Chapter 4
Chapter 4
“Competition is always a good thing. It forces us to do our best. A monopoly renders people complacent and
satisfied with mediocrity.” – Nancy Pearcy
4.1 Introduction
It is true that competition breeds champions. It is the vigil of the true capitalist. In nascent
markets, it can even be in your own best interest to collaborate with competitors to grow the
overall market size. As they say, a rising tide lifts all boats. As markets mature, competition
keeps you sharp. According to Schumpeter 1, “It makes sure you never get complacent or you
risk being taken over .Competition in a dynamic setting is subject to the Schumpeterian forces of
creative destruction". This entails an industry that is flexible and can restructure and adapt easily
to changing circumstances. For this to be possible, and for capital and labour to relocate to more
efficient 2 uses more easily, requires much more rapid bankruptcy procedures than those that are
currently in place 3.
Competition laws are a body of rules that seek to promote competition in the market and prohibit
practices that negatively impact competition, economic efficiency and consumer welfare.
According to Fox, competition law regulates business practices and transactions that create or
abuse market power and interfere with the free play of market forces 4. Rodger and MacCulloh
point out that competition law concerns intervention in the market place when there is some
problem with the competition process and/or when there is market failure. 5In Haridas Exports 6,
1
Schumpeter J.A., Capitalism, socialism and democracy, Harper & Brothers,1942
2
Competition policy and liberal trade policy seek to achieve the same objective namely economic efficiency.
3
Report of High Level Committee on Competition Policy and Law ,para 2.9.2
4
Fox, Eleanor M, Competition Law International Economic Law, Oxford University Press, 2002 pp. 340-383
5
Rodger, Barry and Angus MacCulloh, Competition Law in the EC and UK, Cavendish Publishing, London ,(2004).
6
Haridas Exports v. All India Float Glass Manufacturers Association AIR 2002 SC 2728
106
the Supreme Court observed that “Competition law is concerned with the regulation of
Modern competition law can be seen as a fundamental rulebook which is aimed as far as possible
to allow markets to function properly. So Schere and Ross opines that “it is designed to prohibit
abuses of market power, whether by an individual firm or by a group of firms acting collectively
competition law lies in the suggestion that competition produces social benefits which get
vanished through monopoly and that legal controls can reduce, or eliminate the damage done.
Agreeing to it Agnew holds that “the welfare of a society, which establishes an effective form of
regulation, will, thereby, improve” 8. In India, Competition in its earlier form was inspired by the
MRTP Act, 1969 , gave effect to the expression ‘socialist’ used in the preamble and Articles 38
and39 of the Constitution of India. Concise Oxford Dictionary defines ‘socialism’ as “a political
and economic theory of a social organisation which advocates that the means of production,
distribution and exchange should be owned or regulated by the community as whole”. The
Supreme Court in D.S Nakara v. Union of India 9 observed that the principal object of socialist
states is to wipe out the inequality in economic conditions, status and standard of life. In a
democratic welfare economy, the role of the state is never over looked. In Samatha v. State of
Andhra Pradesh 10the Supreme Court observed that “the word Socialist used in the Preamble
must be read from the goals, Article 14,15,16,17,21,23,38,39,46 and all other cognate Articles
7
Scherer and Ross, (1990), “Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance” quoted in Anant, TC:
“Competition Advocacy”, Presentation at the Competition Advocacy Seminar for Professional Bodies, 2nd March
2005 available at http://competition-commission-india.nic.in last visited on January 3 2018
8
Agnew, J.H,Competition Law, Allen and Unwin, London, 1985 at p. 1
9
AIR 1983 SC 183
10
AIR 1997 SC 3297
107
sought to establish, i.e. to reduce inequalities in income and status and to provide equality of
The father of economics Adam Smith in his famous book “An Inquiry into the Nature and
Causes of the Wealth of Nations” emphasizes that self-interest is the driving force behind
economic activity. Though, self-interest per se has negative connotations, these forces are
balanced by the competitive forces arising out of the market. Therefore, while self-interest is the
motivator behind economic activity, competition is the de-facto driver of the economy. These
forces of self-interest and competition are defined by Adam Smith as the invisible hands which
guide the resources towards their most efficient use. When India adopted the new economic
order in the early 1990s, it empowered the invisible hands of the market and ensured economic
Competition law has always been recognised world over by most as essential instrument in
curbing market distortions, containing anticompetitive practices, preventing monopoly and abuse
of monopoly, inducing optimum allocation of resources and being beneficial to consumers with
Competition law thus seeks inter alia, to promote and maintain competition in the market and
protect the interests of consumers. In Australian Competition and Consumer Commission v. ABB
proscribing the misuse of monopoly or oligopoly power, and by making unlawful conduct such
as market rigging, collusive tendering, price-fixing and other acts that inhibit the minimization
11
“Review of Legislation/Policies: A Competition Perspective”,Fair Play Volume 19 : October-December 2016
(the quarterly newsletter of Competition Commission of India)
12
[2002] FCA 3
108
of production costs and the efficient allocation of resources. That is to say, antitrust law is
founded on the underlying premise that free competition is essential for the welfare of the State”.
In NT Power Generation v. Power & Water Authority 13, it was observed that
“Antitrust laws serve a variety of aims, such as the efficient use of resources,
the development of cheaper production methods and improved products, stability in output and
employment and an equitable distribution of income. So, antitrust legislation strikes down
collusive agreements that restrict competition, as well as unilateral conduct that affects
The objectives of Competition Law across jurisdiction are to maintain and encourage the process
of competition in order to promote efficient use of resources while protecting the freedom of
various players in the market. The intention of competition Law is neither to restrict nor to
constraint anything that may be detrimental to the growth of the economy. It keeps the goal very
clear, avoiding market domination by a few players through various modes as cartelization, price
By 1990 only sixteen developing nations around the world had enacted Competition Law. In
1990s, the drafting and adoption of Competition legislation in another 50 countries was under
taken by United Nations Conference on Trade and Development 15. Currently, over 100
countries worldwide have competition laws, with more than half of them in the category of
developing countries. The mere adoption of the Competition Law has to be essentially preceded
13
[2002] FCAFC 302
14
OECD, The objective of Competition Policy, www.oecd.org/daf/competition/2486329.pdf, last visited on march
15, 2018
15
UNTAD had helped may other countries with process for enacting Competition Law.
109
as well as succeeded by other conditions 16 to be part of market reform. Competition Laws have
acquired much importance today with growing globalisation and the opening of markets across
the globe. The United States Supreme Court observed in United States v. Topco Associates Inc17
that
“Antitrust laws in general, and the Sherman Act in particular, are the
Magna Carta of free enterprise. They are as important to the preservation of economic freedom
and our free-enterprise system as the Bill of Rights is to the protection of our fundamental
personal freedoms. And the freedom guaranteed each and every business, no matter how small,
is the freedom to compete to assert with vigour, imagination, devotion, and ingenuity whatever
The importance of having a sound competition policy and law has been realised around the
world and about one hundred countries have competition legislations. Competition Law appears
to be one of those fields of law the purpose of which is not self-explanatory.one may study the
structure of the competition Act in relation to its stated objectives. This will cover major
provisions dealing with antitrust issues, viz. regulation of anti-competitive agreements, abuse of
a dominant position and a combination falling under the Act. A well formulated and efficacious
competition law is likely to promote the creation of an enabling business environment, which
enhances static and dynamic efficiency, and leads to optimum resource allocation in which the
abuse of market power is discouraged by fair competition. In addition, competition law prevents
artificial entry barriers, facilitates market access and provides level playing field.
16
Many such conditions are missing in the developing countries. E.g financial human technical resources are always
scarce.
17
405 US 593 (1972)
18
http: //caselaw.lp.findlaw.com/scripts/getcase.pl?navby=case&court=us&vol=405+&page=596, see also
Vishwanathan, T(2005) : “Presentation on “Competition Law”, http://www.competition-commission-india.nic.in,
last visited on March 18,2018.
110
It also aims at promoting competition as a means of market response and consumer preference so
as to ensure effective and efficient allocation of resources and to create an incentive for the
The history of the Competition Act, 2002 is a good example of the proverb that the road to hell is
paved with good intentions. True, the Act was late compared to the legislation of many countries,
but it was unexceptionable in terms of the key issues it was intended to deal with. A modern,
statutory competition regime emerged in India only after the globalization 20liberalization and
privatization era in early 90’s. This paradigm shift in the Indian economy and changing scenario
of world trade lead to formation of Raghavan 21 committee, which ultimately laid down clear path
Its aim was to preserve fair competition in the market, principally through control of anti-
competitive acts, agreements, abuse of dominant position, and mergers that would hinder or
eliminate competition in a particular market. It was introduced at a time when large multinational
here. The Act received the assent of the President of India on 13 January 2003. The first set of
provisions of the Act were notified on March 31,2003, while others were notified subsequently
.Most of the sections were brought into force through notifications in the gazette , but key
19
UNTAD Secretariat, “objectives of Competition Law and Policy: Toward a Coherent Strategy for Promoting
Competition and Development” available at http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/fias.nsf/attachments by title.
20
The world economy has been experiencing a progressive international economic integration for the last half a
century. There has been a marked acceleration in this process of globalisation and also liberalisation during the last
three decades. Para3.1.1,Report of High Level Committee on Competition Policy and Law
21
Supra note 79,
111
position (section 4), combination (section 5) and regulation of combination (section 6) were
not 22.,On May 20,2009, the working provisions, that is, provisions relating to anti-competitive
The preamble of the Competition Act ,2002 states “an Act to provide, keeping in view of the
economic development of the country for the establishment of a commission to prevent practices
having adverse effect on competition , to promote and sustain competition in markets, to protect
the interest of consumers and to ensure freedom of trade carried on by other participants in
markets, in India and for matters connected therewith or incidental thereto”. The preamble
reveals that Competition Act was enacted keeping in view the economic development that
resulted in removal of controls and consequent economic liberalization which required the Indian
economy be enabled to allow competition in the market from within the country and
outside 23.The Competition Act deals with the three broad substantive issues ;
1. Anti-competitive agreements
The Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act 24, 1969 (MRTP Act), was the first
enactment in India to deal with competition among private commercial enterprises and was a
22
Ramappa. T, Competition Law in India- Policy ,Issues and Development, oxford University press, 2nd edition
23
Statements of objects and Reasons accompanying the Competition (Amendment) Bill, 2007.
24
The MRTP Act was a product of another era. It covered three categories of competition matters, superficially
corresponding to those described above, but dealt with them in ways that departed from standard antitrust treatment.
