Analyzing The International Trade and Environment Regimes
Analyzing The International Trade and Environment Regimes
Can Trade Policy Support the Next Global Climate Agreement?: Analyzing the
International Trade and Environment Regimes
Author(s): Margaret Lay
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace (2008)
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve
and extend access to this content.
Margaret Lay
No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means
without permission in writing from the Carnegie Endowment. Please direct inquiries to:
Carnegie Papers
Carnegie Papers present new research by Endowment associates and their collaborators
from other institutions. The series includes new time-sensitive research and key excerpts
from larger works in progress. Comments from readers are most welcome; please reply to
the author at the address above or by e-mail to pubs@CarnegieEndowment.org.
Summary 1
Introduction 1
Conclusion 25
Introduction
The European Union recently threatened to impose a carbon tariff on goods
produced in countries where greenhouse gas emissions do not meet European
standards. Recent climate proposals in the United States have similarly included
measures that would require importers of carbon-intensive manufactured goods
from nations without comparable climate initiatives to purchase emissions al-
lowances. These proposals have stirred heated debate among trade and climate
policy makers. Proponents of freer trade fear that addressing these concerns
will lead down the “slippery slope” to protectionism. Many believe that the
proposals stem from the concerns of domestic carbon-intensive industry about
declining competitiveness as a result of pursuing expensive carbon emission
reductions. Climate policy makers, on the other hand, are attracted to the po-
tential of trade measures to reduce the migration of carbon-emitting indus-
tries to countries with less stringent climate policies. Trade restrictions limiting
the outsourcing of emissions may increase the effectiveness of any national or
global climate policy.
The prospect of using carbon tariffs to further climate policy is a new and
dramatic manifestation of a long-standing debate on the proper relationship
between trade measures and environment policy. The history of this relation-
ship holds important lessons for initiatives to develop effective national and
global climate policies. This paper examines that relationship. The first and
second sections consider the broad debate on trade and environment policy.
The first section examines the structure and objectives of the existing trade and
environment regimes to shed light on potential areas of conflict and synergy
between the two. The second section reviews examples of trade measures that
have supported environment policy. It first looks at how two multilateral en-
vironmental agreements employ trade-related measures. It then explores opin-
ion within the World Trade Organization (WTO) toward environmental trade
measures by considering WTO jurisprudence on environmental disputes and
current relevant WTO treaty negotiations. This review of the historical rela-
tionship between trade and the environment reveals guideposts for the integra-
tion of WTO-consistent trade measures into climate policy. The third section
explores current proposals for integrating trade-related measures into national
climate policy. It considers the history of the relationship between the trade and
environment regimes and the guideposts set by the WTO, and it examines the
channels through which trade policy can support national climate policy and
suggests trade policies that could support global climate initiatives.
The Concerns
Trade liberalization has several potential negative effects on the environment.
A primary objective of the global trade regime is to increase the volume of
global production. This, in turn, may lead to an increased exploitation of nat-
ural resources and higher levels of carbon emissions in the production pro-
cess. Transporting more goods longer distances will also result in the use of
more fossil fuels. Conversely, foreign investment and competition may intro-
duce cleaner production methods to developing countries, and the rules of the
Potential Synergies
Even in the face of these concerns, increased international trade, the rules of the
multilateral trade regime, and the incentives they present could be harnessed to
Unlike international trade, which is governed by one identifiable multilateral trade regime, MEAs
arise to address particular environmental problems. Several organizations, including the United
Nations Environment Program and the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change,
are involved in developing and implementing MEAs.
An estimated 230 MEAs employ a variety of tools to address distinct environmental challenges.
Only twenty of these MEAs include trade restrictions. Six MEAs, all of which include trade restric-
tions and are monitored by the United Nations Environment Program, constitute the core multilateral
environmental initiatives. The Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species works to
ensure that international trade in endangered species does not further threaten the survival of those
species. The Montreal Protocol protects the ozone layer by controlling the production and consump-
tion of ozone-depleting substances. The Basel Convention on Hazardous Wastes controls the system
of the transboundary movement, disposal, and management of hazardous wastes. The Rotterdam
Convention on Pesticides and Chemicals facilitates the exchange of information on pesticides and
chemicals, and works to promote their environmentally sound use. The Cartagena Protocol aims
to protect biodiversity from the potential risks posed by living modified organisms resulting from
modern biotechnology. Finally, the Stockholm Convention works to protect humanity’s health and
environment from persistent organic pollutants.
These MEAs are negotiated in separate forums, but they share common principles and char-
acteristics. Each is based upon the principle of “common but differentiated responsibility,” which
recognizes that countries contribute to the environmental problem at different levels and enjoy
different capacities to address it. Each MEA is driven by and updated according to scientific assess-
ments, and it is carefully tailored to the particular environmental problem at hand. These MEAs have
garnered widespread support within the international community, largely because of these com-
mon characteristics: They enjoy legitimacy based on scientific investigations, they were developed
through transparent and inclusive negotiations, and they recognize that developing countries may
have a limited capacity to contribute to the resolution of environmental problems.
The Kyoto Protocol, administered by the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate
Change, is the global climate agreement. It aims to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by setting
emissions reduction targets for each of its signatories. It shares many of the characteristics listed
above. Developed countries have stringent reduction targets, whereas developing countries are not
held to specific targets in the first commitment period for the protocol. Members are left to devise
national policies that will enable them to meet the protocol’s targets. The protocol does not include
specific trade-related obligations, but it has established several mechanisms to assist members in
meeting their reduction targets. These mechanisms include the Clean Development Mechanism,
which allows nations to implement projects in developing countries in exchange for emissions re-
duction credits, and Joint Implementation, which allows developed nations to work together on
projects to reduce emissions.
