Levinepaper
Levinepaper
Ross Levine*
July 2010
* James and Merryl Tisch Professor of Economics, Brown University, 64 Waterman Street, Providence RI,
02912, ross_levine@brown.edu. I thank James Barth, John Boyd, Gerard Caprio, Peter Howitt, Randall
Kroszner, Glenn Loury, Yona Rubinstein, Andrei Shleifer, Joe Stiglitz, David Weil, and Ivo Welch for helpful
conversations and communications. Seminar participants at the Bank for International Settlements, the
Boston and Chicago Federal Reserve Banks, the IMF, World Bank, George Washington University, and Brown
University provided insightful comments. I bear full responsibility for the views expressed in the paper.
1
1. Introduction
The first objective of this paper is to document that the collapse of the global
financial system reflects a systemic failure of the governance of financial regulation – the
system associated with designing, enacting, implementing, and reforming financial policies.
maintained policies that destabilized the global financial system. They maintained these
policies even as the regulatory authorities acquired information that their policies were
increasing financial system fragility. Moreover, the authorities acquired this information
during the decade before the crisis, when they had ample time to adjust their policies under
relatively calm conditions. Yet, financial policymakers did not adjust, advertising
Levine (2011), indicate that the crisis does not only reflect unsustainable global
supervisory power, and unclear lines of regulatory authority. These factors played a role,
but only a partial role. Rather, bad policy choices created perverse incentives that
encouraged financial institutions to take excessive risk and divert society’s savings toward
unproductive ends. Failures in the governance of financial regulation helped cause the
inconsistency between a dynamic financial sector and a regulatory system that failed to
collateralized debt obligations, and credit default swaps, could have had primarily positive
effects on the lives of most citizens. Yet, the inability, or unwillingness, of the governance
financial innovations to metastasize and ruin the financial system. A better functioning
system for establishing financial policies could have captured the benefits, while avoiding
This conclusion – that systemic governance failures contributed to the crisis – has
material implications for reforming financial regulation. There are several policy proposals
to increase the power of financial regulatory agencies, reduce regulatory gaps, develop
better crisis management tools, and consolidate the regulation of all systemically important
institutions in the hands of a single entity. Yet, if technical glitches and regulatory gaps
played only a partial role in fostering the crisis, then these proposed reforms represent
only partial and thus incomplete steps in establishing a sound financial system. This is not
an argument against the reforms that have been proposed and adopted. It is an argument
institutions that promote transparency, timely and informed debate, and hence the
The second objective of the paper is to propose a new institution, which I label the
“Sentinel,” to act as the public’s sentry over financial policies and thereby improve the
governance of financial regulation. Its sole power would be to demand any information
necessary for evaluating the state of financial regulation. Its sole responsibility would be to
continuously assess and comment on financial policies, delivering a formal report to the
legislative and executive branches of government annually. Critically, and uniquely, the
3
Senior members would be appointed for staggered terms to limit political influence. To
shield it from market influences, senior staff would be prohibited from receiving
compensation from the financial sector after completing public services for a timely period.
The goal is to create an institution in which the personal motives, ambitions, and prestige
of its employees are inextricably connected to accurately assessing the impact of financial
The Sentinel would improve the entire apparatus for writing, enacting, adapting,
would reduce the ability of regulators to obfuscate regulatory actions and would instead
make regulators more accountable for the societal repercussions of their actions. As an
reduce the probability and costliness of regulatory mistakes and supervisory failures. As a
prominent institution, the Sentinel’s reports to legislators would help reduce the influence
evaluate the state of financial regulation from the perspective of the public, it would help
inform the public and thereby augment public influence over financial regulation.
Given the existing myriad of regulatory agencies, quasi-regulatory bodies, and other
oversight entities, do we really need another regulatory institution? Yes. No other existing
entity currently has the incentives, power, or capabilities to perform the role of a public
First and foremost, unlike any existing institution, the Sentinel would be
independent of both political and market influences. Incentives matter in regulation too.