Chapter III, on concentration of economic power, originally applied to firms that were either large (those whose
assets together with those of their ‘interconnected undertakings’ exceeded Rs 20 crore), or ‘dominant’ (whose assets
exceeded Rs one crore and whose share of the market exceeded one-third, later reduced to one-fourth in 1982). All
such ‘MRTP companies’ were required to register themselves and thereafter obtain government permission for
mergers, amalgamations and takeovers—but also for establishment of new undertakings and substantial expansion
of old ones, thus reinforcing the then-prevailing system of industrial licensing. Chapter IV, on monopolistic trade
practices (MTPs), originally applied to ‘monopolistic’ undertakings that were either dominant (as defined above) or
commanded half or more of the market along with not more than two other independent undertakings. An inquiry
112
precursor to the Competition Act,2002. The object behind passing of MRTP Act was the
resources to sub serve the common good. The MRTP Act had in its large portions been taken
from Restrictive Trade Practices Act of United Kingdom. This Act did remain in action until the
Competition Act was brought in operation in 2007,as in the changed economic dynamics the
MRTP Act 25 was found deficient to deal with the challenges put forth in the market by global
economic circumstances. One of the major reasons for failure of the MRTP Act was its inability
to do justice with its basic principle because of the regular shifts in governmental industrial
policy
The statement of object associated with Competition Bill had identified the Monopolies and
Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1969 had become obsolete in certain respects in the light of
international economic developments relating more particularly to competition laws and there
was a need to shift the focus from curbing monopolies to promoting competition 26.Thus , in
1999, a committee 27 was constituted to recommend an up to date competition Law, which was in
consonance with the international developments in this regard and also catered to the Indian
needs. This committee suggested the government to make a separate Competition Act to deal
with laws on this issue, to create an authority on competition, i.e., the competition commission of
could be ordered if it appeared that a monopolistic undertaking was ‘unreasonably’ limiting competition or technical
development, which would today be called abuse of dominance—but also if it appeared to be ‘unreasonably’
maintaining or increasing prices and limiting investment, which are usually not antitrust concerns. The government
was armed with the authority to prohibit MTPs, if necessary by regulating prices, production, distribution, and
quality. It could refer Chapter III applications or complaints about MTPs to the MRTP Commission, but did not
have to accept its opinion.
25
Para 7.1.9 Raghavan committee Report-A perusal of the MRTP Act will show that there is no definition nor even a
mention of certain offending trade practices which are restrictive in character. Some illustrations of these are:
- Abuse of Dominance
- Cartels, Collusion and Price Fixing
- Bid Rigging
- Boycotts and Refusal to Deal
- Predatory pricing
26
Statements of objects and Reasons accompanying the Competition Bill,2001.
27
Supra note 79.
113
India, and also to repeal the MRTP Act and wind up MRTP commission. It further pushed for
reforms to be made in state’s policies, to stabilize the base over which the new competition law
The Competition Act was finally passed in the year 2002 by the parliament to take over the reins
of competition among private commercial enterprises in India. The Competition Act is highly
inspired by the relevant provisions in the European Union and the United States 29. The
Competition Act,2002 was enacted to make India ready to face competition both from within the
country and from the international market as well. The Competition Act ,2002 is supposed to
replace the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1969(MRTP Act). The cases
pending before the MRTP commission had been transferred to the Competition Commission of
India ,CCI 30.Section 66 of the new Act, “provided for the repeal of the MRTP Act, the
dissolution of the MRTP Commission, and the disposal of pending cases. UTP cases and
investigations (other than those involving ‘false or misleading facts disparaging the goods,
constituted under the COPRA, to be decided in accordance with the latter Act”. The remainder
were to be transferred to the Competition Commission of India (CCI), a new body to be set up
under the Competition Act, but would be decided under the MRTP Act 31.Though the
Competition Act ,2002 is successor to the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act , the
scope of both the Acts are completely different. The change in economic policies reflects change
in legal regime. After 1990’s onward India changed her economy from protection, insulation and
regulation to free market economy. This change finds reflection in the objectives of the MRTP
28
Dhall vinod, “Competition Law in India”, 21 ANTITRUST 72,73-78(2006-2007)
29
VahiniVersha, Indian Competition Law, Lexis Nexis, 1st edition ,2016.
30
Singh Avtar, Competition Law ,Eastern Book Company ,1st edition, 2012
31
Bhattacharjea Aaditya , “ Of Omissions and Commissions: India’s Competition Laws”, Economic and Political
Weekly, xlv( 35), 28 august 2010
114
Act and Competition Act, 2002. When, after economic liberalization, the control of market
economy shifted from government and shopkeepers to national and transnational corporations, it
became necessary to regulate competition, lest the big fish may devour the small, resulting in
stifling the competition at the cost of the consumer. In the changed context, the Competition Act
was passed in 2002, but the Competition Commission of India began its functioning in 2009 32.
The objectives of the Competition Law were highlighted by the Supreme Court in its decision in
Competition Commission of India v SAIL 33as “the rationale of free market economy is that
competitive offers of different suppliers allow the buyers to make the best purchase. The
motivation of each participant in a free economy is to maximise self-interest, but the result is
favourable to the society”. The court cited Adam Smith as saying, “there is an invisible hand at
work to take care of this”. The main aim of the Competition Law is using competition, to
promote economic efficiency as one of the means of assisting the creation of market responsive
2) Productive efficiency, which ensures that the cost of production are kept at a minimum;
and
These factors by and large have been accepted all over the world as the guiding principles of
In fact, Correa opines that “competition is not essentially unsuited with and, on the contrary, can
32
Dixit Vinod, “Competition Law”, Annual Survey of Indian Law,2011
33
(2010) 10 SCC 744
34
They are globally accepted principles.
115
powerful incentive to introduce product, process or organizational innovations, even noted by the
Federal Trade Commission” 35.“Competition can stimulate innovation. Competition among firms
can spur the invention of new or better products or more efficient processes. Firms may race to
be the first to market an innovation technology, companies may invent lower cost manufacturing
processes, thereby increasing their profits and enhancing their ability to compete. Competition
can prompt firm to identify consumers’ unmet needs and develop new products or services to
Unfortunately, the Competition Act does not contain the definition of the term ‘competition’,
referred and used differently in different contexts. The new Competition Act states that, “it shall
be the duty of the commission to eliminate practices having adverse effect on competition, to
promote and sustain competition, protect the interest of consumers and ensure freedom of trade
carried on by other participants, in markets in India” 37.In exercise of power conferred upon it
under the Act, the central government established the CCI having its head office at New Delhi
with effect from October 14, 2003. In accordance with the discussion on the subject , the Act had
• 1st phase – In the first year Competition advocacy and training for officers and staff of
35
Correa ,C. (2007). “Intellectual property and Competition Law :Exploring Some Issues of Relevance to
Developing Countries”, ICTSD IPRs and Sustainable Development Programme Issue Paper No.21,International
Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development, Geneva, Switzerland, available at www.ictsd.org, Last visited on
15th June 2017
36
FTC-United States, 20003a, p.1-2
37
Preamble The Competition Act,2002
38
Para 8.1.1,Raghavan committee Report
116
• 2nd phase – In the second year provisions 39 relating to anti-competitive practices and
• 3rd phase- In the third year provisions 40 relating to combination to be brought into action
There were two fundamental views emerging from the Raghavan committee report for
implementation of competition law in India. One view in the Committee contended that by
enacting the Bill at this stage i.e. referring to the economic political scenario of 1990s, India’s
bargaining power at WTO negotiations would be negatively affected. So it was suggested that
the enactment of the Bill should be withheld till January 1, 2005 by which time decisions on
issues like competition policy, trade and investment and related matters would be taken.
Therefore, it was suggested that there was no rush in passing the Bill and that the MRTP Act
could be appositely amended to meet the need of the present time. The second view preferred the
passage of the Bill. It was of the view that the MRTP Act was based on old economic theory
with different object, which was no longer efficacious enough to check the assault of foreign
companies against domestic companies. This shift would be of great assistance to the Indian
economy to adapt to the changing environment as well as result in affluence and employment 41.
If we look at the major antitrust regimes like United States the conflicting view do appeared
there also in terms of whether to follow Harvard approach or that of Chicago approach. But at
the end ,Chicago school of thought was followed with some influences of Harvard school,
39
It came into force in 2009,around six years later. The delay is attributed to the judicial challenges to the power of
the Chairman of CCI.
40
It came into force in 2011.
41
Raghavan committee report, para7.2.2 It has been noted earlier that a large number of anti-competition practices
that may accompany trade practices, during the implementation of the WTO agreements will have to be drafted and
incorporated in the Competition Law. Amendment of the MRTP Act, in the context of the requirements outlined
above, may, therefore will have to be very extensive, tantamounting to enacting a new Law. On balance, it appears
eminently desirable to enact a new Competition Law without tinkering with the existing MRTP Act. Furthermore, as
would be seen in the next section of this chapter, the entire provisions relating to unfair trade practices will have to
be taken out of the MRTP Act as they figure in the Consumer Protection Act, 1986. Mergers, Amalgamations etc.
will have to be brought within the contours of Competition Law afresh. For all these reasons, a new law is warranted
117
antitrust law in United States are broadly based on a consumer welfare standard that is concerned
with allocative efficiency and per se prohibition on market practices are to be avoided. While in
the European Union competition law, the object is to integrate the market and protection of
competition. The market integration of the economies had its own political reasons than
economic ones. The protection of competition in the EU market does revolve around
‘dominance’ concept. The abuse of ‘dominant position’ is violation of competition Law as this
conduct injures consumers and competitors. EU Competition law approaches the competition
understandings, and concerted practices among firms that purport to restrict competition;
The Competition Act, 20002, sets for multiple goals instead for focusing on one . Given the state
of economic scenario the nation was subjected to it would not have been wise to blindly follow
the regime of developed counties as they were in the different zone of development.
The preamble of the Act broadly recognises the four core focal engagements;
• Consumer welfare
118
A bare understanding of these focal points which are now well recognised as goals of the 2002
Act gives clear indication that the Competition Act is pursuing to achieve economic as well as
social goals. According to Payal “the Preamble of the Act provides an institutional context to the
CCI. It states: An Act to provide, keeping in view of the economic development of the country.
This is a rather unique and unambiguous endorsement of the link between the micro functioning
of individual markets and the larger development imperatives of the country. This is also to
affirm that competition is not an end in itself, but a means to achieve greater economic
goals” 42.The Competition Act of 2002, which was amended in 2007 and 2009,deals with anti-
trust issues, viz. regulation of anti-competitive agreements, abuse of dominant position and a
The objective of ‘ensuring freedom of trade carried on by other participants in the market’ has
the social and political implications in addition to economic considerations. Freedom of trade of
other participants upholds the advanced political value of ‘freedom for all’ and social goal of
protection of small and medium enterprises. This objective will also aid in promoting and
sustaining competition. The most imperative social goal is the protection of consumers i.e.
consumer welfare. That’s the reason why it was required to have competition policy to
promote efficiencies among the domestic industry along with consumer welfare. It is important
here to understand ‘consumer welfare’, though different jurisdictions do take different approach
42
Payal Malik, “Competition Law in India: Developing Efficient Markets for Greater Good”, Vikalpa ,The Journal
for Decision Makers , volume 41 , issue 2 , april-june 2016,page 176, available at .
http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/pdf/10.1177/0256090916647222, last assessed on 15th June 2017
119
While clarifying the consumer welfare stance, Hovenkamp opines that “the consumer welfare
test is not a balancing test, in the sense that one must attempt to measure efficiency gains and
losses and net them out. Under the test, if consumers are harmed (either by reduced output or
product quality, or by higher prices resulting from the exercise of market power), then this fact
trumps any offsetting gains to producers and, presumably, to others. Theoretically, even a minor
injury to consumers outweighs significant efficiency gains. In this sense the consumer welfare
test can be easier to administer on a case by case basis than general welfare tests. Even the
consumer welfare test can be difficult to administer, however, when a practice impacts different
groups of consumers differently. Practices that involve price discrimination, such as variable
proportion ties or patent field of use restrictions, typically have this result” 43.
