Theory & Politics of Development Ch-1&2
Theory & Politics of Development Ch-1&2
Although we cannot be sure about when the concept originated, most people agree that
development is closely related with the evolution of capitalism and the demise of feudalism.
The concept of development is very elusive (difficult to understand in its totality).
Development has many meanings. Thus, in order to understand the various theories of
development, one must see them from the historical and contextual perspectives. The terms
"Developed", "Underdeveloped", "Undeveloped", and "Less Developed" are used to denote
the social and economic conditions of countries.
However, whoever tries to describe the term "development" should incorporate ideas in a
manner that it can be perceived as: researches
1) A condition of life,
2) A goal to be achieved, and
3) A capacity to grow and change
These three points or ideas should be bound together in all efforts to understand and deal with
the theory and practice of development.
i) The Everest Reason:- "Why did you climb Mount Everest?" Answer: "Because it was
there!" The developing world constitutes the vast majority of the world's territory,
hence it is not only important to correct such imbalances, but also is a must to be
worried about to understand the impacts of lack of it and find ways of its realization.
ii) Human Compassion: Approximately, 75% of the world population lives in developing
countries and in below standard and sub-standard conditions. Human compassion
dictates that understanding development and being able to apply that knowledge to help
those in such conditions is a useful endeavor.
iii) Terrorism: Recent events have brought to forefront the threats and impacts of global
terrorism and that many of those involved individuals come from the developing world.
Thus, development can be a tool in the war on terrorism.
The dominant meanings have been those attributed by economists. Development has thus
been equated with economic development, and economic development in turn with economic
growth or simply growth. Upon economic considerations, Coffey defined development as
"sustained and irreversible economic growth, which will be characterized in quantitative
terms by an increase in real income per capita…accompanied by certain structural and social
transformations of a given country".
However, defining development on the basis of the economic growth model or approach has
shortcomings, since it doesn't show the real impact of the growth on the public life. Economic
growth is not just the same thing as development and the difference between the two has been
identified by many recent contributions to development economics. For example, Todaro
(1994) and Nelson (1970) do not agree with the equivalent meanings of economic growth and
development. They instead argue that acceleration of economic growth would make sense
only when it ensures the reduction of inequality and the eradication of absolute poverty.
Despite progress in Per Capita Income, GNP, or GDP in many developing nations, disparities
in the living conditions between rich and poor countries and between the richest and poorest
people within the developing countries continue to widen, and the absolute number of the
poor increases overtime (Rondinelli, 1993:1).
According to Des Gasper (2004:2), it is a bare fact that ‘globalization’ is generating great
wealth these days, which could be used to massively reduce poverty worldwide and to reduce
global inequality. However, the reverse is still happening in practice.
“The world’s richest 225 people have a combined wealth equal to the annual
income of the poorest 47 per cent of the world’s people. Almost one in four of the
world’s population lives in abject poverty without access to adequate food, clean
water, sanitation, essential healthcare, or basic education services. This tells that
1.3 billion people whose lives are blighted by poverty, robbed of their dignity,
deprived of the opportunity to fulfill their potential”
In recent years, there has come a wide consensus in that development should primarily mean,
and be measured in terms of an improvement in the general welfare situation of the people
through poverty reduction. Starting from the 1970s in particular, development came to be
redefined in terms of the reduction or elimination of poverty, inequality and
unemployment. Hence, “redistribution from growth” became a common slogan. This is a
shift away from the earlier understanding of the meaning, measurement and objective of
development.
It broadly implies social transformations involving complex economic, social, political, and
cultural changes towards positive ends. Riggs (1964) defined development as "a process of
increasing autonomy (discretion) of social systems by raising the level of diffraction. While
'discretion' is the ability to choose among alternatives, 'diffraction' refers to the degree of
differentiation and integration in a social system". Development, as Montgomery also
describes, "…is usually perceived as an aspect of ‘good’ change that is desirable, broadly
predicted or planned and administered or influenced by government action".
If development means good change; i.e. ‘societal improvement’, questions arise about what is
good and what sorts of change matter. Robert Chambers (2005:184-193) has added a new
concept for a development agenda; that, development is change with “responsible well-
being”.