Numerous critics of the Kyoto Protocol argue that it is ineffective in stemming the risk of global
warming. The world’s largest polluter, the United States, has not signed the protocol or agreed to
limit its carbon emissions. As noted above, the protocol has limited enforcement mechanisms to
ensure that its members actually meet their assigned targets. The current commitment period for
the protocol expires in 2012, and international climate policy makers are investigating policy tools
that can be incorporated into an effectivive post-2012 climate regime. International trade policy is
one of these tools.
The Concerns
Many in the trade community fear that environmental measures incorpo-
rated into trade agreements could be exploited for protectionist reasons. The
U.S. Trade Representative, Susan Schwab, argues that border tariffs and simi-
lar “trade restrictions run the risk of tit-for-tat retaliation and even an all-out
trade war where no one wins and everyone loses.”7 If the United States were
to restrict imports from China of goods produced in a more carbon-intensive
manner, China could retaliate by closing markets to U.S. goods. Tit-for-tat
policies would cause markets to contract and world economic activity to de-
cline. The WTO website describes this phenomenon as a “self-defeating and
destructive drift into protectionism.”8
Today’s multilateral trade regime was born, in part, in response to the “beg-
gar-thy-neighbor” policies that contributed to a drastic contraction of interna-
tional trade between World War I and World War II. Through these policies,
nations sought to curb domestic economic depression and unemployment by
focusing on domestic production and limiting imports. One example is the
United States’ Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act of 1930, which raised the average tariff
rate by 20 percent. Within two years, dozens of countries had enacted similar
protectionist policies. Between 1929 and 1934, global trade declined by 66
percent. A pillar of the multilateral trade regime is the belief that these tit-for-
tat trade policies impeded international cooperation and exacerbated the Great
Depression. The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) was negoti-
ated to prevent countries from increasing tariffs and likewise to prevent protec-
tionism from leading to another breakdown in international trade cooperation
and a contraction of the global marketplace.
Yet economic opinion has evolved over the past half century. Economists
increasingly recognize that government trade interventions are not inherently
market distortions; they can be valuable tools for correcting market imperfec-
tions and creating missing markets. Economic actors may not consider the true
cost of environmental damage. Economist Joseph Stiglitz describes the lack of
stringent environmental standards in the United States as a form of subsidy:
The U.S. refusal to restrict the emission of carbon dioxide and other green-
house gases unfairly lowers U.S. manufacturing costs. One of the core objec-
tives of the WTO is to establish a level playing field for its members. A carbon
tariff, by offsetting the implicit subsidy given by a lax climate policy, could be
seen to support this objective.9
Potential Synergies
The GATT and the Marrakesh Accords, the agreement creating the WTO,
recognize that policies in pursuit of the primary objectives of the trade regime—
open borders and a level playing field—may undermine another principle to
which the GATT and the Marrakesh Accords pay lip service: sustainable devel-
opment. The GATT of 1947 includes an exemption clause, Article XX, which
allows members to adopt trade policies that would otherwise be inconsistent
with the GATT if such policies protect human, plant, or animal life or health,
or protect exhaustible resources.
Since the WTO was established with the Marrakesh Accords in 1995, the
WTO Appellate Body, which rules on disputes between WTO members, has
become increasingly open to using Article XX to exempt environmental trade
measures. However, this exemption article has a limited range of applicability.
One question that is central to determining that range is: Can trade restrictions
be enacted against a product based on the process by which that product was
made, rather than its physical characteristics? This and other issues related to
Article XX’s applicability will be discussed in detail in the third section below.
Before the WTO was established, GATT jurisprudence clearly set the prece-
dent that process-based standards were not acceptable justifications for trade re-
strictions. However, jurisprudence within the WTO has been increasingly open
to accepting standards based on process and production methods (see the dis-
cussion of the Mexican tuna case in box 3 below). Furthermore, the Marrakesh
Accords include two agreements on standards and regulations that—of par-
ticular importance—are often interpreted to cover process-based standards: the
Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT), which addresses technical
negotiations and standards, and its counterpart, the Agreement on Sanitary
and Phytosanitary (SPS) Measures, which addresses food safety and animal and
plant health regulations. These two agreements recognize that member coun-
tries can set environmental standards (including those that are process-based)
and restrict trade accordingly. They lay out specific directives to ensure that
standards do not restrict trade excessively, they call for transparency in estab-
lishing and implementing trade measures, and they encourage the international
harmonization of standards where possible.10
The 1994 Ministerial Decision on Trade and Environment constituted
another important treaty-based shift in the international trade regime that could
lead to more synergies between trade and the environment.11 It established the
Committee on Trade and Environment (CTE), which has specific mandates to
investigate the environmental impact of trade policy and to suggest modifica-
tions to trade rules that will most effectively promote sustainable development.
The CTE explores the relationship between trade and environment in all areas
of the WTO. It reports to and advises the General Council, one of the WTO’s
highest decision-making bodies and its top rule-making body.
The environmental policy community and scientific community have the
needed environmental expertise to be helpful in shaping the CTE’s discussion.
The United Nations Environment Program works to develop a coordinated
position in the environmental policy community on trade-related issues. Such a
coordinated position could enable environmental advocates to contribute more
to discussions within the CTE. While offering the trade community the advice
it seeks in the mandate of the CTE, the environmental community could also
help shape the environmental considerations of the trade debate.
The existence of an organization like the CTE with this role and position
within the international trade regime may appear to suggest a reconciliation of
the concerns of the trade and environmental communities. However, a closer
examination may lead to skepticism about the CTE’s effectiveness and scope.
Within the WTO, the CTE has no direct rule-making power; though it advises
the General Council, it cannot directly change the laws of the multilateral trade
The multilateral trade regime grew out of the economic tumult following the Great Depression
and World War II. The world’s top economists and policy makers envisioned an international eco-
nomic order built upon three pillars: the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund, and the
International Trade Organization (ITO). The ITO would monitor the trade aspects of international
economic cooperation. Its objective would be to avoid the proliferation of the “beggar-thy-neigh-
bor” trade policies—that is, trade measures aimed at curing domestic economic depressions and
unemployment by encouraging domestic production and limiting imports—that exacerbated the
global Great Depression in the 1930s. The fear is that trading partners will retaliate by banning im-
ports from countries that have closed domestic markets. Within the trade policy community, this is
considered “tit-for-tat” protectionism, which leads to a contraction of world markets and economic
activity. The multilateral trade regime works to avoid this dynamic by increasing international trade
cooperation and opening borders among nations.
