Rohini 41146270927
Rohini 41146270927
& TECHNOLOGY
DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS
BA4201 / QUANTITATIVE TECHNIQUES FOR DECISION MAKING
INTRODUCTION
Decision tree analysis is a powerful decision-making tool which initiates a structured
nonparametric approach for problem-solving. It facilitates the evaluation and comparison
of the various options and their results, as shown in a decision tree. It helps to choose the
most competitive alternative. A decision tree is the graphical depiction of all the
possibilities or outcomes to solve a specific issue or avail a potential opportunity. It is a
useful financial tool which visually facilitates the classification of all the probable results.
Let us understand some of the relevant concepts and terms used in the decision tree:
Root Node: A root node compiles the whole sample, it is then divided into multiple
sets which comprise of homogeneous variables.
Decision Node: That sub-node which diverges into further possibilities, can be
denoted as a decision node.
Terminal Node: The final node showing the outcome which cannot be categorized
any further, is termed as a value or terminal node.
Branch: A branch denotes the various alternatives available with the decision tree
maker.
Splitting: The division of the available option (depicted by a node or sub-node) into
multiple sub-nodes is termed as splitting.
Pruning: It is just the reverse of splitting, where the decision tree maker can
eliminate one or more sub-nodes from a particular decision node.
Steps in Decision Tree Analysis
Following steps simplify the interpretation process of a decision tree:
1. The first step is understanding and specifying the problem area for which decision
making is required.
2. The second step is interpreting and chalking out all possible solutions to the
particular issue as well as their consequences.
3. The third step is presenting the variables on a decision tree along with its respective
probability values.
4. The fourth step is finding out the outcomes of all the variables and specifying it in
the decision tree.
5. The last step is highly crucial and backs the overall analysis of this process. It
involves calculating the EMV values for all the chance nodes or options, to figure
out the solution which provides the highest expected value.
Problem : 1 : ABC Company is considering whether it should tender for two contracts
(MS1 and MS2) on offer from a government department for the supply of certain
components. The company has three options: tender for MS1 only; or tender for MS2 only;
or tender for both MS1 and MS2. If tenders are to be submitted the company will incur
additional costs. These costs will have to be entirely recouped from the contract price. The
risk, of course, is that if a tender is unsuccessful the company will have made a loss. The
cost of tendering for contract MS1 only is £50,000. The component supply cost if the tender
is successful would be £18,000. The cost of tendering for contract MS2 only is £14,000.
The component supply cost if the tender is successful would be £12,000. The cost of
tendering for both contract MS1 and contract MS2 is £55,000. The component supply cost
if the tender is successful would be £24,000. For each contract, possible tender prices have
been determined. In addition, subjective assessments have been made of the probability of
getting the contract with a particular tender price as shown below. Note here that the
company can only submit one tender and cannot, for example, submit two tenders (at
different prices) for the same contract.
Option Possible Probability
tender of getting
prices (£) contract
MS1 only 130,000 0.20
115,000 0.85
MS2 only 70,000 0.15
65,000 0.80
60,000 0.95
MS1 and MS2 190,000 0.05
140,000 0.65
In the event that the company tenders for both MS1 and MS2 it will either win both
contracts (at the price shown above) or no contract at all.
What do you suggest the company should do and why?
What are the downside and the upside of your suggested course of action?
A consultant has approached your company with an offer that in return for £20,000
in cash she will ensure that if you tender £60,000 for contract MS2 only your tender
is guaranteed to be successful. Should you accept her offer or not and why?
Solution
Below we carry out step 1 of the decision tree solution procedure which (for this
example) involves working out the total profit for each of the paths from the initial node
to the terminal node (all figures in £'000).
Step 1
path to terminal node 12, we tender for MS1 only (cost 50), at a price of 130, and
win the contract, so incurring component supply costs of 18,
total profit 130-50-18 = 62
path to terminal node 13, we tender for MS1 only (cost 50), at a price of 130, and
lose the contract, total profit -50
path to terminal node 14, we tender for MS1 only (cost 50), at a price of 115, and
win the contract, so incurring component supply costs of 18,
total profit 115-50-18 = 47
path to terminal node 15, we tender for MS1 only (cost 50), at a price of 115, and
lose the contract, total profit -50
path to terminal node 16, we tender for MS2 only (cost 14), at a price of 70, and
win the contract, so incurring component supply costs of 12,
total profit 70-14-12 = 44
path to terminal node 17, we tender for MS2 only (cost 14), at a price of 70, and
lose the contract, total profit -14
path to terminal node 18, we tender for MS2 only (cost 14), at a price of 65, and
win the contract, so incurring component supply costs of 12,
total profit 65-14-12 = 39
path to terminal node 19, we tender for MS2 only (cost 14), at a price of 65, and
lose the contract, total profit -14
path to terminal node 20, we tender for MS2 only (cost 14), at a price of 60, and
win the contract, so incurring component supply costs of 12,
total profit 60-14-12 = 34
path to terminal node 21, we tender for MS2 only (cost 14), at a price of 60, and
lose the contract, total profit -14
path to terminal node 22, we tender for MS1 and MS2 (cost 55), at a price of 190,
and win the contract, so incurring component supply costs of 24,
total profit 190-55- 24=111
path to terminal node 23, we tender for MS1 and MS2 (cost 55), at a price of 190,
and lose the contract, total profit -55
path to terminal node 24, we tender for MS1 and MS2 (cost 55), at a price of 140,
and win the contract, so incurring component supply costs of 24,
total profit 140-55- 24=61
path to terminal node 25, we tender for MS1 and MS2 (cost 55), at a price of 140,
and lose the contract, total profit -55
Hence we can arrive at the table below indicating for each branch the total profit involved
in that branch from the initial node to the terminal node.