Antitrust in all jurisdictions is seen as a public policy aimed at fostering a public good, that is,
narrow concept of competition may induce interventions that are not in line with the ultimate
intended goal of the law. Researcher believes that consumer as central focus has been explicitly
recognized the for enforcement under the preamble of the Competition law, additionally also
identifies economic development through the consumer welfare prospective. Thus, when
consumer welfare is seen in relation with realizing the goal of economic development, static
allocative efficiency i.e., consumer welfare, in certain cases, may have to be sacrificed for
dynamic efficiency. The Preamble of the Competition law allows for a broader interpretation of
efficiency, incorporating both static and dynamic ,as the inconsistency between allocative
efficiency and dynamic efficiency is well established. Therefore, the tone and tenor is sets by the
120
The Preamble along with the body of the statute in India and the antitrust law worldwide
generally puts great stress on the economic aspect of the instrumentality of the law. Agreeing to
the above statement , Baker and Bresnahan holds that, “an emphasis on economic goals
inevitably brings economics to bear, where antitrust issues are framed in terms of economic
concepts such as market power, competitive effects, entry, and efficiencies, and to interpret the
detailed facts involving a particular industry and specific challenged practices through
application of the logical framework provided by economic theory. This approach requires a
rigorous analysis about the effects of the challenged conduct on competition: identifying the
market or markets in which competition has or will likely be harmed and the mechanism by
The understanding that competition law should wish to encourage some form of economic
welfare which is innately connected to the influence of economics and in particular welfare
economics, consumer welfare , competitors protection and related fields in competition law
analysis .At the same time also keenly looking into specific step with respect to improving
Recently in Indian competition scenario, In shri Shamsher Kataria v.HondaSiel 45, the
“The role of antitrust can best be understood in terms of a fundamental standard ‘the
standard of consumer choice’. The antitrust laws are intended to ensure that the market
place remains competitive so that worthwhile options are produced and made available to
44
Baker, J. B., and Bresnahan, T. “Economic evidence in antitrust: Defining markets and measuring market power”
(Stanford Law and Economics Olin Working Paper No. 328). (2006, September) Accessed on 10 January, 2018
from http://ssrn.com/abstract=931225 or http:// dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.931225
45
2014 Comp LR 001(CCI) ; the Commission acknowledged the words of Professor Robert H.Lande while writing
the order in this case.
121
consumers, and this range of options is not to be significantly impaired or distorted by
anti-competitive practices. How many options must be present in the market for consumer
choice to be optimized? Antitrust certainty does not require that the number of options be
maximized. Nor does antitrust prevent all conduct or transactions that have the effect of
reducing the number of options available to consumers. Nor does the law affirmatively
require the creation of options. Rather , it prevents business conduct that artificially limits
Keeping pace with these goals, it is significant for developing country like India to have
competition policy that gives further impetus to the foreign investment in addition to engaging
In the preceding pages the researcher is trying to bring in under lying goals for the enforcement
An institutional framework is recognized for CCI under the Preamble of the Act. It states: “An
Act to provide, keeping in view of the economic development of the country”. This is a rather
distinctive and explicit endorsement of the relation between the micro functioning of individual
markets and the larger economic development requirements of the country. This narrative is also
to affirm that competition is not an end in itself, but a means to achieve greater economic
goals.so that there can be a clear distinction between the ends and the means while dealing the
The obligation of the commission, as explicit in the Preamble of the Competition Act, is
122
(b) To promote and sustain competition in markets,
All though the above four objectives are quite different but these objectives are to be understood
in harmony. These objectives and goals bring clarity only when these distinct objectives are seen
as fraction of a whole. While comparing to many other antitrust jurisdictions world over,
maintenance of the market processes and rights to engage in commerce are accorded a priority in
the Indian Competition Act as well. These are seen as equivalent to striking down or preventing
unreasonable restraints on competition and at the same time keeping focus on freedom to trade
,freedom of choice, and access to markets. Preamble of the law has explicitly endorsed the
consumer as significant for enforcement, but at the same time has also set the consumer welfare
standard in the context of economic development. It is even clearly incorporated under section
The duty on the Commission to eradicate practices having adverse effect on competition,
promote and sustain competition, protect the interests of consumers and ensure freedom of trade
carried on by other participants, in markets in India while Subjecting to the provisions of the
Competition Act
As a result, preamble read with section 18, when seen in conjunction with achieving the goal of
economic development, static allocative efficiency (consumer welfare), in certain cases, may
have to give way for dynamic efficiency. So allocative efficiency and dynamic efficiency do put
forth inconsistent situations, the Preamble of the law allows for a broader interpretation of
123
efficiency, including both static and dynamic. Hence, the Preamble arrays the tone and tenor of
The view that competition law should aim to promote some form of economic welfare is
intrinsically linked to the influence of economics and in particular welfare economics, consumer
theory and related fields in competition law analysis 46.so it is imperative to strike balance
between the dynamic and allocative efficiency. The Act thus endeavors to balance the two
Before getting into these areas on competition law it’s important to understand the territorial
The territorial scope of the Competition Act as per section 1 (2) extends to whole of India except
the state of Jammu and Kashmir. However, the impact of the statement gets limited in view of
the Act recognising the ‘effect’ doctrine. As per the doctrine, the effect of the actions or
behaviour would determine whether the action or behaviour is anti-competitive and comes within
the mischief of the Act. The Act gives clear power to the Competition Commission of India to
46
Lianos, I. “Some reflections on the question of thegoals of EU Competition Law” (CLES Working Paper Series
3/2013). Available at from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2235875,
visited on 7 February 2017
124
exercise jurisdiction over foreign entities if the effect of their anti-competitive behaviour is felt in
Indian territory. The ‘effects doctrine’ laid down by US courts in the United States v. Aluminium
Corporation of America 47decision permits courts to exercise jurisdiction over entities outside
their territorial jurisdiction if the anti-competitive conduct of such entities has an impact within
their territorial jurisdiction. The effects doctrine was given statutory recognition in the US in
1994 by the International Antitrust Enforcement Assistance Act 48. Similarly, the United
Kingdom enacted the Protection of Trading Interests Act, 1980 49 which recognises this concept,
This doctrine is applied in many countries to address anti-competitive activities of foreign firms
that adversely affect competition within their markets. In India under the MRTP Act , the effect
doctrine was considered by supreme court in Haridas Exports v. All India Float Glass
Manufacturers Association 50, which involved case of imports from foreign cartels. The court
while reflecting on section 37 51 of the Act, the court held that “ any act which falls under the
47
148F 2d416(2nd Circuit) ;also known as Alcoa case
48
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/internat.htm
49
http://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/1980/11/contents
50
AIR 2002 SC 2728
51
section37. Investigation into restrictive trade practices by Commission
(1) The Commission may inquire into any restrictive trade practice, whether the agreement, if any, relating thereto
has been registered under section 35 or not, which may come before it for inquiry it is of opinion that the practice is
prejudicial to the public interest, the Commission may, by order, direct that,-
(b) the agreement relating thereto shall be void in respect of such restrictive trade practice or shall stand modified in
respect thereof in such manner as may be specified in the order.
(2) The Commission may, instead of making any order under this section, permit the party to any restrictive trade
practice, if he so applies, to take such steps within the time specified in this behalf by the Commission as may be
125
category of restrictive trade practices can be investigated into and orders passed under section
37(1). It further noted that Sections.2(o) and 2(u) do not specifically indicate that the practice
should be carried on by a person or persons in India, and if the trade practice is such that it be
becomes a restrictive trade practice in India as contemplated by section 2(o), then action can be
Unlike Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act,1969 ,the Competition Act 2002
specifically incorporates the ‘effect’ doctrine under section 32. Section 32 is founded on what is
ordinarily known as the “effects doctrine”, which permits regulators to extend jurisdiction
beyond the “principle of territoriality”. In most countries, the legal view which is endorsed is that
the domestic competition law captures such acts even if the guilty enterprise is not located within
the territory of country, provided that the anti-competitive act has an effect on market of the
said country. The 2002 Act thus does not necessitate that the practice/ agreement take place
within the territory of India and confers the power to inquire and pass appropriate orders even if
any of the parties is outside India, provided the agreement has or may have an ‘appreciable
necessary to ensure that the trade practice is no longer prejudicial to the public interest, and, in any such case, if the
Commission is satisfied that the necessary steps have been taken within the time specified, it may decide not to
make any order under this section in respect of the trade practice.
(a) any agreement between buyers relating to goods which are bought by the buyers for consumption and not for
ultimate resale whether in the same or different form, type or specie or as constituent of some other goods;
(b) a trade practice which is expressly authorized by any law for the time being in force.
(4) Notwithstanding anything contained in this Act, if the Commission, during the course of an inquiry under sub-
section (1), finds that 48[the owner of any undertaking is indulging in monopolistic trade practices], it may, after
passing such orders under sub-section (1) or sub-section (2) with respect to the restrictive trade practices as it may
consider necessary, submit the case along with its findings thereon to the Central Government 49[* * *] for such
action as that Government may take under section 31.
126
adverse effect’ on competition in the relevant market in India 52.Therefore, CCI now has power to
take action against a foreign entity in a similar situation as that of under Haridas Export case.
This power has been coupled along with the power to conduct enquiry as well the procedure for
investigation under Sections 19, 20, 26, 29 and 30 of the Act, which lays down the power as well
as the procedure to be followed by the CCI in its inquiry into any alleged anticompetitive
merger or amalgamation, and inquire into whether such an agreement/combination has caused or
is likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition in India. Keeping in mind the
shortcomings of extra territorial jurisdiction and the hiccups involved in the enforcements of
private international law, Section 18 of the Act also empowers the CCI to enter into any
memorandum or arrangement with the prior approval of the Central Government, with any
agency of any foreign country in order to discharge its duty under the provision of the Act 53.
The increasing globalisation of business activity along with the close to universal acceptance of
the “effects doctrine” has led to the increasing of the scope of national competition laws to cross-
border business activities. The principles of extra-territorial jurisdiction can be split in two parts,
firstly subject matter jurisdiction and secondly enforcement jurisdiction. For the purpose of
subject matter jurisdiction, the territorial and nationality principles are sufficient to undertake a
great number of infringements of competition laws. Whereas, for giving true effect to the
agreements, it would be difficult to give due effect to the provisions of the Act. Thus, as per the
52
Supra note 195.
53
Maheshwari Kartik and Reis Simone, “Extraterritorial Application of the Competition Act and Its Impact”,
Competition Law Reports , vol.1,January 2012, page 146
127
requirement, the CCI must undertake efforts to enter into bilateral or multi-lateral agreements
For example, the proposed merger of Boeing and McDonnell Douglas 54 was approved by the US
antitrust authorities but then precluded by the European Commission. European Union
regulators said they are awaiting new "remedies" from Boeing Co. after competition experts
from the 15 EU nations unanimously agreed that the U.S. plane maker's $14 billion merger with
McDonnell Douglas Corporation should be blocked 55. This stand-offended only after months of
forceful political negotiations and potential threats of a United States–Europe trade war, since the
EC wanted to guard the interests of Airbus whereas the United States was insistent for the
authorities to increasingly co-operate with each other to ensure a free and fair market. The US &
EU competition authorities after years of acrimony are now increasingly moving towards
entering into a number of bilateral as well as multi-lateral cooperation agreements such as the
Agreement between the Government of the United States of America and the European
Competition Laws in 1991 56. "This historic agreement between the United States and the
markets can best be achieved by international cooperation in the enforcement of our respective
54
The Boeing-Mcdonnell Douglas merger. The consolidation of the aerospace industry reached a climax on
December 15, 1996 when Boeing CEO Phil Condit and Mcdonnell Douglas CEO Harry Stone cipher announced the
two aerospace giants would merge in a $13.3 billion stock-for-stock transaction. Available at
www1.american.edu/ted/hpages/aero/BAMD.HTM
55
see generally, https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB868213225416324500, last visited on January 20,2018.
56
23 September 1991 Agreement between the Government of the United States of America and the European
Communities Regarding the Application of Their Competition Laws, and the exchange of interpretative letters dated
31 May and 31 July 1995 in relation to that Agreement is well accepted and followed by US and EU. The
agreements are available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/agreement-between-united-states-and-european-
communities-application-positive-comity-principles , last visited on March 20 ,2018.
