises shortly after 2022. In China
and Thailand it exceeds 100 percent by 2050. In Korea and Vietnam, the
debt ratio hits its nadir around 2030 and then rises to 110 percent in
Korea and 115 percent in Vietnam by 2050. The debt paths for Malaysia
and Sri Lanka are well above those of Scenario 1. For India, Indonesia,
and the Philippines—the youngest economies in the sample—the impact
of aging on the debt path is much more muted, with the debt ratio for
2050 exceeding that in Scenario 1 by only about 15 percentage points.
Japan China
450 160
400 140
350 120
300 100
250 80
200
60
150
40
100
20
50
0
0
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
Korea Thailand
160 250
140
120 200
100
150
80
60 100
40
20 50
0
–20 0
–40 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
India Indonesia
90 100
80
80
70
60 60
50
40
40
30 20
20
0
10
0 –20
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 351
Figure 15.4 Actual and projected public debt in selected Asian
economies, 2000–50 (percent of GDP) (continued)
Malaysia Philippines
90 80
80
70 60
60
40
50
40 20
30
20 0
10
0 –20
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
–40
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
n Under Scenario 4a, the gradual decline in the IRGD does not have a
large impact on the debt path, except in Japan, where the debt ratio in
2050 falls by 50 percentage points compared with Scenario 3, reflecting
its elevated level.
n Under Scenario 4b, the gradual but significant increase in the IRGD
raises the debt-to-GDP ratio in 2050, particularly in Japan (by 140 per-
centage points compared with Scenario 3) and Thailand (40 percentage
Figure 15.5 decomposes the change in the debt ratio over 2022–50 under
Scenario 4b into three factors: the status quo primary balance as of 2022,
the increase in age-related spending, and the IRGD. In Japan, where the debt
level is already very high, the stability of the debt path hinges on maintain-
ing a favorable IRGD and a primary balance in the face of still rising age-re-
lated spending. China, Korea, and Thailand (Group 2) face significant fiscal
pressures from aging in the long term, but Korea has kept its debt level low
and will have more time to address rising age-related spending than China
and Thailand. Group 3 countries are more diverse. Indonesia and the Philip-
pines have built fiscal buffers, and demographic prospects do not appear to
pose a threat to fiscal sustainability. Stabilizing debt paths in India, Malay-
sia, and Sri Lanka hinges on a negative IRGD (India) or a behavioral shift
from the past to maintain a primary surplus over the long term (Malaysia
and Sri Lanka). Vietnam’s debt prospects look similar to China’s, with de-
mographics negatively affecting debt dynamics relatively early.
6. Theoretically, a negative IRGD implies that the economy is dynamically inefficient (i.e.,
reducing the saving rates would leave all generations better off). Mankiw (2015) argues that
such a Pareto-improving opportunity is unlikely to be sustained. Escolano, Shabunina, and
Woo (2017) attribute negative IRGDs in developing economies to real interest rates well
below market equilibrium, reflecting financial repression and captive and distorted markets.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 353
354
Figure 15.5 Decomposition of change in debt ratio under Scenario 4b
percent of GDP
250
200
150
100
50
0
–50
–100
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; IMF Staff calculations.
innovation (IMF 2016); and fiscal policies for labor and product market
reforms that increase productivity (IMF 2014b, Banerji et al. 2017).
This section presents stylized facts on the level, composition, and effi-
ciency of public spending and tax systems in Asian economies, benchmarked
against countries from other regions at similar income levels.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 355
356
Figure 15.6 Index of quality of infrastructure
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; World Economic Forum; IMF Staff calculations.
Figure 15.7 Efficiency frontier of public investment
120
100
80
60
40
Frontier Group 1
Group 2 Group 3
20 Emerging Europe Latin America
Other advanced Other
0
0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 50,000 60,000
public capital stock per capita (dollars)
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 357
Figure 15.8 Public spending on health care as percent of GDP in
selected economies, 2001 and 2014
percent of GDP
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
pa
n a g a e
in on re or an
d sh dia sia dia os ka lia sia es am ed pe ica
Ja Ch K Ko gap hail a de bo ne In La Lan ngo lay pin etn a nc uro er
l o i a i p i v E m
ng n T ng am Ind
o
Sr M M hil V ad ing in A
Ho Si Ba C P r
e g at
th er L
O Em
2014
2001
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; World Economic Forum;
IMF Staff calculations.
75
70
65
60
55
50
45 Frontier Group 1
Group 2 Group 3
40 Other advanced Latin America
Emerging Europe Other
35
0 1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000
healthcare expenditure per capita
(purchasing power parity dollars)
percent of GDP
8
7 2014
2001
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
pa
n a g a e d
in on re or an sh dia sia dia os ka sia es d e
ce rop eric
a
Ja Ch K Ko gap hail a de bo ne In La Lan lay pin a n u
l o i a ip m
ng n T ng Cam Ind Sr M hil dv g E A
Ho Si Ba P r a gin atin
e
th er L
O Em
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; World Economic
Forum; IMF Staff calculations.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 359
360
Figure 15.11 Efficiency frontier of public spending on education
100
80
60
40
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; World Economic Forum; IMF Staff
calculations.
Figure 15.11 Efficiency frontier of public spending on education
b. PISA scores
PISA score
600
500
400
300
361
calculations.
Figure 15.12 Spending on research and development in selected
economies, 2015
percent of GDP
0
a a a a a sia es m
pa
n e
in ong re or and sia di nk oli n a ed pe ica
Ja Ch K Ko gap ail o ne In La ng alay ppi etn a nc uro er
i ili Vi m
ng n Th d Sr M
o M dv g E A
Ho Si In Ph r a gin atin
e r
th e L
O Em
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; World Economic Forum;
IMF Staff calculations.
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
GDP per capita (US dollars in logs)
Group 1 Group 2
Group 3 Other advanced (average)
Emerging Europe Latin America (average)
(average) Other
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; World Economic
Forum; IMF Staff calculations.
percent
40
25
20
15
10
0
a h ia ia ia s a ia s
pa
n a e
in ong re or and es od es Ind Lao ank ys ine ed pe ica
Ja Ch K Ko gap ail l ad b on L ala ipp a nc uro er
h i m
n g n T ng Cam Ind Sr M hil d gE A
v
Ho Si Ba P r a gin atin
e
th er L
O Em
Note: Tax yields are defined as income tax revenues in percent of GDP divided by
the middle and the maximum statutory tax rates.
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; IMF, Government
Finance Statistics; IMF Staff calculations.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 363
364
Figure 15.15 Sources of tax revenue in selected economies, 2015
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook April 2017 database; IMF, Government Finance Statistics;
IMF Staff calculations.
The simulations are based on the IMF’s APDMOD, a semi-structural
model of the global economy that includes blocks for 16 Asian countries
and 8 regions representing the rest of the world.11 The model’s fiscal sector
includes spending on consumption; infrastructure; transfers; lump-sum
taxation on households; and distortionary taxation on consumption, labor,
and capital. Only some households (“saving” households) hold debt as a
source of wealth, which allows them to smooth consumption in the face of
shocks or policy changes. Other households cannot save effectively; these
liquidity-constrained households live off their current income.12 These non-
Ricardian properties allow a powerful role for fiscal policy in both the short
and long term. For most countries, monetary policy is assumed to follow an
inflation-targeting regime.
By implementing fiscal policy reforms, Asian countries can achieve
stronger growth and productivity, although some measures impose short-
term costs on households and firms. These costs can be mitigated by ad-
dressing adverse effects on income equality and by phasing implementation
over time. Better results may be achievable by taking advantage of synergies
with monetary policy in countries facing low inflation.13
11. APDMOD is part of the Flexible System of Global Models (FSGM). See Andrle et al.
(2015) for a complete treatment of the model.
12. APDMOD assumes that 60 percent of households in Asian countries are liquidity
constrained, except in Hong Kong, Japan, Korea, and Singapore, where liquidity-constrained
households represent just 35 percent of the population. Liquidity-constrained households
account for 20 to 30 percent of total consumption in the advanced Asian economies and 45
to 55 percent in the others.
13. For a discussion of the concepts of coordination and comprehensiveness, particularly
around the use of spending, tax, and labor measures, see Gaspar, Obstfeld, and Sahay (2016).
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 365
up the size of the public capital stock by 5 percentage points.14 Invest-
ment then increases permanently by 0.2 percent of GDP to replace the
loss from an annual depreciation rate of 4 percent. Economies near the
frontier or in which spending is already high (the advanced economies
and China) do not participate.
Financing varies across the region. In many of the economies
analyzed, half of it is in the form of PPP, accounted for as private invest-
ment and debt and recouped by user fees.15 The other half is traditional
public investment, financed by a temporary reduction in general trans-
fers. In two countries (Cambodia and the Philippines), the fiscal deficit
is allowed to increase.
2. Rebalancing toward indirect taxes. VAT collection increases by 1.5 percent
of GDP. It is offset by cuts of 0.75 percent of GDP to both the personal
and the corporate income tax.16 The increase excludes additional tax
changes needed to finance labor sector reforms (see below). Some econ-
omies do not participate fully or at all, either because doing so would
conflict with other goals (Japan and India, with baseline scenarios that
already factor in VAT increases) or because direct taxes already repre-
sent a small share of tax revenues (Bangladesh, China, Hong Kong, and
Sri Lanka).
For countries in Group 3, liquidity-constrained households receive
a 0.5 percent of GDP rebate, to address the adverse impact of tax reform
on income inequality. To achieve a net VAT increase of 1.5 percent of
GDP, VAT collection is increased by 2 percent of GDP. In addition,
the cut in personal income tax is progressive, benefiting only liquidity-
constrained households.
3. Labor sector reforms. All countries participate in the following reforms:
n The retirement age is increased by two years. Average retirement
ages are currently 57 in Asia, 61 in emerging-market economies in
Europe, 62 in Latin America, and 64 years in advanced economies
14. The exception in Group 3 is India, which has limited scope to reallocate spending within
the budget envelope.
15. The exception is Bangladesh, whose PPP framework needs further development, where
the assumption is that 100 percent of infrastructure is built through public procurement
and accounted for as public investment.
16. In APDMOD the personal income tax is combined with social security taxes. Simulations
here consider only changes to the personal income tax.
17. Figures are based on estimates in Bouis and Duval (2011), originally calculated for the
OECD.
18. Figures are based on estimates in Bassanini and Duval (2006), originally calculated for
the OECD.
19. Figures are based on estimates in Bouis and Duval (2011), originally calculated for the
OECD.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 367
Figure 15.16 Projected effects of fiscal measures on real
GDP in selected Asian economies
a. Asia
percentage point difference in
real GDP associated with fiscal measure
2.4
2.0
1.6
1.2
0.8
0.4
0
–0.4
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027
b. Group 1 (Japan)
percentage point difference in
real GDP associated with fiscal measure
2.4
2.0
1.6
1.2
0.8
0.4
0
–0.4
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027
Infrastructure investment
Tax reform
Labor sector reform (figure continues)
Panel a of figure 15.16 shows the effects on real GDP. By the end of the
first decade, labor reforms contribute about half of the increase in real GDP;
infrastructure investment and tax reform each contribute about a quarter.
Infrastructure investment has the longest-lasting impact on growth,
through higher productivity. The larger stock of infrastructure lowers
transaction and transportation costs. Healthcare- and education-related
infrastructure can also increase the quality and productivity of the labor
force in the long term.
Rebalancing toward indirect taxes provides most of the benefits to
growth in the short term. A hike in VAT discourages consumption, but a
cut in personal and corporate income tax more than compensates by stim-
c. Group 2
percentage point difference in
real GDP associated with fiscal measure
2.4
2.0
1.6
1.2
0.8
0.4
0
–0.4
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027
d. Group 3
percentage point difference in
real GDP associated with fiscal measure
2.4
2.0
1.6
1.2
0.8
0.4
–0.4
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027
Infrastructure investment
Tax reform
Labor sector reform
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 369
Labor reforms also have a long-term impact (the black line minus
the light grey line in figure 15.16). Raising the retirement age shrinks the
cohort that relies on government pensions and increases the labor supply.
