13 Isbn-9780198800040-Book-Part-7
13 Isbn-9780198800040-Book-Part-7
A. Introduction
When parties to an agreement have thought about the matter, seriously intend to bind
themselves, and are unaffected by mistake, deceit, or duress, the contract is normally
binding. But if the agreement is that A is to pay B for giving perjured evidence on his
behalf, neither party would be able to claim either for performance or for damages for
non-performance. However committed a legal system may be to the principle of free-
dom of contract, it is bound to deny enforcement to a contract which conflicts with
the law or good morals or offends ‘public policy’ or is ‘contraire aux bonnes moeurs ou
à l’ordre public’.
Legislative provisions in this area are necessarily rather vague.1 Some continental
civil codes do no more than distinguish between contracts which are illegal and those
which are immoral,2 to which the Dutch Civil Code adds contracts in breach of pub-
lic order.3 The French Code civil used to deal with the present problem in relation to
the concept of cause. This was abandoned in the course of the recent reform of French
contract law,4 and arts. 1128 and 1162 now simply provide that a contract must have
‘un contenu licite’ and must not derogate from ‘l’ordre public’.5
The codal texts on contracts which conflict with good morals, public order, or legal
prescriptions are all what German lawyers call ‘general clauses’, which need to be
fleshed out by reference to court decisions. That is why commentators who try to put
European Contract Law. Second Edition. Hein Kötz, Oxford University Press (2017). © Hein Kötz 2017
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780198800040.003.0007
110 Unfair, Illegal, and Immoral Contracts
the cases into some sort of order invariably add that the categories they adopt are nei-
ther exhaustive nor mutually exclusive.
Contracts which until quite recently were regarded as offensive may now be per-
fectly acceptable. This is especially the case with respect to contracts where it is uncer-
tain if they contravene generally accepted principles of family life or sexual morals.
Contracts whereby a party in an unmarried partnership could promise to pay the
other a certain sum of money if the partnership were to end would previously have
6 See, for example, Civ. 22 Oct. 1980, Bull.cass. 1980.I. no. 269; Civ 11 Feb. 1986, Bull.cass. 1986.I. no. 21;
BGH 31 Mar. 1970, BGHZ 53, 369; BGH 12 Jan. 1984, [1984] NJW 2150: BG 17 Jan. 1983, BGE 109 II 15. See
also the case law discussed in GH Treitel, The Law of Contract (13th edn, by E Peel, 2011) no. 11-040.
7 See H MacQueen, ‘Illegality and Immorality in Contracts’ in A Hartkamp et al. (eds), Towards a
European Civil Code (4th edn, 2011) 555.
Performance and Counterperformance 111
centuries. Classical Roman law had no such requirement, and recognised the validity
of a contract of sale whatever the relationship between the price and the true value of
the goods. It was only in the later Roman period, according to the Corpus Iuris,8 that
an ordinance was promulgated—there is some doubt whether it dates from the third
or only the sixth century ad—which gave the seller of land the right to resile from the
contract if the price agreed was less than half its true value. Socio-political consider
ations were clearly behind this innovation: peasants impoverished by the Emperor’s
8 C. 4.44.2.
9 On this, and what follows, see R Zimmermann, The Law of Obligations, Roman Foundations of the
Civilian Tradition (1990) 259ff. with references to the extensive literature on the history of laesio enormis.
See also von Mehren (n 1) vol. VII ch 1, 83ff.
10 § 351a Austrian Commercial Code.
112 Unfair, Illegal, and Immoral Contracts
benefit of the bargain (art. 1681). The practical application of this article has not been
trouble-free.11
Such rules do not figure in more recent civil codes: they were rather out of place in
an economy increasingly dominated by liberalism. In an acquisitive bourgeois soci-
ety founded on freedom of contract, establishment, and competition, it was an article
of faith that people were sufficiently businesslike and judicious to look after them-
selves. Thus, any rule that allowed the judge to avoid a contract because of substantial
11 See the details in J Ghestin, Traité de droit civil, La formation du contrat (1993) no. 555ff; B Starck,
H Roland, and L Boyer, Droit civil, Obligations, Contrat et quasi-contrat, Régime général (5th edn, 1995)
nn 806ff.
12 § 879(2) no. 4 ABGB; art. 21 OR; art. 179 Greek Civil Code; § 31 Nordic Contract Law; art. 282
Portuguese Civil Code. See also art. 388 Polish Civil Code.