The United States failed to ratify the ITO Charter, and the ITO never took form. In 1947, twenty-
three nations that had been involved in the ITO negotiations developed a provisional treaty—the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)—that established the rules guiding the international
trade policies of its signatories. This treaty was the primary institution facilitating international trade
cooperation for fifty years. The GATT signatories reduced tariffs, opened borders, and updated the
international trade rules through seven rounds of negotiations.
In 1995, the Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations established the World Trade
Organization. This organization fills the role of the failed ITO. Its central pillar, the Dispute Settlement
Mechanism (DSM), litigates disputes between World Trade Organization members. The multilateral
trade regime is dynamic; successive rounds of negotiations update GATT law, and litigation through
the DSM sets precedents on how those laws are interpreted.
The multilateral trade regime has five core principles: trade without discrimination, free trade
gradually through negotiation, predictability through bound tariff rates and transparency, promot-
ing fair competition, and encouraging development and economic reform. These principles have
led to an international trade regime that encourages the use of international standards, prohibits
quantitative restrictions on trade, and promotes sustainable development through trade. This re-
gime is commonly referred to as a rules-based system. The GATT determines the written laws of
international trade relations, whereas litigation through the DSM establishes common laws. This
structure establishes two access points to shape international trade law.
CITES, which entered into force in 1975, regulates trade in endangered spe-
cies so that it will not further threaten their survival. Trade restrictions form a
key component of the treaty; all importing, exporting, re-exporting, and intro-
duction from the sea of species covered by CITES has to be authorized through
a licensing system. Three annexes list all the endangered species covered by
CITES, categorized according to the level of protection they need.
The Conference of the Parties, the supreme CITES decision-making body, is
made up of representatives from all 172 CITES members. This body decides the
criteria that determine in which annex a species will be listed; Annex I includes
the species in immediate need of protection, Annex II includes the species that
are slightly further from extinction, and Annex III includes species that at least
one party to CITES protects under national policy. A member adds a species to
CITES by proposing and providing scientific justification for the species’ inclu-
sion in one of the three annexes during a regular meeting of the Conference of
the Parties. All members discuss and vote. The CITES secretariat, together with
the Conference of the Parties’ Standing Committee, is responsible for gathering
scientific findings and suggesting the appropriate trade restrictions to protect all
species listed in CITES annexes between regular meetings.15
CITES establishes guidelines for its members’ national-level enforcement
committees on monitoring the treatment of endangered species and enforcing
policies that protect endangered species. Individual member states issue import
and export permits according to these guidelines. The movement of a specimen
of a species listed in Annex I or Annex II requires both an export and an import
permit from the involved countries. Annex I permits are issued only in special
circumstances, when importing and exporting countries follow strict care and
protection guidelines. Annex II permits have less stringent requirements, but
they are also issued only when member countries can abide by specific monitor-
ing and protection standards. For species in Annex III, only export permits are
required. CITES also establishes quota systems for certain highly endangered
species, including the African elephant, the sturgeon, and the leopard. Though
species are added to the annexes and subject to quotas based upon their physi-
cal characteristics and the level of protection they need, trade permits are issued
based upon a country’s ability to abide by process-based standards—the moni-
toring and enforcement practices of the trading countries.
CITES also includes trade restrictions to enforce compliance with this moni-
toring and enforcement system—restrictions that are applicable to both par-
ties and nonparties. Trade restrictions are rarely enforced against nonparties;
instead, the CITES secretariat focuses on working with nonparties to achieve
remedial action. The parties to CITES are expected to provide documentation
that they are inspecting and enforcing international standards for catching those
endangered species that are listed. If these parties do not provide this documen-
tation, they are subject to punishment by the CITES secretariat.16
refusing to sign it, jeopardizing its passing. Directly after the inclusion of the
trade restrictions, these countries signed it. The negotiators representing these
countries revealed to the lead negotiator for the protocol that its trade restric-
tions were the prime factor motivating their shift in position. These restrictions
were implicitly designed to convince developing countries holding out on sign-
ing the protocol to participate in the multilateral ozone treaty. Because partici-
pation in the protocol was virtually full, these restrictions were never enforced,
and no country that was a party to the GATT (or, later, the WTO) has ever
issued a complaint against them.19
Before including trade restrictions in the Montreal Protocol, the negotia-
tors discussed whether these restrictions complied with international trade rules
with the GATT secretariat.20 The secretariat confirmed that, under Article XX
of the GATT, trade restrictions were permissible, if they could be considered
necessary to protect human, animal, or plant life or health; or if they are related
to the conservation of exhaustible natural resources.21 Yet after the Montreal
Protocol was signed, including its trade restrictions, the GATT secretariat sig-
nificantly revised its opinion. Despite the fact that no country ever launched a
complaint against these restrictions in the GATT or then the WTO, the GATT
secretariat issued a statement that these restrictions were unnecessary. It argued
that (1) the protocol could have been negotiated to reduce CFCs without in-
cluding trade restrictions and (2) the protocol’s trade restrictions were intended
to protect domestic industry. The secretariat argued that these restrictions pro-
vided compensation to CFC producers in participating countries by allowing
them to receive extra profits from selling the diminishing quantities of CFCs.
According to the secretariat, the restrictions discriminated against nonparties.
The secretariat’s statement, however, neglected to note that CFC-producing
industries in participating countries were actually taxed on the extra profits they
gained under the protocol.22 Though the secretariat does not wield the power
to make decisions within the international trade regime (contracting parties
negotiate the rules, and the dispute settlement panels and Appellate Body de-
termine GATT/WTO jurisprudence), its opinion reveals fears within the trade
community about environmental trade measures.