It allows governments to increase the size of pensions per capita without in-
creasing overall spending, which may be crucial in countries where replace-
ment ratios are too low. Provision of child care expands the labor supply by
making it easier for women to work, which can be especially useful in coun-
tries facing downward labor supply pressures from demographics. Active
labor market policies can help lower the long-term unemployment rate. All
three measures expand the labor force and increase tax collection (especially
personal income tax).
The effect of reforms varies across the three country groups. In Group
1 (Japan) benefits accrue only from increasing childcare spending, which
would offset some of the significant impact of demographics; the remaining
impacts are spillovers from other countries’ measures. Group 2 countries
benefit most strongly from labor sector reforms. Outside of China, there is
also strong support from infrastructure investment and tax reform. Group
3 countries gain from both their own reforms and the positive spillovers
from improvements in major countries in the region with which they trade.
Gains are higher than in Group 2: Real GDP is 1.3 percent higher after 10
years for Group 3 countries and 1.2 percent higher for Group 2 countries.
Group 3 has the most balanced gains from each of the reform packages.
20. See Garcia Morales et al. (2018) for a discussion of the Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN) countries.
21. Similar results are obtained in a scenario in which, rather than adopting a standard linear
Taylor rule, monetary policy follows a policy reaction function that minimizes a quadratic
loss function of inflation and output gaps.
Japan
Korea
Thailand
Bangladesh
India
Indonesia
Mongolia
Philippines
0 12 24 36 48 60
number of months below target
Note: Figure excludes effects of changes in indirect taxes on Consumer Price Index
inflation. Data cover January 2013–December 2017.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; IMF Staff calculations.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 371
Figure 15.18 Projected effect of accommodative monetary policy on real GDP, government
372
debt, consumption, and current account balance in Thailand
0.5 –1.1
–0.5
–1.6
–1.5 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022
Fiscal package funded by cuts in transfers; Fiscal package funded by deficit financing;
monetary policy conducted normally monetary policy conducted normally
Fiscal package funded by cuts in transfers; Fiscal package funded by deficit financing;
interest rates fixed for five years interest rates fixed for five years
Fiscal Rules
A fiscal rule imposes a long-lasting constraint on fiscal policy by setting
numerical limits on budgetary aggregates, in order to establish a credible
medium- and long-term anchor for fiscal sustainability while mitigating
any resulting short-term economic volatility. There are four types of fiscal
rules: debt rules, fiscal balance rules, expenditure rules, and revenue rules
(Schaechter et al. 2012).
Figure 15.19 shows the share of countries with one of the four types of
fiscal rules in each country group over the 30-year period between 1985 and
2015. Most advanced economies, including Japan and Singapore, adopted
fiscal rules. In contrast, only about a quarter of Asia’s developing econo-
mies (including Indonesia, Malaysia, Maldives, Mongolia, Sri Lanka, and
Thailand) did so—a significantly smaller share than in emerging Europe,
Latin America, or Sub-Saharan Africa.
The design of fiscal rules should be guided by the following principles
and practices (Schaechter et al. 2012), while taking country circumstances
into account:
n Provide broad coverage and ensure strong legislative support. Fiscal rules
should also cover all revenue and expenditure items. Excluding public
investment from a fiscal balance rule weakens the rule’s link to public
debt and can provide incentives for creative accounting. Rules enshrined
in high-level legislation or the constitution can instill greater commit-
ment and policy credibility.
n Be neutral or countercyclical. Rules governing the (unadjusted) fiscal bal
ance can lead to procyclical fiscal policy. To prevent such an effect, rules
can set limits on the cyclically adjusted or structural fiscal balance (al-
though there are technical challenges in estimating these measures).
An expenditure rule that limits expenditure growth to potential GDP
growth is one way to reduce procyclicality.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 373
Figure 15.19 Share of countries with fiscal rules, by region,
1985–2015
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
85
87
89
91
93
95
97
99
01
05
03
07
09
11
13
15
20
19
20
20
20
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
Advanced (34)
Developing Asia (19)
Emerging Europe (23)
Latin America (30)
Middle East and North Africa (22)
Sub-Saharan Africa (46)
n Allow flexibility in the face of large shocks. An escape clause can provide flex-
ibility in dealing with a rare but devastating shock (such as a natural
disaster). A defined trigger and exit strategy should be articulated.
n Create supportive arrangements. Effective implementation of fiscal rules
calls for sound public financial management institutions, including
medium-term budget frameworks, procedural and transparency re-
quirements for budget processes and fiscal authorities, and indepen-
dent fiscal councils tasked with assessing compliance with fiscal rules
(Corbacho and Ter-Minassian 2013).
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 375
Increasing efficiency calls for a larger role for indirect taxes. Closing VAT
collection gaps arising from exemptions and low compliance can enhance
the productivity of the tax without increasing rates. Raising excise taxes on
alcohol, tobacco, and even sugar can be justified on health grounds (IMF
2015a). The regressive impact of higher indirect taxes can be compensat-
ed for by expanding programs that disproportionately benefit the poor.
Rationalizing tax exemptions and preferential tax treatment could mobilize
revenue and promote equity. Revenue administration should be improved
through risk-based compliance strategies, proper segmentation of taxpay-
ers, and simplification of laws and procedures (IMF 2015a).
Continuing to eliminate energy subsidies and introducing environmen-
tal taxes can create fiscal space efficiently and equitably. Energy subsidies
distort consumption and production decisions and are often very poorly
targeted (Coady, Flamini, and Sears 2015). Replacing these subsidies with
targeted social assistance can free up resources for productive spending
while enhancing the redistributive role of fiscal policies. Environmental
taxes such as carbon taxes can create fiscal space while addressing negative
environmental externalities.
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 377
Appendix 15A Public Spending Efficiency Frontiers
Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) applies linear programming methods
to build an efficiency frontier by connecting the bundles of units (coun-
tries) for which no other unit (country) produces the same or more output
with a given amount of input. For each economy analyzed in this chapter,
table 15A.1 shows the distance from the efficiency frontier, calculated as the
percentage difference in the output variable (e.g., quality of infrastructure,
secondary school enrollment, scores on the Programme for International
Student Assessment (PISA), and healthy life expectancy relative to the fron-
tier at the corresponding level of the input variables (public capital stock,
public spending on education and health care).
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 379
380
Table 15B.1 Composition of fiscal packages in selected Asian economies
Infrastructure Tax reform (increase in VAT, cut in Labor reforms (increase in retirement age, extension
Group/economy spending personal and corporate income tax) of child care, active labor market policies)
Group 1
4 CHAPTER
Personal income tax only (1 percent
SUSTAINING
Japan None of GDP to liquidity-constrained Yes, financed by higher VAT
households from saving households)
Group 2
Yes, financed by additional personal income tax (not
China None None
imposed on liquidity-constrained households)
15—GRAPHICS
Cut to taxes other than personal
Hong Kong None Yes, financed by additional personal income tax
income tax
Korea None Yes Yes, financed by additional personal income tax
Singapore None Yes Yes, financed by additional personal income tax
Public–private Liquidity-constrained households
partnership (PPP), receive all of the personal income tax Yes, financed by additional personal income tax (not
CHAPTER
cut and a VAT rebate of 0.5 percent imposed on liquidity-constrained households)
transfers
of GDP
Liquidity-constrained households
CAN FISCAL
PPP, financed by
receive all of the personal income tax Yes, financed by additional personal income tax (not
Pacific Island countries five-year cut in
cut and a VAT rebate of 0.5 percent imposed on liquidity-constrained households)
transfers
of GDP
VAT = value-added tax; PPP = purchasing power parity
15—GRAPHICS
Source: IMF Staff assumptions for illustrative purposes.
POLICY DO?
5 381
382
Table 15B.2 Cost of fiscal packages in selected Asian economies (percent of GDP change in fiscal instruments relative
to baseline)
Transfers
Share of to liquidity- Value- Corporate
Group/ Government Government public General constrained added income
6 SUSTAINING
economy deficit consumption investment transfers households tax Personal income tax tax
Group 1
–1.00 for liquidity-constrained
Japan None 0.25 None 0.25 None 0.5 households, None
+1.00 for saving households
CHAPTER 15—GRAPHICS
Group 2
China None 0.25 None 0.25 None None +0.50 for saving households None
–0.25 for –0.40 for liquidity-constrained
five years, households,
Hong Kong None 0.25 None None 1.5 –0.75
+0.25
thereafter +0.15 for saving households
(table continues)
Table 15B.2 Cost of fiscal packages in selected Asian economies (percent of GDP change in fiscal instruments relative
to baseline) (continued)
Group 3
–0.80 after
+1.00 for
Bangladesh year five 0.25 +0.25 0.5 2 None None
five years
years
+0.50 for –0.75 for liquidity-constrained
Cambodia 0.5 0.25 +0.25 0.5 2 –0.75
five years households
None, but
+0.5 on
India None 0.25 None 0.25 None None None
excise
tax
–0.25 for –0.59 for liquidity-constrained
+0.50 for five years, households,
Indonesia None 0.25 0.5 2 –0.75
five years +0.25
thereafter +0.34 for saving households
CHAPTER
+0.5 five
+0.50 for
Sri Lanka None 0.25 +0.25 0.5 years +0.50 for saving households None
five years
CAN FISCAL
only
–0.25 for –0.59 for liquidity-constrained
+0.50 for five years, households,
Vietnam None 0.25 +0.5 2 –0.75
five years +0.25
thereafter +0.34 for saving households
15—GRAPHICS
–0.25 for –0.59 for liquidity-constrained
Pacific
+1.00 for five years,
POLICY DO? 7
Island None 0.25 0.5 2 households, –0.75
five years +0.25
Countries
383
thereafter +0.34 for saving households
AVOIDING A NEW MEDIOCRE IN ASIA: WHAT CAN FISCAL POLICY DO? 385
Saenz, M., A. Corbacho, I. Fukunaga, D. Muir, S.J. Peiris, and S. Rafiq. 2018. Macroeconomic
Policy Synergies for Sustained Growth. In The ASEAN Way: Sustaining Growth and Stability,
ed. A. Corbacho and S.J. Peiris. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Schaechter, A., N. Budina, T. Kinda, and A. Weber. 2012. Fiscal Rules in Response to the Crisis:
Toward the “Next-Generation” Rules. A Dataset. IMF Working Paper 12/187. Washington:
International Monetary Fund.
United Nations. 2015. World Population Prospects: The 2015 Revision. New York: Population Divi-
sion, Department of Economic and Social Affairs.
World Bank. 2012. Creating Fiscal Space through Revenue Mobilization. South Asia Economic Fo-
cus, June. Washington.
Caroline Freund, senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics since May 2013, is on leave
for public service as director of trade, competition and investment climate at the World Bank. She is grateful to
Olivier Blanchard, Jérémie Cohen-Setton, Davin Chor, Joseph Gagnon, Thomas Helbling, Maurice Obstfeld,
Adam Posen, and conference participants for discussions and comments on an earlier draft.
387
Figure 16.1 Global imbalances and global trade since 1982
.30 .06
.05
.25
.04
.20
.03
Trade/GDP
Imbalances/GDP .02
.15
.1 .2
0 0
−.1 −.2
t����
∑ |������∗� �������∗� |
∑�|������∗��� �������∗���| ������
� ������ ∗∗ ∑∑��|�������|
∑ |� �� | (16.1)
� t����
���� � ���� �
� � ∑∑��������� � ����� ����
∑ � ���
���������� � ����� � �
where x denotes GDP growth and i is the index for individual countries.