13 See It. Cass. 28 June 1994, republished in part in ZEuP 1997, 475 with note by C Becker.
14 See Hoge Raad 29 May 1964, [1965] NedJur 104: A vendor, whose age-related inexperience was taken
advantage of, may rescind a contract for the sale of real property even if the agreed price was reasonable.
15 See art. 4: 109 PECL; art. 3.2.7 PICC; art. II.-7:207 DCFR; art. 30(3) CEC; art. 51 CESL. There is
agreement that a contract concluded under such circumstances is not void per se, but can be voided or
challenged by the disadvantaged party.
Performance and Counterperformance 113
pursuant to the requirements of § 138(2) BGB, the disadvantaged party can still assert
that the contract is void pursuant to § 138(1). It is true that the advantaged party must
have acted ‘with reprehensible attitude’, but such an attitude can be assumed even if
the advantaged party had no knowledge of the gross disparity.16
The French Code civil contains no rule comparable to § 138(2) BGB, but the courts
reach much the same results in practice by allowing the advantaged party to impugn
the contract on the ground of ‘violence’. Under art. 1143 Code civil, it is to be consid-
16 See BGH 19 Jan. 2001, BGHZ 146, 298; BGH 19 July 2002, [2002] NJW 3165; BGH 29 June 2007,
[2007] NJW 2841. The assumption that they have acted with a ‘reprehensible attitude’ can be refuted by
the advantaged party if it can be shown that the parties had relied on an (erroneous) expert report. For
criticism of this, see T Finkenauer, ‘Zur Renaissance des laesio enormis beim Kaufvertrag’ in Festschrift
H.P. Westermann (2008) 183; R Bork, Allgemeiner Teil des Bürgerlichen Gesetzbuchs (4th edn, 2016) mn.
1193, 1199.
17 In some cases of this type, the contract has been held invalid for dol. See, for example, Civ. 20 April
1966, Bull.cass. 1966.I. no. 224; Civ. 23 Jan. 1969, Bull.cass. 1969.I. no. 21; Civ. 30 May 2000, Bull.cass.
2000.I. no. 69; Civ. 3 April 2002, Bull.cass. 2002.I. no. 108.
18 See Req. 12 Jan. 1931, Gaz Pal 1931.1.441; Paris 22 Mar. 1952, Gaz Pal 1952.2.102. Occasionally, the
courts have allowed the disadvantaged party to attack the contract on the ground of erreur; see Ghestin
(n 11) nos. 513, 579, 586, 588.
19 [1978] 1 WLR 255; and compare Backhouse v. Backhouse [1978] 1 All ER 1158, 1165f.
114 Unfair, Illegal, and Immoral Contracts
The important English institution of undue influence gives grounds for avoiding a
contract where a party can show that, although there was no duress, the contract was
concluded following undue pressure or on the basis of false information provided by
the other party. Such proof is not required if there is a relationship of special trust on
the basis of which one party could expect the other party to give loyal and complete
advice. The courts have found such a relationship of special trust, for example, in the
relationship between child and parent, ward and guardian, patient and doctor, peni-
20 See Treitel (n 6) no. 10-013ff. In continental systems, one often finds texts which seek to guard against
such conflicts of interest. Thus parents and guardians, as statutory agents, are like all other agents pro-
hibited from entering Insichgeschäfte, ie transactions in which they act as both agent and beneficiary. On
this, see below, pp. 303f. See also arts. 907, 909 Code civil, whereby contracts and testamentary disposi-
tions made during a fatal illness are void if made in favour of an attendant doctor or priest. Transactions
are also void if made by a resident in a residential home for senior citizens in favour of the personnel: see
arts. L.331-4 and L.443-6 French Code de l’action sociale et des familles; BGH 9 Feb. 1990, BGHZ 110, 235;
BayObLG 28 June 1991, [1992] NJW 55. See in detail, AP Bell, ‘Abuse of a Relationship: Undue Influence
in English and French Law’ (2007) 15 ERPL 555.
21 Royal Bank of Scotland v. Etridge (No. 2) [2001] 4 All ER 449; see also Barclays Bank v. O’Brien [1994]
1 AC 180 and Treitel (n 6) no. 10-013ff.
22 [1975] QB 326 (CA).