4
In capitals around the world, lobbyists shape legislation and the revolving door between
industry and regulatory agencies spins rapidly. While there are good reasons for having
highly-skilled individuals with private sector expertise help in regulating the financial
sector, there are similarly good reasons for worrying about conflicts of interest and
regulation.
housed in a central bank or other entity that is designed to be independent of the public
and regulatory power in the hands of publicly unaccountable officials breaks the
democratic lines of influence running from the public to the design and execution of
policies that determine the allocation of capital. The Sentinel would shine an illuminating,
and potentially disinfecting, light on the financial system that would enhance the
governance of financial regulation. Moreover, although the Sentinel would not set any
policy, it would provide an objective, independent assessment of policy. This would have
been enormously valuable during the decade-long series of policy gaffes that contributed to
While no panacea, the Sentinel would improve the regulatory apparatus. We face
the complex, and consequential, challenge of creating a regulatory regime that adapts to
incentivize financiers to provide the financial services necessary for economic growth.
2.1. Introduction
In this section, I argue that the collapse of the global financial system was partially
caused by a systemic failure of financial regulation. To make this case, I focus on four policy
failures. Though these examples focus on the United States, they have clear international
connections. It should be remembered that while the bulk of toxic assets were made in the
USA, financial institutions around the world readily purchased them, abetted by systemic
regulatory failures in their home countries. Moreover, although I choose four policies, there
are many examples that illustrate how financial regulators, with frequent help from their
political overseers, did not act in the long interests of the public. Barth, Caprio, and Levine
(2011) provide both more examples from the United States and from around the world in a
book-length treatment of these themes. But, since the major objective of this paper is to
As a first example of how regulatory actions – and inaction – helped trigger the
crisis, consider credit rating agencies, which were central participants in the global
financial crisis. To appreciate their role, consider the securitization of mortgages. Mortgage
companies routinely provided loans to borrowers with little ability to repay those debts
because (1) they earned fees for each loan and (2) they could sell those loans to investment
banks and other financial institutions. Investment banks and other financial institutions
6
gobbled-up those mortgages because (1) they earned fees for packaging the mortgages into
new securities and (2) they could sell those new mortgage backed securities (MBSs) to
other financial institutions, including banks, insurance companies, and pension funds
around the world. These other financial institutions bought the MBSs because credit rating
agencies said they were safe. By fueling the demand for MBS and related securities, credit
rating agencies encouraged a broad array of financial institutions to make the poor
investments that ultimately toppled the global financial system. Thus, an informed
postmortem of the financial system requires a dissection of why financial institutions relied
How did credit rating agencies become so pivotal? Until the 1970s, credit rating
agencies were insignificant institutions that sold their assessments of credit risk to
subscribers. Now, it is virtually impossible for a firm to issue a security without first
purchasing a rating.
(NRSRO) designation, which it granted to the largest credit rating agencies. The SEC then
relied on the NRSRO’s credit risk assessment in establishing capital requirements on SEC-
The creation of -- and reliance on -- NRSROs by the SEC triggered a global cascade of
regulatory decisions that increased the demand for their credit ratings. Bank regulators,
insurance regulators, federal, state, and local agencies, foundations, endowments, and
numerous entities around the world all started using NRSRO ratings to establish capital
regulatory agencies on NRSRO ratings, private endowments, foundations, and mutual funds
also used their ratings in setting asset allocation guidelines for their investment managers.
selling their ratings to the issuers of securities. Since regulators, official agencies, and
private institutions around the world relied on NRSRO ratings, virtually every issuer of
securities was compelled to purchase an NRSRO rating if it wanted a large market for its
securities.
There are well-known conflicts of interest associated with credit rating agencies
selling their ratings to the issuers of securities. Issuers have an interest in paying rating
agencies more for higher ratings since those ratings influence the demand for and hence
reduces the pernicious incentive to sell better ratings. If a rating agency does not provide
sound, objective assessments of a security, the agency will experience damage to its
will reduce their reliance on this agency, which will reduce demand for all securities rated
by the agency. As a result, issuers will reduce their demand for the services provide by that
agency, reducing the agency’s future profits. From this perspective, reputational capital is
vital for the long-run profitability of credit rating agencies and will therefore contain any
short-run conflicts of interest associated with “selling” a superior rating on any particular
security.
