10306104
10306104
2003
Thorsten Fischer , David R. Kamerschen
MEASURING COMPETITION IN THE U.S. AIRLINE INDUSTRY
USING THE ROSSE-PANZAR TEST AND CROSS-SECTIONAL
REGRESSION ANALYSES
Journal of Applied Economics. Mayo. Vol. 6. Núm. 1
Universidad del CEMA
Buenos Aires, Argentina
pp. 73-93
http://redalyc.uaemex.mx
Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. VI, No. 1 (May 2003), 73-93
MEASURING COMPETITION IN THE U.S. AIRLINE INDUSTRY 73
THORSTEN FISCHER*
Economy.com, Inc.
and
DAVID R. KAMERSCHEN*
The University of Georgia
*
The authors are Economist, Economy.com, Inc., and Distinguished Professor of Economics
and Jasper N. Dorsey Chairholder, Terry College of Business, The University of Georgia,
respectively. We are heavily indebted to Drs. Scott E. Atkinson, Charles D. DeLorme, Jr.,
Claudia E. Halabi, Donald C. Keenan, Peter G. Klein, David B. Robinson, and an
anonymous referee for their ideas and suggestions.
74 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
I. Introduction
The U.S. airline industry has experienced revolutionary change in the last
two decades moving from strict regulation to modest regulation, now allowing
airlines to decide such things as their pricing strategies, frequency of schedule,
and entry into and exit from markets. However, access to some key inputs,
such as airport boarding sites, is still determined by non-market or regulatory
conditions. Proponents of deregulation expected better performance through
enhanced competition, resulting in higher productivity, lower costs, lower
fares, and better service. This optimism has been largely fulfilled as the U.S.
airline industry in recent years has had steady growth, falling prices, more
convenient schedules, and moderate concentration, although profits have been
rather volatile (see, e.g., Bailey, 2002, Gowrisankaran, 2002). It can be argued
that since the late 1980s and early 1990s, the industry has settled into a new
equilibrium. The vital and challenging question is whether this (less than
ideal) deregulated market performed better than before, or whether there still
exists market power and market conduct that are less optimal than previously.
This paper examines the economics underlying the U.S. airline industry,
and its development and evolution since deregulation. More specifically, this
paper studies the pricing strategy, market conduct, and market performance
in the U.S. airline industry in recent years. Two empirical models are employed,
each with a different focus and methodology. The level of analysis is on the
micro-level, concentrating on the firm and airport-pair level. This enables a
more detailed and precise approach to the study of market conduct than would
be feasible with more aggregated data.
The statistical analysis is restricted to airport-pairs originating in Atlanta.
Atlanta is an appropriate choice for conducting such a study for several reasons.
First, Atlanta serves as a major hub for Delta Air Lines, one of the nation’s
largest carriers. Delta accounts for more than eighty percent of all departures
and arrivals at Atlanta’s Hartsfield International airport. Therefore, any effects
that a dominant firm may have on the market’s competitiveness are captured.
Second, Atlanta is an important market for all other major U.S. carriers that
compete with Delta by offering one-stop service to most cities connecting
through their respective hubs. Third, Atlanta has experienced entry by a
remarkably successful lowcost carrier, ValuJet Airlines, which started in 1993
MEASURING COMPETITION IN THE U.S. AIRLINE INDUSTRY 75
and grew rapidly. At its peak, it served almost 30 markets and used more than
50 aircraft. After the loss of one of its planes in May 1996, ValuJet was
grounded for approximately three months and is still struggling to rebuild its
former position. ValuJet faced severe restrictions imposed by regulators on
its growth opportunities. Furthermore, consumer confidence in its safety and
reliability suffered immensely. In July 1997, Valujet Inc., the parent of ValuJet
Airlines, announced plans to merge with Florida-based Airways Corp., parent
of AirTran Airways. The merger took effect with the larger carrier, ValuJet,
adopting the smaller carrier’s name, AirTran, to eliminate any association
with the crash. The Orlando-based AirTran Airways with its hub in Atlanta
has experienced steady growth and consolidated its position as a successful
provider of lowcost air travel. Early in 2000, it took delivery of the first of 50
new-generation Boeing 717 aircraft, in pursuit of its strategy of growth and
modernization of its fleet. In 2002, AirTran was named Airline of the Year
for the fourth consecutive year by the American Society of Travel Agents.
