This Content Downloaded From 82.76.225.235 On Tue, 28 Sep 2021 01:27:11 UTC
This Content Downloaded From 82.76.225.235 On Tue, 28 Sep 2021 01:27:11 UTC
Comments]
Author(s): Justin Yifu Lin, Anne Krueger and Dani Rodrik
Source: The World Bank Research Observer , August 2011, Vol. 26, No. 2 (August 2011),
pp. 193-229
Published by: Oxford University Press
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
The World Bank Research Observer
194 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: the next section examines
the evolution of development thinking and offers a critical review of some of its
main schools of thought. I then outline the basic principles and conceptual fra-
mework of the new structural economics, the function of the market, and the
roles of a facilitating state. In the next section I highlight similarities and differ-
ences between old and new structural economics, and discusses some preliminary
insights on major policy issues based on this new approach.
Lin 195
196 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Lin 197
198 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Lin 199
200 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Lin 201
The process of industrial upgrading and diversification also increases the level
of risk faced by firms. As firms move closer to the global technology frontier, it
becomes increasingly difficult for them to borrow mature technology from
advanced countries. They increasingly need to invent new technologies and pro-
ducts and thus face more risk. The idiosyncratic risk of a firm has three com-
ponents based on risk sources: technological innovation, product innovation, and
managerial capacity. At the early level of development, firms tend to use mature
technologies to produce mature products for mature markets. At that level, the
main source of risk is the managerial ability of firms' owner-operators. At a
higher level of development, firms often invent new technologies to produce new
products for new markets. In addition to managerial capacity, such firms face
risks arising from the maturity of technology and markets. Therefore, while tech-
nological innovation, product innovation, and managerial capacity all contribute
to the overall level of risk associated with firms, their relative importance varies
greatly from one industry to another and from one level of economic development
to another.
With changes in the size of firms, scope of the market, and nature of risk,
along with the upgrading of the industrial structure, the requirements for infra-
structure services, both hard and soft, also change. If the infrastructure is not
improved simultaneously, the upgrading process in various industries may face
the problem of x-inefficiency, a phenomenon discussed by Leibenstein (1957).
Because the industrial structure in an economy at a specific time is endogenous
to its given relative abundance of labor, capital, and natural resources at that
time, the economy's factor endowment will change with capital accumulation or
population growth, pushing its industrial structure to deviate from the optimal
determined by its previous level.4
When firms choose to enter industries and adopt technologies that are consist-
ent with the comparative advantage determined by changes in the country's
factor endowments,5 the economy is most competitive.6 As competitive industries
and firms grow, they claim larger domestic as well as international market shares
and create the greatest possible economic surplus in the form of profits and sal-
aries. Reinvested surpluses earn the highest return possible as well, because the
industrial structure is optimal for that endowment structure. Over time, this
approach allows the economy to accumulate physical and human capital,
202 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Lin 203
204 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
In terms of similarities, the "new" and the "old" structural economics are both
founded on structural differences between developed and developing countries
and acknowledge the active role of the state in facilitating the movement of the
economy from a lower level of development to a higher one. However, there are
profound differences between these two approaches regarding their targets and
the modalities of state intervention. The old structural economics advocates devel-
opment policies that go against an economy's comparative advantage and advise
governments in developing countries to develop advanced capital-intensive indus-
tries through direct administrative measures and price distortions. By contrast,
the new structural economics stresses the central role of the market in resource
allocation and advises the state to play a facilitating role to assist firms in the
process of industrial upgrading by addressing externality and coordination issues.
The differences between the two frameworks derive from their dissimilar views
on the sources of structural rigidities: old structural economics assumes that the
market failures that make the development of advanced capital-intensive indus-
tries difficult in developing countries are exogenously determined by structural
rigidities due to the existence of monopolies, labor's perverse response to price
signals, and/or the immobility of factors. By contrast, the new structural econ-
omics posits that the failure to develop advanced capital-intensive industries in
developing countries is endogenously determined by their endowments. The
Lin 205
206 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
The ultimate goal of development thinking is to provide policy advice that facili-
tates the quest for sustainable and inclusive economic and social progress in poor
countries. Although specific policy measures to be derived from the new struc-
tural economics approach will require further research and depend very much on
country context and circumstances, in this section I will make some conjectures
about a few preliminary insights on various topics.