Reputational capital will reduce conflicts of interest, however, only under particular
conditions. First, the demand for securities must respond to poor rating agency
8
performance, so that decision makers at rating agencies are punished for issuing bloated
ratings on even a few securities. Second, decision makers at rating agencies must have a
sufficiently long-run profit horizon, so that the long-run costs to the decision maker from
harming the agencies reputation outweigh the short-run benefits from selling a bloated
rating.
These conditions do not hold, however. First, regulations weaken the degree to
which a decline in the reputation of a credit rating agency reduced demand for its services.
Specifically, regulations induce the vast majority of the buyers of securities to use NRSRO
rating in selecting assets. These regulations hold regardless of NRSRO performance, which
moderates the degree to which poor ratings performance reduces the demand for NRSRO
services. Such regulations mitigate the positive relation between rating agency
dramatically changed the incentives of decision makers at credit rating agencies, inducing
them to sell bloated ratings at the expense of a loss in the long-run reputation of the
agency.
The explosive growth of securitized and structured financial products from the late-
1990s onward dramatically intensified the conflicts of interest problem. Securitization and
structuring involves the packaging and rating of trillions of dollars worth of new financial
instruments. Huge fees associated with processing these securities flowed to banks and
NRSROs. Impediments to this securitization and structuring process, such as the issuance
of low credit rating on the securities, would gum-up the system, reducing rating agency
profits. In fact, the NRSROs started selling ancillary consulting services to facilitate the
on structured products. Besides purchasing ratings from the NRSROs, the banks associated
with creating structured financial products would first pay the rating agencies for guidance
on how to package the securities to get high ratings and then pay the rating agencies to rate
By the early 2000s, it was well-known that the boom in securitization was
encouraging credit rating agencies to inflate their ratings for huge profits. Moreover,
regulators had seen the accounting debacle of 2001-2002, when corporations paid
accounting firms both to structure and then to audit financial statements. So, when banks
started paying the NRSROs both to structure and then to rate securities, this should have
been a grim – and familiar – warning. The short-run profits associated with greasing the
flow of structured products with optimistic ratings were mind bogglingly large and made
the future losses from the inevitable loss of reputational capital irrelevant. For example, the
operating margin at Moody’s between 2000 and 2007 averaged 53 percent. This compares
But, the global regulatory community did not adapt to these well-publicized
rely on their ratings. While the global financial crisis does not have a single cause, the
imagine the behavior of the credit rating agencies without the regulations that created and
Next, consider the role of complex derivative contracts, including credit default
from issuer B on security C. If security C has a predefined “credit related event,” such as
missing an interest payment, receiving a credit downgrade, or filing for bankruptcy, then
issuer B pays purchaser A. While having insurance-like qualities, CDSs are not formally
insurance contracts. Neither the purchaser nor the issuer of the CDS needs to hold the
underlying security, leading to the frequently used analogy that CDSs are like buying fire
insurance on your neighbor’s house. Moreover, since CDSs are not insurance contracts,
they are not regulated as tightly as insurance products. CDSs are financial derivatives that
In principle, banks can use credit default swaps to reduce both their exposure to
credit risk and the amount of capital held against potential losses. For example, if a bank
purchases a CDS on a loan, this can reduce its credit risk: if the loan defaults, the
counterparty to the CDS will compensate the bank for the loss. If the bank’s regulator
concludes that the counterparty to the CDS will actually pay the bank if the loan defaults,
then the regulator typically allows the bank to reallocate capital to higher-expected return,
higher-risk assets.
The Fed made a momentous decision in 1996: it permitted banks to use CDSs to
reduce capital reserves (Tett, 2009, p. 49). Regulators treated securities guaranteed by a
seller of CDSs as having the risk level of the seller – or more accurately, the counterparty –
of the CDS. For example, a bank purchasing full CDS protection from American
loans would have those CDOs treated as AAA securities for capital regulatory purposes
because AIG had an AAA rating from a Nationally Recognized Statistical Rating
In light of this decision, banks used CDSs to reduce capital and invest in more
lucrative, albeit more risky, assets. For example, a bank with a typical portfolio of $10
billion of commercial loans could reduce its capital reserves against these assets from
about $800 million to under $200 million by purchasing CDSs for a small fee (Tett, 2009, p.