As���� trade
𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇 grows
𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇����
����
faster than income, imbalances
𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴��
��
as a����
𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 share of GDP in-
����
crease, � � � � � � � fact, �over
� �����the period
𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺�� but 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺
��
imbalances
����
����
as a share of
�
� total
𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇
����
trade do𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇
not. In ����
����
ratio
3.0
Global imbalances/GDP
Global imbalances/trade
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
in question both increased (figure 16.3), indicating that the growth in im-
balances was associated with relatively high import growth in the importer/
deficit countries and relatively high export growth in the exporter/surplus
countries.
1998−2008 2012−2015
percentage points percentage points
4 4
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
Balance Deficit Surplus Balance Deficit Surplus
Import growth
Export growth
1998−2008 2012−2015
percentage points percentage points
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
c a as sia p e i a ca as sia pe ia
fri ric A ro an fri er
ic A ro an
A
m
e Eu ce A
m Eu ce
A O A O
Import growth
Export growth
over time, controlling for global growth. In the basic regression, the depen-
dent variable is the change in the ratio of trade to GDP and the indepen-
dent variable is the change in the absolute volume of imbalances to GDP.
Year fixed effects are included in all regressions to pick up global trade
growth. ∑ |(1+2𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥)∗𝑋𝑋𝑋𝑋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 −(1+2𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥)∗𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 | (1+2𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥) ∑ |𝑋𝑋𝑋𝑋𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 −𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 |
t + 1 = t + 1 = 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ∑ (1+𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥)𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 = (1+𝑥𝑥𝑥𝑥) ∗ ∑𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺
One concern with 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 this specification
𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is that 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 if 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖exports and imports are
1.0 1.0
.8 .8
.6 .6
.4 .4
.2 .2
0 0
China United States China United States
b. East Asia
1998−2008 2012−2015
percentage points percentage points
.4 .4
.3 .3
.2 .2
.1
.1
0
0
Import growth
Export growth
1. Results are almost identical if country fixed effects are included (not reported). Since the
equation is in first differences, country effects control for constant growth in openness.
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
0.756*** 0.813*** 0.730*** 0.669*** 0.829 0.560***
d(absolute value of imbalance/GDP)
(0.0550) (0.0654) (0.0765) (0.245) (0.553) (0.163)
Observations 5,870 2,013 3,857 922 356 566
R-squared 0.317 0.281 0.337 0.270 0.175 0.356
GLOBAL IMBALANCES
16—SUSTAINING
AND
0.123* 0.155** 0.1000 0.0916 0.0342 0.194**
d(absolute value of imbalance/trade)
(0.0641) (0.0654) (0.0999) (0.0608) (0.0736) (0.0913)
Observations 5,870 2,013 3,857 922 356 566
R-squared 0.065 0.034 0.082 0.203 0.082 0.316
ECONOMIC
THE TRADE
Notes: All regressions include year fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Source: Author’s calculations.
GROWTH
SLOWDOWN
IN ASIA3951
lute balance relative to trade increased by 9 percentage points between
1995 and 2007, implying that imbalances contributed to an expansion
of openness in China of only 2 to 4 percentage points. For China, the
trade-to-GDP ratio increased by 28 percentage points, mainly driven by
the exports-to-GDP ratio, which increased by 18 percentage points. But
import growth was also vibrant: The imports-to-GDP ratio was up 10
percentage points.
The first criterion ensures that the deficit is reasonably large. The
second ensures that it is larger than its historical norm. The second condi-
tion is important because a number of small developing countries had
large imbalances in the 1990s, and the rule allows them to maintain these
imbalances.
For countries where the deficit reaches the limit, imports are assumed
to decline to the level that would allow the current account deficit to be
within one standard deviation of its historical value or to trade balance,
whichever is larger. This case maintains global imbalances near an average
of 2.5 percent of GDP.
For both specifications, feedback effects to surplus countries are incor-
porated because exports use imports in their production. The feedback
trade/GDP ratio
.30
.25
Observed
.20 Trade balance
Constrained
2. Data on exports, imports, GDP, and the import share of exports are available for 57 coun-
tries from the OECD Trade in Value Added (TiVA) database.
398GRAPHICS
2 - CHAPTER
SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
16—SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA
Table 16.3 Trade growth in surplus Asian countries is highly correlated with US import growth
Deficit Balance Surplus
Hong
Variable Laos Cambodia Vietnam Indonesia Philippines Japan Korea China Thailand Kong Taiwan Malaysia Singapore
Dependent variable: Import growth
US import 0.0223 0.66 –0.186 0.505 0.0767 0.636*** 0.695 0.596* 1.110** 0.625** 1.237*** 1.173*** 0.825***
GRAPHICS - CHAPTER
growth (0.414) (0.489) (0.418) (0.523) (0.375) (0.174) (0.400) (0.282) (0.417) (0.234) (0.206) (0.323) (0.269)
Observations 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18
R-squared 0.00 0.10 0.01 0.06 0.00 0.46 0.16 0.22 0.31 0.31 0.69 0.45 0.37
Average CA/
–16.26 –5.82 –1.14 1.12 1.83 2.72 3.28 3.84 3.86 7.22 7.66 10.28 18.89
GDP
GLOBAL IMBALANCES
Dependent variable: Export growth
16—SUSTAINING
AND
US import 0.275 0.783* –0.108 0.133 0.434 1.189*** 0.718*** 1.051** 0.931*** 0.720*** 1.013*** 0.918*** 0.740***
growth (0.343) (0.381) (0.238) (0.371) (0.464) (0.241) (0.177) (0.364) (0.131) (0.222) (0.206) (0.206) (0.212)
Observations 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18
R-squared 0.039 0.209 0.013 0.008 0.052 0.603 0.508 0.342 0.761 0.397 0.602 0.553 0.432
ECONOMIC
THE TRADE
Average CA/
–16.26 –5.82 –1.14 1.12 1.83 2.72 3.28 3.84 3.86 7.22 7.66 10.28 18.89
GDP
Notes: * indicates significance at the 10 percent level, ** 5 percent level, and *** 1 percent level. Data are real import and export growth from the
GROWTH
International Monetary Fund.
Source: Author’s calculations.
SLOWDOWN 3
IN ASIA 399
The IMF World Economic Outlook (2016) did the most extensive study
to date and found that demand is largely to blame for the trade slowdown,
accounting for 50 to 80 percent, with supply chains and protectionism
each explaining at most 5 percent. The results are consistent with research
showing that investment tends to drive trade movements (Bussière et al.
2013). While trade imbalances are, of course, related to demand, neither
study considered whether increasing global imbalances in the mid-1990s
may have affected the relationship between trade and growth.
A number of studies focus on the role of China in the trade slowdown.
Constantinescu, Mattoo, and Ruta (2015) find that the deceleration in
vertical integration, particularly in China, is important. Gaulier et al. (2015)
focus on China’s rise as a manufacturing center and its shift to domestic
demand as important in explaining changes in global trade growth over
time. Consideration of the role of widening global imbalances in fueling
trade growth is complementary to these studies in that it helps to explain
how China’s exports could grow so rapidly and the timing of the shift to
domestic demand-driven growth.
The importance of borrowing in the period of hyperglobalization
before the financial crisis is also consistent with work by Shin (2011) and
Borio, James, and Shin (2014) on the surge in credit in the period leading
up to the financial crisis. A banking glut led to an expansion of gross and
net capital flows in the United States. On the real side, that was reflected in
an import surge in the United States and the credit expansion also fueled
greater unbundling of production.
While there is no reason trade could not surge in an environment of
more balanced trade (indeed, most trade models assume trade is balanced),
the ability to have large trade imbalances could enhance trade growth
because countries can import more when demand is strong. The growth in
cross-border capital flows magnifies the effects of the existing explanations
because budget constraints are no longer binding. In terms of demand as
an explanation, the ease of borrowing from abroad means that demand
can exceed supply for longer periods, without price increases. Similarly, in
the presence of greater capital mobility, the buildup of supply chains was
likely faster than it otherwise would have been.
The trade growth puzzle may therefore be the next of kin to one of the
major paradoxes in macroeconomics from the 1980s, the high correlation
between savings and investment across countries. Theory predicts that
savings should flow to the best investment opportunities. Because the top
investment prospects may not be in the domestic market, the correlation
between savings and investment across countries should be low. Instead
economists found it to be very high in the 1960s and 1970s. This paradox,
known as the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle (Feldstein and Horioka 1980) for the
References
Borio, Claudio, Harold James, and Hyun Song Shin. 2014. The International Monetary and Fi-
nancial System: A Capital Account Historical Perspective. Working Paper 204. Dallas: Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute.
Bussière, Matthieu, Giovanni Callegari, Fabio Ghironi, Giulia Sestieri, and Norihiko Yama-
no. 2013. Estimating Trade Elasticities: Demand Composition and the Trade Collapse of
2008-2009. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5, no. 3: 118–51.
Davin Chor is professor in the Department of Economics at the National University of Singapore.
Two themes shaped the discussions during this conference. The first is that
the “old” Asian model is obsolete and that countries in the region have to
reorient their strategies for sustaining growth. The second is that an impor-
tant element of any such reorientation must take into account the oppor-
tunities the region itself provides. This chapter explores both themes and
draws some implications for a “new” Asian model.
Subir Gokarn is executive director for Bangladesh, Bhutan, India, and Sri Lanka at the International Monetary
Fund. The views expressed in this chapter are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the
IMF, its Executive Board, or its management.
407
sectors required combining low-cost labor, organized in efficient structures,
with the lowest-cost intermediate and capital goods. Initially, the latter were
sourced from abroad (for countries entering the formation later, possibly
from predecessors who had developed these capabilities). The key to lever-
age was that even as countries began to integrate backward into upstream
segments of the supply chain, preserving the competitiveness of the down-
stream remained paramount.
Leverage contributed to efficient backward integration, the basis of the
second aspect of replication, which might be referred to as succession. Even as
downstream competitiveness in earlier generations of countries eroded as
labor costs rose, upstream competitiveness allowed the export-led growth
process to sustain. Of course, as standards of living rose, domestic demand
became increasingly significant in the growth process. However, the virtuous
circle of efficiency and competitiveness moving upstream over the supply
chain was a key contributor to the sustainability of exports. Downstream
products shifted location and the export baskets of individual countries
changed over time, but the importance of exports in the growth of the region
remained.
Summary
Several key messages emerged from the conference. First, the changing land-
scape in advanced-economy markets is combining with structural changes
in Asia to render the traditional export channels less and less significant for
the region as a whole.