128
competition laws,” 57 , clearly bringing in and confirming doctrine of “positive comity”
.Principles in the Enforcement of their Competition Laws in 1998, the Agreement on Mutual
Legal Assistance between the European Union and the United States of America in 2003 are also
i. Agreements
Generally a mutual understanding between two or more persons indicates the existence of an
agreement. Blacks Law Dictionary defines agreement as “A mutual understanding between two
or more persons about their relative rights and duties regarding past or future performances, a
manifestation of mutual consent by two or more persons”. The Iyers Law Lexicon, explains
agreement is the “Coming together of parties, in opinion or in final determination, the union of
two or more minds in a thing done or to be done, a mutual assent to do a thing”. It has also been
defined by Osborn as “The concurrence of two or more persons in affecting or altering their
The agreement does not call for a formal contract to be formed under the Competition Act. The
‘Agreement’ is defined and interpreted in a inclusive manner to include not only expressly
written and formally entered into agreements but also wide range of implied , informal and
unwritten agreements, which may include any arrangement or understanding or action in concert.
So any arrangement between the undertakings may be held to be anti-competitive. The term
57
Press release of 4th june,1998 Federal Trade Commission Chairman Robert Pitofsky., available at
https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/1998/06/united-states-and-european-communities-sign-agreement-
positive,last visited on January 2,2018.
58
Osborn’s Concise Law Dictionary 8th Ed. P. 26
129
‘agreement’ also includes what is called a gentleman’s promise and can be held to be anti-
competitive if its purpose is to retard competition. The intention of the parties to such an
agreement regarding its enforceability is irrelevant. Even if the parties do not intend their
In the case of Bayer AG v Commission 60 at European Union , the meaning of agreement was
“Centers around the existence of a concurrence of wills between at least two parties, the
form in which it is manifested being unimportant so long as it constitutes the faithful expression
of the parties intention 61”. Gentleman’s agreements 62 and simple understandings have been held
concurrence of will between the parties constitutes an agreement within the meaning of Article
101 (1) 63. Connected agreements may be treated as a whole contract. An agreement may be
informal or oral too. There may be ‘inchoate’ understandings and conditional or partial
agreement during bargaining process sufficient to amount to an agreement. This is the clear
understanding followed in the sense of Article 101(1) TFEU 64.The concept of agreement
revolves around the existence of a concurrence of wills between at least two parties, the form in
59
Supra note 188.
60
Case T-41/96[2000] ECR II-3383
61
Id, para 69.
62
Case C-110/10 P, European Court Reports2011 I-10439
63
Whish Richard and Bailey David, Competition Law ,Oxford University press,2012
6464
Treaty on Functioning of European Union.
130
which it is manifested is unimportant so long as it constitutes the faithful expression of the
In the Indian context, the definition of ‘agreement’ in the Competition Act is an inclusive
definition that not only includes written agreements having force of law but also covers any
‘arrangement’, ‘understanding’ or ‘action in concert’ between the parties. These terms enlarge
the scope of the word ‘agreement’ used under the Act. The definition under Section 2 (b) of the
legal proceedings”;
This definition is giving way to much wider connotation to the word “agreement” than what is
generally assumed under the Indian contract Act, 1872 66 . That is precisely the reason why
legislators have refrained from using the term “contract” under the Competition Act .the
definition is even wider than that of MRTP Act, 1969, which demonstrated streaks of section
In Re, Aluminum Phosphate Tablets Manufacturers 68, the Competition Commission observed
that the provisions of Section 2(b) do not restrict agreement to mean a written form of agreement
65
The formal requirement of agreement is not looked for.
66
Section 2(e) and Section 2(h) of the Act.
67
RTP Act,1976 of the United Kingdom
68
2012 Comp LR 753 (CCI)
131
not formal or in writing. Thus covering all the dealings which manifest common intention of the
Some agreement among enterprises has the potential of curbing competition. These agreements
include a group of firms act together as a single firm; it can damage the market by thwarting
competition. In CCI V Co-ordination Committee of Artists and Technicians of W.B. Film and
Television 69 Justice Sikri held “The 'agreement' or 'concerted practice' is the means through
competition. These concepts translate the objective of Competition Law to have economic
frowning upon the activities of those undertakings (whether natural persons or legal entities)
who, while undertaking their economic activities, indulge in practices which effect the
While explaining the word agreement, the Australian Commission in Newton 70s case defined
“the word arrangement is apt to describe something less than a binding contract/agreement,
something in the nature of an understanding between two or more persons- a plan between them
In United States broad and inclusive definition of the term “agreement” is defined in terms of
contract or combination under Section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act, 1890 72.The definition of
69
Civil appeal no. 6691 of 2014, it is one of the first decisions of the Supreme Court with regard to Competition
Act,2002.
70
Newton v. Commissioner of Income Tax of Commonwealth of Australia (1958) 2 All ER 759
71
Iyer’s law Lexicon p. 141 quoting Newton v. Commissioner of Income Tax of Commonwealth of Australia (1958)
2 All ER 759
72
Section 1. Trusts, etc., in restraint of trade illegal; penalty Every contract, combination in the form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is
declared to be illegal. Every person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby
declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not
exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $350,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding three
132
agreement has been recurring antitrust problem because illegality under the Sherman Act is often
predicated upon the existence of an agreement to restrain trade 73.That the difference between
unlawful “tacit collusion” and lawful oligopolistic interdependence is not to be found in any
phrase that describes the state of mind of the industry participants. Once we are outside the
“conscious commitment to a common scheme”, etc., that exists in a situation of tacit collusion
can exist to the same extent in a situation of (lawful) classic oligopoly. Rather, if there is to be a
category of unlawful tacit collusion which is to be distinguished from classic oligopoly, the
difference must lie, not in the state of mind of the competitors, but on the specific elements of
behaviour that brought about that state of mind 74. Hence the expression used in section 1
‘contract or combination’ not only include the valid contracts or agreement backed by law but
Section 3 of the Competition Act 2002,includes, the parties to an agreement who are prohibited,
combination of these .
Sections 3 and 4 of the Competition Act,2002, are applicable to enterprises. The term
133
“enterprise means a person or a department of the Government, who or which is, or has been,
engaged in any activity, relating to the production, storage, supply, distribution, acquisition or
control of articles or goods, or the provision of services, of any kind, or in investment, or in the
securities of any other body corporate, either directly or through one or more of its units or
divisions or subsidiaries, whether such unit or division or subsidiary is located at the same place
where the enterprise is located or at a different place or at different places, but does not include
any activity of the Government relatable to the sovereign functions of the Government including
all activities carried on by the departments of the Central Government dealing with atomic
(b) “article” includes a new article and “service” includes a new service;
(i) a plant or factory established for the production, storage, supply distribution,
(ii) any branch or office established for the provision of any service;
The above definition includes a person or a government department. In its modest form, an
particular entity are considered a sovereign function, not all functions can be sovereign. The
functional aspects of an entity take precedence over its institutional aspects in order to
134
Hon’ble Delhi High Court, in UOI v. CCI Order of 23/02/2012 75 also clarified that:
“An enterprise may perform some sovereign functions while other functions
performed by it, and the activities undertaken by it, may not refer to sovereign functions. The
exemption under section 54 could be granted in relation to the activities relatable to sovereign
functions of the Government, and not in relation to all the activities of such an enterprise.
Therefore, it is the functional aspects and not the institutional aspects that are dominant in
activity is an “enterprise”. It should be noted that “acquisition” of goods and services can
performing sovereign functions such as collection of taxes, or for statutory functions such
3. Trade Associations generally provide a platform to its members to show its views and do
not carry out any commercial activity, hence are not an enterprise. Although, the
customers for distribution of work to its constituent members- such association does
qualify as an “enterprise”.
75
UOI v. CCI, W.P.(c) 993/2012&CM Nos 2178-7 9/2012 dated 23-02-2012
135
4. Autonomous Bodies do qualify as “enterprise” if they carry out an economic activity.
Sports bodies like BCCI or Hockey India do qualify as an “enterprise” as they carry out
The term ‘enterprises’ is seen as equivalent to the word ‘undertaking’ used under the
European Union Competition Law that the reason it becomes imperative for CCI to
In KalusHofner& Fritz Elser v. MacrotronGmb H 76whilst considering the definition of the term
regardless of the legal status of the entity and of the way in which it is financed. It was
the general economic interest remains subject to the EEC competition rules. The above decision
was also followed in the case titled as Distribution of Package Tours During the 1990 World
Cup 77 where the EEC Commission, whilst re affirming the decision in the case of Walrave v
form, constitutes an undertaking within the meaning of Article 85 of the EEC Treaty and further
stated that an activity of an economic nature means any activity, whether or not profit making,
that involves an economic trade” . In Kalus Hofner& Fritz Elser v MacrotronGmb H decision
dated 23/04/1991, the Court of Justice of European Communities whilst considering the
76
23/04/1991, Court of Justice of European Communities
77
OJ (1992) l 326/31
78
Cases 36/74 of 12 December 1974
136
definition of the term ‘undertaking’ under the EEC Competition Law, held that “the concept of
legal status of the entity and of the way in which it is financed. It was accordingly held that
Similarly in Surinder Singh Barmi v. BCCI 80the CCI held that the BCCI undertakes the two roles
i.ecurator and that of organiser. In this broad based objective, the BCCI is tangled in the
selection of team India which represent India in international sporting events, to work towards
the growth and enhancement of cricket by organizing training camps etc., as well as organising
the game throughout the year. These activities also are intricately attached to aspect of
‘organisation’ which brings in revenues to the BCCI. It include managing of media rights , sale
of tickets, etc. the activities of ‘organising events’ are definitely economic activities as there is
revenue aspect is germane to the organisational activities of the BCCI. Hence the BCCI could be
treated as enterprise. Following the European Court Of Justice , CCI holds all sporting
The relevant market definition encompasses the depiction of the context in which certain
economically harmful practice could take place. Therefore, the process of defining a market and
a relevant market, is fore most important, so as to define the deviations and curb anti-competitive
practice. The process begins by assuming provisionally that certain anti-competitive conduct
79
See generally,Available at http://www.cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/702014D.pdf
80
Surinder Singh Barmi v. Board of Control of Cricket in India, 2013 Comp LR 297.
137
exists in the market. It then proceeds to define through a series of questions, the boundaries of
the smallest market in which such conduct could be sustained. After the contours of the smallest
market are defined and drawn, the actual conduct in question is subjected to an analysis, to
The relevant market as defined in Section 2(r) of the Competition Act can only be inclusive as
the term owes its source to the concept of Economics and thus is bound to be susceptible to
"relevant market means the market which may be determined by the Commission with reference
to the relevant product market or the relevant geographic market or with reference to both the
markets”;
It is apparent from the above definition that the duty of identifying the "relevant market" is left in
the hands of the Commission. Further on the terms like 'relevant product market' and the
Economics and also involves analysis of volumes of data/statistics before arriving unto a
conclusion.
"Relevant geographic market means a market comprising the area in which the conditions of
81
Dr. S chakravarthy, relevant market in competition case analyses available at
http://www.circ.in/pdf/Relevant_Market-In-Competition-Case-Analyses.pdf visited on 22nd December 2017.