64).
The CDS market boomed following the Fed decision. By 2007, the largest U.S.
commercial banks had purchased $7.9 trillion in CDS protection, and, at a broader level, the
overall CDS market reached a notional value of $62 trillion in 2007 according to Barth et al
(2009).
There were, however, serious problems associated with allowing banks to reduce
their capital via CDSs. Given the active trading of CDSs, it was sometimes difficult to
exposures to CDS risk. For example, AIG had a notional exposure of about $500 billion to
CDSs (and related derivatives) in 2007, while having a capital base of about $100 billion to
cover all its traditional insurance activities as well as its financial derivatives business. The
growing exposure of AIG and other issuers of CDSs should have – and did -- raise concerns
The Fed was aware of the growing danger to the safety and soundness of the
banking system from CDSs. For instance, Tett (2009, p. 157-163) recounts how Timothy
12
Geithner, then President of the New York Federal Reserve Bank, became concerned in 2004
about the lack of information on CDSs and the growing counterparty risk facing banks.
Barth et al (2009) demonstrates through the use of internal Fed documents that it knew by
2004 of the growing problems associated with subprime mortgage related assets, on which
many CDSs were written. Indeed, the FBI publicly warned in 2004 of an epidemic of fraud
in subprime lending. In terms of the sellers of CDSs, detailed accounts by Lewis (2009) and
McDonald (2009) illustrate the Fed’s awareness by 2006 of AIG’s growing fragility and the
Yet, even more momentously than the original decision allowing banks to reduce
their capital reserves through the use of CDSs, the Fed did not adjust its policies as it
learned of the growing fragility of the banking system due to the mushrooming use of
The key question is why the Fed maintained its capital regulations. Bank purchases
of CDSs boomed immediately after the 1996 regulatory decision allowing a reduction in
bank capital from the purchase of CDSs. Why didn’t the Fed respond by demanding greater
transparency before granting capital relief and conducting its own assessment of the
counterparty risks facing the systemically important banks under its supervision? Why
didn’t the Fed adjust in 2004 as it learned of the opaque nature of the CDS market and as
the FBI warned of the fraudulent practices associated with the issuance of the sub-prime
about the fragility of AIG, or in 2007 when hedge funds warned the Fed, the Treasury, and
G8 delegates about the growing fragility of commercial banks (Tett, 2009, p. 160-3)? Why
13
didn’t the Fed prohibit banks from reducing regulatory capital via CDSs until the Fed had
The Fed’s decision to maintain its regulatory stance toward CDSs was neither a
Fed documents, Barth et al (2009, p. 184) note, “… even if the top officials from these
regulatory agencies did not appreciate or wish to act earlier on the information they had,
their subordinates apparently fully understood and appreciated the growing magnitude of
the problem.” And, even in 2004, the Fed issued Interpretive Letter #998 that reiterated its
capital regulatory policy with respect to CDSs. To more comprehensively reform the
financial regulatory system, we need to examine why these types of decisions were made
and undertake institutional reforms to make these systemic mistakes less likely.
efforts to make the CDS market more transparent. The Fed (under Alan Greenspan), the
Treasury (under Robert Rubin and then Larry Summers), and the SEC (under Arthur
Commission (CFTC) to shed light on the multi-trillion dollar OTC derivatives market, which
Incidents of fraud, manipulation, and failure in the OTC derivatives market began as
early as 1994, with the sensational bankruptcy of Orange County and court cases involving
Gibson Greeting Cards and Procter and Gamble against Bankers Trust. Numerous problems,
plagued the market. Further, OTC derivates played a dominant role in the dramatic failure
agency had any warning of LTCM’s demise, or the potential systemic implications of its
dollar OTC derivatives market, the CFTC issued a “concept release” report in 1998 calling
for greater transparency of OTC derivatives. The CFTC sought greater information
disclosure, improvements in record keeping, and controls on fraud. The CFTC did not call
for draconian controls on the derivatives market; it called for more transparency.