According to Des Gasper (2004:14), the very idea of development as societal improvement is
value relative, which justifies the need for the study of development ethics. Development
ethics is also defined as ‘the normative or ethical assessment of the means and ends of
development’.
Galtung (1980), quoted in Gasper (2004), defined development as, “a process transforming
structures – particularly those of production-consumption and major institutions – so that
basic human needs are satisfied for an increasing number of individuals at an increasingly
high level within the framework meaning provided by culture and the outer limits provided
by nature.
Todaro has come also with a new concept known as the "core values'' of development, which
represent common goals sought by all individuals and societies. In his words, at least three
basic components or core values should serve as a conceptual basis and practical guideline
for understanding the inner meaning of development. These core values are: sustenance, self-
esteem, and freedom,
i) Sustenance: by sustenance, he meant the ability to meet basic needs that people invariably
have without which life would be impossible. These life-sustaining basic human needs
include food, shelter, health, and protection. When any of these is absent, or in critically
short supply, a condition of "absolute underdevelopment" exists. Here, therefore, we may
claim that economic development is a necessary condition for the improvement in the
quality of life, and that is what should be called 'development'.
ii) Self-esteem is used to denote 'to be a person", a sense of worth and self-respect, dignity,
identity, honor, recognition, of not being used as a tool by others for their own ends. The
nature and form of this self-esteem may vary from society to society and from culture to
culture. However, with the expansion of the "modern values" of developed nations, many
societies in the Third World Countries that have had profound sense of their own worth
suffer from serious cultural confusion when they establish close contact with economically
and technologically advanced societies.
iii) Freedom from servitude (from suppression or from obeying by others' interest) means to
be emancipated from alienating material conditions, or to be able to choose from an
expanded range of options available for societies together with the minimization of external
constraints in the pursuit of some social goals, which we call development. The advantage
of economic growth is not that wealth increases happiness, but that it increases the range of
human choices. Wealth can enable people to gain greater control over nature and the
physical environment than they would have if they remained poor.
Despite differences in the political and development patterns of countries, (both in the
developed and developing ones), there is a widely shared consensus among people and
leaders regarding the goals and objectives of development. Many scholars in the field of
comparative administration (development administration) agree that the two major elements
of development objectives are “nation-building and socio-economic progress”. Esman (1966)
describes nation-building as "the deliberate fashioning of an integrated political community
within the fixed geographic boundary in which the nation-state is the dominant political
institution, while economic and social progress is defined as the sustained and widely
diffused improvement of social welfare".
Therefore, the emphasis of recent arguments is on clarifying the target and purpose of
development; i.e. the well-being of all people by providing them with the opportunities to
ensure better life. In this context, Wen (1976: 355) argued, "...development will not have
moral as well as practical validity or justifications unless it is firmly subordinated
(associated) to supreme social objectives, namely, the preservation of humanity and
improvements in the quality of life of the poor". Hence, development as a process involves
integration of social and economic objectives; i.e. growth with equity.
i) Livelihood Security: Livelihood can be defined as adequate stocks and flows of food
and income to meet basic needs and to support well-being. Security refers to assured
rights, physical safety, and reliable access to resources, food and income, and basic
services.
ii) Capabilities: Are the means to the fulfillment of livelihood and well-being and their
enlargement through learning; practicing, training and education. Capabilities refer to
what people are capable of doing and being.
iii) Equity: Suggests that the poor, the weak, the vulnerable, and the exploited should come
first. Equity includes human rights, intergenerational and gender equity, and the
reversals of “putting the last first and the first last”, to be considered in all contexts.
However, the reversals are not absolute, but to balance and level.
In objective terms, as Titi and Singh (1995:9) noted, the primary objective of development
should be to overcome poverty and to protect or broaden human options. This in turn requires
the formulation of appropriate development policies. These days, almost all countries adopt
development policies in the face of a new philosophy known as “people-centered” or
“community-based” development.