138
are distinctly homogenous and can be distinguished from the conditions prevailing in the
Section 2(t) of the Competition Act 2002 defines the 'relevant product market' as follows:
"relevant product market means a market comprising all those products or services which are
A relevant product market basically refers to two kinds of substitutability of the product/service
– one is the 'demand side substitution' which stipulates a situation where the market player is not
benefited by a slight increase in price because the consumer has the option of substituting the use
of such product/service and the second is the 'supply side substitution' when other market players
increase supply of such product/service cancelling the effect of any increase in price 83.
The above mentioned definitions sounds like a cakewalk but it can be aptly said it’s not so. In the
case of Belaire Owner's Association v. DLF Limited 84. CCI pronounced its order which
produced currents in the Competition jurisprudence; as the said order was one of the first order
on relevant market under Indian competition jurisprudence, which was supposed to clear the dust
surrounding the concept "relevant market". But soon the notion seemed to whittle down with
more such orders being pronounced by our own CCI Orders in the case of unitech builders and
EMR case etc. It can be rightly asserted that the concept 'Relevant market' is an ineffaceable
ingredient in determining the abuse of dominant position by a market player and thus every time
CCI pronounces its order, it needs to interpret the concept 'relevant market'.
82
Competition Act of India,2002
83
Sameeksha Bhola, “India: Determination Of Relevant Market – ‘Easier Said Than Done”, available
atwww.http://www.mondaq.com/india/x/295618/Trade+Regulation+Practices/Determination+Of+Relevant+Market
+Easier+Said+Than+Done’, last visited on January 2,2018
84
Case No. 19 of 2010, order dated August 12,2012.
139
Relevant market is crucial in examining Dominance and offences of Abuse of Dominance. The
enterprise in the relevant market, which enables it to operate independently of competitive forces
prevailing in the relevant market or affect its competitors or consumers or the relevant market in
its favour. The same Act describes, inter alia, abuse of dominance to occur when an enterprise
uses its dominant position in one relevant market to enter into, or protect, other relevant market.
For an enterprise to abuse a dominant position, it must hold a dominant position in a relevant
market. The first step, therefore, in an evaluation of an enterprise’s actions is to define the
It is an acceptable fact that majority of the members in the commission define ‘relevant market’
vary widely. This tendency has two important concerns. First, if relevant market is defined too
widely, AAEC ceases to be appreciable, which must be proved for establishing a vertical anti-
competitive agreement , as well as it becomes easier to rebut the inference of AAEC in case of
horizontal agreements. Second , if the relevant market is defined too widely, an enterprise,
The relevant market within which to analyse market power or assess a given competition concern
has both a product dimension and a geographic dimension. In this context, the relevant product
market comprises all those products which are considered interchangeable or substitutable by
buyers because of the products' characteristics, prices and intended use. The
relevant geographic market comprises all those regions or areas where buyers would be able or
willing to find substitutes for the products in question. The relevant product and geographic
85
Supra note.75
86
Dixit Vinod, “Competition Law”, Annual Survey of Indian Law, Vol .XLVII, 2011, Page 149.
140
market for a particular product may vary depending on the nature of the buyers and suppliers
concerned by the conduct under examination and their position in the supply chain. For example,
if the questionable conduct is concerned at the wholesale level, the relevant market has to be
defined from the perspective of the wholesale buyers. On the other hand, if the concern is to
examine the conduct at the retail level, the relevant market needs
It is to be borne in mind that the process of defining the relevant market starts by looking into a
relatively narrow potential product market definition. The potential product market is then
expanded to include those substituted products to which buyers would turn in the face of a price
increase above the competitive price. Likewise, the relevant geographic market can be defined
using the same general process as that used to define the relevant product market 88.
In the pursuit of globalization, followed by liberalization and privatization, India has geared for
the challenge by opening up its economy, shackles of removing controls, and restoring to
liberalization. Articles 38 and 39 of the Constitution provide that “the State shall strive to
promote the welfare of the people by securing and protecting as effectively, as it may, a social
order in which justice – social, economic and political – shall inform all the institutions of the
national life, and the State shall, in particular, direct its policy towards securing (a) that the
ownership and control of material resources of the community are so distributed as best to sub
serve the common good; and (b) that the operation of the economic system does not result in the
concentration of wealth and means of production to the common detriment”. As a result Indian
87
CCI v Co ordination Committee of Artist and Technicians ,Civil Appeal No. 6691 of 2014,para 33,at page no 31
88
Ibidi, para 34 at page 32.
141
Parliament in late sixties enacted the MRTP Act thereafter, the complete change in the economic
order for the reasons just discussed above leading to the enactment of Competition Act to
stimulate economic power and equitable distribution of wealth. The Act as discussed above is the
creation of the parliament with no parallel or corresponding legislation formulated at the state
level. The Statement of the Objects and Reasons to the Act states the reason for enacting the new
law clearly.
Section 3 and 4 of the Act lays down violations and the relief for such violations is granted under
section 27 of the Act. In accordance with Section 27 , the CCI is empowered to grant orders in
the nature of a ‘cease and desist’ order, or inflicting a penalty which does not exceeding ‘10 % of
the average turnover during the preceding three years from the date of order. In cartel cases CCI
could impose a penalty that could be higher of either up to 10 percent of the turnover or three
times the amount of profit derived from the cartel agreement. Under the provision of Section 48
of the Competition Act, in the situations of ‘violation by companies’, CCI may go ahead and
punish any person who, at the time of the violation, was in charge of the company, unless that
person can show that the violation was committed ‘without his knowledge’ or that he had
exercised ‘all due diligence to prevent the violation’. Section 43- A provides that “in case of a
failure to notify a combination, the Commission shall impose a penalty of 1% of the total assets
or turnover of the combination”. Section 42A of the Act provides “for the compensation in case
of contravention of orders of the CCI. Hence the section lays down the provision for recovery of
the compensation from the appellate body that is COMPAT by making an application to
142
COMPAT, for recovery of compensation from an enterprise for any loss or damage suffered by
him for violating the directions of the CCI under sections 27, 28, 32, 33 and 41 of the Act” 89.
The prohibition identified under Section 3 and Section 4 of the Act with respect to anti-
endurance of competition. According to Bhatia C.R , “the conjoint cord in prohibition of "Anti-
mentioned under Section 4 is that both pursue to maintain and sustain competition in the markets
and are to be enforced ‘ex post’. An enterprise or association of enterprises is liable under
Section 3, only when, they enter into an agreement relating to production/ supply of goods or
rendering of services which causes or is likely to cause appreciable adverse effect on competition
within in India. On the other hand, abuse of dominance bears upon unilateral behaviour of
dominant enterprise or group thereof. Thus, while the concurrence of wills of two or more
abuse of dominance, being a unilateral conduct, does not emanate from an agreement, which
Anti-competitive agreements are divided into vertical and horizontal agreements. Vertical
agreements are agreement between firms at different stage of production, e.g. an agreement to
supply raw materials. The common nature of such agreements are refusal to deal, resale price
89
Desai Nishit, “Competition Law in India-Jurisprudential Trends and the way forward”, April 2013 available at
http://www.nishithdesai.com/fileadmin/user_upload/pdfs/Research%20Papers/Competition%20Law%20in%20India
.pdf, Last accessed on 1st December 2017.
90
Bhatia G.R, “Assessment Of Dominance: Issues And Challenges Under The Indian Competition Act, 2002”,
available at www.manupatraarticles.com, last accessed on December 12,2017.
143
maintenance, tie in arrangement, exclusive supply etc. Horizontal agreements are ones between
firms at the same level of distribution. The agreements emanating from the collective action of a
group engaged in the same line of business activity. These are in nature of cartels or concerted
action which envisages harmonisation in the market by the competing players i.e. producers or
suppliers. The common types of such agreements are bid rigging, collusive bidding, price
fixation etc. The 'agreement' or 'concerted practice' is the means through which enterprise or
concepts translate the objective of Competition Law to have economic operators determine their
commercial policy independently. Competition Law is aimed at frowning upon the activities of
those undertakings (whether natural persons or legal entities) who, while undertaking their
economic activities, indulge in practices which effect the competition adversely or take
The agreements which are entered by parties which are the same level in the market chain are
categorized into horizontal agreements explicitly included under Section 3(3) of the Competition
Act. The Horizontal agreement have been mentioned under para 4.3 of the Raghavan Committee
Report and defined as “agreements between two or more enterprises that are at the same stage
of the production chain and, in the same market. The most obvious example would be that of
important to define the relevant market .To attract the provision of the law, the products must be
substitutes. Being at the same stage of the production chain implies that the parties to the
agreement are both (all) producers, or retailers or wholesalers. As has been interpreted over the
91
Competition Commission Of India Vs. Co-ordination Committee of Artist and technicians of West Bengal Film and
Television, Civil Appeal No 6691 of 2014
144
years in the U.S. (and enacted more recently in other countries) a distinction is drawn in this
regard between horizontal and vertical agreements. In certain circumstances it can be established
that firms that are collaborating on some socially valuable activity may need to agree to do away
with competition so to establish the cooperative relationship. In this, the European Community
law goes beyond the objective of maximising welfare and explicitly allows some restrictive
contracts if they promote progressiveness and consumers ultimately stand to gain. The Japanese
law also allows for actions in contravention of the law provided they are in the ‘public interest’.
It would be dangerous to allow the kind of discretion in interpretation possible under the
Japanese law. Any exceptions that are permissible should be clearly laid down. However, we
recommend that restrictive contract which is designed to promote use of energy efficient
The presumption in case of horizontal agreements and cartelization is that drives towards
adverse effect on competition. This provision of per se illegality is rooted in the provisions of the
U.S. law and has a parallel in most modern legislations on the subject 93. Even under the
Australian law, it forbids most price fixing arrangements, boycotts and certain kind of exclusive
dealing. Similarly, the U.K. Competition law presumes that certain agreements do have an
"appreciable effect" on competition. So inclusion of such provisions should always be done with
restricted scope for discretion and interpretation on the part of the authorities. Hence, such
92
High level Committee on Competition Policy and Law, Para 4.3.4, Raghavan Committee report.
93
Para 4.3.8,Raghavan Committee report, high level Committee on Competition Policy and Law
145
agreements are presumed to be illegal and the governing principle is that they have an
The other type of agreement which is entered into by enterprises having different levels in the
supply chain or production chain and, therefore, in different markets. They are the agreements
which are entered into between the enterprises operating at different levels of supply chain in the
market, such as between the producer of a product and a retailer 95. An example of this would be
an agreement between a producer and a distributor. These agreements are not free from the
control by Competition Law. Since these agreements brings in restrain, which has a direct impact
on competition, so the anti- competitive vertical agreement are condemn by the Competition
Law. The Raghavan committee has also identified various restrains as “vertical restraints” on
1. Tie-in arrangements
4. Refusal to deal
In the past, the U.S. anti-trust authorities had treated vertical restraints, like tie-in arrangements
illegal quite harshly. This approach has changed in last two decades as they take up a lenient
94
It may be pointed out that a significant number of the Members of the RaghavanCommittee were not in favour of
identifying categories presumed to be illegal. They felt that they should be subject to the ‘rule of reason’ and that the
CCI can issue relevant regulations in this regard. But the majority however felt that such agreements are presumed
to be illegal.
95
Middleton. K and Rodger B.J.et al., Cases and Material on U.K &EC Competition Law, Oxford University Press,
2003, page 219.