The response by the Fed, Treasury, and SEC was swift: They stopped the CFTC. First,
they obtained a six month moratorium on the CFTC’s ability to implement the strategies
outlined in its concept release. Second, the President’s Working Group on Financial
Markets, which consists of the Secretary of the Treasury, the Chairman of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, the Chairman of the SEC, and the Chairman of the
CFTC, initiated a study of the OTC derivatives market. Finally, they helped convince
Congress to pass the Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, which exempted the
OTC derivates market – and hence the CDS market – from government oversight.
Senior regulators and policymakers lobbied hard to keep CDSs and other derivatives
in opaque markets. A comprehensive assessment of the causes of the crisis must evaluate
why policymakers made choices like this. Indeed, Nick Timiraos and James R. Hagerty
“Nearly a year and half after the outbreak of the global economic crisis, many
of the problems that contributed to it haven’t been tamed. The U.S. has no
system in place to tackle a failure of its largest financial institutions.
Derivatives contracts of the kind that crippled American International Group
15
Inc. still trade in the shadows. And investors remain heavily reliant on the
same credit-ratings firms that gave AAA ratings to lousy mortgage
securities.”
As a final example, consider the SECs oversight – or lack thereof – of the five major
investment banks, all of which experienced major “transformations” in 2008. Only a few
days after the SEC Chairman expressed confidence in the financial soundness of the
investment banks, a failed Bear Stearns merged with the commercial bank JP Morgan Chase
& Co. Six months later, Lehman Brothers went bankrupt, and a few months later, at the
brink of insolvency, Merrill Lynch merged with Bank of America. In the autumn of 2008,
Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley were “pressured” into becoming bank holding
companies by the Federal Reserve and arguably rescued from failure through an
The SEC’s fingerprints are indelibly imprinted on this debacle, as reflected in three
interrelated SEC decisions. First, the SEC in 2004 essentially exempted the broker-dealers
of the five largest investment banks from using the traditional method for computing
capital in satisfying the net capital rule, which was a 1975 rule for computing minimum
capital standards at broker-dealers. The investment banks were permitted to use their own
mathematical models of asset and portfolio risk to compute appropriate capital levels. The
investment banks responded by issuing more debt to purchase more risky securities
without putting commensurately more of their own capital at risk. Leverage ratios soared
from their 2004 levels, as the bank’s models indicated that they had sufficient capital
cushions.
In a second, coordinated 2004 policy change, the SEC enacted a rule that induced the
five investment banks to become “consolidated supervised entities” (CSEs): The SEC would
oversee the entire financial firm. Specifically, the SEC now had responsibility for
supervising the holding company, broker-dealer affiliates, and all other affiliates on a
consolidated basis. These other affiliates include other regulated entities, such as foreign-
dealers (Colby, 2007). The SEC was charged with evaluating the models employed by the
broker-dealers in computing appropriate capital levels and assessing the overall stability of
the consolidated investment bank. Given the size and complexity of these financial
responsibility.
Third, the SEC neutered its ability to conduct consolidated supervision of major
investment banks. With the elimination of the net capital rule and the added complexity of
17
consolidated supervision, the SEC’s head of market regulation, Annette Nazareth, promised
to hire high-skilled supervisors to assess the riskiness of investment banking activities. But,
the SEC didn’t. In fact, the SEC had only seven people to examine the parent companies of
the investment banks, which controlled over $4 trillion in assets. Under Christopher Cox,
who became chairman in 2005, the SEC eliminated the risk management office and failed to
complete a single inspection of a major investment bank in the year and a half before the
collapse of those banks (Labaton, 2008). Cox also weakened the Enforcement Division’s
In easing the net capital rule, adopting a system of consolidated supervision, but
failing to develop the capabilities to supervise large financial conglomerates, the SEC
supervisory guardrails, while simultaneously arguing to the U.S. Congress in 2007, and
hence global financial markets, that it had a “successful consolidated supervision program.”