Performance and Counterperformance 115
on undue influence, since the father had been a customer of the bank for very many
years and the circumstances were such that he could expect it to give him full infor-
mation and advice. But the third judge, Lord Denning, adduced a general principle of
law in support of the same conclusion. After recounting all the various ways in which
English law had protected the weaker party from disadvantageous contracts, he said:
Gathering all together, I would suggest that through all these instances there runs a
23 Ibid at 339.
24 See National Westminster Bank v. Morgan [1985] 1 All ER 821, 830 (per Lord Scarman). In this deci-
sion, Lord Scarman doubted ‘whether there is any need in the modern law to erect a general principle of
relief against inequality of bargaining power. Parliament has undertaken the task—a nd it is essentially a
legislative task—of enacting such restrictions upon freedom of contract as are in its judgment necessary
to relief against [such] mischief.’ Such laws are enacted where there is a need, for example, to protect con-
sumers against disadvantage from credit agreements (see Consumer Credit Act 1974, s. 140 A and B) or
from unfair contract terms (see Unfair Contract Terms Act 1977; Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts
Regulations 1999; and below, pp. 140ff.).
25 See, for example, H Beale, ‘Inequality of Bargaining Power’ [1986] OJLS 123; S Thal, ‘The Inequality
of Bargaining Power Doctrine’ [1988] OJLS 17; S Smith, ‘In Defence of Substantive Fairness’ (1996) 112
LQR 138; E McKendrick, Contract Law (8th edn, 2009) no. 17.4 and 7; contra Treitel (n 6) no. 10-046.
In other Common Law jurisdictions, such as Canada and Australia, the development is clearly in this
direction, and in the US § 2-302 UCC provides that a court may refuse to enforce a contract or clause in
a contract which it finds ‘unconscionable’; Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 208 is to the same effect.
26 Paris 18 Jan. 1978, JCP 1980.II.19318, n. P Simler. See also the decision of the court of Bordeaux 6
Dec. 1977, ibid.: guarantees of a notary’s debts given by his wife and parents-in-law were void for ‘défaut
de cause et erreur substantielle’ where they had had no conception of the extent of his liability. See also
Civ. 25 May 1964, D.P. 1964, 626 and HR 1 Jun. 1990, [1991] NedJur 3293. In cases of this type, the con-
tract may also be void on the ground of violence (art. 1143 Code civil).
116 Unfair, Illegal, and Immoral Contracts
bank cannot enforce the guarantee where the person is not aware of the extent of the
liabilities.27
In such cases, German courts invoke § 138 BGB. Subsection (2) of this provision,
as mentioned above, is admittedly inapplicable since it is impossible for performance
and counterperformance to be ‘clearly disproportionate’ in the case of a guarantee,
where there is no counterperformance at all. Instead, one looks to subsection (1) and
asks if the guarantee is morally offensive. Usually it is not, since even adults whose
27 See also § 25d of the Austrian Consumer Protection Law: under this, the judge may ‘reduce or even
waive in its entirety’ the liabilities of a consumer arising from a guarantee (or from another form of inter-
cession) if ‘under all the circumstances the liability is out of all proportion to the financial abilities’ of
the consumer. The circumstances that the judge can take into account include the benefit flowing to the
consumer from the performance of the creditor and ‘the imprudence, predicament, inexperience, agita-
tion or dependence of the intercessionary to the debtor when the liability was assumed’.
28 The guarantor must also issue the guarantee in writing (see above, c hapter 5.B), and if undertaken as
a consumer as part of a doorstep contract, such guarantee may also be subsequently recalled (see below,
chapter 11.B.I).
29 See, for example, BGH 18 Sept. 1997, BGHZ 136, 350; BGH 14 Nov. 2000, BGHZ 146, 37; BGH 14
May 2002, BGHZ 151,34; BGH 14 Oct. 2003, BGHZ 156, 302; BGH 25 Jan. 2005, [2005] NJW 971 (settled
case law).
30 For a historical legal and comparative history of the issue, see also N Jansen, ‘Seriositätskontrollen
existentiell belastender Versprechen’ in R Zimmermann (ed), Störungen der Willensbildung bei
Vertragsschluß (2007) 125. Also G Wagner, ‘Materialisierung des Schuldrechts unter dem Einfluß von
Undue Restraints 117
There is also great debate about whether a contract that offends ‘good morals’ or
contravenes ordre public is always void per se, or whether a judge may modify, reduce,
or reform the contract, thus maintaining its validity with a modified content.31 What
is the position, for example, if a party insists on an unconscionably high or low price,
or accepts a guarantee that ‘greatly overstretches’ the debtor? Can the judge reduce
or raise the purchase price to a reasonable level, or so restrict the scope of the guar-
antee that the guarantor can meet the resulting liabilities with available means? The
Verfassungsrecht und Europarecht—Was bleibt von der Vertragsfreiheit?’ in K Blaurock and B Hager
(eds), Obligationenrecht im 21. Jahrhundert (2010) 13, 30ff.