In the pre 1970s, development has been measured in terms of the capacity of the national
economy to show an annual increase in its GNP or the ability of the nation to expand its
output at a rate faster than the growth rate of its population. A common economic index of
development has been therefore the use of the rates of growth of income per capita or per
capita GNP. The levels and rates of growth of "real" per capita GNP (monetary growth of
GNP Per capita minus the rate of inflation) are normally used to measure the overall
economic well-being of a population. However, such measurements and assumptions of
development have had very little to do with changes in the living standards of the poor.
Social scientists tend to disagree among themselves about the characteristics of measures of
development. Economists equate it with the capacity to produce a high level of material
output or resources in relation to size of population. Such measures are translated in concrete
terms as Gross National Product (GDP), Gross Domestic Product (GDP), and Per Capita
Income (PCI). Others focus on the forms of social and economic organization as prevailed or
evidenced in developed countries. Such measures are relative or qualitative in nature, which
may include:
These all imply that the term “development” goes beyond a material conceptualization of the
common good. Moreover, pure economic measurements of development alone, which have
been conventionally used in the pre 1970s, cannot adequately demonstrate the actual living
standards of a society.
Tip
GDP is the measure of the value of goods and services produced by the national
economy over a year. To avoid double counting, only goods used for final
consumption or investment are included, not those used up in producing the final
goods. Gross National Product (GNP) adds to GDP the income that accrues to
domestic residents from investment abroad, and deducts the income earned in the
domestic economy, which is owned by people abroad. GNP per capita is therefore
the better measure of development as welfare, while GDP per capita is a better
measure of productive forces.
1.4. Development strategies of developing countries
There are many ways in which countries try to promote growth and development.
These can be placed in two broad categories:
Those policies that rely on free markets to stimulate growth and development, and
those approaches that rely more on state intervention and central planning.
I. Market-orientated strategies
1. Trade liberalisation
Free trade has long been seen as an effective means of achieving growth and
development through what is commonly called an outward-looking approach.
Free trade means trade without any barriers or restrictions and requires countries to
specialise in goods and services for which they have a comparative cost advantage.
Removing barriers, such as tariffs, can help ‘create trade’, which can help create
employment and output.
2. Export promotion
An extension of the simple free trade approach is the push for export-led growth. This
means shifting the focus of economic policy away from growth through increased
domestic consumption or government expenditure towards targeting export markets.
Depending on the role of government, this strategy straddles both the market-led and
state-led approach to development.
Certainly, China has adopted an export led approach to developing its economy given
the relatively low purchasing power of a large proportion of its population.
3. Promotion of FDI
Given the savings gap experienced by many developing economies, encouraging FDI
can help fill this gap and increase aggregate investment in an economy when domestic
saving is weak.
Direct investment refers to a situation where the resident of one economy (as an
individual or private or public organisation) acquires a lasting interest in an asset in
another economy.
FDI will affect the balance of payments, and enable technology transfer where the
recipient country benefits from access to new technology (and the skills to use it.)
There are several positive externalities associated with an inflow of FDI in terms of
human capital development and improvements in infrastructure.
However, critics point out that FDI is often associated with unregulated global
multinational companies who repatriate profits and often manage to operate complex
tax avoid strategies - denying host countries of valuable tax revenue.
For example, during the financial crisis many governments supported banks by
providing large bailouts. While this may have been necessary in the short run, bailouts
can prevent banks attempting to become more efficient, or operate more prudently.
Government involvement in a specific sector through subsidies may prevent FDI and
act as a disincentive to the private sector.
However, subsidies can also be used to encourage FDI and protect infant industries
which may allow growth in the future.
The idea that floating exchange rates are preferable to fixed exchange rates is a long
held view associated with free market, liberal economics.
The view here is that floating exchange rates can help achieve an external equilibrium
with other countries, and that fixing exchange rates can store up problems in terms of
‘over’ or ‘under’ valuation of currencies.
6. Microfinance schemes
Microfinance relates to small scale financial schemes where investors put small
amounts of money into a bank, and where borrowers can withdraw small amounts to
develop their business ideas.
It removes the need for collateral and conventional credit rating processes, and has
been seen as a way to ‘fix’ the broken credit markets in developing countries.
7. Privatisation
Economic development depends to a great extent on the level of human capital that
exists.