Second, the obsolescence of the old model should be a cause for concern
only if there is nothing to succeed it. But the two elements of the old
model—leverage and replicability—have created centers of efficiency across
the region along the entire supply chain in many sectors. And decades of
sustained growth in Asia have created a large market and set of opportuni-
Reference
Subramanian, Arvind. 2011. Eclipse: Living in the Shadow of Chinese Economic Dominance. Wash-
ington: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
413
aging speed macroeconomic developments in,
associated with higher current account 287–289, 287f
balances, 52 projected effects of fiscal measures,
change between 2020 and 2030, 58f 368f
creating a demographic tax on growth, Asia-15 economies, inflation rates in,
3 288–289, 288f
defined, 58f Asian crisis (1997–98), 269
effects on interest rates, 58, 60 Asian economies
rapid in Asia, 37, 66–67, 344 danger from secular stagnation, 1–2
resulting in lower investment, 51 dominated by China and India, 116
setting to create a demographic tax on largest, 33n
growth, 67 public debt, 346f
airplane design, trial and error used in, 17n public spending on pensions and
“All 100 Million Playing an Active Role” health care, 346f
(Ichi-Oku Sou-Katsuyaku), 141 Asian model
Android platform, as Google’s innovation, efficiency and competitiveness up the
91 supply chain, 408
annual growth rates, in Korea and the as obsolete, 5
global economy, 166, 167f asset churning, 275
Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and “asset market meltdown” hypothesis, 62
Exchange Restrictions (AREAER), 110, asset prices, 194, 304
125 asset returns, demographics and, 62–64,
Anti-Monopoly Law, in Japan, 82 62t, 63t
APDMOD semi-structural model of the atmospheric pressure, Torricelli’s discovery
global economy (IMF), 365, 365n, of, 17
365n, 366n Australia
arbitrage, between foreign and domestic alternative policy strategies, 326f, 327f
bonds, 114 change in 10-year government yield,
artificial intelligence (AI), replacing 55f
workers, 28 demographic characteristics, 35t
ASEAN (Association of Southeast Asian demographic impact on current
Nations), real GDP growth relative to, account, 53f
2000–16, 241f higher old-age dependency by 2020, 52
ASEAN-4 (Malaysia, Thailand, and the immigration, 37
Philippines), 244 impact of aging on TFP, 48f
ASEAN-9 (Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, impact of continued immigration on
Malaysia, Myanmar, the Philippines, the workforce, 43
Singapore, Thailand, and Vietnam), impact of demographics on 10-year
249 real interest rates, 61f
Asia impact of demographic trends, 42f
adopting full-fledged inflation-forecast labor force participation rates, 48f, 49f
targeting, 323 as a large commodity-exporting
China and India providing growth economy, 324
momentum, 408 as a late-dividend economy, 35, 37
contribution to real trade growth, 392f lower speed of aging, 52
countries crossing dependency maintained higher real interest rates,
thresholds, 409 116
demographic impact on 10-year real managing downside risks and avoiding
interest rates, 61f a deflation trap, 324–328
demographic impact on current old-age dependency ratio, 36t, 38f, 57f
account, 53f open-economy New Keynesian model,
demographic trends, 34–40 337
growth leadership shifting from Japan per capita income level, 39f
to China, 270 real neutral interest rates, 56f
INDEX 415
business cycle synchronization, 239n in Korea and selected countries,
business enterprise research and 1970–2015, 168f
development (BERD), in Japan, 151f carbon prices, 183
business environment, in Indonesia, 242 Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety, 23
business models, development in China of cartels, in Japan, 82
new, 185 Ceauşescu, Nicolae, 22, 23
business R&D and government support, in CEIC database, 224
Japan, 151f Central Asian republics, governance
business regulation and taxation, indicators, 22
simplifying in India, 222 central bank(s)
active use of balance sheets, 301–302,
Cambodia 302t
fiscal packages, 380t, 383t avoiding the traps of fiscal and
in Group 3, 347b financial dominance, 304
infrastructure, index of quality of, 356f balance sheets
personal income tax (PIT) yields, 363f advancing objectives, 286
public debt, actual and projected, 346f keeping markets for local financial
public spending efficiency frontier, assets operating, 298
distance from, 378t policies, 4
public spending on education, 359f clear signals, providing, 321
public spending on health care, 358f conducting QE through purchases of
tax revenue sources, 364f government bonds, 302
trade growth in, 399t deflation risks, fighting, 323
capacity utilization gap, in the US, easing monetary policy but tightening
299–300, 299t macroprudential policies, 309
capital inflation, control of low, 298–304
cost of, 124 interest rate, publishing, 323
taxation of, 353 interest rates, 125
capital accumulation, in Indonesia, limited influence of in China, 187, 188
256–257 monetary autonomy of, 312
capital exporters and importers, 51, 53 monetary policy
capital flows in China, 189
across borders, 275, 276f conduct of, 318
demographic factors strengthening, nominal interest rate, determining,
52–53 114
management of, 118 official inflation targets of, 316
opportunities for, 67 policy interest rate, setting the path
spurred by unconventional monetary of, 321
policy, 237 policy rates, reducing below zero, 300
capital formation, in Japan, 143 scope when inflation expectations
capital gains, to financial firms holding settle at low levels, 286
bonds, 307 tolerating longer periods of inflation
capital inflows, 114 below target, 307
capital mobility, 112, 387 world real interest rate, ready for
capital openness index (CO), 58 external shocks to, 297
capital stock, in Indonesia, 262, 262f central bankers, managing inflation, 269
capital surcharges, enhancing resilience to central bank transparency index, 323, 324f
shocks, 334 Centre for Monitoring the Indian Economy
capital-to-effective-labor ratio, remaining (CMIE), 225
constant, 41 CGE model, showing China’s annual GDP
capital-to-labor ratio, 50 growth, 183
capital-to-output ratio chaebols (Korea’s industrial
approaching ratios in advanced conglomerates), 86, 86n, 88
countries, 166, 168f channels of spillover, for low productivity
growth, 104
INDEX 417
polity not democratic and open, 22 cloud technology, just getting started, 26
as a post-dividend economy, 35 clusters and agglomeration, power of, 409
primary commodity exports from Cobb-Douglas production function, 339
Indonesia, 243n Cœur, Jacques, 12n
productivity, slowdown in, 347 commodities, 339
public debt, actual and projected, 351f competition, in Japan, 82–83
public spending competitiveness indicator, 339
on education, 359f Complete Dictionary of Arts and Sciences
efficiency frontier, distance from, (Croker), 26n
378t composition effects, accounting for drag on
on health care, 358f wage growth in the US, 134
on pensions and health care, 346f Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for
quasi-fiscal debt of local governments, Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP), 130
190 computer memory, decreasing cost of, 27n
real GDP growth correlated to computers, improvements in, 24–25
Indonesia’s, 253t conditional forecast path, publication of,
real GDP volatility, 2000–16, 241f 319
real neutral interest rates, 56f conditionality, communicating, 323
real per capita GDP, growth rate of, Condorcet, 1795 essay on human progress,
287f 16n
real short-term interest rate, 293f constant true prices, reflected by an
rebalancing from investment toward inflation rate of 1 percent, 292
consumption, 243 consumer and industrial goods, US market
research and development spending, for, 76b
362f consumer preference, shifting from goods
reserves fell over the past three years, to services in China, 184
310–311 consumer price and wage inflation,
restructuring in, 316 modeled by reduced-form Phillips’
Scenario 3 and, 350 curves, 339
scope for quantitative easing, consumer price inflation, domestic, 251
December 2016, 303t consumption, 267, 338
services and manufacturing sectors as consumption tax, in Japan, 131, 132, 289n
percent of GDP, 185f contagion, channels of, 3, 108
shift in consumer preference from contingent liabilities, emanating from
goods to services, 184 SOEs, 376
slowdown in economic growth, 3–4, conventional forward guidance, 322
191 convergence argument, 169n
SOEs in, 376 core CPI inflation
spillovers to the rest of the world, 325 for Japan, 333f
State Council setting monetary growth in Korea, 296f
targets, 187 in Thailand, 296f
tariff rates, 230 core inflation, keeping at or above 2
tax revenue sources, 364f percent, 285
10-year government yield, 55f Corporate Enterprise Annual Statistics, from
trade growth in, 399t the Ministry of Finance in Japan, 150
trade slowdown, role in, 400 corporate income tax, effects of cutting, 369
trade surpluses, expanded, 388 correlations, reflecting a causal
trade-to-GDP ratio driven by exports- relationship, 404
to-GDP ratio, 396 corruption indices, 14
WTO, accession to, 270 corrupt nations, interacting with nations
youth dependency ratio, 57f with better institutions, 22
Chinn-Ito index, 109–110, 118, 125 corrupt regimes, being deposed, 24
chonsei, rental system of Korea, 174n countercyclical fiscal rules, 373
city-states, set up city governments, 13
INDEX 419
deficits, as a systemic risk, 396 scenario for public debt projection,
deficits (and surpluses), in slower-growing 348
advanced debtors (and creditors), 280 taking as destiny, 134
defined-benefit pension system, 375 demographic “tax,” on growth, 40
deflation demographic transitions, 6
Japan’s policies to exit, 330–333 demographic trends
response to in the early 1990s, 291 affecting savings, investment, and
threat of faded in most countries, 285 current account balance, 50
deflationary spiral, fear of, 291 in Asia, 34–40
demand for Asian growth, 67
boosting aggregate in the short term, baseline growth impact of, 42f
267 global impact of, 42f
changes in domestic correlated with implications of, 40–64
changes in domestic credit, 122 policy implications of, 64–66
China’s shift to domestic, 400 for post-dividend countries, 41
cyclical changes in, 108 reducing growth in post-dividend
domestic in Indonesia, 239–240 countries, 50
exceeding supply without price demographic variables, 52n, 60n
increases, 400 demography, Korea’s following Japan’s, 170
trade slowdown and, 400, 404 deregulating, targeted sectors, 141
demand elasticity, decline in, 229 Desaguliers, John T., 18
demand rebalancing, planting seeds of developing Asia, public debt as percent of
secular stagnation, 123 GDP, 345f
demand shocks, central banks dealing with, development zones, in China, 187, 189, 191
328 difference-in-difference methodology, 108n
demand-side issues, in Indonesia, 267 diffusion of technologies, determining
demand slump, countering, 237 productivity growth, 107
demand stimulus, tradeoff with financial diminishing returns to research, in
stability, 7 individual sectors, 27
demand weakness, assertive policy actions Dincer-Eichengreen index of transparency,
following, 316 for four Asian countries, 323, 324f
demographic changes direct taxes, 366
baseline impact of, 41 discount, high rate of, 14
effects of, 176, 177f discretionary monetary policy, 317
demographic classification, of Asia, 35t distribution system, in Japan, 82
demographic dividend DNA molecule, 24
for early- and late-dividend countries, “doctrine of equivalents,” 79
41 domestic and global factors, correlation
ending for many Asian economies, 33 to domestic real GDP growth in
harnessing for early-dividend Indonesia, 253, 253t
countries, 64 domestic assets, expanding holdings of, 312
in Indonesia, 261 domestic factors, explaining deviation of
reversing in many countries, 6 Indonesia’s growth, 253, 254f
demographic model, on the effect of the domestic financial assets, buying, 302
two-child policy in China, 182 domestic financial markets, 286. See also
demographic negative feedback, 10 financial markets
demographic projections, long-term, 43n domestic interest rate, 112, 113, 114
demographics domestic supply linkages, strengthening in
in Asia, 316 India, 230
in Korea and Japan, 171f dominant elites, extracting rents, 12
labor productivity and, 47t downside scenario, in China, 325
rapid decline in the labor force in downward nominal wage rigidity, 292
China, 182 DRAM chips, Korean production of, 89,
89n
INDEX 421
empirical models, data for, 224–228 impact larger with greater foreign
employees by firm size, all industries, Japan currency exposure, 244
and United States, 2001, 2006, 159t Japan’s real and nominal, 80
employment movements not affecting exports in
gap, in the US, 299–300, 299t India, 202
as the most important macroeconomic policies, 101, 309–311
policy objective in China, 186, 191 of the yen and the won in the mid-