Terminal node Total profit £'000
12 62
13 -50
14 47
15 -50
16 44
17 -14
18 39
19 -14
20 34
21 -14
22 111
23 -55
24 61
25 -55
We can now carry out the second step of the decision tree solution procedure where we
work from the right-hand side of the diagram back to the left-hand side.
Step 2
Hence the best decision at decision node 2 is to tender at a price of 115 (EMV=32.45).
Hence the best decision at decision node 4 is to tender at a price of 140 (EMV=20.4).
Hence the best decision is to tender for MS1 only (at a price of 115) as it has the highest
expected monetary value of 32.45 (£'000).
With regard to the consultants offer then, ignoring ethical considerations, we could of
course, tender 60 for MS2 only without her help and if we were to do that we would have
a 0.95 probability of having our tender accepted. Hence there are essentially three
options:
as before, tender for MS1 only at a price of 115: EMV 32.45, downside -50
(probability 0.15), upside 47 (probability 0.85)
tender for MS2 only at a price of 60, unaided by the consultant: EMV 31.6,
downside -14 (probability 0.05), upside 34 (probability 0.95)
tender for MS2 only at a price of 60, with the consultants help, then (assuming she
can fulfil her promise of guaranteeing we will be successful), we have a certain
outcome with a profit of 34 (terminal node 20) - 20
(cash paid to the consultant) = 14
On an EMV basis we would still support our original decision. Looking at the risks
(probabilities) of loosing money, and considering tendering for MS2 only at 60, we
would essentially be paying the consultant 20 to avoid a 0.05 chance of loosing 14, the
downside of tendering unaided. Paying 20 to guarantee not incurring a loss of 14 which
will occur with a probability of 0.05 (one in twenty) does not seem like an awfully good
investment and so we should reject her offer
If the three-day test exploration indicates significant metal deposits then the chances of
finding manganese, gold and silver increase to 3%, 2% and 1% respectively. If the three-
day test exploration fails to indicate significant metal deposits then the chances of finding
manganese, gold and silver decrease to 0.75%, 0.04% and 0.175% respectively.
Hence we can arrive at the table below indicating for each branch the total profit involved
in that branch from the initial node to the terminal node.
Terminal node Total profit £
8 0
9 26
10 246
11 146
12 -4
13 25
14 245
15 145
16 -5
17 -1
18 25
19 245
20 145
21 -5
22 -1
We can now carry out the second step of the decision tree solution procedure where we
work from the right-hand side of the diagram back to the left-hand side.
Step 2
Consider chance node 7 with branches to terminal nodes 15-21 emanating from it. The
expected monetary value for this chance node is given by
0.0075(25) + 0.0004(245) + 0.00175(145) + 0.99035(-5) = -4.4125
Hence the best decision at decision node 5 is to abandon (EMV=-1).
The EMV for chance node 6 is given by
0.03(25) + 0.02(245) + 0.01(145) + 0.94(-5) = 2.4
Hence the best decision at decision node 4 is to purchase (EMV=2.4).
The EMV for chance node 3 is given by 0.5(2.4) + 0.5(-1) = 0.7
The EMV for chance node 2 is given by 0.01(26) + 0.0005(246) + 0.002(146) + 0.9875(-
4) = -3.275
Hence at decision node 1 have three alternatives:
abandon EMV=0
purchase and explore EMV=-3.275
3-day test EMV=0.7
Hence the best decision is the 3-day test as it has the highest expected monetary value of
0.7 (£m).
Sharing the costs and revenues on a 50:50 basis merely halves all the monetary figures in
the above calculations and so the optimal EMV decision is exactly as before. However in
a wider context by accepting to share costs and revenues the company is spreading its
risk and from that point of view may well be a wise offer to accept.