146
view, so now under the rule of reason, vertical agreements are generally treated more leniently
The United States District Court for the Middle District of Florida held in Costco Wholesale
96
Corp v Johnson & Johnson Vision Care, that the legality of any vertical agreement between
JJVC and its resellers would be tested under the rule of reason 97. According to the court,
plaintiff needs to prove three fundamental points (a) the anticompetitive effect of JJVC’s conduct
on a relevant market and (b) that the conduct lacks any procompetitive benefit or
justification, and it analysed the sufficiency of the complaint under these criteria. After
concluding that Costco had antitrust standing to bring the action, the court held that the
complaint adequately alleged relevant product markets, one comprising Costco and other firms
that purchase lenses from JJVC (the Wholesale Market) and the other comprising their
downstream customers (the Retail Market). Since JJVC was one of only four firms
manufacturing contact lenses in the relevant geographic market (United States) and had a forty
three per cent market share, the court had little difficulty holding that the complaint adequately
alleged ‘a plausible claim of actual and potential harm to competition and consumers in the
market. 98’
Even in EU competition law treats horizontal agreements different from the vertical
agreements 99. Similarly in India, the nature of agreement depends on the locus the parties hold in
96
2015 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 168581 (M.D. Fla. 2015)
97
Id at 20
98
Id at 41, available at.http://globalcompetitionreview.com/insight/the-antitrust-review-of-the-americas-
2017/1068697/united-states-vertical-restraints, last assessed on 6th December 2017
99
Commission Regulation 330/2010 of 20 April 2010 on the application of Article 101(3) of the Treaty on the
Functioning of the European Union to categories of vertical agreements and concerted practices available at
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/vertical.html, last accessed on December 6, 2017
147
the market. The reason for variant treatment is because sometimes the vertical agreements have
positive effect on the competition. While to see the anti-competitive effect on the market, one of
the party should have significant market power. In any case, given a situation, the agreement is,
Section 3 of the competition Act provides for prohibition entering into anti-competitive
agreements. Any such agreement which causes or is likely to cause an appreciable adverse affect
on the competition within India shall be void. Section 3 was brought into effect from 20th May
2009, vide notification No.1241(E), dated 15th May 2009.section 3(1) clearly provides that “no
enterprise or association of enterprises or person or association of persons shall enter into any
competition within India”. Where there is an accusation that an agreement is likely to cause
In the recent Prem Prakash and Principal Secretary , Government of Madhya Pradesh 100 it
“the basic objective of competition law is promotion and protection of the competitive
process and ensuring a level-playing field for all market players that will help markets to be
competitive. Thus, in public procurement processes, it is desirable that the conditions imposed
on suppliers are not such that they exclude firms from the market. Rather endeavor should be to
100
Case No 50 of 2014, Page 18,order dated 17th March 2017.The information in this case was filed by Shri Prem
Prakash (the ‘Informant’) under Section 19(1)(a) of the Competition Act, 2002 (the ‘Act’) against the Principal
Secretary, Public Works Department, Government of Madhya Pradesh (‘OP-1’) and the Director General, Central
Public Works Department, New Delhi (‘OP-2’) alleging contravention of the provisions of Sections 3 and 4 of the
Act.
148
promote competition by being more flexible so that more number of firms would be eligible to
provide services. Also, the conditions should be such that they ensure equal and non-
discriminatory treatment as well as the best possible environment for competition. Accordingly,
when a department of the Government such as OPs require quality certificates in their tender
conditions, the terms must not specify any specific accrediting entity rather the terms should
specify the standards. This would not only enable participation by more laboratories but also
ensure that the laboratories which have been accredited as per the stipulated international
standards are not discriminated based on the accreditation body that certifies them”
Adding to the above note, the CCI held in FICCI – Multiplex case 101 while following the
Kingfisher Airlines v Competition Commission 102 ,in case where a cartel comes into effect prior
to the notification of section 3 of the Act and if it continues after the enforcement of the said
The first and much awaited order under section 3(1) of the Competition Act,
2002, RamakantKini v. Dr. L.H. Hiranandani Hospital, Powai, Mumbai 104 has garnered more
than its share of controversy since the time Commission has put down the precedence of
applicability of Section 3(1) and opined that, "Section 3(3) and section 3(4) are expansion of
section 3(1) but are not exhaustive of the scope of section 3(1)..... scope of section 3(1) is
The core of section 3(1) is causation or likelihood of adverse appreciable affect within a
particular market; if the said provision is disengaged from the section, a standalone enforcement
101
Supra note 274.
102
(2010) 4 Comp .L J 557 (Bom)
103
FICCI-Multiplex Association of India v United Producer/Distributors case no .01/2009, order dated 25thfeb 2011
104
Ramakant Kini v. Dr. L.H. Hiranandani Hospital, Powai, Mumbai, Case No. 39 of 2012, order dated 05 February,
2014.
105
Id page 11.
149
of the section can only be unwarranted and unreasonable. The disinclination of the Commission
to demarcate the relevant market in section 3 cases, it is hard to envision its assessment under
section 3(1) and the basis of holding an agreement anti-competitive. The term “appreciable
adverse effect on competition” has not been defined in the Act. However, the Competition Act
brings out certain grounds mentioned under section 19(3) for commission to have due regard
while taking note of agreements under section 3. Some of the grounds are as mentioned below
The rulings of the Competition commission in matters under section 3 and section 4 of the
Competition Act show profound sense of understanding of the present day business dealings.
The reasoning of the Competition commission in Automobiles Dealers and Lamborghini and
whole lot of other cases by and large is balanced and recognises changes in business models
Commission in these rulings has depended on the criteria provided under section 19 of the Act
and has also recommended that all the factors mentioned therein be examined and has sought to
150
• Automobile Order 106
The present case was brought before commission by Shri Shamsher Katarai, under Section
19(1)(a) of the Competition Act against the leading car manufacturers of Indian market namely
Honda, Volkswagen and Fait claiming that the non-availability of original spare parts in the free
conduct.
Competition Commission noted that “as per the provisions of section 3(4) of the Act, only
agreements which cause or are likely to cause an AAEC on competition in India, shall be subject
to the prohibition contained in section 3(1) of the Act. Therefore, in order to determine if the
agreements entered between the OEMs and the authorized dealers are in the nature of an
exclusive distribution agreement or refusal to deal under section 3(4)(c) and 3(4)(d) of the Act,
the Commission needs to determine if such agreements cause an AAEC in the market based upon
However, while in Automobiles Case, restrictive supply of spares and services only through
authorised dealers was held to be anti-competitive, in Snap deal order 107, a similar condition
imposed by SanDisk corporation was considered reasonable condition and was not considered
“That the storage devices sold through the online portals should be bought from its
protect the sanctity of its distribution channel. In a quality-driven market, brand image and
goodwill are important concerns and it appears a prudent business policy that sale of
106
Shamsher katari vs Honda siel, Case No 03 of 2011
107
Ashish Ahuja and Snapdeal ,Case No. 17 of 2014.
151
products emanating from unknown/ unverified/ unauthorised sources are not
encouraged/allowed”.
This apparent inconsistency still remains there, the challenge to the Automobiles Case vide
interim order dated February 6,2013 in the Madras High Court was finally dispose-off on
February 4, 2015 with the confirmation of jurisdiction on the commission and held that neither
Director General nor CCI exceed the jurisdiction vested in them by the statute and even after
COMPAT order dated December 9, 2016 upholding the CCI order but reducing the quantum of
CCI, applying principles stated in the First Report, first examined the presence of an agreement
and then the elements of Section 3. Although CCI agreed with the finding of DG that the market
was oligopolistic, CCI concluded that pricing policies followed by the major players did not
reveal presence of a prior agreement. Materially, CCI concluded that interdependence of parties
in an oligopolistic market was not conclusive of presence of an agreement for the purpose of a
cartel. CCI also concluded that behaviour of firms in pricing showed that manufacturers were not
108
In Re: Alleged Cartelization by Steel Producers, Case No: RTPE No. 09 of 2008 (MRTP).
The MRTP Commission took cognizance on the basis of an article published in the Financial Express which spoke
about a sudden spike in prices of steel by steel companies such as SAIL and RINL which would have a grave
inflationary effect, affecting prices in other industries such as automobile and construction. Engineering Export
Promotion Council (EEPC) subsequently filed a complaint addressed to the DG I&R (Investigation and Registration,
under MRTP Act) about a possible cartelization in the Steel Industry. It was contended that between April 2007 and
January 2008, there was an average increase in the price of steel by 10%. Consequently, thirty four steel companies
were directed to be investigated by DG I&R. Subsequently upon the repeal of the MRTP Act, the matter was
transferred to CCI under Section 66 (6) of the Act. CCI concluded that a prima facie case existed and directed the
DG under the Act to carry out further investigation and submit a report.
.
152
a. Profit margin is an important indicator of price fixing strategies. This can be indicative of
b. Price parallelism by itself is not indicative of cartels or cartel-like behavior unless there is
c. Since circumstantial evidence would be relied upon, the material gathered should lead one to
the conclusion that there is more than mere parallelism and firms have crossed the ‘line’ thereby
West Bengal film and television 109 Supreme Court held “When the lenses of the reasoning
process are duly adjusted with their focus on the picture, the picture gets sharpened and haziness
disappears. One can clearly view that prohibition on the exhibition of dubbed serial on the
television prevented the competing parties in pursuing their commercial activities. Thus, the CCI
rightly observed that the protection in the name of the language goes against the interest of the
Committee definitely caused harm to consumers by depriving them from watching the dubbed
serial on TV channel; albeit for a brief period. It also hindered competition in the market by
barring dubbed TV serials from exhibition on TV channels in the State of West Bengal. It
amounted to creating barriers to the entry of new content in the said dubbed TV serial. Such act
and conduct also limited the supply of serial dubbed in Bangla, which amounts to violation of the
provision of Section 3(3)(b) of the Act” 110. In the instant case the appeal of Competition
Commission was allowed. Court held that the trade union which is The Coordination Committee,
109
Civil Appeal No. 6691 of 2014(Supreme Court of India)
110
Supra note 275,
153
and not related to any other activity would not be treated as an ‘enterprise’ or the kind of
Section 3(3) of the Act deals with certain specific anti competitive agreements, practices and
decisions of those supplying identical or similar trade of goods or provision of services, acting in
concert or such actions by cartels. it also provides that in the cases of suppliers of identical or
similar goods or services, including cartels, certain arrangements between those enterprises,
practices carried on by them and decisions taken by them, will be presumed to have been an
Section 3(4) of the Act prohibits tie-in arrangements, exclusive supply agreements, exclusive
distribution agreement, refusal to deal and resale price maintenance. Any of these practices
having adverse effect on competition in India is prohibited .it means that anti-competitive
practice may happen inside or outside India, but if the effect is within the country, competition
authorities of India can take appropriate action. However , section 3(5)(i) of the Act gives the IP
right holder to put restraint on infringement and to impose reasonable restrictions and conditions
in order to protect his right on copyright, patents, trademarks, geographical Indications of goods,
4.7 Dominance
World over the Competition laws are predominantly concerned with the exercise of market
power and its abuse. The term “market power” is variously known as “dominant position”,
111
Raju .K.D, The Intellectual Property Rights and Competition Law; A Comparative Analysis, Eastern Law
House,2015 at page 184.
112
Supra note 277 at page 183.
154
Section 4 113 of the Competition Act, 2002 provides for prohibition of abuse of dominant
position.it was brought into effect from May 20,2009, vide NotificationNo.1241(E) , dated 15th
may 2009.The Act defines “dominant position in terms of a position of strength enjoyed by an
It is the capability of the firm to conduct independently of the market forces that controls its
enterprise has control over the market, especially in the determination of price of the product.
Keeping this in view, the Act specifies a number of factors that should be taken into account
while determining whether an enterprise is dominant or not. The dominant position can be
113
Abuse of dominant position
“4. [(1) No enterprise or group shall abuse its dominant position.]