(See the SEC’s Deputy Director’s testimony before the U.S. House of Representatives
the SEC provided an official stamp of approval of these major investment banks, weakening
These policy choices point inexorably toward the SEC as an accomplice in causing the
As noted by Senator Carl Levin, “The recent financial crisis was not a natural disaster; it
was a manmade economic assault. It will happen again unless we change the rules.”
3.1. Preamble
improve regulatory governance: the system for selecting, interpreting, and implementing,
and adapting regulations. One might accept the desirability of rethinking the governance of
financial regulation and yet reject the specific Sentinel proposal. I simply offer the Sentinel
Furthermore, in describing the Sentinel, I do not address a range of key questions, such as
(i) which are the right regulations for achieving desirable outcomes, such as stability and
growth and (ii) what are the right trade-offs among these potentially competing outcomes?
Rather, the goal of the Sentinel is to improve the process through which these decisions are
made. Finally, I sketch the Sentinel from the perspective of somebody most familiar with
the institutional contours of the United States. While many of the general principles – such
as transparency and checks and balances – translate to other political and cultural contexts,
19
some elements will not. I emphasize key attributes of the Sentinel that are crucial to its
proper functioning.
The only power of the Sentinel would be to acquire any information that it deems
necessary for evaluating the state of financial regulation over time, including the rules
collected by the Sentinel would be made publicly available, potentially with some delay.
Transparency is necessary; thus, the law establishing the Sentinel must clearly and
unambiguously assert that the Sentinel should be granted immediate and unencumbered
access to any information it deems appropriate from any and all regulatory authorities and
financial institutions. Sentinel demands for information must trump the desires of
regulatory agencies for discretion, secrecy, and confidentiality. This “sunshine” regulatory
approach has a long and promising history as discussed in McCraw’s (1984) impressive
book. This approach is also fully consistent with the notion of checks and balances
incorporated into the political philosophies of several countries. In other words, the basic
The only responsibility of the Sentinel would be to deliver an annual report to the
legislative and executive branches of government assessing the current and long-run
impact of financial regulatory and supervisory rules and practices on the public. The
Sentinel would have no official power over the central bank, the regulatory agencies, or
financial markets and institutions. To emphasize this point, the Sentinel would not affect
the power and responsibilities of the central bank or financial regulatory agencies. But, the
20
Sentinel would have broad responsibilities for assessing the impact of the overall
constellation of regulatory and supervisory practices on the financial system, not just the
impact of a single regulatory agency. The Sentinel would look across all segments of the
financial system, from banks and securities markets, to derivatives and rating agencies, to
insurance companies and executive compensation, etc, and produce a detailed evaluation
The major design challenges are to create a Sentinel that is (1) politically
independent, (2) independent of financial markets, and (3) sufficiently staffed that it can
that it is not ignored. These are essential ingredients. While elected official should
ultimately set public policies, creating a Sentinel that is independent of narrow political and
market influences would help in providing impartial, expert advice to politicians and the
public. The goal is to create an institution in which the professional ambitions and personal
goals of its staff align with its mission of boosting the degree to which financial regulations
reflect the public interest. Given this goal and the Sentinel’s responsibility of examining the
complete financial system, it must have the staff and resources to deliver on these
ambitious goals and responsibilities. While the objectives are the same, the precise
organizational mechanisms for achieving such a Sentinel will necessarily differ across
countries.
Here are a few design suggestions, using the United States as a point of reference.