The trade group said it honored the discount airline for creating an Internet
booking engine aimed at travel agents, and for continuing to provide
competition in the industry. Most big carriers, including Delta, eliminated
base travel agent commissions in 2002. Of course, what long-run impact the
terrorist attacks on the U.S. on September 11, 2001, will have on AirTran and
indeed the entire U.S. airline industry is hard to predict at this time.
Our format provides an interesting opportunity to study market conduct
in different competitive environments: markets where Delta is the only carrier,
markets where Delta competes with other majors, and finally markets where
Delta competes against a lowcost, start-up carrier. Anecdotal evidence suggests
that after the grounding of ValuJet, airfares in certain markets rose sharply.
One well-publicized example is the route linking Atlanta and Mobile, AL,
where the coach fare rose from $79 to more than $400. Some communities in
the Southeast provided financial incentives to ValuJet to induce the carrier to
serve their airports.
New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) research identifies and
estimates the degree of market power, specifies and estimates the behavioral
equations that drive price and quantity, and often infers marginal cost or
measures market power without it. NEIO studies emphasize individual
industries, because institutional details make broad cross-section studies of
76 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
over the 24 quarters from January 1991 to December 1996. Finally, a cross-
section regression model is employed to supplement the studies on market
structure, to provide additional insight into pricing strategies, and to explore
the factors that influence the price of air travel.
Section II presents an approach to testing for monopoly behavior, the Rosse-
Panzar test, which allows for a first impression regarding market conduct.
Section III implements the Rosse-Panzar test empirically and presents the
results. Section IV presents a cross-section regression for the Atlanta market
to assess the impact of a lowcost carrier on fares. Section V briefly concludes
with the major findings.
Rosse and Panzar (1977) and Panzar and Rosse (1987) introduce a series
of tests based on properties of reduced-form revenue equations at the firm
level on which the hypothesis of monopoly or oligopoly profit maximization
places testable restrictions.1 The data requirements, consisting of revenues
and factor prices, are relatively modest. The following model is taken from
Panzar and Rosse (1987) and follows their development of the test closely.
Let q be a vector of decision variables that affect a firm’s revenue. In the
most natural case q would describe a vector of output quantities. Let z denote
a vector of variables that are exogenous to the firm and shift the firm’s revenue
function. The firm’s cost function also depends on q, so that C = C (q, w, t),
where w is a vector of factor prices also taken as given by the firm and t is a
vector of exogenous variables that shift the firm’s cost curve.2 It follows that
the firm’s profit function is given by
π = R − C = π (q, z , w, t ) (1)
Let q0 be the argument that maximizes this profit function. Also, let q1 be
1
For an extension of the Rosse and Panzar test when variables besides the firms’ revenues
are observable, see Sullivan (1985) and Ashenfelter and Sullivan (1987).
2
While this cost function ignores efficiencies generated by hubs, these cost complementaries
do not make the Rosse-Panzar result inapplicable.
78 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
Using the fact that the cost function is linearly homogeneous in w, this can be
written as
and that
( R1 − R0 ) / h = [ R* ( z, (1 + h) w, t ) − R* ( z, w, t ) / h] ≤ 0 (4)
This is the non-parametric result that indicates that a proportional cost increase
will result in a decrease of the firm’s revenues. Assuming that the reduced-
form revenue equation is differentiable, taking the limit of (4) for h → 0 and
dividing by R* yields
where the wi are the components of the vector w, so that wi denotes the price
of the ith input factor.
This describes a restriction imposed on a profit-maximizing monopoly.