Given that education and, to some extent, training are merit goods, it is likely that free
markets will fail to allocate sufficient resources to the provision of education.
Hence, the state will need to take an active role in educational provision.
The state can either provide all education, through 'public' education, or some of it in
conjunction with the private sector.
2. Protectionism
While those favouring the use of free markets to generate the right environment for
economic growth, many countries have used protection of their industries as a way of
stimulating growth.
Import substitution (or import substitution industrialisation) was a popular strategy for
many developing countries from the 1950s, and involved governments investing in
those sectors where imports were significant.
A stable exchange rate, they argue, encourages investment as firms can predict their
imported costs and their expected revenue from sales abroad.
While most systems today allow some flexibility, managing exchange rates ultimately
means pegging one currency to the currency of the dominant export market, or indeed
scrapping individual currencies and joining a currency union.
4. Infrastructure development
Many are land-locked and rely on road networks for exporting and importing key
resources. Being land-locked, as in the case of 16 African countries is a considerable
constraint on development.
Infrastructure projects are extremely costly and usually relate to public and quasi-
public goods, such as roads, bridges, tunnels, docks, and airport infrastructure.
These projects are likely to be too expensive for private firms to build on their own,
hence public money is commonly used - either on its own, or in tandem with private
finance – often through joint ventures with foreign companies.
They require a smaller capital commitment than a wholly owned foreign enterprise.
Joint ventures can also provide a cultural bridge between the foreign company and the
overseas market helping to encourage the development of products suitable for local
markets.
6. Other strategies
Industrialisation:
Lewis argued that industrialisation will improve labour productivity, free-up surplus
labour and lead to rapid economic growth.
Lewis argued that if inefficient workers were transferred from the agricultural sector
to the industrial sector there would be a net gain in output (and economic growth).
2. Development of tourism
Tourism has long been seen as providing a solution to low development for smaller
economies, including Caribbean islands.
Tourism also has many linkages to other sectors, including energy, construction and,
education and, critically, the wider service sector.
There is also a significant positive multiplier effect from tourism.
Greater linkages generally translate into higher levels of local economic activity (and
growth), which tend to occur when tourism enterprises source their goods and
services (including labour) locally rather than from imports.
Tourism also generates considerable tax revenue to governments, which can be used
to develop human capital, infrastructure or agricultural improvements.
While dependency on primary products has been a concern and a potential constraint
on economic growth and development, a switch to secondary industry is seen as a
sensible way forward.
Over 75% of the world’s poorest work on small areas of land, using low grade
technology, or none at all.
Crop yields in many developing countries, especially those of sub-Saharan Africa are
extremely low compared with more developed and emerging economies.
4. Aid
Aid falls into one of two categories – humanitarian aid, which is provided to countries
suffering from natural disasters, or military conflict, and development aid.
Development aid can be provided by governments, or by non-governmental
organisations (NGOs). Official aid is referred to official development assistance,
ODA.
Aid can also be direct ‘bi-lateral’ aid, when the provider gives aid directly to another
country, or ‘multi-lateral’ when aid is provided by countries to NGOs, who then
distribute it according to their own plans.
While helping fill any savings gap, as well as provide a means of achieving
development, aid can be targeted to important projects, such as agricultural
improvements, clean water supplies, infrastructure projects and education.
5. Debt relief
6. Remittances
Finally, remittances cannot be ignored when considering factors that influence growth
and development.
Remittances arise when workers who are employed abroad send back money to their
families, and can contribute significant amounts, and outstip the importance of aid.
It is estimated that around one billion people, are involved with remittances, either by
sending them as migrant workers or by receiving them, with one in seven people
globally benefitting from these flows.
In fact, they are the main source of external finance for many developing economies.
While remittances bring well established benefits in terms of growth, countries lose
labour, which offsets some of the benefits.