(2) There shall be an abuse of dominant position 4 [under sub-section (1), if an enterprise or a group].—-
(a) directly or indirectly, imposes unfair or discriminatory—
(i) condition in purchase or sale of goods or service; or
(ii) price in purchase or sale (including predatory price) of goods or
service.
Explanation.— For the purposes of this clause, the unfair or discriminatory condition in purchase or sale of goods or
service referred to in sub-clause (i) and unfair or discriminatory price in purchase or sale of goods (including
predatory price) or service referred to in sub-clause (ii) shall not include such discriminatory condition or price
which may be adopted to meet the competition; or
(b) limits or restricts—
(i) production of goods or provision of services or market there for or
(ii) technical or scientific development relating to goods or services to the prejudice of consumers; or
(c) indulges in practice or practices resulting in denial of market access [in any manner]; or
(d) makes conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by other parties of supplementary obligations which, by
their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts; or
(e) uses its dominant position in one relevant market to enter into, or protect, other relevant market.
Explanation.—For the purposes of this section, the expression—
(a) “dominant position” means a position of strength, enjoyed by an enterprise, in the relevant market, in India,
which enables it to—
(i) operate independently of competitive forces prevailing in the relevant market; or
(ii) affect its competitors or consumers or the relevant market in its favour.
(b) “predatory price” means the sale of goods or provision of services, at a. price which is below the cost, as may be
determined by regulations, of production of the goods or provision of services, with a view to reduce competition or
eliminate the competitors.
[(c)“group” shall have the same meaning as assigned to it in clause (b) of the Explanation to section 5.]”
155
determined in the context of the relevant market and on the basis of any of the thirteen factors
The lookout for the abuse of dominance by a group or a single firm would involve three stages ;
First being identification of the relevant market which is evaluated from the perspective of
The above two dimensions of the relevant market are governed by several factors. CCI in Atos
case 114 defined “product market as to comprise all those products or services that are regarded as
services, their prices and intended use” 115.The CCI held that relevant product market is to be
looked at form both demand and supply perspectives based on the characteristics of the product,
Relevant geographic markets could be local or national depending upon the facts in each case,
but it cannot be global 117. These are areas where demand and supply of goods of services can be
It might be said that market share, though a major factor, is not the sole yardstick in
Hiranandani Hospital, Powai, Mumbai. 119 The Commission was assessing the dominance of the
Hiranandani hospital. The relevant market was for provision of maternity services by super
114
Atos Worldline V Verifone India, Case No. 56 of 2012, para 6.3
115
Ibidi
116
Surinder Singh Barmi V BCCI, Case No 61 of 2010.
117
Bijay Poddar V Coal India Ltd., Case No 59 of 2013.
118
Supra note 280
119
Case No. 39 of 2012.
156
specialty and high-end hospitals within a distance of 12 kilometres from the Hiranandani
Hospital. The Commission, in the case, clarified that the market shares cannot be the lone
merely enjoying dominant position in the market is not a breach of the law. Its bad only when
intervention under the Act, serves as a filter and it is presumed that the same conduct either
The abuse of dominant position impedes fair competition between the firms, exploits consumers,
and makes it difficult for other players to compete with the dominant enterprise on merit. Abuses
as specified in the Act fall into two broad categories: exploitative (excessive or discriminatory
pricing) and exclusionary (for example, denial of market access). Hence according to the
Raghavan committee Report, para 3.6 contains abuse of dominant position as following;
2) Predatory pricing;
7) Using dominant position in one market to gain advantages in another market 120.
120
Report of High Level Committee on Competition Policy and Law, Para 3.6
157
The exclusionary conducts are those in which the dominant entity uses its dominance to restrict
entry of competition into the relevant market. In Re Shri ShamsherKataria v Seil Honda 121,
“where there existed agreements between the dominant entities and the Overseas Suppliers of
original car parts which prevented the Overseas Suppliers from supplying parts to independent
repairers, such agreements were held to be anti-competitive as they restricted entry of new
firms”.
While the conduct which can be referred as exploitative conduct are the ones wherein the
dominant firms levy unjust or discriminatory conditions and exploits its dominance. The case
122
dealing with the issue is Pankaj Agarwal v DLF , “where, in a case pertaining to allotment of
apartments, the contracts drafted unilaterally by DLF enabled them to be arbitrary about
allotment of super-area, secretive about information relevant to the purchaser, like, the number of
apartments on a floor, and to cancel allotments and forfeit booking amounts. The Commission
held the contracts to be exploitative against buyers, and thus, abusive” 123.
The word dominance, in some jurisdictions, is based on a structured approach having rebuttable
if an enterprise enjoys a market share of 45 per cent/50 per cent in South Africa and Israel,
respectively. A rebut table presumption of dominance arises in case of market share of 80 per
cent, 50 per cent and 33 per cent in Canada, Korea and Germany, respectively. The Court of
“although the importance of the market shares may vary from one
market to another the view may legitimately be taken that very large shares are in themselves,
121
Case no 03 of 2011, para 8.1.7
122
Pankaj Agarwal v. DLF case no 13 of 2010 and case no 55 of 2012.
123
http://cis-india.org/a2k/blogs/abuse-of-dominant-position-in-indian-competition-law-a-brief-guide
124
Case 85/76 [1979]ECR 461
158
and save in exceptional circumstances, evidence of the existence of a dominant position. An
undertaking which has a very large market share and holds it for some time is by virtue of that
share in a position of strength. The Court further pointed to Roche’s highly developed sales
network as a relevant factor conferring upon it commercial advantages over its rivals. The
commission has treated both vertical integration and the benefit of well established distribution
systems as a barrier to entry in several other decisions, since this could impede access for would
In exercise of powers vested under section 19 of the Act, the Commission may inquire into any
alleged contravention of section 4 (1) of the Act that proscribes abuse of dominance. Section 19
(4) gives a detailed list of factors that the Commission shall consider while inquiring into any
allegation of abuse of dominance. Some of these factors are market share of the enterprise, size
and resources of the enterprise, size and importance of the competitors, dependence of
consumers, entry barriers, and social obligations and costs in the relevant geographic and product
market. The Commission, on being satisfied that there exists a prima facie case of abuse of
dominance, shall direct the Director General to cause an investigation and furnish a report. The
Commission has the powers vested in a Civil Court under the Code of Civil Procedure in respect
of matters like summoning or enforcing attendance of any person and examining him on oath,
requiring discovery and production of documents and receiving evidence on affidavit. The
Director General, for the purpose of carrying out investigation, is vested with powers of civil
125
Advocacy Series 4 , provisions relating to abuse of dominance, Competition Commission of India ,Available at
http://www.cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/advocacy_booklet_document/AOD.pdf
159
Orders
• GHCL Limited And 1. Coal India Limited 2. Western Coalfields Limited (Opposite
The year 2017 saw one of the important orders of CCI in Coal India Case in relation to the anti-
competitive conduct assumed by the Cola India and the subsidiaries. As regards the market share
of Coal India, “CCI concluded that prima facie Coal India was in a dominant position in the
relevant market. In a series of cases, CCI had directed investigation into allegations against Coal
India and its subsidiaries in respect of the FSAs. Allegations raised in Coal India Case were also
The Commission is of considered opinion that “CIL through its subsidiaries operates
independently of market forces and enjoys dominance in the relevant market of ‘production and
sale of non-coking coal to thermal power producers including captive power plants in India”.
The Commission also holds “the Opposite Parties to be in contravention of the provisions of
Section 4(2)(a)(i) of the Act for imposing unfair/ discriminatory conditions and indulging in
unfair/ discriminatory conduct in the matter of supply of non-coking coal, as detailed in the
order. Accordingly, the Opposite Parties are directed to cease and desist from indulging in the
conduct which has been found to be in contravention of the provisions of the Act; and to effect
the changes in the fuel supply agreements in light of the observations and findings recorded in
the present order”. For effecting these modifications in the agreements, CIL is further directed to
126
Case No 08 of 2014.
127
It is observed that vide separate order dated 24.03.2017 passed by the Commission in Maharashtra State Power
Generation Company Ltd. etc. v .Mahanadi Coalfields Ltd. &Ors. etc. in Case Nos. 03, 11 & 59 of 2012, the
relevant market has been defined by the Commission as “production and saleof non-coking coal to thermal power
generators in India” after considering in detail the pleas advanced by CIL seeking to expand the relevant geographic
market as global. While rejecting the plea, the Commission noted that imported coal cannot be considered a
substitute for domestic coal on account of various factors as discussed there in. Case No. 5 of 2013, along with Case
No. 7 of 2013, M/s. Madhya Pradesh Power Generating Company Limited v. M/s. South Eastern Coalfields Ltd.
&Anr .and Case No. 37 of 2013 M/s. West Bengal Power Development Corporation td.
160
consult all the stakeholders including the Informant herein. As a penalty of Rs. 591.01 crore has
already been imposed upon the Opposite Parties vide separate order dated 24.03.2017 of the
Commission passed in the previous batch of informations (i.e. in Case Nos. 03, 11 and 59 of
2012), the Commission deems it appropriate not to impose any further monetary penalty upon
BCCI, a society registered under Tamil Nadu Societies Registration Act, 1975 is engaged
primarily in controlling and promoting cricket in India. The year 2008 saw the rise of Indian
Premier Leagueby BCCI in the name of T- 20 format and established global brand with an
Mr. Surinder Singh Barmi, introducing himself as the cricket fan and the informant in this case,
filed a complaint under Section 19(1) (a) of the Act, against BCCI alleging anti-competitive
activities in with respect to organization of IPL. He alleged irregularities ranging from the grant
of franchise rights for team ownership, to gross irregularities in the grant of media rights, to
loopholes in the award of sponsorship rights. The CCI ruled under Section 26(1) that a prima
facie case existed and directed the Director General 130 to investigate it.
CCI held that BCCI is a de factor regulator of cricket in India and the fact that BCCI is a “not-
for-profit” organization does not take it out of the ambit of definition of an “enterprise”, only
128
C. No. 08 of 2014 order dated 21st April 2017.
129
2013 Comp LR 297
130
On the basis of the report submitted by the DG, it was observed that the process for grant of franchisee
agreements for infinitum tenure was unfair and discriminatory, as also the mechanism of awarding the media rights
for a period of 10 years caused appreciable adverse effect on the market. While deciding this case, CCI dealt with
several key issues like the legal status of BCCI, whether BCCI could be considered an enterprise for the purposes of
the Act, and finally whether BCCI had abused its dominant position in the relevant market in contravention of
Section 4 of the Act.
161
exception is permissible in relation to sovereign functions of the Government. Thus, The CCI
concluded that BCCI had contravened provisions of the Act and directed them with cease and
desist from using their regulatory power specially with respect to commercial activity and also
with respect to denying market access to potential competitors. In addition it imposed penalty of
The BCCI , aggrieved with orders of CCI approached COMPAT under Section 53B of the Act
on various grounds including violation of principles of natural justice. It held that the finding
recorded by the Commission on the issue of abuse of dominance is legally unsustainable and is
liable to be set-aside because the information downloaded from the net and similar other material
do not have any evidentiary value and, in any case, the same could not have been relied upon by
the Commission without giving an effective opportunity to the appellant to controvert the
same 131.
COMPAT looked failure to comply with the principles of natural justice by the commission ,
which was the procedural requirement though COMPAT send it back to commission for fresh
look with clear stress on following the principles of natural justice. COMPAT has laid pressure
on the importance of parties being heard as also the opportunity of controverting the evidence
placed against it. This order of appellate body made sure that in future CCI will have no choice
but to follow the principles of natural justice while complying with the procedural requirement.