The sum of the factor price elasticities of the reduced-form revenue equation
cannot be positive. Intuitively, the question that the test statistic ψ* tries to
answer is what is the percentage change in the firm’s equilibrium revenue
resulting from a one-percent increase in all factor prices. An increase in factor
prices shifts all cost curves, including the marginal cost curve, up.
Consequently, the price charged by the monopolist goes up and the quantity
decreases. Since the monopolist operates on the elastic portion of the demand
curve, total revenue decreases. Hence, ψ* is non-positive. The generality of
the result causes one drawback for the test. Even for “monopolies” facing a
MEASURING COMPETITION IN THE U.S. AIRLINE INDUSTRY 79
perfectly elastic demand curve, the value for ψ* is less than zero. All firms
which operate in isolation, that is, all firms whose structural revenue functions
do not depend on any other agent’s decisions, will show a test statistic that is
non-positive. Therefore, a rejection of the hypothesis that ψ* is less than zero
must indicate that the firm is affected by other agents’ actions.
The next question, then, is whether there exist any models consistent with
an estimate for ψ greater than zero. Fortunately, this is the case. Rosse and
Panzar cite three models of equilibrium consistent with a positive value for ψ.
In all three models, the revenue function facing the firm depends on the action
of potential or actual rivals. In other words, the firm no longer acts in isolation.
The results for the models depend crucially on the assumption that the observed
firms be in long-run equilibrium. We will restrict our attention to two additional
models that are interesting with respect to airlines. First, the benchmark case
of the long-run competitive equilibrium is examined, and subsequently the
conjectural variation oligopoly is explored. Unless some kind of interaction
between firms is introduced into the model dealing with perfect competition,
price-taking behavior will lead to a ψ* less than zero. The output price that a
firm faces, therefore, is endogenized by allowing for competitive entry and exit.
This model has been discussed most prominently by Silberberg (1974). The
reasoning is as follows. Changes in factor prices will, at least in the longrun,
lead to exit or entry and consequently to changes in output prices. These changes
in turn will affect input demand and output supply decisions of the firm.
For firms observed in long-run equilibrium, the sum of the elasticities of
reduced form revenues with respect to factor prices equals unity (Rosse and
Panzar, 1987). The intuition behind this result is that a one-percent increase
in all factor prices will result in an equal-proportional that is one-percent,
increase in total revenue. Because average cost is homogeneous of degree
one in w, a one-percent increase in all factor prices will shift the average cost
curve up by one percent for all output levels. Consequently, the minimum
point is unchanged. Since in long-run competitive equilibrium the firm operates
at minimum average cost, the competitive output qc remains unchanged.
However, in equilibrium, the competitive price pc must be equal to minimum
average cost, which has increased by one percent. Therefore, pc must have
increased by one per cent also, driving up total revenues by the same
percentage. Therefore the condition that ψc be equal to one is established.
80 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
Contrast this with the result if firms are not in long-run equilibrium. More
specifically, assume we observe a firm after the one-percent increase in all
factor prices, but before any firms have exited from the market. The firm will
respond by reducing output while the price remains initially unchanged, thus
resulting in a decrease in total revenues. Hence, in the shortrun, ψ is less or
equal to zero. Only after some firms exit does the price go up to the new long-
run equilibrium level and is output restored to its original level. This should
underline the importance of the long-run equilibrium assumption.
The final point to be made is that a conjectural variations oligopoly model
that exhibits strategic interactions among a fixed number of rivals may also be
consistent with positive values of ψ. Only if the oligopoly behaves close to a
joint monopoly, that is, if firms collude, is the marginal industry revenue
positive.
In summary, we have provided a non-structural test for the existence of
monopoly power, and we have derived three important results.3 First, the
sum of elasticities of revenue with respect to each input price is negative in
monopoly or collusive (joint monopoly) equilibrium. It is also negative in
short-run competitive equilibrium. Moreover, it is equal to unity in long-run
competitive equilibrium and indeterminate in a general conjectural variation
oligopoly equilibrium. These implications can be tested empirically. For
instance, a finding of a test statistic Ψ that is positive, would rule out monopoly
or a collusive cartel equilibrium.