CHAPTER TWO
2. Paradigms and Theories of Development
2.1 Introduction
The concept of development is essentially concerned with social changes and human progress
in developing countries, which suffered from the evils of colonialism. Colonies began to
achieve their independence following the end of the 2 nd WW. But there was another
phenomenon known as the ‘cold war’ that took place between the capitalist of the west and
the communist east. Part of this war was the struggle to acquire allies from the developing
countries. The search for such allies has in turn come to be backed by the emergences and
applications of different development theories. Radical new theories emerged under the
various schools of thoughts or paradigms, each claiming that their theory held the key to
understand development and underdevelopment.
Development paradigms provide the basic underpinnings to describe the theories and policy
approaches of development and guide the applications of such development theories and
policies into practices. Paradigms and theories are much alike in their abstractions, except
that the former is broader to encompass many such of the latter. Both use assumptions and
past experiences to argue on their respective positions and explain propositions. Theories and
paradigms are generalizations. Hence, the implications of a given paradigm and theory vary
widely from country to country since every country has unique economic, social, cultural,
and historical experiences.
Both paradigms are conceptual constructs, which in practice may rarely occur or be
distinguished in pure forms. Despite differences between those who espouse or advocate the
center-down paradigm and that of the bottom-up development paradigm, there are some areas
of agreement between the two approaches concerning the ways and means for alleviating
poverty. These may include:
Both schools of thoughts recognize that nations/regions will progress through different
"Stages"; evolve from lower stages to higher stages of development. According to Rostow
(1960, 1971), the transition from underdevelopment to development can be described in
terms of a series of stapes or stages through which all countries must pass (have passed).
Rostow sees national/regional development progressing in five stages, namely: traditional,
transitional, takeoff, maturity, and mass consumption. Therefore, it is possible to identify all
societies in their economic dimensions, as lying on one of the five categories.
(b) Transitional Stage (precondition for takeoff): the second stage of growth embraces
societies in the process of transition; that is, the period when the preconditions for takeoff are
developed. At this stage, surpluses for trading and entrepreneurs emerge supported by an
emerging transport infrastructure. Savings and investment grow. In the second stage, the
region's economic and social structure begins to change. This occurs when leading regions
make investments in lagging regions in transportation, communication, and manufacturing
processes for the purpose of exploiting natural resources. In this stage, managers and skilled
labor are transferred to the lagging regions, and new social and political elites emerge.
(c) Takeoff: In the third stage, industrialization increases rapidly, new techniques spread in
majors sectors, with workers switching form the agriculture to manufacturing sector. During
the takeoff, the rate of effective investment and savings may raise with significant proportion
to the national income. Growth is concentrated in few regions of a country and in one or two
industries. New political and social institutions evolve to support industrialization. It occurs
when an external stimulus infuses investment by leading regions into lagging regions, and
when the new social and political order works to sustain continued national investment by
inducing private sector investment in core industries.
Rostow's model has its own limitations. For example, Rostow explains well the development
experiences western countries, but does not explain the experience of countries with different
cultures and traditions. Considerations of development from "above" or "below" are in
essence the considerations of the nature of development itself by individuals. Because, in the
ultimate sense, development is the reflection of personal values, conditioned by societal
framework in which one lives. In different national or regional situations there is undoubtedly
considerable variation in the make-up of these two schools of thoughts. Let us briefly contrast
the two paradigms (concepts) with each other.
DEVELOPMENT FROM:
OR
At least until recently, the center-down development paradigm has dominated the spatial
planning theory and practice in the context of developing countries. This school is rooted to
the traditional neoclassical economic models; in the balanced versus unbalanced growth
controversies of the 1950.
(a) Balanced growth (or the big push) theory argues that as a large number of industries
develop simultaneously, each generates a market for one another. Balanced growth
involves the simultaneous expansion of a large number of industries in all sectors and
regions of the economy. If a large number of different manufacturing industries are
created simultaneously then markets are created for additional output. For example,
firms producing final goods can find domestic industries that can supply them with their
inputs. The benefits of growth are spread over all sectors and, ideally, over all regions.
Balanced growth theory is an extension of Say’s Law; the demand for one product is
generated by the production of others. It is argued that free markets are unable to
deliver balanced growth because entrepreneurs:
Do not expect a market for additional output – why risk resources when sales are
uncertain?