This reaction of the GATT secretariat to the Montreal Protocol’s trade re-
strictions highlights several concerns that resonate today within the trade policy
community. First, the secretariat argued that the protocol could have achieved
its objectives without including the trade restrictions, underlining the strict “ne-
cessity test” to which environmental trade restrictions are held: Trade restrictions
are legal only if they are virtually indispensable to the environmental objec-
tive of the overarching policy and they are imposed in a way that is as least
trade distorting as possible. The most contentious trade restriction—the ability
of parties to the protocol to ban trade with nonparties in products produced
using CFCs—highlights the concern about standards related to the process and
production methods of a good. The GATT secretariat’s fear that the trade
This box reviews four WTO disputes that reveal precedents within the organization regarding exemp-
tions for environmental trade policy from the rules of the multilateral trading system. Environmental
trade policy can be exempted from WTO rules under paragraphs b or g of GATT Article XX. Paragraph
b exempts trade measures that are necessary to protect human, animal, or plant life or health.
Paragraph g exempts trade measures that are related to the conservation of exhaustible natural re-
sources. As the DSM special panels and the WTO Appellate Body consider whether a trade measure
meets these qualifications, questions about process-based standards and extraterritoriality often
arise. In this way, litigation trends in environmental disputes also reveal WTO precedents on these
two important issues. If a trade measure qualifies for exemption under paragraph b or g, the DSM
panel then considers whether the measure meets the specifications of the introductory chapter
(“chapeau”) of Article XX by looking for embedded discrimination or protectionism. The evolution
of litigation in these rulings reveals a DSM that increasingly supports policy space, under paragraphs
b and g, for members to enact environmental trade policy. However, the DSM has also set strict
guideposts for environmental trade measures on the issues of discrimination and protectionism.
The Mexican tuna case of 1994 is often considered the first precedent-setting environmental trade
dispute. The United States enacted an import ban against Mexican tuna that were not caught in
a dolphin-safe manner. The GATT dispute settlement panel ruled that these U.S. trade restrictions
constituted discrimination against similar products and thus were illegal. The panel also decided
that because these U.S. trade restrictions aimed to enforce national U.S. standards for tuna-fishing
practices among Mexican fishers, they violated Mexico’s national sovereignty. The panel warned
that any lenience on either of these issues—enforcing standards based on process and production
methods and extraterritoriality—could lead down the “slippery slope” to protectionism and the
unilateral imposition of national standards on other countries. Such lenience would undermine the
fundamental principles of the multilateral trade regime by decreasing predictability in international
trade markets and policy. (Source: WTO Environmental Disputes, http://www.wto.org/english/tra-
top_e/envir_e/edis00_e.htm.)
The U.S. gasoline dispute in 1995 was the first environmental case decided through the WTO’s
DSM. Under the U.S. Clean Air Act, the United States prohibited gasoline refiners from selling
gasoline that was less clean (below a “refinery baseline”) than the gasoline each refiner sold in
1990. Each domestic refiner established an individual refinery baseline that was equivalent to the
quality of gasoline it sold in 1990. Foreign refiners were subject to a refinery baseline set by the U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency, which was intended to reflect the average quality of gasoline in
1990. Imports of gasoline below this refinery baseline were banned.
The DSM special panel ruled that this import restriction was not justified under paragraphs b
or g of GATT Article XX. In particular, although the panel recognized clean air as an “exhaustible
natural resource,” it argued that the refinery baseline was not a measure related to its conservation
and thus did not satisfy paragraph g. The Appellate Body overturned this ruling, claiming that the
refinery baseline was indeed related to the conservation of clean air and qualified as an exemption
under paragraph g. However, the Appellate Body argued that because foreign producers were sub-
ject to different standards than domestic producers, the policy was discriminatory and did not meet
the qualifications of Article XX’s chapeau. With this ruling, the Appellate Body pushed the boundar-
ies of paragraph g, but it continued to hold environmental trade policy to a stringent interpretation
of discrimination. (Source: “United States—Standards for Reformulated Gasoline,” Report of the
Appellate Body, AB-1996-1, WT/DS2/AB/R, April 29, 1996.)
The 1997 shrimp-turtle case echoed the dynamic of the U.S. gasoline case. Under the U.S.
Endangered Species Act, the United States enacted trade restrictions against imports of shrimp
caught by trawlers that did not use a turtle-excluder device, intended to protect five species of en-
dangered turtles that migrated through U.S. waters. Though the special panel initially ruled that the
trade restriction was not justified under paragraphs b or g of Article XX, the Appellate Body over-
turned this ruling. It argued that sea turtles could be deemed an “exhaustible natural resource” and
that these production-based standards were necessary for their protection. However, the Appellate
Body maintained that the United States had discriminated against India, Malaysia, Pakistan, and
Thailand in its imposition of the restriction; the United States had provided countries in the Western
Hemisphere with financial and technical assistance in starting to use the turtle-excluder devices, but
it had not offered equivalent assistance to the plaintiffs.
Through this ruling, the Appellate Body expanded the notion of national territory that was es-
tablished by the Mexican tuna case. The United States was allowed to enforce these process-based
standards because they protected turtles migrating through U.S. waters. The Appellate Body issued
a statement encouraging WTO members to take bilateral, plurilateral, or multilateral action through
trade policy to protect the environment. Yet again, the Appellate Body clearly indicated that envi-
ronmental trade policies cannot discriminate among trading partners. (Source: WTO Environmental
Disputes, http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/envir_e/edis00_e.htm.)