scenario analysis for Indonesia, 262f 1980s, 89
security, in Japan, 81 excise taxes, raising, 376
system, in Japan, 146n exogenous path, for the policy rate, 320n
endogenous credibility-building process, expected stock returns, 62n
328 expenditure on wages and salaries,
endogenous interest rate, producing, 320 strengthening the rupee, 205,
endogenous monetary policy, 320 218t–219t
endogenous policy credibility, model for expenditure rules, 373
India, 337–338 expenditures, types of, 339
endogenous policy rate, 322 expenditure-switching policies, 404
energy export(s)
clean more expensive than dirty, 183 changing composition of India’s,
pricing reforms, 376 198–199
subsidies, 376 constraining current account deficits,
engineering goods, exporting from India, 396
198 as a critical driver of India’s slowdown,
Enlightenment Europe, artisans and 197, 197f
scientists, 18 decline of Indonesia’s, 244
enterprise creation and growth, Japan elasticity of India’s, 200–201
behind the United States, 163 elasticity of with respect to the
entry barriers, in Korea, 170 exchange rate, 204, 206t–207t
environmental costs, in China, 182–184 examining the drivers of India’s, 229
environmental taxes, introducing, 376 growing twice as fast as GDP, 389
epistemic base, in technology, 18 growth rates on for Indonesia, 244n
“equality before the law,” 12 increasing in sophistication and value
“equal work, equal pay” rule, in Japan, 141 addition from India, 198
equilibrium rates of interest, decline in, India increasing its share of global,
292, 294 197, 198f
equities, official purchases of, 302 India’s, 194f
equity and real estate price bubbles, in market share of by sectors in India,
Japan, 289 205, 211f
equity prices, run-up in US, 272 measuring the elasticity of India’s, 200
equity purchases, as the most untapped observed and predicted, 397, 397f
channel for QE, 303 reduction translating to an import
escape clauses, for fiscal rules, 374 reduction in surplus countries, 397
EU-28, workforce with productivity rising by region for Indonesia, 245, 246f, 247
or falling, 45f response to exchange rate movements,
EU-Japan trade agreements, 130 222
Euler, Leonhard, 17n role in India’s growth slowdown, 196f,
Europe, old-age dependency ratio, 38f, 57f 197f
exchange rates sensitivity of India’s, 200–202
changes not affecting exports, 229 share of India’s in GDP, 195f
diminished passthrough not specific supporting economic growth in
to Japan, 135 Indonesia, 266
effects of weaker, 243 from surplus countries, 390
fixed keeping Japan’s cost of export basket, composition of Indonesia’s,
production relatively low, 79–80 241n
INDEX 423
demographic trends for, 67 response to demand shocks in Korea,
efficiency of in Korea, 170 169
expecting a permanent slowdown in firm-size differences, in labor quality and
advanced economies, 244 TFP, 158
implications of demographic trends firm-size wage differences, 149, 156
for, 53–64 “the first 21st century crisis,” 269
improving access to in India, 222 fiscal and quasi-fiscal expenditures,
in Japan, 81–82 planning of, 186, 191
financial openness fiscal institutions, need for supporting, 371,
Chinn-Ito index of, 109–110, 118, 125 373–376
of Indonesia, 245, 245f fiscal measures, effects on real GDP in
financial policies, in Indonesia, 242 selected Asian economies, 368f–369f
financial risks, sector-specific, 308 fiscal packages
financial sector, supervisory oversight in composition and cost of, 379–383,
Indonesia, 242 380t–381t, 382t–383t
financial side effects, risks during recovery covering public infrastructure, tax
phases, 7 rebalancing, and labor markets, 363
financial stability fiscal policy
from accommodative monetary policy, addressing long-term implications of
334 the new mediocre, 377
considerations regarding, 334–335 addressing the risk of a new mediocre,
mitigating risks, 64 343
risks to, 286, 304–309 assisting monetary policy, 325
worries not justifying keeping the complementing monetary policy, 328
policy rate higher than warranted, governed by long-run fiscal policy
312 targets, 339
financial vulnerabilities, in various parts of political desire for wasteful procyclical,
the world, 315 132–133
financing, of labor sector reforms, 367 supporting sustained and inclusive
finite resource, planet earth as, 21 growth, 353, 355
firm-level data, results often difficult to fiscal reforms
translate to the aggregate level, 108 effects across Asia, 367–370
firms. See also large firms financing through debt, 377
deferring compensation in Japan, 144 illustrative packages, 365–367
early emergence of leading, 75b payoff in a low-inflation environment,
increasing part-time workers in Japan, 370–371
146 potential to improve growth, 343
incumbent resisting rendering existing quantifying the payoff of, 363–371
business models obsolete, 76b fiscal room, determining available, 132
investment determined by a Tobin’s fiscal rules, 373–374, 374f
Q combined with the Bernanke- fiscal space
Gertler-Gilchrist model, 338 in Indonesia, 242
in job training contributing more to using, 7
firm-size wage differences, 155 fiscal stabilization, in Japan, 130, 133
as net borrowers, 338 fiscal stimulus
not adjusting investments in response in Abenomics, 139
to exchange rate fluctuations, 205, early improving outcomes in Australia,
220t–221t 325
paying a premium to part-time fiscal sustainability, 5
workers, 145 flexible inflation targeting, 318–319, 324
productivity and wage gaps between floating exchange rate era, 269
large and small in Japan, 149–159 flow deficit, 278
reluctant to employ more regular flow indicators, 248
employees in Japan, 162 flying geese formation, 407
INDEX 425
natural rate of interest declining after, India’s growing participation in, 229
54 global trade
of 2008–09, 270 slowdown symptomatic of secular
global financial cycle, 121 stagnation, 242
global financial integration, across slowdown unprecedented in recent
emerging markets, 249f history, 387
global financing shocks, 250 world trade growth under more
global gross financial flows, 276f balanced global trade, 396–401
global growth, 194, 195, 199 global value chains, India’s limited role in,
global imbalances. See also imbalances 230, 231f
calculated, 388, 388f Gourinchas-Rey effect, 280
correlated with global trade, 403 government(s)
effects of shifts in on countries’ fiscal stimulus targeting the lower
subsequent trade positions, 405 middle class in Indonesia, 267
in the emerging markets, 270 policies encouraging entrepreneurship
excess, 278, 282 and global competitiveness in Japan,
and global trade since 1982, 366f 164
linking to the decline in the growth publishing balance sheets in China,
rate of international trade flows, 403 190
mono-causal explanations for purchases of bonds, 302
excessive, 4 reducing exposure to SOE-related
owing little to foreign exchange fiscal risks, 376
intervention by EMDEs, 281 resisting higher bond yields, 304
policy implications, 282–283 revenue as percent of GDP, 362f
relationship with trade, 5 revenue ratios compared with other
relationship with trade flows, 403–404 economies, 359, 362f
relative to global trade remaining spending or taxation mattering more
constant, 389 than debt levels, 132
rise of, 270–273 supported the low-inflation objective,
risks from excess, 278–282 318
role in fueling trade growth, 400 gravity models, indicating geographical
twenty-five years of, 269–283 proximity conducive to trade, 410
widening and narrowing of, 387, 397f, “gray market” for capital, tolerated in
401 Taiwan, 92
global imbalances/GDP, versus global Great Depression, described, 305
imbalances/trade, 390f Great Enrichment, 9, 18
global implications, of Asia’s demographic Great Recession, 105, 111
evolution, 38 Greece, governance indicators, 22
global integration, India’s, 194, 223 gross capital flows, 282–283
global investment liabilities stock, 277f gross external positions, 275, 277f
global liquidity trap, 105 Group 1 (Japan), 347b, 368f, 370
globally integrated economy, channels of Group 2 countries
international transmission of secular effect of fiscal reforms, 370
stagnation, 103 including China, Hong Kong, Korea,
global neutral real rate, settling at around Singapore, and Thailand, 347b
1 percent in the medium to long run, increasing spending pressures from
293 demographic trends, 359
global real prices, determining, 339 projected effects of fiscal measures,
global real trade growth, contributions to, 369f
390, 392f, 393f Group 3 countries
global risks, India vulnerable to, 4 gaining from reforms and positive
global supply chains. See also supply chains spillovers, 370
development of explaining the recent
trade slowdown, 398
INDEX 427
scope for quantitative easing, prolonging the demographic dividend,
December 2016, 303t 65
tax revenues, direct taxes as a small softening the impact of aging, 67
share of, 366 impact theory, 17n
tax revenue sources, 364f import constraint, in deficit countries, 396
trade growth in, 399t imported intermediate inputs, in sectors
workforce, share of, with productivity with low domestic value, 205, 210t
rising or falling, 45f imported intermediates, response to
youth dependency ratio, 57f an appreciation of the rupee, 204,
Hong Kong Monetary Authority, 298 208t–209t
household deposits, lack of pass-through of imports
negative rates, 300 by deficit countries, 390
household property mortgages, rules on, growth rates declining for Indonesia,
308 244n
households, types of in APDMOD, 365 by region to Indonesia, 245, 246f, 247
housing bubble, 306 temporary trade restrictions on
Hsinchu Science Park, 94–95 Indonesian, 258, 260f
Huawei, 91, 91n imports-to-GDP ratio, for China, 396
“human bridges,” 76b income growth, relationship with trade
human capital growth, 387
concentrated in large firms in Japan, income per capita, on a global scale as self-
81 limiting, 21
East Asian investment in, 78 incomes policy, aimed directly at sluggish
growth rate of slowing, 258 wage-price dynamics, 332
in Japan, 77–78 India
raising in India, 222 aging, impact on TFP, 48f
upgrading, 65 aging speed change between 2020 and
human capital accumulation 2030, 58f
affecting TFP, 258 banks’ nonperforming and
boosting, 353 restructured assets, 232f
economic loss by reducing, 162 central bank, attempting to reduce
growth rate in Indonesia, 258 long-term expectations of inflation,
high-skill in Indonesia, 258, 259f 317
supporting, 367 central bank, transparency, 323, 324f
hydrostatics, needed for ship design, 17n Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation
hyperglobalization, 270, 400 declining, 324
Hyundai, 86n CPI inflation rates, 1985–2016, 288f
credibility, building, 328–330
ideas, 27, 28 current account balances, 1985–2016,
imbalances. See also global imbalances 310f
enhancing transmission from slow US dark corner for, 338
growth to East Asian exports and debt paths, stabilizing, 353
imports, 398 debt ratio change under Scenario 4b,
expanding openness in China, 396 354f
moving together with trade within demographic characteristics, 35t
countries, 394 demographic impact on current
relationship with trade, 388, 389–390 account, 53f
and trade growth at the country level, demographics, impact on 10-year real
391–392, 394–396 interest rates, 61f
IMF. See International Monetary Fund demographic trends, impact of, 42f
(IMF) as an early-dividend economy, 37
immigration endogenous policy credibility, model
effects on the workforce, 43, 43n of, 337–338
exchange rate appreciation, 231
INDEX 429
Indonesia in Group 3, 347b
aging, impact on TFP, 48f growth
aging speed change between 2020 and domestic and external contributions
2030, 58f to, 251, 253–255
average openness (exports + imports), higher since the global financial
2000–16, 245, 245f crisis, 194
budget deficit legally limited, 266 rate of real per capita GDP, 287f
CPI inflation rates, 288f rate of the working-age population,
credit gaps, increases in, 119 261f
current account balances, 310f sources of lower potential, 256
debt ratio change under Scenario 4b, health care, gap between actual and
354f expected public spending on, 355n
demographic characteristics, 35t imports by region, 245, 246f, 247
demographic impact on current infrastructure, index of quality of, 356f
account, 53f labor, future paths for, 261
demographics, impact on 10-year real labor force participation, impact of
interest rates, 61f higher, 49f
demographic trends, impact of, 42f labor force participation rate, 48f,
domestic and external factors role in 261–262, 261f
the deceleration of TFP growth in, long-term public debt projection, 349t
258 medium-term potential growth
domestic demand, 239, 241 increasing, 262
domestic real GDP growth, correlation months inflation rate below inflation
with domestic and global factors, target, 371f
253, 253t more exposed than other large
as an early-dividend economy, 37 economies, 245
Emerging Market Bond Index (EMBI) most-favored nation (MFN) applied
spread, 252f tariff rates, 230f