After inquiry the Commission may pass inter- alia any or all of the following orders under
131
competition appellate tribunal Appeal No.17 of 2013 With I.A. No.26 of 2013 available at
162
1) direct the parties to discontinue and not to re-enter such agreement;
3) direct the enterprises concerned to abide by such other orders as the Commission may pass
and comply with the directions, including payment of costs, if any; and
4) pass such other orders or issue such directions as it may deem fit.
5) can impose such penalty as it may deem fit. The penalty can be up to 10% of the average
turnover for the last three preceding financial years upon each of such persons or enterprises
position to ensure that such enterprise does not abuse its dominant position.
Under section 33 132 of the Act, during the pendency of an inquiry into abuse of dominant
position, the Commission may temporarily restrain any party from continuance with the alleged
offending act until conclusion of the inquiry or until further orders, without giving notice to such
4.8.2 Appeals
The Competition Appellate Tribunal (COMPAT) is established under section 53A of the Act, to
hear and dispose of appeals against any direction issued or decision made or order passed by the
132
The procedures related to interim order is under Regulation No. 2 of 2009 dated May 21, 2009 available at
www.cci.gov.in, last visited on January 23, 2018
163
Commission under specified sections of the Act. An appeal has to be filed within 60 days of
The Competition Commission ON 20TH FEB 2017 dismissed allegations of abuse of dominance
made against Dhanlaxmi Bank with respect to a property loan. It was alleged by a Delhi-based
complainant that the bank charged higher interest rate and imposed pre-payment charges .For the
case, Competition Commission of India considered 'market for provision of loan against property
in Delhi' as the relevant one After concluding that the bank is not a dominant player in the
relevant market, the regulator said that "no case of contravention of Section 4" of the
Competition Act is made out against opposite party Dhanlaxmi Bank. Section 4 of the
Competition Act pertains to abuse of dominant position. "The commission observes that
considering the small size of OP and presence of other major banks such as SBI, HDFC, ICICI,
Axis, Central Bank of India, Bank of India, Union Bank of India andPNB , kotak bank and other
nationalised and private sector banks, OP is not dominant in the relevant market," CCI said "In
the absence of dominance of OP in the relevant market, the question of abuse of dominance in
terms of Section 4 of the Act does not arise," it added. The complainant, who had taken the loan
back in 2011, had alleged that the bank increased the floating rate when RBI hiked the repo rate,
but did not reduce it when the central bank brought it down 134.
133
In Re Ashish Dandona and Dhanlakshmi Bank , Case no 66 of 2016
134
See generally, available at
http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/news/industry/banking/finance/banking/competition-commission-rejects-
complaint-against-dhanlaxmi-bank/articleshow/57275151.cms, Last visited on December 20,2017.
164
The foundation of the Competition law is based on three facets- firstly, preservation or
thirdly, consumer welfare. All the three facets are inter-related. Among these, Regulation of
combinations is one such facet of the competition law in regards to which the law in India is still
at nascent stage and jurisprudential aspects as to the same are being incorporated from studying
the pattern with EU jurisdiction and the U.S. jurisdiction. The EU rules on the control of mergers
or, to use an alternative term often in the parlance of EU law, ‘concentrations’, are contained in
the EU Merger Regulation, Regulation 139/2004. A true merger involves two separate
undertakings merging entirely into a new entity; a high profile example of this was the fusion in
1996 of Ciba- Geigy and Sandoz to form the major pharmaceutical and chemical company
Novartis 135. To add on further, in the year 2000 the merger of Glaxo Wellcome and SmithKline
mark that the term ‘merger’ as used under Competition Act includes a far broader range of
commercial transactions than what are above mentioned. Competition law is concerned about the
possibility that a merger will lead to the market being less competitive in the future than it
currently is, leading to adverse effects for consumers. The main concern of competition
authorities when assessing a merger is whether it will have adverse horizontal effects; there may
also be concern about vertical and conglomerate effects, but these concerns are much rarer. It is
possible that the same case can give rise to horizontal, vertical and conglomerate concerns 136
amalgamations and acquisition of control, shares, voting rights and assets of one company by
another company or group. The Competition Act regulates mergers but these provisions came
135
Case No M 737, decision of 17thjuly 1996, available at www.europa.eu/competition/mergers/cases, last visited on
December 20,2017.
136
Whish Richard and Bailey David, Competition Law ,Oxford University Press, 7thed.page 810
165
into effect in the year 2011. Large firms that propose to merge or to acquire other large firms
must notify the government in advance. Mergers that have AAEC are unlawful. In line with the
notified merger thresholds, notified by way of Combination Regulations 2011, the CCI looks
into the aspect of effect to market competition efficacy and effectiveness of a particular
witnessing constant growth in India, in terms of both law and legal philosophy.
The Competition Act,2002, regulates the combinations under sections 5 137 and 6 read with
sections 20(3) ,29,30 and 31. The regulation provisions under the Competition Law are limited in
its scope. The pertinent question of inquiry under these provisions is limited to that of preventing
anti- competitive effect of mergers or acquisition. Mostly the companies use merger as a
combination method or tool to avoid competition in the market and subsequently increase the
market power. In each case the Commission would investigate the nature of action, relevant
market and adverse effect on competition. The exceeding thresholds were explained in Section 5
Following grounds are to be taken into consideration by the Commission for the determination of
4. Likelihood that the combination would result in the parties to the combination being able
137
Revised threshold under S.O 675(E) dated March 4,2016.
166
6. Extent to which substitutes are available or are likely to be available in the market
8. Likelihood that the combination would result in the removal of a vigorous and effective
12. Relative advantage, by way of the contribution to the economic development by any
13. Whether the benefits of the combination outweigh the adverse impact of the combination,
if any 138
An important case decided in 2014 was a challenge to the Jet – Etihad Case. It is however to be
noted, that the Commission 139 is granting the present approval, under section 31(1) of the Act,
and that such approval is being granted, pursuant to the underlying competition assessment,
based upon the information/details provided by the Parties, in the notice given under subsection
(2) of Section 6 of the Act, as modified and supplemented from time to time. This approval
should not be construed as immunity in any manner from subsequent proceedings before the
Commission for violations of other provisions of the Act. It is incumbent upon the Parties to
ensure that this ex ante approval does not lead to ex-post violation of the provisions of the Act 140.
138
Raju KD (2014), “Interface between Competition law and Intellectual Property Rights: A Comparative Study of
the US, EU and India”, Intel Prop Rights 2: 115.At page 15.
139
Combination Registration No. C-2013/05/12, Notice u/s 6 (2) of the Competition Act, 2002 given by: (i) Etihad
Airways PJSC; and (ii) Jet Airways (India) Limited
140
Order available at http://www.cci.gov.in/sites/default/files/C-2013-05-122%20Order%20121113.pdf
167
The combination was approved by CCI in November 2013. While examining the proposed
combination, views of Air India were solicited which raised certain concerns. These were
considered and disposed off when CCI finally approved the proposed combination by way of an
order under Section 31 (1) of the Act (Jet – Etihad Order). An appeal under Section 53B was
made to COMPAT challenging the Jet – Etihad Order by Jitender Bhargava, a public citizen with
over 20 years association with Air India. COMPAT dismissed the appeal on the point of locus
standi without examining the merits of the Jet – Etihad Order. Although Section 53A provides
that ‘any person, aggrieved’ may challenge an order of CCI, COMPAT interpreted ‘any person’
to mean, a person ‘aggrieved’ by the CCI order and that it could not mean ‘any’ and ‘every’
person.
NCR and Chandigarh, subject to modification in an order dated 4th may 2016.
The CCI order mentioned that the PVR has given commitments such as divestiture of 15 screens
in Noida at Garden Galleria, divestiture of seven screens in Gurgaon at Airia Mall, in addition to
commitment to not open any new theatre or acquire existing theatres in South Delhi for five
years. The pricing also grabbed much required attention. The commitments by PVR cinemas,
also include price caps on tickets and food and beverage prices for PVR and DT Cinemas in
South Delhi for five years with an ability to increase prices by no more than five per cent of
141
Combination Registration No. C-2015/07/288
168
CCI approves Acquisition of VCDs business of St. Jude’s Medical, Inc. by Abbott laboratories.
It is a company incorporated and listed in the USA, well known a global health care company
which is engaged in research, development, manufacture and sale of a range of health care
products on a global basis. It filed a notice with the Commission on 1st August, 2016 relating to
its acquisition of the Vascular Closure Devices business of St. Jude Medical, Inc. The notice was
filed pursuant to execution of an agreement and Plan of Merger entered into between the Parties
The Commission noted that the Parties’ activities overlap in ‘small hole’ VCDs in India and that
the combined market share of the Parties in India in 2015 in the ‘small hole’ VCDs as well as the
individual hole sizes within ‘small hole’ VCDs were of the order of 90-100 percent .The other
competitor i.e. Cardinal Health had an insignificant market share. Therefore, the proposed
combination would enhance the merged entity’s market power in the already highly concentrated
market for ‘small hole’ VCDs in India. In order to address the concerns emanating from the
proposed combination, Parties have submitted a modification in the form of a plan of divestiture
of the entire ‘small hole’ VCDs segment of SJM on a worldwide basis under Regulation19(2) of
Combinations)Regulations, 2011. The proposed modification would remove the only overlap
between Abbott and SJM in India, i.e. in ‘small hole’ VCDs and eliminate the competition
concerns identified by the Commission. The Commission approved the proposed combination
142
Combination Registration No. C-2016/08/418
143
Volume 19 : October-December 2016, Fair Play ,competition commission of India-December 2016 Fair Play
144
Combination Registration No. C-2014/05/170
169
On 06.05.2014, the Competition Commission of India received a notice under sub-section (2) of
Section 6 of the Competition Act, 2002 given by Sun Pharmaceutical Industries Limited and
Ranbaxy Laboratories Limited. The proposed combination relates to the merger of Ranbaxy into
Sun Pharma pursuant to a Scheme of Arrangement under Sections 391-394 and other applicable
provisions of the Companies Act, 1956 and the Companies Act, 2013.
The Commission in its meeting held on 05.12.2014 considered and approved the proposed
combination with modification(s) by passing an order under sub-section (7) of Section 31 of the
Act. Under the Order, the Commission directed that the following modification(s) shall be
a.) Sun Pharma shall divest all products containing Tamsulosin + Tolterodine which are currently
i. All products containing Leuprorelin which are currently marketed and supplied under
the Eligard brand name. In the event the divestiture of distribution rights of Eligard is
not achieved within the First Divestiture Period (as defined in the Order), Sun Pharma
shall divest its products containing Leuprorelin currently marketed and supplied
ii. All products containing Terlipresslin which are currently marketed and supplied
iii. All products containing Rosuvastatin + Ezetimibe which are currently marketed and
iv. All products containing Olanzapine + Fluoxetine which are currently marketed and
170
v. All products containing Levosulpiride + Esomeprazole which are currently marketed
Hence the two firms have received go-ahead from the Competition Commission of India for sale
of seven brands to Emcure Pharma to comply with the commission’s conditional permission for
their merger. In an order issued on march 2015, CCI approved the deal with Emcure, which
would purchase the 'divestment products' that were ordered to be sold in an earlier direction
issued in December 2014 by the Competition Commission of India .These seven brands were at
center of the CCI's contention that the merger between Sun Pharmaceutical Industries and
Ranbaxy Laboratories was 'prima-facie' in violation of competition laws and therefore the
regulator had ordered divestment of those products under its 'conditional' approval to the deal.
The reflection on the Indian Competition Act, 2002 takes researcher further to interface issues
involved in the functioning of two laws namely the Competition Act and Intellectual Property
Laws.
171