The 2007 Brazilian tire dispute crystallized the precedent initiated in the U.S. gasoline and shrimp
turtle cases. Brazil enacted a ban on importing retreaded tires, which are closer to turning into
waste than new tires. The accumulation of waste tires presents health risks, and waste tire fires that
generate toxins could ignite and are difficult to put out. The objective of this policy was the “reduc-
tion of the risk of waste tire accumulation to the extent possible.” Brazil did not conduct expensive
policy and economic analysis to prove that the trade ban was necessary to fulfill this objective;
rather, it justified the ban on the basis of logical, deductive reasoning. The Appellate Body accepted
this reasoning and found the ban to be justified under paragraph b of Article XX as necessary to
fulfill this environmental objective. The Appellate Body ruled, however, that Brazil could not invoke
Article XX because, in practice, the import ban discriminated against EU producers. The Brazilian
retreaders, citing violations of their fundamental rights, had managed to receive numerous court
injunctions that allowed them to bypass this import ban and import retreaded tires from countries
and manufacturers of their choosing.
With this ruling, the Appellate Body has clearly announced its support for a WTO member in
creating national environmental standards and in enforcing them as the member sees fit. In accept-
ing Brazil’s deductive argument, the Appellate Body has made it easier for developing countries
that do not have the funds and expertise necessary to conduct extensive policy analyses to enact
environmental trade policies. However, the guidepost for discrimination remains high; discrimina-
tion against products based on production standards or physical characteristics will only be legal
when it is justified by the same environmental rationale as the trade measure itself. Some argue
that this reveals a DSM that encourages environmental action through trade but focuses on block-
ing protectionism and discrimination: “While trade can and will be unequivocally trumped by good
faith nontrade policy measures, at least those catering to key societal interests such as health and
the environment (trade seems a distant second), this must happen without discrimination and must
not otherwise be abused as a trade policy measure (trade catches up)” (BRIDGES Monthly Digest,
February 2008, http://www.ictsd.org/monthly/bridges/BRIDGES_12-1.pdf).
or among trading partners, and that these measures thus do not meet the quali-
fications for exemption under the chapeau to GATT Article XX. To further
complicate the identification of discrimination, Articles I and III do not clearly
define “equivalent products.” Many environmental trade policies limit trade
in products because they were produced in an environmentally harmful way,
such as the EU carbon tariff or the trade ban on goods produced using CFCs
suggested in the Montreal Protocol. The question of the legality of trade dis-
crimination based on process and production methods is at the core of many
environmental trade debates. The Mexican tuna and shrimp-turtle cases are
examples of conflicting rulings on this issue.
Article IX of the GATT prohibits quantitative restrictions on trade, such as
bans and quotas. Many trade policies designed to support environmental objec-
tives employ quantitative restrictions—for example, the ban on trade in prod-
ucts containing CFCs under the Montreal Protocol and the issuance of export
quotas for endangered species enforced by the CITES secretariat. GATT Article
VIII prohibits government subsidies. Some subsidies, such as those to the agri-
cultural and fishing sectors, promote the unsustainable use of natural resources,
and many environmentalists believe that they should be eliminated. However,
other subsidies, such as those used to promote the adaptation of existing facili-
ties to new environmental technologies and requirements, are beneficial to the
environment. Until 1999, these subsidies were considered nonactionable (that
is, permitted) under the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures.
This provision has since expired, and these environmental subsidies are techni-
cally inconsistent with multilateral trade law.25
Environmental trade measures may violate the laws discussed above.
Defendants in WTO cases tend to appeal to Article XX of the GATT or to
the TBT and SPS agreements. GATT Article XX, the exemption clause, is the
most powerful tool available to defendants concerned with environmental trade
policy. This article allows a trade measure to be exempted from GATT law if it
is necessary to protect plant, animal, or human life or health (paragraph b); or
is related to the conservation of exhaustible resources (paragraph g). However,
the chapeau to Article XX stipulates that a trade measure that meets these re-
quirements must meet two further conditions: It cannot constitute disguised
protectionism, and it cannot constitute arbitrary or unjustified discrimination
among WTO members.
Recent litigation on environmental disputes has revealed that the WTO
Appellate Body is increasingly open to qualifying environmental trade
measures as necessary to protect plant, animal, or human life or health; or to
conserve exhaustible resources. Yet the Appellate Body continues to make a strict
interpretation of what constitutes disguised protectionism or discrimination.
The result is that very few environmental trade policies pass through the DSM
unscathed. This dynamic is evident in the shrimp-turtle, U.S. gasoline, and
Brazil tire disputes.
The TBT and SPS agreements set boundaries for WTO members to enforce
national environmental standards and regulations through trade policy. These
agreements include provisions designed to ensure that related trade policies are
not overly trade restrictive. Environmental standards and regulations must be
developed through a transparent and scientific process, and quantitative restric-
tions (bans and quotas) enforcing those standards should be avoided when pos-
sible. The agreements encourage the use of international and multilateral, rather
than unilateral, environmental standards. Trade advocates are concerned that
an ad hoc system of national standards would undermine the WTO’s objective
of creating a consistent, predictable international trade environment.
“Extraterritoriality” is a concern related to the unilateral imposition of stan-
dards; trade policies that in effect hold other nations to domestic standards
could be considered to infringe upon their national sovereignty. Recent WTO
Appellate Body rulings, notably in the shrimp-turtle case, have expanded the
notion of “territory” to allow WTO members to enact trade measures that af-
fect environmental standards in other countries. Jurisprudence has evolved so
that questions of extraterritoriality and of process and production methods no
longer present absolute roadblocks.
Rules Negotiations
The boundaries defining acceptable environmental trade policy appear to be
expanding through dispute settlement jurisprudence. Yet formal treaty negotia-
tions, the products of consensus discussions among all WTO member coun-
tries, have produced fewer results. Both the Uruguay Round text and the Doha
Round mandate pay lip service to the importance of sustainable development
to the multilateral trade regime. However, there has been little tangible progress
in negotiations toward trade law that effectively supports environmental trade
policy. Though dispute settlement rulings indicate that environmental stan-
dards based on production methods are legal, WTO members shy away from
mentioning process and production methods in formal discussions, much less
writing a provision into the WTO treaty. Because past rounds of rules negotia-
tions have created an organizational structure that includes the Committee on
Trade and Environment, at first glance these rounds appear to have been geared
to address the issues in the trade and environment conflict. Yet the limited
scope of discussions within the CTE suggest otherwise.