31 This problem also arises where a contract includes provisions by which there is an ‘excessive’ restric-
tion on a party’s freedom of contract, an ‘excessive’ disadvantaging of the party’s legal status, or an
‘excessive’ contravention of statutory provisions designed to protect the party’s position. The overriding
question is whether the impact of the ‘excess’ may be reduced in order to maintain the validity of the con-
tract. On this, see pp. 121, 143. The matter is different if the party relying on the invalidity of the contract
states a willingness to accept the contract if the terms are amended to its advantage. International rules
allow for contractual amendment in such cases. See art. 4:109(2) PECL: a party can avoid a contract if
its weakness has been exploited by the other party, thereby giving that party an unfair or excess benefit.
Upon the request of the disadvantaged party, the judge may ‘if it is appropriate adapt the contract in
order to bring it into accordance with what might have been agreed had the requirements of good faith
and fair dealing been followed.’ Similarly, art. 3.2.7(2) and (3) PICC; art. II.-7: 207(2) and (3) DCFR.
Those legal orders that recognise laesio enormis permit the perpetuation of the contract, provided that
the advantaged party is prepared to allow its own performance to be adapted so that there is a balance
with the performance of the other party. See art. 1450 Codice civile; art. 1674 Code civil; § 947 ABGB.
Pursuant to art. 3:54(2) BW, at the request of one party, instead of declaring a contract to be void due to
exploitation of the circumstances, the judge may adapt the contract so as to balance out the disadvantage.
See, in the same sense, BG 26 June 1997, BGE 123 III 292 and the comparative note by P Pichonnaz (1999)
7 ZEuP 140.
32 BGH 21 March 1977, BGHZ 68, 204, 207; BGH 14 Nov. 2000, BGHZ 146, 37, 47f; BGH 17 Oct. 2008,
[2009] NJW 1135.
118 Unfair, Illegal, and Immoral Contracts
freedom. Thus, if a borrower promises a lender not to move house or change jobs
without the lender’s written permission, nor to take out further loans or dispose of any
of his property, the borrower is not bound by his promise.33 Equally invalid is a trans-
action whereby a person transfers so much of his property to another as virtually to
deprive himself of the capacity and ability to make any future dispositions.34
While the principal concern in such cases is the public interest in the citizen’s free-
dom of trade, profession, and artistic activity, there is also an element of protecting the
III. Non-compete agreements
An undertaking not to compete with the other party could, if held valid, involve an
unacceptable restriction of economic freedom. Such non-compete agreements often
figure in contracts of employment, since employers are afraid that employees may
leave to join a competitor, or set up a business of their own, and then make contact
with the employer’s customers or exploit the special skills or information they gained
in their previous job. On the other hand, a non-compete agreement may have a seri-
ous impact on an employee’s ability to work—often their only source of income. The
employer’s greater bargaining power also means that agreements often favour the
employer’s interests at the expense of the employee. Accordingly, employment law
upholds such non-compete agreements only in special circumstances, and they are
often laid down by statute or in collective bargaining agreements. Thus, art. 2125 of
the Italian Codice civile provides that a non-compete agreement is only valid if it is
made in writing, is restricted in scope, duration, and locality, with the further con-
dition that the employee must be paid something extra for agreeing to it.41 Courts in
France and England have evolved somewhat similar rules.42
When a business is sold, it is very common for the seller to promise not to enter into
competition with the buyer. Such a covenant benefits the seller as well as the buyer, for
the buyer will pay more for the business in confidence that the seller will not compete,
solicit former customers, or try to profit from special familiarity with sources and
outlets. This consideration identifies the viewpoint from which the validity of such a
clause must be judged: it should not limit the seller’s freedom to compete beyond what
is needed to maintain the value of the business being sold and its goodwill (clientele,
43 Here one must also consider the compatibility of the clause with national or European competi-
tion law. See BGH 3 Nov. 1981, [1982] NJW 2000: here the non-compete clause in the sale of a busi-
ness was unobjectionable under § 138 BGB, but possibly in conflict with § 1 Act against Restraints of
Competition (GWB).