energy and commodities, producer of, as a net debtor, 243n
266 net emigration from, impact of, 43
export demand, insulated from weaker, old-age dependency ratio, 36t, 38f, 57f
247 older workers, share of, 44f
exports by region, 245, 246f, 247 output dynamics, 238–242, 255–257
external balance sheet foreign currency per capita income level, 39f
exposure, 250f personal income tax (PIT) yields, 363f
external demand from advanced population with tertiary education,
economies, 247, 247f 259f
external financing, cost of, 250, 252f potential growth rate, 256–257, 257f
external sector, 244, 245f potential output growth rate, 255–256,
fertility rates, 19, 37 256f
financially integrated economies, one protectionism, increase in, 258
of the least, 249, 249f public debt, actual and projected, 346f,
fiscal buffers, 353 351f
fiscal packages, 381t, 383t public spending
foreign exchange reserves and net on education as percent of GDP,
official assets, 311f 359f
foreign participation, bans on, 249 efficiency frontier, distance from,
global developments, insulated from, 378t
263 on health care as percent of GDP,
global economy, financial integration 358f
with, 248, 248f on pensions and health care, 346f
global economy, reduced financial R&D spending, 357
integration with, 248f real GDP growth, 239f, 240f, 241f, 247f
global financial integration, 249f real GDP volatility, 241f
INDEX 431
Japanese companies underinvested in, exogenous having no nominal anchor,
163 320
Japanese style focused on relatively exposures rising to risks, 308
incremental invention, 79n financial stability risks, keeping too
leadership in East Asia, 74 raising, 334
maintaining a high level of, 29 foreign secular stagnation, insulating
pro-incremental and pro-incumbent from, 114
biases in East Asia, 96 high enough to counter a potential
rates of, 6 financial threat as crippling, 305
reform of Japan’s system for, 84 levels before the global financial crisis
shifting from radical experimentation and after, 115
to incremental improvements of low
existing designs, 75b creating larger maturity mismatch
systems, 3, 75b risks, 308
innovative activity, incremental, 75b encouraging debtors to continue
innovative firms, motivating employees in borrowing, 278
Japan, 85 having problematic side effects, 103
innovators, output sustaining growth leading central banks, 335
without increasing effort, 27 transmitted across countries, 104
institutional changes, reorienting from in the macroeconomic spillover data,
external to domestic demand, 237 115
institutions near their effective lower bound, 316
extending credit to households and not responding to much higher public
firms, 334 debt levels, 132
quality of, key to adopting superior policy in Taiwan, 92
technologies, 259 world real, 55f
insufficient final demand (excess saving interest rate growth differential. See IRGD
problem), in Japan, 139 (interest rate growth differential)
insularity, in Indonesia, 244n interest rates, low, reducing debt service
insurers and service providers, competition burdens of borrowers, 304
among, 375 interfirm alliances, in Japan, 82–83
intellectual property protection, in Japan, international financial cooperation, need
78–79 for, 283
intellectual property rights, 6, 76b international financial institutions,
intellectual property system, strengthened structural impediments in Indonesia,
in Japan, 84 259–260, 260f
interest parity equation, 112 international financial integration,
interest rate(s) measures of, 125
adjusting to the target, 320 International Monetary Fund (IMF)
adverse effects of low, 124 Asia and Pacific Department of, 2
before and after the global financial on export performance of India, 229
crisis, 115f, 117f monitoring external excess imbalances
aversion to large changes in, 321 annually, 282
decline in (real) attributable to changes projecting a bigger US current account
in real sector fundamentals, 176 deficit in coming years, 281
decline in long-term, 54, 55f projections of growth prospects for
declining in Asia, 2 advanced economies, 280
decreasing everywhere since the early international monetary regime, period of
1990s, 123 adjustment to the new, 269
demographic trends, impact of, 54–62 international spillovers, exposing lower-
demographic variables, impact of, 56t income economies to secular
domestic demographic factors, impact stagnation, 2
of, 59 intra-Asian trade, as an established
phenomenon, 410
INDEX 433
infrastructure, index of quality of, 356f as a post-dividend economy, 35
innovation system, 78, 83n productivity growth, 73
interest rates lowered after the crisis, public debt, actual and projected, 351f
116 public spending
Korea caught up with in the export on education as percent of GDP,
market, 171 359f
Korea’s monetary policy compared efficiency frontier, distance from,
with, 174n 378t
labor, decline in the quality of, 163 on health care as percent of GDP,
labor force participation, impact of 358f
higher, 49f on pensions and health care, 346f
labor force participation rate by age QE, currently engaged in, 302
and employment status, 2013, 147f quality of infrastructure, 355, 356f
labor force participation rates, 48f R&D productivity, trends in, 84f
labor market flexibility enhancing with real 10-year bond yield, 272f
human capital accumulation, 148 real estate market in a bubble in the
labor market institutions, 80–81 1990s, 173–174
labor productivity, 140f, 150f real estate prices and consumer price
labor quality gap, 157f index, 174f
labor supply, transformation of, 134 real neutral interest rates, 56f
LFPRs increased the most in, 49 real per capita GDP, growth rate of,
literacy proficiency, 142f, 143f 287f
long-term public debt projection, 349t real short-term interest rate, 293f
lost decades, 3, 129 real trade growth, 393f
macroeconomic developments, 290f research and development spending,
monetary policy in the 1990s, 174n 362f
months inflation rate below inflation revealed comparative advantages of,
target, 371f 172f
natural interest rate around zero, 178n Scenario 3 and, 350
natural interest rate below zero, 178 Scenario 4a and, 352
net investment, 279f Scenario 4b and, 352
nominal GDP, growth rates, 290f scope for quantitative easing,
nominal GDP growth rates, 173f December 2016, 303t
nonmanufacturing sector wage and secular stagnation, 2, 139
productivity differences by firm size, students, government subsidized study
156f abroad for, 77
nonregular employees, share of in total students, regularly outperform
workers, by sector, 144f Americans, 87
nonregular employment problem, tax revenue sources, 364f
143–149 10-year government yield, change in,
observed phenomena today occurring 55f
worldwide, 135 Three Arrows Plus policy package, 333f
off-the-job training expenses by firm total factor productivity, 96, 141f
size, 158f trade growth, slowdown in, 194
old-age dependency ratio, 35, 36t, 38f, trade growth in, 399t
52, 57f trade imbalances, widening, 391
older workers, share of, 44f trade surpluses, expanded, 388
output gap, 1954Q1–2017Q1, 290f unemployment rate, 1954Q1–2017Q1,
patent system of Bismarck-era 290f
Germany, 78–79 universities underperforming in
pension system with automatic graduate education, 78
adjustment mechanisms, 375 VAT increases, factoring in, 366
per capita income level, 39f wage and productivity differences,
personal income tax (PIT) yields, 363f 153f, 154f, 155f
INDEX 435
monetary policy since the Asian real trade growth, 393f
financial crisis, 296f recession, heading for a prolonged, 3
months inflation rate below inflation research and development spending,
target, 371f 362f
mortality rate, 177f resource allocation, efficiency of,
natural interest rate, declining, and 169–170
monetary policy, 175–178, 175f, revealed comparative advantages of,
176t, 177f 172f
natural interest rate, estimating, 178n Scenario 3 and, 350
negative shocks, preparing policy scope for quantitative easing,
measures for large, 178 December 2016, 303t
nominal and real interest rates, 175f secular stagnation, exhibiting features
nominal GDP growth rates, trends in, of, 2
173f short-term interest rates, 295, 296f
nominal interest rates, 124, 175 students regularly outperform
old-age dependency ratio, 36t, 57f, 344 Japanese students, 87
expected to rise relatively quickly, 57 tax revenue sources, 364f
higher by 2030, 52 10-year government yield, change in,
increasing from 15 to 20 percent, 55f
38f total factor productivity, 177f
older workers, share of, 44f trade growth, 194, 399t
pensions in as partially defined-benefit trade imbalances, widening, 391
systems, 375 trade surpluses, expanded, 388
per capita income level, 39f trend growth in nominal GDP
per capita income trailing Japan’s by deviating from that of Japan, 173
20 years, 172, 173f 20-year lag, mimicking Japan, 3
personal income tax (PIT) yields, 363f underpriced Japanese rivals in the
PISA scores, on the frontier for, 357, 1980s, 89
361f universities, limited research
policies and pro-incremental bias in, capabilities of, 88
87–91 workforce, share of with productivity
as a postdividend economy, 35 rising or falling, 45f
production sites squeezed by Chinese working-age population, absolute
manufacturing capabilities, 90 decline in, 38
public debt, actual and projected, 346f, youth dependency ratio, 57f
351f Korean Ministry of Strategy and Finance, 2
public health care spending, 355 Kuwait, invasion of in August 1990, 21
public spending
on education as percent of GDP, labor
359f future paths in Indonesia, 261
efficiency frontier, distance from, increases in the supply of, 133–134
378t increasing supply through provision of
on health care as percent of GDP, social benefits, 353
358f reforms having a long-term impact,
on pensions and health care, 346f 368f–369f, 370
R&D expenditure, high, 357 reforms package, 366–367
R&D spending among, 88f labor force
real estate prices and consumer price declining in China, 184–185
index, 174f impact of aging on, 344
real natural interest rates, effects of impact on economic growth, 40–43
changes in fundamental variables participation
on, 176t in China, 183f
real neutral interest rates, 56f, 177f increasing, 65
real short-term interest rate, 293f participation rate
INDEX 437
Lehman Brothers, collapse of, 294f long-term and policy interest rate, for
leverage, relating to strategic replication, Japan, 333f
407–408 long-term bond yields: Emerging Asia and
LG, 86n selected advanced economies, 294f
liberal democracy, in Italy and Germany long-term inflation expectations
after 1945, 23 for India, 338
life-cycle savings, positive effect of aging in Japan, 291
speed, 58 long-term interest rates
life expectancy declined since 2000, 292, 294f
in Asia, 34f demographics and, 60t
increases in, 46 of emerging Asian economies, 292
linking changes in the retirement age in Korea, 175, 175f
(or benefits) to, 65–66 lowered, 307
rising, 34 long-term output, estimating, 41
lifetime employment system, 80–81, 148 long-term public debt projections, 349t
life-work balance, in Japan, 141, 148 long-time employment relationships
light radar (Lidar), 25 declining in importance in Japan, 147f
“limited regular employment,” in Japan, in Japan, 146
148 loss absorbency requirements, reducing
linear inflation forecast-based reaction spillover risks, 334
function, for Australia, 325, 326f loss function, procedure minimizing, 321
linear reaction functions, performing loss-minimization approach, to policy
poorly in abnormal times, 321 formulation, 320–322
liquidity-constrained households, 365 loss-minimizing policy response, simulated,
liquidity constrained households, 365n 329, 330f
liquidity traps lost decade, in Japan, 129
avoiding the danger of, 295 lower-for-longer interest rate, 325
emerging-market and developing lower-income countries, tending to grow
economies at a safe distance from, faster, 169n
124 low-inflation environment, payoff to fiscal
falling into, 114 reforms in, 370–371
global, 105 low-inflation trap, 316, 316n, 320
international propagation of, 105n
pushing economies into, 124 M2 growth, in China, 181–182, 187
literacy proficiency, 142f, 143f macroeconomic developments
loan-to-value (LTV) ratios, compared to in Asia, 287–289, 287f
debt-to-income ratios, 308 in Japan, 290f
local bond market liquidity, swings in macroeconomic forecast, publication of,
affecting local financial conditions, 322
297 macroeconomic frameworks, undertaking
local governments (China) stabilizing stimulus, 8
avoiding further expansion of debt, macroeconomic leverage, 181, 184, 187
189 macroeconomic management framework,
central government issuing mandates in China, 4, 181, 187, 191
for, 186 macroeconomic policies, 7, 64, 68
contingent and implicit liabilities of, macroeconomic policy frameworks, 7,
190 186–190
debt surging, 187 macroeconomic slowdown, in Japan, 84
promotion of officials, 186 macroeconomic spillovers, in the
topping up the national growth target, transmission of secular stagnation,
188 111