Require skilled workers but are not willing to hire and train unskilled staff who
may then leave to work for rival firms – employers cannot ‘internalize their
positive externalities’,
Do not anticipate the positive externalities generated by the investment of other
firms engaged in expansion,
Are unable to raise finance for projects
If government can coordinate simultaneous investment in many industries, one firm provides
a market for another. This requires state planning and intervention to:
Train labor
Plan and organize the large-scale investment program
Mobilize the necessary finance
Nationalize strategic industries and undertake infrastructure investments e.g. build
roads
Protect infant industries through tariff (tax on imports) and quota (limit on quantity of
imports) policies
The strategy of balanced growth is beyond the resources of most poor countries. Balanced
growth within a closed economy rather than specialization and trade contradicts comparative
advantage. Government planning results in government failure; i.e. government intervention
in the market fails to bring about an efficient allocation of resources as it involves
bureaucratic processes. LDC’s development policies focusing on import substitution,
agricultural self-sufficiency and state control of production have yielded poor growth.
(b) Unbalanced growth theorists argue that government cannot mobilize sufficient
resources to promote widespread and coordinated investments in all industries. They
share analysis with balanced growth theorists that free markets, alone, cannot generate
development but differ in that government planning or market intervention is required
just in strategic industries. Those with the greatest number of backward and forward
links are prioritized. A country lacks resources to finance balanced growth. Resources
should therefore be concentrated on strategic industries with:
Significant forward linkages; i.e. firms creating essential inputs for other key firms in
the economy,
Significant backward linkages; i.e. key firms buying industrial inputs from a large
number of domestic firms,
Import substitution; i.e. developing domestic industries replaces imports and so
improves the balance of payments,
Government identifies strategically important areas with significant backward and forward
linkages so as to subsidize or fully own such sectors or areas. For example, state owned
development banks finance priority investment projects chosen for their contribution to
growth and development. The development-from-above school views development as
essentially emanating from the core and growth centers and trickling out to the periphery and
hinterlands. In its crudest sense, this school views regional development as starting from
worldwide demand for critical innovation that filters down to national, sub-national, urban
units, and hinterland units.
In other words, the essential position of this paradigm is that development will spread over
time from few dynamic sectors and geographic cluster to the rest spatial system. Of the
historical roots of the development from above paradigm, the unbalanced growth was given
high importance during the period of the 1950s in the highly influential works of Perroux,
Myrdal, Hirschman, and Friedmann.
Perroux coined the term "growth pole" with the primary concern that tended to promote
interactions among industrial sectors rather than spatial development processes. The "growth
center (or pole) and hinterland" concept distinguishes within a regional context. Growth
poles or centers are urban or extended metropolitan areas, here called "urban fields",
containing a set of expanded activities, which induce further economic development
throughout its hinterlands. A growth pole is an urban growth center from which growth
diffuses through the hinterlands. On the other hand, hinterlands are outside the urban fields.
In Perroux's growth pole concept, development in hinterlands is fueled by expanding
metropolitan centers. In this context, investment trickles out from the growth pole or growth
center to the hinterland.
According to Perroux, growth doesn’t appear everywhere at the same time; it manifests itself
in points or poles of growth, with variable intensities; it spreads by different channels and
with variable terminal effects for the economy as a whole. He emphasized on the importance
of entrepreneurial innovation in the development process, which proceeds by a succession of
dynamic sectors, or poles, through time. Perroux reflected the position of the center-down
development strategy; stresses on few dynamic sectoral clusters as well as on urban-industrial
growth as key to development.
The rationale for the growth pole strategy maintains that with limited resources, it would be
inefficient and ineffective to attempt to sprinkle developmental investments thinly over most
or all-across the national territory. Rather, key urban centers should be selected for
concentrated investment programs that would benefit from economies of scale and external
economies of agglomeration. However, empirical studies show that the innovation diffusion
process and the spread effects to the hinterlands are minimal and highly discontinuous in
spatial terms.
Myrdal develops the theory of cumulative causation and mentioned about the existence of
"leading-lagging regions” in the process of the spatial/regional aspect of development. The
"leading-lagging concept distinguishes advanced regions from underdeveloped regions at
both the global and regional levels. To explain the results of the "leading-lagging"
relationships and develop his analysis, Myrdal employed the concepts of "backwash" and
"spread effects".