44 [1894] AC 535.
45 BGH 13 March 1979, [1979] NJW 1605. The decision in Com. 19 Jan. 1981, D.S. 1982.I.R.204, n. Y
Serra, is apparently much more generous: it upheld a contractual restraint on competition by the seller
of a grocery business who had promised not to compete for twenty years within twenty kilometres of the
business sold.
46 BGH 26 March 1984, BGHZ 91, 1, 6ff; see also BGH 9 May 1968, [1968] NJW 1717. To like effect is
Bridge v. Deacons [1984] AC 705 (PC): a solicitor can validly covenant that for five years after leaving the
partnership he will not accept retainers from clients he had advised during his last three years in the
partnership. See also Soc. 12 June 1986, D.S. 1987.Somm. 264, n. Y Serra: covenant valid whereby a lawyer
engaged by a conseil juridique promises for three years not to advise prior clients.
Undue Restraints 121
dans une autre branche d’activité, notamment dans celle d’un ingénieur conseil’.47 A
fortiori, the seller of a legal practice cannot validly bind himself never to compete any-
where at all.48
IV. Partial invalidity
A restraint on competition which is greater than is permissible—namely too wide in
The picture in France is similar. An employee who had promised not to work for a
competitor in the same field during the ten years following his departure, a manifestly
excessive period, nevertheless took a position with a competitor in the same city on
the very day he left the plaintiff’s employment. He was held liable, for ‘une clause de
non-concurrence . . . ne doit être annulée que dans la mesure où elle porte atteinte à la
liberté du travail en raison de son étendue dans le temps et dans l’espace et quant à la
nature de l’activité de l’intéressé’.53
1984 (n 46) 6f. Here the court upheld a clause insofar as it restrained the defendant from contacting the
plaintiff’s customers but struck it down to the extent it restrained him from general competition. Swiss
decisions are to the same effect, see BG 5 Oct. 1965, BGE 91 II 372 (temporal and geographical restraints
on a travelling salesman).
53 Soc. 21 Oct. 1960, JCP 1960.II.11886; Soc. 1 Dec. 1982, Bull.cass. 1982.V. no. 668; Soc. 25 Jan. 1984,
Bull.cass. 1984.V. no. 31. See also Ghestin (n 11) no. 915.
54 Bedford Insurance Co. v. Instituto de Resseguros do Brasil [1985] QB 966; Phoenix General Insurance
Co. v. Halvanon Insurance Co. Ltd. [1988] QB 216.
Breach of the Law 123
More often statutes do not allude to the question whether contracts formed in
breach of their provisions are valid or not; they simply provide that the infringer
shall be punished, have its licence withdrawn, or suffer some other sanction. Here the
judge must construe the statute in order to discover whether its unexpressed inten-
tion was that contracts formed in breach of it should be void. Thus § 134 BGB provides
that contracts which infringe a statute are void ‘unless the statute leads to a different
conclusion’.55
language, scope and purpose, the consequences for the innocent party, and any other
relevant consideration.60
If, for example, court officials (huissiers) are forbidden to engage in remunerated activ-
ity outside of their employment, it is doubtful whether they may claim the agreed
commission from a person for whom they illicitly negotiate a deal. The law is certainly
designed to deter huissiers from such activities and it would clearly serve this aim if
60 Phoenix General Insurance Co. (n 54) per Kerr LJ at 176. To the same effect is BGH 23 Oct. 1980,
BGHZ 78, 263, 265. Such a flexible solution can also be found in art. 15:102 PECL. The most important
consideration is whether the effects of the infringement upon the contract are expressly prescribed by the
mandatory rule. Where the mandatory rule does not expressly prescribe the effects, the contract may be
declared to have full effect, to have some effect, to have no effect, or to be subject to modification. This
turns in particular on the purpose of the rule which has been infringed, whether the party claiming
invalidity belongs to the category of persons for whose protection the rule exists, and any sanction that
may be imposed against the infringer under the rule infringed. A similar approach is taken under art.
3.3.1(3) PICC; art. II. -7:302(3) DC FR.
61 Civ. 15 Feb. 1961, Bull.cass. 1961.I. no105; Civ. 21 Oct. 1968, D.S. 1969, 81.
62 Com. 11 May 1976, JCP 1976.II.18452, n. R Rodière (freight forwarder obtains a valid lien, arising out
of the contract, on the goods of the principal).