First, the most senior members of the Sentinel would be appointed by the President and
confirmed by the Senate for staggered and appropriately long terms. As with the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, the goal is to limit the short-term influence of
21
politics on the evaluations of the Sentinel. Second, the senior members of the Sentinel
would also be prohibited from receiving compensation from the financial services industry,
even after completing their tenure at the Sentinel. Third, Sentinel salaries would have to be
market based and the Sentinel would have to be large, including financial economists,
lawyers, experts with supervisory experience, and – critically – senior professionals with
private financial market experience. Since exactly those individuals with sufficient
expertise to achieve the goals of the Sentinel would also have lucrative opportunities in the
private sector, staffing the Sentinel with sufficiently talented, well-motivated individuals
sector jobs. While problematic, a more lucrative compensation plan is necessary for
limiting conflicts of interest while attracting excellent people to the Sentinel. At the same
time, the Sentinel would be a prominent entity. Those working for the Sentinel could
financial sector policies and achieve these career aspirations would work to attract
The Sentinel would materially enhance the governance of financial regulation along
several dimensions. At the most general level, creating an independent Sentinel with an
informed and expert staff would enhance the analysis and review of financial policies,
improve the design and implementation of those policies, and increase the probability that
governments would select financial policies that promote the interests of the public at
22
large, not only the special interests of a few. While the Sentinel would neither eliminate
crises nor perfect financial system operations, it would improve the functioning of financial
markets, lower the likelihood of systemic crises, and reduce the severity of future crises. It
First, the Sentinel would have the power to demand information, the expertise to
evaluate that information, and both the prominence and independence to make its
judgments heard. It would be difficult for policymakers and the public to ignore the
Sentinel’s views. While regulators and others could refute the Sentinel’s analyses and
informed debate.
By breaking the monopoly that regulatory authorities too frequently have over
information and expertise, the Sentinel would enhance the analysis – and hence the design
the governance of financial policies. If the public and its representatives do not have the
information and expertise to assess and challenge the decisions of the regulatory agencies,
then this will hinder the effective design, implementation, and modification of financial
sector policies. For example, while the Federal Reserve was aware of the destabilizing
effects of its capital policies many years before the onset of the crisis, the public, Congress,
and the Treasury would have found it difficult to obtain this information and discuss
alternative policies with the Fed. A Sentinel would have reduced the probability that U.S.
regulatory authorities would make the types of systematic mistakes over many years that
agencies on information and expertise, it would not limit the de jure power of these
regulatory agencies. The Sentinel would force the regulators to defend their analyses,
decisions, and actions, but it would not create another agency with regulatory power. The
Sentinel would promote transparency and informed debate, but it would not diminish the
run political forces and independent of the private profit motives of financial markets, the
Sentinel would push the policy debate toward focusing on the general welfare of the public
and away from the narrow interests of the politically powerful and financially wealthy.
institutions pay virtually unlimited sums to shape financial policies, regulations, and
literature, narrow political constituencies work tirelessly on tilting the financial rules of the
group to provide an objective assessment of financial policies. Such an institution does not
exist in most countries, certainly not in the United States. While the Sentinel itself is
Third, the Sentinel would examine the entire financial system. It would look beyond
the narrow confines of any particular regulatory agency’s purview and assess how the full
24
constellation of financial policies fit together in shaping the incentives provided to private
reassessing how regulatory and supervisory practices affect the incentives faced by the
financial system. Since financial systems are dynamic, it is vital to relentlessly reevaluate
the incentives shaping the behavior of financial market participants. As the latest crisis
suggests, a regulatory system that worked well before structured financial products
emerged did not work as well afterwards. By constantly assessing the impact of financial
policies, the Sentinel would reduce the likelihood that financial policies become obsolete
and thereby dangerously distort the incentives that shape financial market decisions.
Fifth, by (1) having responsibility for examining the entire financial system, (2)
being politically independent and independent of financial markets, and (3) not having
performance of existing regulatory agencies. At the simplest level, knowing that the
Sentinel is going to scrutinize its actions would increase the performance of regulatory
agencies, reducing complacency. The mere existence of the Sentinel might have reduced the
dubious actions and inactions of several regulatory bodies during the most recent crisis.
financial markets and institutions, the Sentinel would be less constrained in its
For example, if a regulator gives the OK on a particular practice, the regulator might later
find it difficult to reverse or adjust its decision as new information becomes available. The
25
regulator might have the very human fear of losing credibility with the regulated entity.
While a regulator might avoid taking actions against a regulated financial institutions
because such an ex post action implies an ex ante failure of regulation, the Sentinel would
face fewer such conflicts. Thus, the Sentinel would make it more likely that bad policies are
identified and changed. Similarly, while one regulatory agency (for example the Fed) might
steer clear of criticizing another agency’s actions (such as the SEC’s) to avoid triggering
cross-agency battles, the Sentinel would be less reticent. Indeed, it would have the
4. Conclusions
The financial crisis was not simply the result of too little regulatory power, unclear
capital flows in conjunction with toxic financial innovations. All of these were contributing
factors. But, they are incomplete explanations of the collapse of the global financial system.
that increased the fragility of the financial system and the inefficient allocation of capital.