longevity, impact on current account macroeconomic stability screening, setting
balances, 51–52 a limit on total government borrowing,
189
INDEX 439
medieval economy, as dynamic in many adjusting to the outlook for financial
areas, 15 stability, 307
Meiji Restoration of 1868, 77 aggressive easing in Abenomics, 139
mercantilist protectionist policies, 14 allowing the interest rate to vary, 323
merchandise and service exports, avoiding prolonged underemployment
determinants of India’s, 200–201, 201t of resources and to sustain
merchandise exports, from India, 4, 222, investment, 288
231f buffer to counter negative shocks in
microeconomic foundations, of Korea and Japan, 178
consumption and investment, 338 building credibility amid frequent
microscopes, improvements to, 24 supply shocks, 328–329
middle-income trap, idea of, 134 countering weakness in aggregate
migration, 37, 41, 43 demand, 307
minimum pension guarantees, providing, credibility of, 337
66 easy, encouraging risky behavior in
ministries, setting targets for sectoral financial markets, 286
growth, 186 effects on the real economy, 334
Ministry of Finance, pilot programs in enhancing the independence of in
China, 190 China, 186, 188, 191
model(s) expansionary improving financial
deep learning, engaging in data stability, 309
mining, 25 following an inflation-targeting regime
of endogenous policy credibility for in APDOMD, 365
India, 337–338 governed by an interest rate reaction
of a small open economy responding function, 339
to secular stagnation abroad, impact on inflation, 286
111–114 implications of slower growth rates,
summary of, 337–340 285
for sustaining growth for Asian improving communications, 317
economies, 8 in Indonesia, 253t
used by central banks to conduct interest rate by region 2000–16, 115f
policy, 320 in Korea since the Asian financial
model-based simulations, illustrating crisis, 296f
the growth payoff of fiscal reform measures of the BOJ, 291
packages, 377 minimizing a quadratic loss function,
Moerner, William, 24 338
monetary accommodation, with debt in the new mediocre, 315–340
financing leading to higher real GDP, not providing a firm enough anchor in
371, 372f India, 329
monetary and exchange rate policies, for reacting promptly to negative shocks
sustained growth in Asia, 285–312 to growth, 285
monetary and fiscal frameworks, regular reports, 317
reinforcing one another, 332 responses to negative output shocks,
monetary and fiscal policies, room for 316
maneuver, 335 results from low credibility, 328
monetary ease, reduced the risks of banking risk avoidance strategy for, 317–324
system loan portfolios, 334–335 risks to financial stability constraining,
monetary expansion, natural bias toward 304–309
excess in China, 188 scope for unconventional, 300–304
monetary growth targets, setting in China, slowdown in growth for, 4
187 in Thailand, 296f
monetary policy unable to offset the impact of fiscal
accommodative in Thailand, 372f shocks in Japan, 131
INDEX 441
non-Asian emerging-market economies, in Asia, 36t
inflation was significantly higher, 116 change between 2020 and 2030, 57f
nonfinancial corporate debt, low in India, defined, 36t, 38f, 57f, 58f
232 in East Asia, 34
nonfrontier firms, TFP differences with increasing from 15 to 20 percent in
frontier firms, 149n China, Korea, and Thailand, 344
nonmanufacturing sector, in Japan, in Korea following that of Japan, 170,
143–144, 144f, 153, 156f 171f
nonmarket economy, in Japan, 143n rising globally, 19
nonmonetary factors, having a major years to increase from 15 to 20 percent,
influence on inflation, 133 38f
nonperforming loans, 232 “old” Asian model, 407–410
nonregular employees “old corruption,” declined in Britain after
defined, 162 1750, 23
investing in the human capital of, 163 older people, 65, 375
in Japan, 143n, 154, 157f older workers
in total workers by sector, in Japan, associated with reduction in labor
144f productivity growth, 46, 47t
training for, 144 male, as nonregular employees in
nonregular employment, in Japan, 143–149, Japan, 146
162 positive effects on labor force
nonregular workers participation, 375
accumulating less human capital, 162 reducing annual growth, 46
employment adjustment in Korea, 169 in working-age population in Asia, 44f
increase in rising, 146 one-child policy, 182
providing benefits to, 163 “one county, one zone,” as inappropriate in
wages rising in Japan, 148 China, 189
nontraditional employment, in the one-year US Treasury bond rate, 251, 253n,
nonmanufacturing market economy, 253t
162 open capital markets, 76b
notional defined contribution pension open-economy New Keynesian model, for
scheme, 375 Australia, 337
nuclear blackmail, by medium-sized but openness and integration, in Asia, 136
poor nations, 21 Oppo, 91, 91n
numerical target, clarifying monetary Organization for Economic Cooperation
policy, 317 and Development (OECD), Japan the
first nonwestern nation to join, 77
obsolescence, issue of, 408 “original sin,” 250n
off-the-job training expenses, by firm size, output, 321, 329
1975–2010, in Japan, 158f output dynamics
oil exporters in Indonesia, 238–242, 255–257
current account, 275f Indonesia’s output dynamics, 238
with exchange rate pegs, 280n output gap
oil imports, countries understanding the alternative measures of, 299–300, 299t
cost of, 273n BOJ’s estimate of, 290, 290f
Okun’s law, on an excess unemployment defined, 321
rate, 290–291 for Japan, 333f
old-age dependency negative persisting, 335
capital-to-labor ratio and, 51 output growth, in Indonesia, 238
higher found to reduce interest rates, output growth rates, paths for potential,
59 260–262
impact on interest rates, 57, 57f “output of ideas,” 28
reducing current account balance, 51 outward-looking strategy, in Indonesia, 266
old-age dependency ratio
INDEX 443
research and development spending, increasing rapidly, 34
362f as inflationary, 175n
Scenario 3 and, 350, 352 and lower growth in Asia, 2
scope for quantitative easing, macroeconomic impact on saving and
December 2016, 303t investment, 51
tax revenue sources, 364f negative effects of on TFP, 169n
trade growth in, 399t posing a challenge for public debt
working-age people, emigration of, 37 sustainability, 344
working age populations growing threatening long-term fiscal
substantially, 344, 346f sustainability, 377
youth dependency ratio, 57f population dynamics, holding back growth,
Phillips curve 10
containing a nonlinear output gap, population growth. See also youth
337 dependency
declining estimates of the slope of, 286 in Asia, 34f
as dormant, 298–300 capital-to-labor ratio and, 51
estimate of an expectations- changes expected to be relatively small
augmented, 298–299, 299t between 2020–2030, 52n
regressions on US GDP deflator, 299t lower lowering growth, 6
physical capital accumulation, 353 rate for Asia, 34
Pitt, William, 23 triggering technological responses, 11
Poland, governance indicators, 22n “positive checks,” Malthusian, 11
policy positive supply shock, deflationary effect on
adapting to older population, 37 aggregate wages, 134
delay of responses in India, 331f post-65 cohort, extended number of years
emerging markets making changes of productivity, 20
to, 237 post-dividend demographic characteristic,
implications for global imbalances, 35t
282–283 post-dividend economies, 35
implications of demographic trends, potential growth, considering the evolution
64–66 of, 260–262
loss-minimization approach to potential growth rate
formulation, 320–322 declined in emerging markets, 255
need for a forward-looking, 5–8 decomposition into the actual
preserving space as the wrong strategy capital growth rate and potential
for an economy at risk of deflation, employment growth rate, 256n
295 decomposition of Indonesia’s,
strategies for Australia, 325–328, 326f, 2001–14, 256–257
327f in Indonesia, 257f, 262
tools as imperfect, 308 potential output
policy interest rates declined in Indonesia as a result of
choosing, 321 lower TFP growth, 263
as conditional, 322 as endogenous, 339
keeping higher than warranted by scenario analysis for Indonesia, 262f
macroeconomic conditions, 304 potential output growth rate in Indonesia
against the same variable after the actual and forecast, 256f
crisis, 116–117, 117f actual and forecast, 2000–22, 255–256
population potential shocks, sources of, 335
of Korea projected to decrease, 170 practical knowledge, sense of contempt
Malthusian responses to, 11 for, 18
projections affecting output through Prandtl, Ludwig, theory of aerodynamics,
aggregate labor and capital, 41 17n
population aging “precautionary principle,” 23
effect on inflation, 175n
INDEX 445
public investment efficiency frontier, 355, public spending on, 357–359, 362f
357f spending on in selected economies,
public pension funds, reforming the 2015, 362f
management of, 66 strategy, in Japan, 84
public policy choices in East Asia, during radical innovation, effects of, 100
years of rapid growth, 74 rate of real exchange rate appreciation
public-private partnerships (PPPs), for versus the US dollar, 251
infrastructure spending, 355 real 10-year bond yield, in advanced
public spending economies, 1990–2018, 272f
challenges of the new mediocre and, real 10-year Treasury rates, after the Asian
353–363 crisis, 272, 272f
on education as percent of GDP, 359f real depreciation, shifting domestic and
efficiency frontiers, 378, 378t foreign spending, 112
on health care as percent of GDP, 358f real effective exchange rate
level, composition, and efficiency of, correlation to Indonesia’s real GDP
355–359 growth, 253t
on pensions and health care, 346f for Japan, 333f
purchasing power, in Indonesia, 267 real equilibrium level, of the interest rate as
“pure imitator,” transitioning to close to zero, 335
“incremental innovator,” 90 real estate
markets in Japan and Korea, 173–174
quadratic loss function, 320–321 prices and CPI in Korea and Japan,
quantitative easing (QE), scope for in the 174f
Asia-15 economies, 302–304, 303t relationship with demographic
quasi-equilibrium (a “dark corner”), of low- variables, 63–64
inflation or deflation trap, 316 real exchange rate
quasi-fiscal borrowing, 190, 191 constant in the long run, 113
quasi-fiscal expenditures, 189 defined, 112
depreciating less in the short run, 113
depreciating over time, 114
R&D (research and development) index for, 225
East Asian approach having both source of, 125
strengths and weaknesses, 74 real GDP. See also GDP
increased government expenditure on effects of fiscal reforms, 368, 368f
in China, 185 growth rate of in Indonesia and in the
investment, appropriating the returns United States, 238–239, 240f
to in Japan, 79 volatility for selected countries, 241f
labs, top corporate effectively led by real GDP growth
PhD recipients in the United States, contribution of domestic and global
78 factors to Indonesia’s, 254f
productivity contributions to Indonesia’s, 247f
declined in the US, 100 for Japan, 333f
declining in East Asia, 96 rates in Indonesia, 239f
slowdown in growth, 3 rates in Indonesia and the United
trends in Japanese, 84f States, 240f
sector, increasing the proportion of the relative to ASEAN-4, 241f
labor force engaged in, 28 trends in Korea and the world, 167f
spending real growth rate, in China, 251
concentration of among South real interest rate(s)
Korean firms, 88f change in, 118
concentration of in a single chaebol- components of, 323
the Samsung Group, 86 computing, 175f
productivity of Japan’s corporate, decreased, 54, 116, 123, 272
73n defined, 293f
INDEX 447
robotization, replacing workers, 28 IRGD decreasing gradually to 1
robots, skilled people working percentage point below the 2022
collaboratively with, 409 level by 2030, 350
Romania, improved governance indicators, IRGD rising gradually reaching 2
22 percentage points above the 2022
Rome, technological progress not level by 2030, 350
sustainable, 18 for public debt projection, 348, 350
rule of bad law, 12 scholars, contempt for practical knowledge,
rupee, appreciation of, 204–205 18
rural labor migration, projected for 2028, science, advancing with better tools, 24
185n Science and Technology Basic Law,
Russia, theft and corruption by ruling implemented in Japan, 84
elites, 14 scientific knowledge, access to the existing
pool of, 25–26
“safe assets,” increasing the availability of, scientific products, for commercial use in
66 China, 185
Samsung Electronics, R&D expenditure in scientific research, 27
2010, 88f scientists, 17, 18, 26
Samsung Group second 21st century crisis, 269
high fraction of Korean exports, 86 secondary school enrollment, spending on,
produced more DRAM chips, 89n 360f
prominence in the global smartphone sectors, increased market shares with the
industry, 90, 91 strengthening of the rupee, 205, 212f
share of global smartphone shipments, secular stagnation
91n in advanced economies as transmitted
value of, 86n to Indonesia, 242–244, 255
savers, maintaining faith in domestic assets, affected nominal or real interest rates,