Under the Doha Round mandate, the CTE considers three issues, the discus-
sions of which take place in “special sessions.” The first issue is the relationship
between the rules of the WTO and the rules of MEAs. Can a WTO member
enact trade restrictions, dictated by an MEA, against another WTO member
that has also signed the MEA? Can it do so if the other WTO member is not
a signatory to the MEA? The answers to these questions are critical to under-
standing whether trade restrictions in a future climate treaty would be compat-
ible with WTO law. The scope of related discussions within the CTE is limited
to the applicability of WTO rules when both parties involved are signatories
to the MEA in question. They thus do not address an issue critical to the trade
and environment debate: Can the environmental policy community use trade
restrictions to keep nations in line that refuse to sign MEAs?
The second item on the Doha agenda of the CTE is to discuss specific
mechanisms of collaboration between the WTO and the MEAs’ secretariats.
Some forms of cooperation between the two already exist: The CTE holds in-
formation sessions for the members of the MEAs’ secretariats, and the WTO
secretariat collaborates with the MEAs’ secretariats to exchange documents and
provide technical assistance to developing countries on issues that are important
for trade and the environment.
The third item on the CTE’s agenda for the Doha Round is to discuss the
elimination of tariffs and nontariff barriers on environmental goods and ser-
vices. This issue, arguably, has seen more progress than the other two items on
the CTE’s agenda. The elimination of trade barriers is one of the core principles
of the multilateral trade regime. This issue has received more attention within
CTE discussions, in part, because both the United States and the European
Union support liberalization in environmental goods and services. Yet the out-
look for multilateral liberalization of trade in environmental goods remains un-
certain. Currently, CTE discussions remain in the preliminary stage: they are
focused on agreeing upon a method of defining environmental goods and ser-
vices. Developed countries favor a “list” approach, in which members propose
goods and services that are used for environmental purposes to be classified as
“environmental.” Many developing countries, conversely, support a “project”
approach, which would define environmental goods based on their use in envi-
ronmental projects. Neither approach encourages the inclusion of goods on the
basis of whether they were produced in a less environmentally harmful manner.
Most WTO members are hesitant to embark upon discussions of process and
production methods with respect to environmental goods and services, partly
in fear of setting a precedent for introducing this concept to other parts of the
WTO treaty negotiations.26
Some initiatives within the Doha Round that affect trade-related measures
in environmental policy are outside the CTE’s mandate. The elimination of
subsidies to the fisheries sector is discussed as part of the rules negotiations.27
These subsidies distort trade and encourage unsustainable fishing practices. At
the same time, they are fundamental to the livelihoods of many small fishing
communities in developing countries. It is a sensitive issue, and a final decision
on the fisheries subsidies requires a consensus. Thus the negotiation process
on this issue has been slow. The current rules draft would make many types
of subsidies to the fishing sector illegal. Some subsidies would be permitted,
but they would need to be linked to an international standard for fisheries
management systems. The draft also exempts least developed countries from
the ban on subsidies. The “Friends of the Fish”—which include the United
Wicks, argued that a carbon tariff could be used as a “secret weapon” to bring
about the rise of protectionist interests in Europe.29 The EU action plan was
released on January 23 without the proposed carbon tariff. Yet Commission
president José Barrosso threatened to reconsider the tariff in 2011 if key coun-
tries—namely, the United States and China—fail to cooperate with post–Kyoto
global climate initiatives.30
The Lieberman–Warner Climate Security Act, the climate legislation at the
forefront of debate in the United States, also included trade measures. This bill
would have required importers of carbon-intensive goods from countries that
fail to take “comparable” action against climate change to purchase emissions
allowances. The president would decide which countries had taken comparable
action on climate change. The bill was pulled from congressional consideration
on June 6, 2008.
These EU and U.S. approaches both relied on “border” measures enacted
against imports of carbon-intensive goods. Such adjustments could support cli-
mate efforts with three mechanisms: (1) by assuaging the competitiveness con-
cerns of domestic carbon-intensive industry, (2) by reducing emissions leakage,
and (3) by minimizing free riding. The first mechanism is primarily political;
measures to reduce carbon emissions are expensive and will likely meet resistance
from those that have to pay the cost if their competitors are not subject to the
same requirements. A carbon tariff could be used to garner the support of those
necessary constituencies that must incur the costs of emissions reductions.
The second mechanism—reducing emissions leakage—bolsters the environ-
mental effectiveness of climate policy. When carbon-intensive goods and ser-
vices are free to flow across borders, the carbon emissions reductions achieved
in a nation that pursues an aggressive climate policy may “leak” to other coun-
tries with less stringent carbon regulation. This nullifies the climate impact of
the emissions reductions in the original country. Emissions leakage can occur
through several channels: the relocation of production, the restructuring of
consumption, or changes in the price of energy. Rather than incur the costs
of reducing emissions, carbon-intensive firms may relocate to countries where
climate regulations—and thus the cost of abiding by them—are lower. Thus
carbon emissions, along with production, simply relocate to nonregulated
countries, and carbon-intensive goods are exported to countries with higher
emissions standards. Consumers in countries with stringent climate policies
may opt to buy those imported goods produced in countries with less stringent
climate policies because they are cheaper than goods produced at home. As
energy demand decreases in countries with strong climate policies, the price of
energy on the global market may decline, and energy consumption in countries
without strong energy and climate policies may then increase to meet the de-
mand for cheap, carbon-intensive products. Trade measures have the potential
to internalize the environmental costs of carbon emissions in countries that do
not impose a financial burden on their own emitters to account for the envi-
ronmental externalities.