63 BGH 23 Oct. 1980, BGHZ 78, 269 (the agent may claim the commission).
64 BGH 23 Oct. 1980, BGHZ 78, 263 (tax adviser can claim the agreed fee).
65 Archbolds (Freightage) Ltd. v. Spanglett Ltd. [1961] 1 QB 374 (CA): the carrier could not defend a
claim for the value of the goods which had been stolen by arguing that the contract of carriage was
void, but could he have claimed the agreed sum for the carriage if they had been duly delivered? St John
Shipping Corp. v. Joseph Rank [1957] 1 QB 267 held that he could: the carrier’s claim for freight was
granted although the captain had committed an offence by overloading the vessel.
66 BGH 19 Jan. 1984, BGHZ 89, 369. 67 Amiens 9 Feb. 1976, JCP 1977.IV.45.
Restitution of Benefits Conferred 125
any other kind because the law is designed to protect ‘non seulement l’intérêt général et
celui des établissements de crédit, mais aussi celui des crédit-preneurs’.68 By contrast, a
building society empowered by law to accept only first mortgages was able to enforce a
second mortgage, since the aim of the law was to protect the society and its members,
not its debtors.69
68 Com. 19 Nov. 1991, n. J Mestre in (1992) 91 Rev trim civ 381. Different is Civ. 13 Oct. 1982, Bull.cass.
1982.I. no. 286: here the defendant obtained a perfectly normal loan of FF 600,000 from the plaintiff
which was not lawfully entitled to give credit of this kind, not being registered as a bank. The Cour de
cassation held that the plaintiff’s breach of the law ‘ne portant atteinte qu’à l’intérêt général et à celui de la
profession du banquier . . . n’est pas de nature à entraîner la nullité du contrat de prêt’.
69 Nash v. Halifax Building Society [1979] 2 All ER 19. 70 Paul D. 12,5,3.
71 Ulpian D. 12,5,4 pr. 72 Ulpian D. 12,5,4,3.
73 Papinian D. 12,7,5 pr. For historical details and a comparative view, see Zimmermann (n 9) 863ff.
74 See § 817 sent. 2 BGB; art. 66 OR; § 1174 ABGB; art. 2035 Codice civile. Dutch law is different: benefits
conferred pursuant to an invalid contract may in principle be reclaimed even if the nullity results from
infringement of the law or morals. But under art. 6:211 BW a court may reject the claim in restitution if
decency and fairness so require. On this, see HR 28 June 1991, [1992] Ned Jur 787. This solution has the
merit of allowing the judge to weigh openly the reasons for and against the claim for restitution. A similar
flexibility has been proposed in England: in Tinsley v. Milligan [1992] Ch. 310 (CA), [1993] 3 All ER 65 (HL)
two parties who had both contributed to the purchase of a house on the basis that it should belong to them
in equal parts registered it in the name of the plaintiff alone in order that the defendant could dissimulate
her wealth and so claim higher social security benefits. When the parties fell out, the plaintiff sought pos-
session of the house which was in her name alone, and the defendant counterclaimed for an order that the
house be sold and that half of the proceeds be paid to her. Both the Court of Appeal and the House of Lords
allowed the counterclaim, though with dissents in each instance, even though the counterclaimant had
used the transaction in an attempt to defraud the social security authorities and secure herself an illegal
benefit. In the Court of Appeal, Nichols LJ applied what he called the ‘public conscience test’: ‘The court
must weigh, or balance, the adverse consequences of granting relief against the adverse consequences of
refusing relief. The ultimate decision calls for a value judgment . . . Balancing these considerations I have
no doubt that, far from it being an affront to the public conscience to grant relief in this case, it would be an
affront to the public conscience not to do so. Right-t hinking people would not consider that condemnation
of the parties’ fraudulent activities ought to have the consequence of permitting the plaintiff to retain the
defendant’s half-share of this house. That would be to visit on the defendant a disproportionate penalty,
in the circumstances as they are now’ (at 319–21). The House of Lords reached the same conclusion, but
decisively rejected the ‘public conscience’ test. For further details, see McKendrick (n 25) no. 15.18.