Fiscal Policy. Until Britain's very high unemployment of the 1920s and the Great
Depression, economists generally held that the appropriate stance for fiscal policy
was for governments to maintain balanced budgets. The severity of the early
twentieth-century crises gave rise to the Keynesian idea of counter-cyclicality,
which suggested that governments should use tax and expenditure policies to
offset business cycles in the economy. By contrast, neoclassical economics offers
doubts about the implicit assumption behind the Keynesian model of a multiplier
greater than one8 and its implication that governments are able to do something
that the private sector has been unable to do: mobilize idle resources in the
economy (unemployed labor and capital) at almost zero social cost, that is, with
no corresponding decline in other parts of GDP (consumption, investment, and
net exports). Instead, they warn against the possibility of the so-called Ricardian
equivalence trap and point to the fact that households tend to adjust their behav-
ior for consumption or saving on the basis of expectations about the future. They
suggest that expansionary fiscal policy (stimulus packages) is perceived as
immediate spending or tax cuts that will need to be repaid in the future. They
conclude that the multiplier could be less than 1 in situations where the GDP is
given and an increase in government spending does not lead to an equal rise in
other parts of GDP The neoclassical paradigm even suggests the possibility of
some rare instances where multipliers are negative, pointing to situations where
fiscal contractions become expansionary (Francesco and Pagano 1991).
From the viewpoint of new structural economics, the effects of fiscal policy
may be different in developed and developing countries due to the differences in
opportunities of using counter-cyclical expenditure for making productivity-
enhanced investments. Physical infrastructure in general is a binding constraint
for growth in developing countries and governments need to play a critical role in
Lin 207
208 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 201 1)
Lin 209
210 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Lin 211
212 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Lin 213
Concluding Thoughts
The new structural economics approach highlights the importance of endow-
ments and differences in industrial structures at various levels of development
and the implications of distortions stemming from past, misguided, interventions
by policymakers whose belief in old structural economics led them to over-esti-
mate governments' ability to correct market failures. It also points out the fact
that policies advocated under the Washington Consensus often failed to take into
consideration the structural differences between developed and developing
countries and ignored the second-best nature of reforming various types of distor-
tions in developing countries.
The proposed new structural economics attempts to develop a general frame-
work for understanding the causality behind the observed stylized facts of sus-
tained growth. Specifically, the new structural economics proposes to: (i) develop
an analytical framework that takes into account factor and infrastructure endow-
ments, the levels of development, and the corresponding industrial, social, and
economic structures of developing countries; (ii) analyze the roles of the state and
the market at each development level and the mechanics of the transition from
one level to another; and (iii) focus on the causes of economic distortions and the
government's strategies for exit from the distortions. It is not an attempt to substi-
tute another ideologically based policy framework for those that have dominated
development thinking in past decades, yet showing little connection to the empiri-
cal realities of individual countries. Rather, it is an approach that brings attention
to the endowment structure and level of development of each country and
suggests a path toward country-based research that is rigorous, innovative, and
relevant to development policy. This framework stresses the need to understand
better the implications of structural differences at various levels of a country's
development - especially in terms of the appropriate institutions and policies, and
the constraints and incentives for the private sector in the process of structural
change.
The current state of development economics and the severe impact of the
global crisis on the economies of developing countries have generated strong
demand for a new framework for development thinking. The research agenda of
214 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Acknowledgements
Celestin Monga provided invaluable help in preparing this paper. The paper al
benefits from discussions and comments from Gary Becker, Otaviano Canuto, H
Joon Chang, Luiz Pereira Da Silva, Augusto de la Torre, Christian Delvoie, Asi
Demirgiiç-Kunt, Shantayanan Devarajan, Hinh T. Dinh, Shahrokh Fardoust, Arie
Fiszbein, Robert Fogel, Alan Gelb, Indermit S. Gill, Ann Harrison, James
Heckman, Aart Kraay, Auguste Taño Kouame, Norman V Loayza, Frank J. Lysy
Shiva S. Makki, William F. Maloney, Mustapha Kamel Nabli, Vikram Nehru
Howard Pack, Nadia Piffaretti, Claudia Paz Sepulveda, Martin Ravallion,
Mohammad Zia M. Qureshi, Sergio Schmukler, Luis Serven, and Harald Uhlig. I
am also grateful for the editor and three referees for helpful comments and
suggestions.
Notes
Justin Yifu Lin is Senior Vice President and Chief Economist of the World Bank; email address:
justinlin@worldbank.org.