A profit-maximizing monopolist operating on the elastic portion (η < -1)
will exhibit a negative value for Ψ. It also demonstrates that a negative sign
cannot rule out competition since a competitive firm tends to face an even
more elastic demand curve. Using the result obtained previously, Shaffer
(1982a), Shaffer (1983a) derives the Lerner index (Lj) in terms of the Rosse-
Panzar test statistic where sj is firm j’s market share.
3
While the focus of empirical IO has shifted away from identifying conjectures parameters
in simply quantity-setting models to identifying demand and costs in differentiated price-
setting models, we think the conjectures equilibrium framework with quantity competition
and the cross-sectional regressions are still a useful methodology. To see the newer focus,
see, e.g., Berry’s 1992 paper on airline competition where he estimates a model of customer
heterogeneity (business vs. leisure) which is important in this industry because of price
discrimination.
MEASURING COMPETITION IN THE U.S. AIRLINE INDUSTRY 81
We obtain the Lerner index for an individual firm and for the industry as a
whole, respectively.
L j = 1 /(1 − Ψ j ) (6)
and
L = ( H + Σ s 2j λ j ) / s j (1 + λ j ) (1 − Ψ j (7)
Equations (6) and (7) express the firm and industry Lerner indices, respectively,
as a function of market share, the conjectural variation parameter λ and the
Rosse-Panzar test statistic H. The firm’s Lerner index depends only on the
test statistic, which is independent of market share or the conduct parameter.
The result is valid only as long as the short-run equilibrium is considered,
that is, changes in total revenue due to changes in factor prices before entry
and exit occur. In a further paper, Shaffer (1983b) extends his result found in
1982 to a more general connection between the Rosse-Panzar statistic and
the price elasticity of demand.
The reduced-form revenue equation has been used as a test of market
power among others by Shaffer (1982b), Nathan and Neave (1989), and Shaffer
and DiSalvo (1994). In all cases, the test has been applied to the banking
industry. Furthermore, Shaffer and DiSalvo apply both tests, i.e. the conjectural
variations oligopoly and the Rosse-Panzar test, to a duopoly banking market
in Pennsylvania. This is a procedure we follow.
where i = 1,..., 4 denotes inputs and the subscript j denotes airlines. TR denotes
total revenue, q denotes output and w denotes factor prices. The parameters
to be estimated are b0, b1 and c1 through ci.
The equations are estimated separately for each carrier using a generalized
methods of moments approach. We employ price and quantity data for
outbound traffic, year dummies and their interaction term as instruments for
inbound traffic, and inbound data as instruments for outbound data. The
instruments make for a very good fit, since they are highly correlated with the
right-hand variables and almost uncorrelated with the error term. It is clear
from equation (8) that the sum of the estimates for ci yields the required test
statistic Ψ.
RP-Statistic Standard
City - Pair
(outbound) errors*
RP-Statistic Standard
City - Pair
(outbound) errors*
Note: *All coefficients have a significantly positive test statistic, which is also significantly
different from one.
84 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
RP-Statistic Standard
City - Pair
(inbound) errors*
RP-Statistic Standard
City - Pair
(inbound) errors*
Note: *All coefficients have a significantly positive test statistic, which is also significantly
different from one.