Leading regions possess initial comparative advantage due to location, infrastructure, and
other factors. Agglomeration results in ever-increasing investment in leading regions, while
little investment moves from leading regions to lagging regions. Even this little investment is
controlled by leading region elites to assure economic dominance. Hence, lagging regions are
further inhibited from development because of backwash factors. The 'backwash' effects
involve the phenomenon of population migration, trade, and capital movements.
Skilled workers, educated individuals, business leaders, and venture capital will be drawn
from the hinterlands (lagging regions) to the growth poles (leading regions) to seek higher
returns because of increased demand available at the center. Goods and services produced in
the leading regions are sold to the lagging regions at such low prices that local industries
cannot compete. Such backwash effects create the tendency of an increased inequality
between the center and the periphery.
On the other hand, though long time it may take, there is a propensity of "spread effects" that
may counter the 'backwash' effects that emerge as a result of the relationships between the
"leading and lagging regions". Because, one feature of leading regions is that they tend to
spread out into lagging regions. Besides, most lagging regions will have some comparative
advantages, principally in natural resources that result in positive investment flow. Hence,
increased outlets for the hinterland's agricultural products and raw materials and a tendency
of technical advancement to diffuse from the growth centers will be imminent. When the
spread effects become stronger than the backwash effects, cumulative causation leads to
development in the lagging regions.
The actual effects of the growth points or centers on the hinterlands or the peripheries
depend on the balance between favorable effects that trickle-down to the latter from the
progress of the former and the unfavorable, or polarization, effects on the hinterlands as a
consequence of the attractiveness of the growth poles. The most important trickle-down
effects are generated by purchases and investments placed in the hinterlands by the growth
points. On the other hand, polarization may take place in a number of ways. Competition
from the growth points may depress relatively weak and insufficient manufacturing and
export activities in the hinterlands, and the growth points may produce "brain drain" rather
than creating employment opportunities in the hinterlands. Therefore, Hirschman suggests
that the essential task of government is the provision of infrastructure as the only permissive
inducement mechanism, and through which to provide the hinterlands with a continuous
economic activity in different sectors..
Friedmann has made the first attempt to formulate a systematic and comprehensive core-
periphery development model. The "core (center)-periphery" concept distinguishes between
regions on a global scale, while regions can be composed of the entire nations or collections
of states. He argued that development is the unfolding of the creative potential of a society
through a successive series of structural transformations. This occurs through a continuous,
but cumulative, process of innovation. Development originates in a relatively small number
of "centers of change" located at the points of highest interaction.
Hence, innovation diffuses from these centers to dependent areas of lower interaction. In
general, Friedmann's theory assigns a decisive influence to the institutional and
organizational framework of society, especially to the patterns of authority and dependency.
Friedmann's theory also integrates cultural and political processes into the process of
economic development. In summary, it was observed that in the years between the 1960s and
1980s, deploring the use of Western theories and methods, based on an urban-industrial
orientation, in dealing with the problems of developing countries has been almost
fashionable.
The center-down paradigm is not simply a matter of the national economic development of
individual countries; it involves significant and highly controversial international dimensions.
It suggests the creation of multinational firms on a continental basis as a precondition for
more rapid diffusion of innovation in the developing countries. As Hansen said, the concept
of development 'from above' assumes that development, whether spontaneous or induced,
starts only in few dynamic sectors and geographical clusters, from where it will or should,
spread to the remaining sectors and geographical areas.
This 'trickle down' process is essentially supposed to start at the global level (from worldwide
demand, or world innovation centers), and then filter down and outward to national or
regional units, either through the urban hierarchy, through input-output relations, or through
the internal channels of multi-plant business organizations, or large-scale government
organizations. Its emphasis, therefore, has been on urban and industrial capital-intensive
development, the highest available technology, and maximum use of external and scale
economies. This usually involves:
Large investment projects;
Increasing units of functional and territorial integrations;
Increasing scale of the private and public organizations required to transmit
development through these integrated units;
Large redistributive mechanisms; and
The reduction of economic, social, cultural, political and institutional 'barriers'
(including distance friction and institutional differentiation), which might hinder
transmission effects within and between these units.