1. The paper was presented as the Kuznets Lecture at the Economic Growth Center, Yale
University on March 1, 2011. The main arguments of this paper were first presented at DEC's
fourth Lead Economists Meeting and at Lin's first anniversary at the Bank on June 2, 2009. A
shorter version of the paper was presented at the conference on "Challenges and Strategies for
Promoting Economic Growth," organized by the Banco de México in Mexico City on October 19-
20, 2009, and at public lectures in Cairo University on November 5, 2009, Korean Development
Institute on November 17, 2009, OECD on December 8, 2009, UNU-WIDER on January 19, 2010,
Stockholm Institute of Transitional Economics on January 21, 2010, National University of
Management in Cambodia on September 8, 2010, Bank of Italy on April 26, 2011, and University
of Dar es Salaam on April 29, 2011.
2. I will refer to the early contributions by structuralist economists such as Prebisch (1950) and
Furtado (1964, 1970) and recent contributions by structuralist economists such as Taylor (1983,
1991, 2004) and Justman and Gurion (1991) as old structural economics.
3. The total endowments at a specific time - the economy's total budgets at that time and the
endowment structure, together with the households' preferences and firms' available production
technologies - determine the relative factor and product prices in the economy. Total budgets and
relative prices are two of the most fundamental parameters in economic analysis. Moreover, the
endowments are given at any specific time and are changeable over time. These properties make
endowments and the endowment structure the best starting point for analysis of economic
Lin 215
216 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Lin 217
The word processed describes informally reproduced works that may not be com-
monly available through libraries.
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J.A. Robinson. 2001. "The Colonial Origins of Comparative
Development: An Empirical Investigation." American Economic Review 91:1369-401.
Aghion, R, and E Howitt. 1992. 'A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction." Econometrica
60(2): 323-51.
Barro, RJ. 2009. "Government Spending Is No Free Lunch." The Wall Street Journal, January 22.
Becker, Gary S. 1975. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to
Education. 2nd edn. New York: Columbia University Press for NBER.
Caprio, G., and E Honohan. 2001. Finance for Growth: Policy Choices in a Volatile World. New York:
World Bank and Oxford University Press.
Cardoso, E., and A. Helwege. 1995. Latin Americas Economu Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Carneiro, E, and J.J. Heckman. 2003. 'Human Capital Policy'. IZA Discussion Eapers 821, Institute
for the Study of Labor (IZA).
Chang, EK. 1949. Agriculture and Industrialization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Domar, E. 1946. "Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment." Econometrica 14, (April):
137-47.
Easterly, W 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and Misadvent
Tropics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Easterly, W, N. Loayza, and PJ. Montiel. 1997. "Has Latin America's Post-Reform Gr
Disappointing?" World Bank Policy Research Paper 1708, World Bank, Washington
August.
Eichengreen, В., M. Mussa, G. Dell' Ariccia, E. Detragiache, G.M. Milesi-Ferretti, and A. Tweedie.
1999. Liberalizing Capital Movements: Some Analytical Issues. Economie Issues no. 17. IMF,
Washington, D.C.
Francesco, G., and M. Pagano. 1991. "Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? - Tales of
Two Small European Countries." In O.J. Blanchard and S. Fischer, NBER Macroeconomics Annual
1990. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Furtado, С. 1964. Development and Underdevelopment. Los Angeles: University of California Press.
218 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Hirschman, A.O. 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Jones, C.I. 1998. Introduction to Economic Growth. New York: WW Norton.
Jones, C.I., and EM. Romer. 2009. "The New Kaldor Facts: Ideas, Institutions, Population, and
Human Capital." NBER Working Paper Series 15094.
Ju, J., J.Y. Lin, and Y. Wang. 2009. "Endowment Structures, Industrial Dynamics, and Economic
Growth." Policy Research Working Papers Series 5055, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Justman, M., and B. Gurion. 1991. "Structuralist Perspective on the Role of Technology in
Economic Growth and Development." World Development 19(9): 1167-83.
Kanbur, R. 2009. "The Crisis, Economic Development Thinking, and Protecting the Poor."
Presentation to the World Bank's Executive Board, July.
Krueger, A. 1974. "The Political Economy of Rent-Seeking Society." American Economic Review
64(3): 291-303.
Krugman, E 1979. "A Model of Innovation, Technology Transfer, and the World Distribution of
Income." Journal of Political Economy 87(2): 253-66.
Kuznets, S. 1966. Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure and Spread. New Haven, C
University Press.
Lau, L.J., Y. Qian, and G. Roland. 2000. "Reform without Losers: An Interpretation of Chin
track Approach to Transition." Journal of Political Economy 108(1): 120-43.
Leibenstein, H. 1957. Economic Backwardness and Economic Growth: Studies in the Theory of
Development. New York: Wiley.