75 French courts are rather given to using the formula nemo auditur propriam turpitudinem alle-
gans, which is rather wider and prompts commentators to ask whether it may not apply to claims for a
126 Unfair, Illegal, and Immoral Contracts
As long as cases involved parties who had flouted basic moral precepts or conspired
to do something punishable by law it seemed reasonable enough to deny restitution
‘als Strafe für die Betätigung verwerflicher Gesinnung’ (punishment for putting dis-
graceful intentions into action)76 or to justify its denial as protecting the dignity of
the court: ‘No court will lend its aid to a man who founds his cause of action upon an
immoral or illegal act.’77 In Germany also, it was said that restitution must be denied
‘in order to protect the state from abusive invocation of its jurisdiction by deliberate
declaration that the contract is void or to claims in delict. See P le Tourneau, Juris-classeur civil art. 1131
à 1133 (Règle ‘nemo auditur’) no. 34ff.
76 The courts in Germany often use this phrase. See, for example, RG 8 Nov. 1922, RGZ 105, 270, 271
and BGH 31 Jan. 1963, BGHZ 39, 87, 91. The idea of punishment is clearly inappropriate, since for one
thing the ‘punishment’—t he denial of restitution—can be entirely out of proportion to the seriousness
of the infraction and because furthermore the ‘punishment’ leads to the enrichment of the complicitous
defendant who can retain what was transferred even when his conduct was much more deplorable and
therefore more deserving of ‘punishment’ than the claimant’s. It would be more logical to allow the state
to claim the benefit transferred and so deny it to both parties; this was done in the Prussian ALR (1794),
§ 172f. I 16 and in art. 411f. Polish Civil Code.
77 Holman v. Johnson (1775) 1 Cowp. 341, 98 Eng.Rep. 1120, per Lord Mansfield.
78 Supreme Court for the British Zone 10 Dec. 1950, OGHZ 4, 57, 60.
79 Théorie et pratique des obligations (2nd edn, 1885) i, 333, cited by Ghestin (n 11) no. 931.
80 Thus Treitel (n 6) no. 11-127: the ‘general rule’ is that benefits rendered in performance of an illegal
contract cannot be reclaimed, but ‘It would be better if the law did not adopt a “general rule” but asked
in relation to each type of illegality whether it was recovery or non-recovery that was the more likely to
promote the purpose of the invalidating rule.’ The same approach is taken by art. 15:104 PECL whereby
restitution of services performed under a contract turns on whether or not this is justified on the grounds
on which the validity of the contract itself depends. Similarly also art. 3.3.2.(2) PICC.
Restitution of Benefits Conferred 127
rejecting the restitutionary claim? One such rule is surely that restitution should be
allowed if the defendant is the person primarily responsible for the illegality or immor-
ality, and the claimant is relatively innocent or in need of protection. In England, the
saying is that the claim for restitution should only be denied when the parties are ‘in
pari delicto’. If the defendant deceived the claimant into believing the contract licit,
or took advantage of the claimant’s predicament, inexperience, or fecklessness, or the
claimant belonged to a class which it was the purpose of the rule infringed to pro-
81 See C Larroumet, Droit civil, vol. III: Les obligations, Le contrat, Effets (6th edn, 2007) no. 581.
There is special need for the differentiation in accord with the degree of culpability in cases where the
reasons for the invalidity of the contract are not known to one party, which is therefore ‘innocent’. In
such circumstances, both the ‘innocent’ and the ‘non-innocent’ party may assert the contract to be
invalid (see Civ. 7 Oct. 1998, D. 1998, 563 = JCP 1998.II.10202, n. MH Maleville = JCP 1999.I.114, n. C
Jamin). If it is the non-i nnocent party that asserts the claim for restitution, such claim may be denied
on the basis of the rule ‘nemo auditur’; in addition, the party may also be liable for other damages
under the law of tort.
82 RG 24 Oct. 1919, RGZ 97, 82, 84. The claimant was accordingly allowed to reclaim the part of the
price which was illegal. So too BGH 23 Nov. 1959, LM § 817 BGB no. 12, where a merchant could reclaim
the interest paid on a loan void for immorality. Admittedly, he himself had acted immorally in paying
the excessive interest, since as a merchant he must have known that his conduct would accelerate his
financial collapse and prejudice his other creditors, but he had displayed no ‘deplorable attitude’ since it
was only his economic difficulties which led him to enter the contract. Compare BG 21 Nov. 1950, BGE
76 II 346, 369ff: a criminal who has paid hush money can reclaim it despite art. 66 OR if he paid only in
response to blackmail: it is an abuse of right under art. 2 Swiss Civil Code to invoke art. 66 OR in order
to refuse repayment of hush money.