The third mechanism through which border adjustments can support na-
tional climate policy is by discouraging free riders. The climate is a global public
good; carbon emissions in one country will damage the climate for the rest of
the world. Reducing carbon emissions is the most expensive environmental
challenge the world faces today; the incentive to reduce emissions must be sig-
nificant if all countries are to contribute. EU president Barrosso’s threat to re-
consider a carbon tariff in 2011 was designed, in part, to encourage the United
States and China to implement strict climate policies and to cooperate with
global initiatives.
Trade policy could be a powerful tool in addressing these issues and in creat-
ing an incentive structure that will strengthen the global climate regime. Yet
multilateral initiatives to develop climate-related trade measures are lacking,
and unilateral initiatives to include trade restrictions in national climate poli-
cies have some serious limits. For example, if the measures discussed above had
been implemented, both the European Union’s and the United States’ carbon
tariffs would have been applied uniformly to goods from offending countries.
Efficient and inefficient firms alike in those countries would have been pun-
ished. Such a policy mutes the incentive for individual firms in countries with
low carbon emissions standards to independently follow more efficient pro-
duction practices. Additionally, a recent study argues that restricting trade in
carbon-intensive products between the United States and countries with less
stringent carbon standards would not provide a strong enough incentive to
change the carbon-emitting behavior of firms in the less-regulated countries or
to induce those countries to join a multilateral climate regime.31
Amid concerns about protectionism and skewed incentives to firms in de-
veloping countries resulting from these national-level tariff proposals, the trade
and environment policy communities appear to be headed for a major clash
over climate-related trade measures. Yet this paper’s examination of the history
of the earlier use of multilateral and unilateral trade measures to support envi-
ronmental policy suggests that trade measures could be designed to build upon
the synergies between the two regimes. Climate policy makers who are aware of
the synergies could develop trade-related measures that support climate policy
and are consistent with the concerns of the multilateral trade community.
services are multilateral trade initiatives, born within the trade regime to meet
its objective of freer trade, that will have the side effect of benefiting the envi-
ronment. Trade negotiations aimed at reducing the agricultural subsidies that
exacerbate unsustainable farming practices would also fall into this category.
The elimination of trade-distorting practices is the province of trade negotia-
tors, not environmental advocates. Yet the environmental and scientific policy
communities can indirectly influence negotiations on the elimination of en-
vironmentally harmful trade-distorting practices. They can increase awareness
within the trade community of unsustainable practices that are being subsidized
by WTO members and encourage further research and development efforts to
produce more environmentally sustainable goods and services.
Environmental policy makers can take some trade-related environmental steps
independent from trade negotiators. These steps include creating a multilateral
climate regime that restricts trade in carbon-intensive products. The restriction
of trade based upon production methods is one of the most contentious envi-
ronmental trade policies within the trade regime. Yet the argument is increas-
ingly being accepted within the trade regime that the environmental impact of a
product is an important characteristic for consumers and is therefore relevant to
product standards. WTO Director-General Pascal Lamy has committed WTO
support to the next global climate treaty: The “WTO tool-box of rules can
certainly be leveraged in the fight against climate change, and adapted if govern-
ments perceive this to be necessary to better achieve their goals.”32 Those seek-
ing to strengthen the multilateral environmental regime have the opportunity
to capitalize on these openings within the trade regime and to develop a global
climate agreement that considers process-based international standards.
It is important to underscore that the stakeholders in the trade regime will
be more likely to support those trade-related climate measures that are devel-
oped through a multilateral consensus rather than through ad hoc national cli-
mate policies. The WTO’s objective of predictability and consistency in trade
relations would be bolstered by the multilateral consensus on climate trade
maneuvers. In the absence of an international climate agreement with specific
trade-related obligations, trade-related measures intended to protect the cli-
mate are more controversial. Trade restrictions according to production-based
standards may be acceptable if established within a transparent international
framework, but they will likely be challenged when only part of a particular
state’s national climate policy.
Nevertheless, in the absence of global action, many states do enact trade-re-
lated measures that support national environmental policy, and many of these
measures are not disputed in the multilateral trade DSM. If an environmen-
tal trade measure that flouts certain articles of the GATT is challenged in the
WTO, it will be exempted under Article XX only if the nation can prove that it
is necessary to protect human, plant, or animal life or health, or that it is relat-
ed to the conservation of exhaustible resources. Even a quantitative restriction,
typically anathema to trade advocates, may be legal if it also fulfills the prerequi-
sites that it is nondiscriminatory and cannot be used for protectionist purposes.
For the goals of the climate regime, however, a quantitative restriction may
not be ideal; a system of process-based standards could be more effective in
encouraging individual firms to reduce their carbon emissions. Process-based
standards will face fewer challenges from the trade community if they are devel-
oped transparently and enforced with a system of international efficiency stan-
dards rather than quantitative restrictions or bans applied to specific countries.33
Such a system would allow only the most efficient firms in carbon-intensive
industries to export to the global market, thus encouraging efficient practices.
A quantitative restriction against China, conversely, would limit exports from
even the most efficient Chinese firms in carbon-intensive industries, stifling
their incentive to improve efficiency.
Unilateral, process-based trade sanctions that are intended to leverage coun-
tries to join multilateral climate initiatives may be more effective when the
sanction wielder is engaged with the process of multilateral climate negotia-
tions. The European Union may have the moral standing to enforce unilateral
trade measures to support its national climate policy and shape the post-2012
multilateral climate treaty. The United States may not.
Conclusion
The most effective way to exploit the synergies between the multilateral trade
and climate regimes would be to incorporate a multilateral system of efficiency
standards into the next global climate treaty. Unilateral trade restrictions may
also be warranted to induce cooperation, reduce leakage, and discourage free
riding by countries that do not have a coherent climate policy. But unilateral
trade restrictions must be employed with care. The WTO’s rules will likely al-
low nondiscriminatory trade restrictions designed to reduce emissions leakage
and protect the global climate. But these rules will not condone trade restric-
tions intended to protect domestic industry.