Lewis, WA. 1954. "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor." The Manc
School, May.
Lin, J.Y. 2009a. Economic Development and Transition: Thought, Strategy, and Viability. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Lin 219
Monga, С. 1997. L'argent des autres - Banques et petites entreprises en Afrique: le cas du Cameroun.
Paris: LDGJ-Montchretien.
Myrdal, G. 1957. Economie Theory and Under-developed Regions. London: Duckworth.
Naughton, В. 1995. Growing Out of Plan: Chinese Economic Reform 1978-1993. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Nurkse, R. 1953. Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Ramsey, F.E 1928. "A Mathematical Theory of Saving." Economic Journal 38 (152): 543-59.
Ravallion, M. 2009. "Evaluation in the Practice of Development." The World Bank Research Observer
24(1): 29-53.
Rodrik, D. 2004. "Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century." Cambridge, MA. [http://ksghome.
harvard.edu/~drodrik/unidosep.pdf] .
Romer, EM. 1987. "Growth Based on Increasing Returns Due to Specialization." American Economic
Review 77(2): 56-62.
220 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 201 1)
publications/papers/paper.cfm?ResearchID=488].
World Bank. 2005. Economic Growth in the 1990s:
D.C.: World Bank.
Lm 221
Anne Krueger
Ever since development economics became a field, there has been a search for
"the" key to development. Physical capital accumulation, human capital, indus-
trial development, institutional quality, social capital, and a variety of other
factors have been the focus at one time or another. As each became the focal
point, there was a parallel explicit or implied role of government.
If I understand Justin Lin correctly, he is saying that the "new structural econ-
omics" (NSE) accepts that earlier thought ignored comparative advantage, which
should be market determined, but that growth requires improvements in 'hard'
(tangible) and 'soft' (intangible) infrastructure at each stage. Such upgrading and
improvements require coordination and inhere with large externalities to firms'
transaction costs and returns to capital investment. Thus, in addition to an effec-
tive market mechanism, the government should play an active role in facilitating
structural change (p. 206).
He seems also to believe that growth depends almost entirely on industry
growth and believes that constant "upgrading" or moving up the value added
chain is the central challenge. He says that "the laissez-faire approach . . . missed
the importance of the process of continuous, fundamental technological changes
and industrial upgrading, which distinguishes modern economic growth from
premodern economic growth" (p. 196).
It is questionable whether such changes and upgrading must take place early
in the development process. In many countries, unskilled labor has moved to
unskilled-labor-intensive industries, with expansion of those industries' outputs
for a period during which more and more workers acquired acquaintance with
modern factory techniques, and exports of the unskilled-labor-intensive goods
Krueger 223
224 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Krueger 225
Reference
Baldwin, Robert E. 1969. "The Case against Infant Industry Protection." Journal of Political Economy
77(3): 295-305.
226 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 26, no. 2 (August 2011)
Dani Rodrik
Justin Lin wants to make structuralist economics respectable again, and I applaud
him for that. He wants to marry structuralism with neoclassical economic reason-
ing, and I applaud this idea too. So he has two cheers from me. I withhold my
third cheer so I can quibble with some of what he writes.
The central insight of structuralism is that developing countries are qualitat-
ively different from developed ones. They are not just radially shrunk versions of
rich countries. In order to understand the challenges of under-development, you
have to understand how the structure of employment and production - in par-
ticular the large gaps between the social marginal products of labor in traditional
versus modern activities - is determined and how the obstacles that block struc-
tural transformation can be overcome.
The central insight of neoclassical economics is that people respond to incen-
tives. We need to understand the incentives of, say, teachers to show up for work
and impart valuable skills to their students or of entrepreneurs to invest in new
economic activities if we are going to have useful things to say to governments
about what they ought to do. (And of course, leťs not forget that government offi-
cials must have the incentive to do the economically "correct" things too.)
If we put these two sets of ideas together, we can have a useful development
economics, one that does not dismiss the tools of contemporary economic analysis
and yet is sensitive to the specific circumstances of developing economies. This is
the kind of development economics that is appropriately nuanced in its take on
government intervention. It doesn't presume omniscience or altruism on the part
of governments. It has a healthy respect for the power and effectiveness of
markets. But it does not blithely assume that development is an automatic
process that takes care of itself as long as government stays out of the picture.
Note
Dani Rodrik is professor of international political economy at Harvard University's John F. Kennedy
School of Government (dani_rodrik@harvard.edu).
Rodrik 229