Tables 1 and 2 present the Rosse-Panzar test statistic and its standard
error for the 29 airport-pairs by outbound traffic and inbound traffic,
respectively. In our empirical testing for Rosse-Panzar and for cross-sectional
regressions in the next section, we employ quarterly price indices constructed
from raw data provided by the DOT’s Form 41 as Air Carrier Financial
Statistics, and Air Carrier Traffic Statistics. The price indices for labor, fuel,
and materials are constructed using index number theory. The price of capital
in contrast is constructed by employing the Capital Asset Pricing Model
(CAPM). The CAPM computes the correct risk-adjusted return for a risky
asset within the framework of mean-variance portfolio theory. Since it
provides an economic measure of the price of capital and reflects the true
risk-adjusted opportunity cost, it is vastly superior to conventional accounting
measures for the price of capital.4 Price data were derived from Database
1A of the DOT’s origin and destination survey (O&D). The sample period
4
For a more detailed discussion of how the price of capital is calculated, see Fischer and
Kamerschen (2002).
86 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
covers the 24 quarters between the first quarter of 1991 and the fourth quarter
of 1996.
Church and Ware (1999) point out that the Rosse-Panzar test shows what
the market structure or degree of monopoly is not and does not suggest what
is. Following this approach, we can rule out monopoly and perfect competition
for all airport-pairs that have a significantly positive test statistic, which is also
significantly different from 1. This is clearly the case for the majority of the
airport-pairs. Thus, the finding for these airport-pairs is consistent with the
structural model, which indicates conduct somewhere in between the collusive
solution, i.e. monopoly, and perfect competition. A closer look at the airport-
pairs with significantly negative estimates for the test statistic is warranted.
Recall that a negative test statistic can imply both competition or monopoly.
The airport-pairs that require closer scrutiny are Delta in the Detroit market
(inbound only), Memphis, Miami, Chicago O’Hare, and Philadelphia; United
in the Washington-Dulles market, US Air in Pittsburgh (inbound only) and
American for Miami and Chicago O’ Hare. Any further investigation into
market structure with the Rosse-Panzar test statistic remains inconclusive.
Finally, the magnitude of the estimates seems too large if one wants to follow
Shaffer’s suggestion regarding the estimation of the Lerner index. The estimates
obtained seem to preclude this estimation. However, the estimates are very
robust to changes in the specification of the model. Any potential explanation
of the magnitude of the estimates will have to explore in greater detail two
assumptions that could lead to implausibly high values for the test statistic. The
first is the assumption that the air carrier is a price taker on the input side. There
is some evidence that this is not the case, particularly for the input labor. Heavy
unionization and widespread collective bargaining suggest that airlines face a
less than competitive market for their labor inputs. The second is the assumption
that the industry is in long-run equilibrium. Recall that such an assumption is
crucial for the Rosse-Panzar test to work. Shaffer (1982a, b) explicitly points
to the almost contradictory nature of the assumptions that all observations are
identified, and controlled for as being in long-run equilibrium. In particular,
when working with a time-series sample like the airport-pair markets, any
change in factor prices involves some adjustment, which is unlikely to be
completed exactly by the end of the observed period. However, it is precisely
this variation in prices that is needed to identify the test statistic.
MEASURING COMPETITION IN THE U.S. AIRLINE INDUSTRY 87
B. A Cross-Section Regression
+ b8 VACATION
where YIELD is defined as price divided by distance. That is, YIELD measures
the average fare charged by the observed carrier on the given route, divided
by stage length so as to obtain the price per mile and normalize across different
stage lengths. PASSENGERS is equal to the number of passengers transported
on the route during a quarter. It measures the total number of all local origin-
to-destination passenger. DISTANCE measures the stage length between the
departure and arrival cities. AVERAGECOST is a proxy for the cost-
competitiveness of the airline offering the service and is measured in average
cost per seat mile. Adjustments are made to account for different average
stage lengths across carriers. INCOME is a measure of disposable personal
income for the metropolitan statistical area of the destination. It is included to
capture aggregate income at the destination. MARKETSHARE captures the
market share that the airline commands on a given route. It measures the
share of all local origin-to-destination passengers for the observed carrier on
88 JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS
Coefficient Standard
Variable
error*
Note: * Examining the p-values corresponding to the appropriate t-value shows that all
coefficients are significant at the 1% or better level.
IV. Conclusions
References