The financial policy apparatus maintained these policies even as they learned that their
policies were distorting the flow of credit toward questionable ends. They had plenty of
time to assess the impact of their policies and adapt, but they frequently failed to change
their policies. Thus, the institutions responsible for maintaining the safety and soundness
of the global financial system made systematic mistakes. Thus, a comprehensively effective
26
financial reform package must address the systemic failure of the governance of financial
regulation – the system associated with evaluating, enacting, and implementing financial
policies.
The Sentinel is a suggestion for addressing this fundamental cause of the global
financial crisis. Unlike existing institutions, the Sentinel would be independent of both
political and market influence. Supervisory and regulatory officials in many countries move
readily from politically-connected jobs, to lucrative jobs in the private sector, to senior
positions in official financial supervisory agencies. While the vast majority of regulators
surely act in the best interests of the public, it is nevertheless valuable to have an informed,
performance of official agencies and the efficacy of financial policies. While existing
regulatory agencies frequently have internal auditing departments, the Sentinel would play
a much different role. These auditing departments assess whether the particular regulatory
agency adhered to particular rules. Instead, the Sentinel would conduct an independent
evaluation of the impact of the full array of financial regulations and supervisory practices
on the economy.
Unlike existing institutions, the Sentinel would have the prominence, information,
on the information and expertise necessary for making financial regulatory decisions. This
gives too much power over the rules governing the allocation of capital to unelected, and
potentially unaccountable, officials. The Sentinel would shine a cleaning light on the
processes associated with making financial policy decisions, enhancing financial regulation.
27
The Sentinel would provide an independent, expert assessment of financial sector policies
that would inform the debate on these highly complex policy considerations. The absence
of such an institution was clearly evident in the design, implementation, and evolution of
Although not impervious to mistakes and corruption itself, the Sentinel would
incentivizes financiers to provide the financial services necessary for sustaining economic
growth.
28
References
Barth, James R., Gerard Caprio, Jr., and Ross Levine. 2006. Rethinking Bank Regulation: Till
Angels Govern. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Barth, James R., Gerard Caprio, Jr., and Ross Levine. 2011. Guardians of Finance: How to
Make them Work for Us. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, forthcoming.
Barth, James R., Tong Li, Wenling Lu, Tiphon Phumiwasana, Glenn Yago. 2009. The Rise and
Fall of the U.S. Mortgage and Credit Markets. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley & Sons, Inc.
Cecchetti, Stephen G. 2009. Crisis and Responses: The Federal Reserve in the Early Stages
of the Financial Crisis. Journal of Economic Perspectives 23, 51-75.
Colby, Robert. 2007. Testimony Concerning the Consolidated Supervision of U.S. Securities
Firms and Affiliated Industrial Loan Corporations. The U.S. House of Representatives
Financial Services Committee, April 25, 2007.
Labaton, Stephen. 2008. Agency’s ’04 Rule Let Banks Pile Up New Debt. New York Times,
October 3, 2008.
Levine, Ross. 2010a. The Sentinel: Improving the Governance of Financial Policies. In The
International Financial Crisis: Have the Rules of Finance Changed? Eds: Asli
Demirguc-Kunt, Douglas D. Evanoff and George G. Kaufman, World Scientific
Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd, New Jersey.
Levine, Ross. 2010b. An Autopsy of the U.S. Financial System: Accident, Suicide, or Negligent
Homicide? Journal of Financial Economic Policy forthcoming.
Lewis, Michael. 2009. The Man Who Crashed the World. Vanity Fair, August.
Lowenstein, Roger. 2008. Triple-A Failure. New York Times, April 27.
McDonald, Lawrence G. and Patrick Robinson. 2009. A Colossal Failure of Common Sense:
The Inside Story of the Collapse of Lehman Brothers. New York, NY: Crown Publishing
Company.
Tett, Gillian. 2009. Fool’s Gold. New York, NY: Free Press.