The world’s trade and environment regimes have a rich history of syner-
gies and conflicts; it appears inevitable that climate negotiators will meet the
global trade regime as they pursue policy tools that effectively address the threat
of climate change. Climate policy makers must emphasize the value of trade
mechanisms in controlling emissions leakage—rather than in protecting do-
mestic industry—to abide by the rules of the global trade regime. As climate
negotiators work to harness powerful trade incentives, the adaptability of the
global trade regime will again be tested.
Notes
1 Glen Peters and Edgar G. Hertwich, “CO2 Embodied in International Trade with
Implications for Global Climate Policy,” Environmental Science & Technology, vol. 42,
no. 5 (2008), pp. 1401–1407.
2 Rasmus Reinvang and Glen Peters, “Norwegian Consumption, Chinese Pollution: An
Example of How OECD Imports Generate CO2 Emissions in Developing Countries,”
WWF Norway, http://www.ntnu.no/eksternweb/multimedia/
archive/00030/Norwegian_Consumptio_30439a.pdf.
3 “Russia Backs Kyoto to Get on Path to Join the WTO,” Washington Post, May 22,
2004, http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A46416-2004May21.html.
4 Richard Elliot Benedick, Ozone Diplomacy: New Directions in Safeguarding the Planet
(Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1998), pp. 242–243.
5 United Nations Environment Program, “Trade-Related Measures and Multilateral
Environmental Agreements,” 2007, http://www.unep.ch/etb/areas/pdf/
MEA%20Papers/TradeRelated_MeasuresPaper.pdf.
6 Craig Canine, “California Illuminates the World,” OnEarth, Spring 2006,
http://www.nrdc.org/onearth/06spr/ca1.asp.
7 BRIDGES BioRes, “Climate Change: Schwab Opposes Potential Trade Measures,”
March 7, 2008, http://www.ictsd.org/biores/08-03-07/story3.htm.
8 See the WTO website, http://www.wto.org.
9 Joseph Stiglitz, Making Globalization Work (New York: Penguin Books, 2006).
10 The TBT Agreement is generally considered to allow for product-related standards
based on process and production methods (PPM), provided that the standards meet
other criteria of the two agreements. It is still unclear whether the TBT Agreement
allows for non-product-related PPM standards. See Nathalie Bernasconi-Osterwalder
et al., Environment and Trade: A Guide to WTO Jurisprudence (London: Earthscan
Publications / CIEL, 2006), pp. 214–215.
11 The 1994 Ministerial Decision on Trade and Environment was adopted by trade
ministers at a meeting of the Uruguay Round of trade negotiations on April 14, 1994,
prior to the signing of the Marrakesh Accords.
12 Doaa Abdel Motaal, ed., “The Trade and Environment Policy Formulation Process,”
in Trade and Environment: A Resource Book, ICTSD Southern Agenda on Trade and
Environment, http://www.trade-environment.org/page/southernagenda/RB_1-2.htm.
13 Ibid.
27
32 Pascal Lamy, “Doha Could Deliver a Double-Win for Environment and Trade,”
remarks, Bali, December 9, 2007, http://www.wto.org/english/news_e/sppl_e/
sppl83_e.htm.
33 Jason Potts, “The Legality of PPMs under the GATT: Challenges and Opportunities
for Sustainable Trade Policy,” (Winnipeg: International Institute for Sustainable
Development, 2008), http://www.iisd.org/pdf/2008/ppms_gatt.pdf.
31
Carnegie Papers present new research by Endowment associates and their collaborators from
other institutions. The series includes new time-sensitive research and key excerpts from
larger works in progress. Comments from readers are most welcome; please reply by e-mail
to pubs@CarnegieEndowment.org.
2008
Can Trade Policy Support the Next Global Climate Agreement? Analyzing
the International Trade and Environment Regimes (M. Lay)
The Russian World: Changing Meanings and Strategies (V. Tishkov)
The New Arab Diplomacy: Not With the U.S. and Not Against the U.S. (M. Ottaway)
Party for Justice and Development in Morocco: Participation and its Discontents
(A. Hamzawy)
International Labor Migration in a Globalizing Economy (R. Lucas)
Islam in Uzbekistan: Religious Education and State Ideology (M. B. Olcott, D. Ziyaeva)
Assessing Secretary of State Rice’s Reform of U.S. Foreign Assistance (G. F. Hyman)
The Draft Party Platform of the Egyptian Muslim Brotherhood: Foray Into Political
Integration or Retreat Into Old Positions? (N. J. Brown, A. Hamzawy)
2007
Incumbent Regimes and the “King’s Dilemma” in the Arab World: Promise and
Threat of Managed Reform (M. Ottaway and M. Dunne)
Implementing UN Security Council Resolution 1540: A Division of Labor Strategy
(M. Heupel)
Demilitarizing Algeria (H. Roberts)
Fighting on Two Fronts: Secular Parties in the Arab World (M. Ottaway and A. Hamzawy)
Sufism in Central Asia: A Force for Moderation or a Cause of Politicization? (M. B. Olcott)
China’s Economic Prospects 2006–2020 (J. He, S. Li, and S. Polaski)
A Face of Islam: Muhammad-Sodiq Muhammad-Yusuf (M. B. Olcott)
Requiem for Palestinian Reform: Clear Lessons From a Troubled Record (N. J. Brown)
Evaluating Political Reform in Yemen (S. Phillips)
PushingToward Party Politics? Kuwait’s Islamic Constitutional Movement (N. J. Brown)
Protecting Intellectual Property Rights in Chinese Courts: An Analysis of Recent Patent
Judgments (M. Y. Gechlik)
Roots of Radical Islam in Central Asia (M. B. Olcott)
2006
Illusive Reform: Jordan’s Stubborn Stability (J. Choucair)
Islamist Movements in the Arab World and the 2006 Lebanon War
(A. Hamzawy and D. Bishara)