133 118
saving behavior, impact of aging on, 50n appropriate frequency to study, 121
saving determinants, survey of, 50n competing explanations for, 236
“saving” households, holding debt as a contagion across countries, 103
source of wealth, 365 diffusing via international trade in
savings goods and services, 107
aging-related, 52 exposure of Indonesia to, 244–251
demographic trends affecting, 50 foreign, 111, 112, 113, 114
excess in some countries, 105, 387 history and reality, 9–29
and investment across countries, 400 Indonesia countering, 255–262
Scandinavia, rent-seeking in by 1850, 23 Japan’s steps to address, 130
Scenario 1: status quo likelihood of in the foreseeable future,
debt ratio decreasing or stabilizing in 19
all economies, 350 limited transmission of from advanced
for public debt projection, 348, 349t economies to Indonesia, 263
Scenario 2: historical primary balance literature on, 105–106
debt ratio increasing in Japan, and as normal, 9
Malaysia and remaining flat in Sri reducing foreign interest rate and
Lanka, 350 demand in the long run, 113
for public debt projection, 348 results from a shortage of safe assets,
Scenario 3: demographics 105
pensions and healthcare spending, 350 risk of getting trapped in, 7
for public debt projection, 348 as the rule rather than the exception
Scenario 4: productivity and interest rates until 1800, 3
gradual decline in the IRGD, 352 spillovers to output dynamics in
increase in the IRGD raising the debt- Indonesia, 238–255
to-GDP ratio, 352–353 structural causes of Japan’s, 139
INDEX 449
youth dependency ratio, 57f internal factors of, 105
zero lower bound, currently at, 295 standard economic models, naïve view of
65–80 bracket, increased labor force the inflation process, 133
participation by, 20 Standard International Trade Classification
SK, 86n (SITC) codes, 172f
small and medium enterprises (SMEs), startups and new entrants, limited in Japan,
R&D intensity of in Japan, 149, 151f 81
smaller firms, easier access to capital in stasis, likelihood of reverting to a world
Taiwan than in South Korea, 92 of, 29
small firms, more prevalent in Japan than State Council in China, 188
in the United States, 158 state-owned enterprises (SOEs), reform of,
social knowledge, defining, 26 376
social security system, improving in Japan, status quo
141 average annual growth impact relative
“social skills” jobs, productivity rising with to, 41
age, 20n primary balance as of 2022, 353
SOEs (state-owned enterprises), bailouts of scenario for public debt projection,
troubled, 376 348, 349t
spillovers steam engine, theory of thermodynamics
from advanced economies, 106, 109, and, 17
109t steel, discovery of the chemical composition
complexity of to Indonesia, 255 of, 16
Sri Lanka Stein-Hardenberg reforms, in Prussia after
debt ratio change under Scenario 4b, 1806, 23
354f stimulus programs, temporary, 133
direct taxes as a small share of tax stock and bond markets, regulation of in
revenues, 366 Japan, 82
fiscal packages, 381t, 383t stock indicators, 248
in Group 3, 347b stock returns, demographic trends
infrastructure, index of quality of, 356f affecting, 62, 63
long-term public debt projection, 349t storage-and-search techniques, 26
personal income tax (PIT) yields, 363f strategic replication, 407
public debt, actual and projected, 346f, stress tests, of the balance sheets of
352f financial intermediaries, 287
public spending structural break, in India around 2005, 222
on education as percent of GDP, structural reforms
359f addressing challenges of aging, 68
efficiency frontier, distance from, in Japan, 141, 332
378t in Korea, 178
on health care as percent of GDP, as the main policy option, 288
358f need for supporting, 371, 373–376
on pensions and health care, 346f offsetting adverse growth effects of
R&D spending, 357 aging, 65–66
research and development spending, slowing the increase in healthcare
362f costs, 375
Scenario 3 and, 350, 352 undertaking, 8
stabilizing debt paths in, 353 structural supply-side policies, in Indonesia,
tax revenue sources, 364f 267
stabilization policy, against negative students
shocks, 133 with higher education in Indonesia,
“stagflation,” 329 259f
stagnation sending to the best universities in the
in emerging markets, 236–237 world from Indonesia, 267
exceptions to the rule of, 9n
INDEX 451
technological breakthroughs, fueled by rapid until 2030, 52
rapid entry of a large number of new aging speed change between 2020 and
firms, 75b 2030, 58f
technological followers, catching up by, 28 core CPI inflation, 296f
technological frontier, moving ahead to core inflation remaining well below 2
avoid secular stagnation, 28 percent, 286
technological innovation CPI inflation rates, 288f
accounting for low growth in advanced credit gaps, increases in, 119
economies, 257 current account balances, 1985–2016,
promotion of in China, 185 310f
technologically dynamic sectors, risks and debt ratio change under Scenario 4b,
rewards for talented young American 354f
managers and engineers, 76b demographic characteristics, 35t
technological paradigm, creating a new, 75b demographic impact on current
technological progress account, 53f
Chinese and pre-1700 Western as demographics impact on 10-year real
experience-based, 16n interest rates, 61f
impact on economic well-being in the demographic trends, impact of, 42f
Middle Ages, 15 fiscal packages, 380t, 382t
land- and resource-augmenting, 12 foreign capital, volatility of the supply
most critical for East Asian economies, of, 251f
101 foreign exchange reserves and net
resource-augmenting, 21 official assets, 311f
technological spillovers, found to raise TFP gap between actual and expected
and growth, 257 public spending on health care,
technology 355n
acceleration of development, 186 global financial integration across
adopting new in Japan, 164 emerging markets, 249f
allowing the elderly to cope with in Group 2, 347b
handicaps of old age, 20n inflation below 1 percent in 2016, 289
as another challenge, 409 infrastructure, 356f, 371, 372f
coevolving with science, 24 labor force aging, impact of, 344
developing and improving, 24 labor force participation, 48f, 49f
gap narrowing in Korea, 169 long-term public debt projection, 349t
gradual widening epistemic base of, 16 monetary ease, conditions supporting
partially offsetting downward pressure further, 311
on economic growth in China, 186 monetary policy, effects of
telescopes, improvements to, 24 accommodative, 372f
Temporary Trade Barriers database (World monetary policy since the Asian
Bank), 258 financial crisis, 296f
10-year government yield, change in, 55f months inflation rate below inflation
10-year real interest rates, 58–61, 61f target, 371f
terms-of-trade growth, correlation to old-age dependency ratio, 36t, 38f, 57f,
Indonesia’s real GDP growth, 253t 344
tertiary education, low levels of in older workers, share of, 44f
Indonesia, 258, 259f pensions in a partially defined-benefit
TFP. See total factor productivity (TFP) systems, 375
Thailand per capita income level, 39f
age-related spending projected to rise, personal income tax (PIT) yields, 363f
344, 346f as a post-dividend economy, 35
aging public debt, actual and projected, 346f,
fiscal pressures from, 353 351f
impact on growth, 41 public spending
impact on TFP, 48f
INDEX 453
moderating imbalances associated trade-to-GDP ratio, increased, 394
with slowing, 5 training
not sufficient to explain widening differences in on-the-job and off-the-
trade balances, 389 job, 155, 158f
period of rapid, 390, 391f gearing up, 410
for the periods 1995–2008 and moving to universities and vocational
2012–14, 397–398, 398t schools, 163
periods of high accompanied by transformative innovations, requiring
relatively faster import and export incremental inventions, 75b
growth, 394 transgenic crops, opposition to, 23
in surplus Asian countries Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), Japan
correlated with US import growth, pushing for, 141
399t Transparency International, corruption
imbalances, 400, 401 indices, 14
improvement in Indonesia, 266 transparent communications, conventional
integration forward guidance for, 322–324
having a negative impact on TFP trend total factor productivity (TFP)
growth, 110 growth
in Japan, 130 boosting potential, 353, 355
measured by the ratio of exports to impact of aging on, 344
GDP in 2007, 109 Trump administration, rhetoric on bilateral
liberalization, encouraging firms to US deficits, 404
reduce the number of products, turning Japanese, risk of in the late 1990s
146n sense, 129
linkages, as a direct source of
transmission of spillovers of secular ultra-low inflation, dangers of, 289–298
stagnation, 242 undisbursed loans, steadily rising in
modeled by reduced-forms equations, Indonesia, 267
339 unemployment, lowering long-term, 367
nature of between countries similarly unemployment rate
endowed, 409 in Japan, 290, 290f
relationship with imbalances, 389–390 lowering the long-term, 370
responsiveness to income and global United Kingdom
imbalances, 398t change in 10-year government yield,
restrictions 55f
doing little to alter global current per capita income level, 39f
imbalances, 283 United States
in Indonesia, 258–259 absolute balance relative to GDP and
slowdown, explanations for, 398, to trade, 394
400–401 account balances and reserve
and specialization, growth from purchases, 271f
vulnerable to political shocks, 14 aging speed change between 2020 and
tensions between the United States 2030, 58f
and trading partners in Asia, 6 business R&D and government
warfare, sparked global imbalances, support for business R&D, by firm
280 size, 151f
trade-facilitating infrastructure, expanding capital-to-output ratios, 168f
or building, 410 central bank transparency, 323, 324f
trade/GDP ratio, without growing current account balances, 1991–2017,
imbalances, 397f 274f
Trade in Value Added (TiVA) database deficit, growing after the mid-1990s,
(OECD), 397n 270
trade-related exposure, of Indonesia to demand, fueling export growth in Asia,
secular stagnation, 244–248 398
INDEX 455
CPI inflation rates, 1985–2016, 288f wage and labor productivity differences,
current account balances, 1985–2016, between large and small firms, 152,
310f 153f
debt prospects similar to China’s, 353 wage gap
debt ratio change under Scenario 4b, between large and small firms in Japan,
354f 162
demographic characteristics, 35t between nonregular and regular
demographic trends, impact of, 42f employees in Japan, 144, 145f, 162
emigration from, impact of net, 43 regulations reducing between regular
fiscal packages, 381t, 383t and nonregular employees in Japan,
foreign exchange reserves and net 148
official assets, 1985–2016, 311f between the two firm groups, 153f, 154
in Group 3, 347b wage profile, relationship with marginal
infrastructure, index of quality of, 356f productivity of employees in Japan,
labor force participation, 48f, 49f 145
long-term public debt projection, 349t wages and prices, forcing down, 291
old-age dependency ratio, 36t, 38f, 57f water pollution costs, likely to rise, 183
older workers, share of, 44f water power, improvement in, 16–17
pensions, 375 Watt, James, 17
per capita income level, 39f weak demand, explaining the recent trade
public debt, actual and projected, 346f, slowdown, 398
352f wealth, of urban areas before the
public spending Enlightenment, 13
efficiency frontier, distance from, Wells, H. G., 10
378t women
on health care as percent of GDP, increasing labor force participation, 65
358f retaining in the workforce, 133
on pensions and health care, 346f “Womenomics,” in Japan, 133
real per capita GDP, growth rate of, won
1985–2016, 287f depreciated sharply against the yen, 89
real short-term interest rate, 292, 293f strength of the Korean, 90
real trade growth, 1998–2008, workers
2012–2015, 393f accumulating human capital, 144
research and development spending, flow across firms and industries
362f limited in Japan, 81
Scenario 3 and, 350 LFPRs and, 46n
scope for quantitative easing, not changing jobs because of deferred
December 2016, 303t compensation in Japan, 149
tax revenue sources, 364f retraining, 65
10-year government yield, change in, working hours in Japan, 133
55f workforce aging
trade growth in, 399t associated with higher capital per
workforce, share of with productivity worker, 49
rising or falling, 45f estimated impact of projected on
youth dependency ratio, 57f growth, 46, 48f
virtual reality, as an educational tool, 27 estimating the effect on productivity,
Vivo, 91n 44–45
volatility share with productivity rising or
defined, 241f falling, 45f
of Indonesia’s net nonofficial inflows workforce composition, changes in, 3
compares favorably with regional working-age population
peers, 250, 251f absolute changes for different
of the supply of foreign capital, 251f demographic country groups in
voluntary saving, encouraging, 66 Asia, 38, 40f
INDEX 457