T3 FactorModels
T3 FactorModels
Fernando Chague
2019
Beta Pricing Models
Remarks:
cov (f˜,R̃ )
βf = var (f˜)
is the beta of R̃ (factor loading, “quantity” of risk)
λ is the factor risk premium (the price of a unit of beta-risk)
Rz is the return on a cov f˜, R˜z = 0 asset; if ∃ Rf , then Rz = Rf
Beta Pricing Models
Remarks:
cov (R̃ ∗ ,R̃ ∗ )
h i
1. If the factor is also a return R̃ ∗ = f˜, then E R̃ ∗ = Rz + λ var R̃ ∗
( )
h i cov R̃ ∗ , R̃ h i
E R̃ = Rz + E R̃ ∗ − Rz
var R̃ ∗
Remarks:
3. Assume a single-factor beta pricing exists and let Rz 6= 0. Then, the following
random variable is a Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF):
1 ψ ˜ h i
m̃ = − f − E f˜
Rz Rz
Intuition:
I Under i), ii), or iii), MV analysis is valid
I Under MV analysis, each investor hold a portfolio on the MV frontier
I Each of these portfolios is a linear combination of two frontier portfolios
I The market portfolio is a convex combination of all investor’s portfolios and,
by the convexity of the efficient set, is also a frontier portfolio
Capital Market Line
Theorem
Suppose m is on the MV efficient frontier and q is another MV efficient frontier
portfolio, then:
E [Rm ] − Rf
E [Rq ] = Rf + σq
σm
which defines the Capital Market Line (CML).
Remarks:
E [Rq ]−Rf E [Rm ]−Rf
I Since q is MV efficient, σq = σm
E [Rm ]−Rf
I
σm is also known as the Sharpe Ratio (SR)
I The inclination of the CML is the SR (the maximum SR among all possible
portfolios)
I The market portfolio is the tangency portfolio with only risky assets
I The Security Market Line (SML) has (µ, β ) as coordinates
CAPM Derivations
where
I N
wm,0 = ∑ wi,0 and R̃m = ∑ πm,j R̃j
i =1 j =1
CAPM Derivations
or
E u 0 (w1i )
Cov w1i , Rj = − 00i
E Rj − Rf
E ui (w1i )
00 0
I Define θi = −E ui (w1i ) /E ui (w1i ) and aggregate over investors:
!
l l
∑ 1/θi E Rj − Rf = ∑ Cov w1i , Rj = Cov w1m , Rj
i=1 i=1
= Cov w0m (1 + Rm ) , Rj = w0m Cov Rm , Rj
ai − bi E wi,1 E Rj − Rf = −Cov ai − bi wi,1 , Rj = bi Cov wi,1 , Rj
I Divide by bi and aggregate over investors
!
I
ai
∑ bi − E wm,1 E Rj − Rf = −wm,0 Cov Rm , Rj
i=1
I For j = m, we have:
!
I
ai
∑ − E wm,1 (E [Rm ] − Rf ) = −wm,0 Var [Rm ]
i=1 bi
E [R] = Rz + λ 0 Σ−1
F cov (F , R)
Remarks:
I β = Σ−1F cov (F , R) is vector of betas (“factor loadings”, quantity of risky)
I λ is the vector of factor risk premia (the price of a unit of beta-risk)
I Rz is the return on a Σ−1F cov (F , R) = 0 asset; if ∃ Rf , then Rz = Rf
Beta Pricing Models
Remarks:
1. One can write a beta pricing model in terms of covariances:
E [R] = Rz + ψ 0 cov (F , R)
where ψ 0 = Σ−1
F λ
2. We can transform factors to have zero means, unit variances and to be
mutually uncorrelated:
E [R] = Rz + ψ 0 cov (G, R)
where ψ 0 = L−1 λ and G is the Gram-Schmidt orthogonalization of F (that is
G = L−1 (F − E [F ]), where L is the Cholesky decomposition of ΣF )
3. The number of factors is not uniquely determined; e.g. we can combine factors
in one single factor λ 0 Σ−1
F F
APT
cov (εi , ε` ) = 0
And so on...
Evidence shows that the first 3, 4 principal components are sufficient to
capture most of the variation (Roll and Ross, 1980)
Multifactor Models