The paradigm of development 'from above' is also based upon the following hypotheses:
(1) Development in its economic, social, cultural, and political dimensions can be
generated only by some very few selected agents such as entrepreneurial pioneers, the
white, the urbanite, or the intellectual;
(1) The rest of the population are considered 'incapable of initiatives in making
improvements, consequently everything must be done for them from outside, at least
temporarily;
(2) These few, agents are able and willing to allow all others to participate in the
development process within a reasonable time-span and on a reasonably equal basis;.
(3) These other groups (recipients) are able and willing to adopt the same type of
development pattern.
All these assumptions and hypothesis generally imply that the paradigm presumes an
eventually monolithic and uniform concept of development, value systems, and human
happiness, which automatically will spread over the entire world. These notions are related
very closely to the interests of the large-scale organizations, which were installed, to serve as
the "'motor' of development. In many cases, however, these have come instead to dominant
the system that we want to address; very often overruling the interests of local and regional
communities, which they were meant to serve.
This has led to a high concentration of power in few private or governmental organizations
which now dominate the greater part of the world system. At the same time such a strategy
ignores:
(1) The great diversity of value systems and aspirations created by the differences between
cultural systems.
(2) The great variations in natural conditions;
(3) The fact that, with different aspirations and cultural and natural preconditions, the
imposition of a uniform concept and measurement of development is bound to relegate
some groups to what is called 'underdevelopment', leaving them further away from
those set standards and plunging them further into the role of the disadvantaged in any
measurement;
(4) That this subsequently leads to differing levels of 'dependence'. Once such
economically disadvantaged groups start to interact more intensively with more
developed ones on the latter's terms, they are increasingly forced to adopt the same
social, cultural, political, and institutional norms in order to compete with them in
economic terms;
(5) That this entails the subordination of broader societal and cultural values to economic
determinants, which is a fact that can be observed in most highly developed countries
and those directly influenced by them today.
Critical appraisal of the center-down paradigm has further alleged that, within developing
countries, this orientation has contributed to:
1) Dependence on developed countries and multi-national corporations situated in these
countries,
2) The persistent dominance of one or few large cities, which have critical problems of
unemployment and underemployment in themselves,
3) Increasing income inequalities,
4) Persistent and growing food shortages,
5) Deteriorating material conditions in the countryside.
The relevance of these propositions varies depending on the objective conditions of
individual countries. Marxist and other critics who emphasize the issue of dependence have
done so largely on two grounds:
(i) The political dependence that tends to accompany economic dependence, and
(ii) The failure of existing institutional mechanisms to alleviate mass poverty, especially in
rural areas. However, while there are apparent shortcomings of the center-down
paradigm, it may be wrong to dismiss this approach as altogether useless and harmful.
Whatever the merits of these objections, they don't in themselves provide an alternative
development strategy.
Worldwide investment stagnation and pressures on multinationals to invest at home are not
obviously helping developing countries. While some informed observers have become
pessimistic about the efficacy of the approach, others argue that it has not been implemented
properly as investment has been too few; planners have worked with unrealistic short-time
horizons. Thus, one may say that the center-down is not necessarily wrong; it has never been
tried. Normally, large-scale organizational linkages between areas of greatly differing levels
of development lead (due to factors such as unequal distribution of power, unequal terms of
trade, unequal distribution of scale economies) to increasing spatial divergence rather than a
convergence of living levels.
In other words, even with explicit sub-national development policies operating through large-
scale organizations, the sum of backwash effects in most cases still seems to exceed spread
effects. With a "top-down" development strategy, this can only be avoided if at the national
level there is both a strong control mechanism avoiding leakages to the exterior (a control on
commodity and factor flows) and a strong internal redistributive mechanism with broad
public participation. Hence, the alternative would be to give clear priority for economically
less developed social groups and areas to their own self-determined societal standards. This
alternative approach is that of "development from below". Indeed, some critics of the center-
down paradigm assert that rural development and bottom-up strategies are necessary for
developing countries.