83 RG 10 Jan. 1930, RGZ 127, 276, 279; Gray v. Southouse [1949] 2 All ER 1019; Kiriri Cotton Co.
v. Dewani [1960] AC 192 (PC).
84 See Com. 11 May 1976, Bull.cass. 1976.IV. no. 162.
128 Unfair, Illegal, and Immoral Contracts
return of the capital paid out.85 This decision went too far. The financial sanctions on
the bank for breach of the law were already stringent, and it was quite unnecessary to
deny its claim to restitution and give the customer an undeserved bonus. Furthermore,
the purpose of the law was to cool the economy rather than to protect the borrower,
and leaving the borrower with the money had just the opposite effect.
French commentators often note that while restitution is denied in the case of
immoral contracts, it is generally allowed where the contract is merely illegal.86
85 BG 21 Dec. 1976, BGE 102 II 401, 411f. The decision has been severely criticised. It would have been
better to allow the bank to recover the money lent under the second loan, at least after the agreed period.
German courts decide in this way when a loan has been made on terms which are usurious and accord-
ingly immoral. The effect of § 817 sent. 2 BGB is that the bank cannot claim interest for the period of the
loan, but can recover the capital at the end of the agreed period. The leading case is RG 30 June 1939, RGZ
161, 52, 57ff. and subsequent decisions.
86 See, for example, Starck, Roland, and Boyer (n 11) no. 937ff; J Carbonnier, Droit civil: Les obligations
(22nd edn, 2000) no. 49. This is explicit in Aix 28 Mar. 1945, Gaz.Pal. 1945.2.12; Colmar 4 Jan. 1961, Gaz.
Pal. 1961.1.304. The commentators all agree, however, that this is simply a rule of thumb.
87 Civ. 18 June 1969, JCP 1969.II.16131, n. P.L.; see also Angers 2 Apr. 1952, JCP 1952.II.6953.
88 Shelley v. Paddock [1980] 1 All ER 1009 (CA). It is different if both parties know that the proposed
transaction infringes exchange control regulations: see Bigos v. Bousted [1951] 1 All ER 92.
89 RG 16 May 1919, RGZ 95, 347, 349.
90 The Bundesgericht allows an exception only when the claimant was deceived by the defendant. See
the decision to this effect of 27 Jan. 1948, BGE 74 II 23. See also OLG Hamm 22 May 1986, [1986] NJW
2440: a person who runs a bar without the proper licence, and pays money to the defendant to ensure that
the true licence-holder keeps quiet, cannot reclaim the money unless the defendant has taken advantage
of the economic plight or inexperience of the plaintiff so that, as the English judges might say, the parties
are not ‘in pari delicto’.
91 See text to n 59 above.
Restitution of Benefits Conferred 129
law is not met if the customer can keep the benefit of the services rendered without
paying anything to the black market service provider. The customer should pay the
objective value of those services, which will be rather less than the contract price
in view of the fact that the customer has no come-back should the services prove
defective.92
In English law, a restitutionary claim may be allowed if the transaction was not fully
executed. This ‘locus poenitentiae’, as it is called, gives the claimant an incentive to
92 See BGH 31 May 1990, BGHZ 111, 308, 312ff. 93 See Treitel (n 6) no. 11-136ff.
94 See Bowmakers Ltd. v. Barnet Instruments [1945] KB 65, and on it Treitel (n 6) no. 11-139ff.
95 See for example Paris 16 Mar. 1926, S. 1926.2.76; Nancy 8 June 1934, D.P.1935.2.33, n. Voirin.
96 Thus when an owner has delivered property of his to the defendant in circumstances of illegality or
immorality, he can claim damages if the defendant damages the thing or, if he uses it, the objective value
of such use. See BGH 14 June 1951, [1951] NJW 643; BGH 8 Jan. 1975, BGHZ 63, 365, 368f.
97 BGH 20 May 1964, BGHZ 41, 341, 343ff. The decision could hardly be different when demand is
made for immediate repayment of a loan to set up a brothel. Here there is no question of the lender
relying on his ownership, but the claim must be granted because otherwise the defendant could use the
money to run the brothel without even having to pay interest on it.
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/book/41064/chapter/349770516 by Thammasat University user on 03 September 2024