Problem : 3
A company is trying to decide whether to bid for a certain contract or not. They estimate
that merely preparing the bid will cost £10,000. If their company bid then they estimate
that there is a 50% chance that their bid will be put on the "short-list", otherwise their bid
will be rejected. Once "short-listed" the company will have to supply further detailed
information (entailing costs estimated at £5,000). After this stage their bid will either be
accepted or rejected. The company estimate that the labour and material costs associated
with the contract are £127,000. They are considering three possible bid prices, namely
£155,000, £170,000 and £190,000. They estimate that the probability of these bids being
accepted (once they have been short-listed) is 0.90, 0.75 and 0.35 respectively. What
should the company do and what is the expected monetary value of your suggested course
of action?
Solution
We can now carry out the second step of the decision tree solution procedure where we
work from the right-hand side of the diagram back to the left-hand side.
Step 2
Consider chance node 4 with branches to terminal nodes 9 and 10 emanating from it. The
expected monetary value for this chance node is given by 0.90(13) + 0.10(-15) = 10.2
Similarly the EMV for chance node 5 is given by 0.75(28) + 0.25(-15) = 17.25
Hence at the bid price decision node we have the four alternatives
Hence the best alternative is to prepare the bid leading to an EMV of £3625. In the event
that the company is short-listed then (as discussed above) it should bid £170,000.
Problem : 4
A householder is currently considering insuring the contents of his house against theft for
one year. He estimates that the contents of his house would cost him £20,000 to replace.
Local crime statistics indicate that there is a probability of 0.03 that his house will be
broken into in the coming year. In that event his losses would be 10%, 20%, or 40% of the
contents with probabilities 0.5, 0.35 and 0.15 respectively. An insurance policy from
company A costs £150 a year but guarantees to replace any losses due to theft. An insurance
policy from company B is cheaper at £100 a year but the householder has to pay the first
£x of any loss himself. An insurance policy from company C is even cheaper at £75 a year
but only replaces a fraction (y%) of any loss suffered.
minimise x
s.t. -100 - 0.03x >= -108 i.e. EMV B >= EMV no policy
-100 - 0.03x >= -150 EMV B >= EMV A
-100 - 0.03x >= -183 + 1.08y EMV B >= EMV C
i.e.
minimise x
s.t.
x <= 266.67
x <= 1666.67
1.08y + 0.03x <= 83
x >= 0
y >= 0 and y <= 100
If x = 2000 then EMV B becomes -100-0.03(2000) = -160 so if x becomes that high we
would prefer no policy (EMV for chance node 1 = -108).
Problem : 5
Below we carry out step 1 of the decision tree solution procedure which (for this
example) involves working out the total profit for each of the paths from the initial node
to the terminal nodes.
Step 1
path to terminal node 9 - we carry out no program and flu does not strike
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 0
Total profit = 0
path to terminal node 10 - we carry out no program and flu strikes costing the
government £7m
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 7
Total profit = -7 (all figures in £m)
path to terminal nodes 11 and 12 similar to the case above giving a total profit of -
10 and -15 respectively
path to terminal node 13 - we carry out a program costing £7m and flu does not
strike
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 7
Total profit = -7
path to terminal node 14 - we carry out a program costing £7m and flu strikes.
Now we would have lost £7m with this flu outbreak but because of the program
(which we assume to be 100% effective) we do not.
The key here is to regard the £7m paid for the program as "insurance" which reimburses
the government for whatever losses are suffered as a result of flu striking. Hence we have
Total revenue = 7 (reimbursement)
Total cost = 7 (cost of program) + 7 (loss due to flu striking)
Total profit = -7
It is clear from the above calculation that since (in this case) the reimbursement always
exactly equals the amount lost the total profit will just be the cost of the "insurance" (-
£7m).
The situation with the vaccination program is very similar to household insurance where
a single payment guarantees replacement of any losses suffered. Whatever happens the
effect of the insurance will be "as if" nothing had occurred. Under these circumstances
the only expense (in effect) is the cost of the insurance.
path to terminal nodes 15 and 16 similar to the case above where we carry out a
program costing £7m and this insures us against losses. Hence
Total profit = -7 terminal node 15
Total profit = -7 terminal node 16
path to terminal node 17 - we carry out an early warning program costing £3m and
flu does not strike giving
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 3
Total profit = -3
path to terminal nodes 18, 19 and 20 - we carry out an early warning program
costing £3m, flu strikes and we decide to vaccinate costing £10m. Hence for a
total cost of £13m we are insured against losses so that we have
Total profit = -13 terminal node 18
Total profit = -13 terminal node 19
Total profit = -13 terminal node 20
path to terminal nodes 21, 22 and 23 - we carry out an early warning program
costing £3m, flu strikes but we decide not to vaccinate, leading to costs of £7m,
£10m and £15m. Hence
Total profit = -10 terminal node 21
Total profit = -13 terminal node 22
Total profit = -18 terminal node 23
Hence we can form the table below indicating for each branch the total profit involved in
that branch from the initial node to the terminal node.
Terminal node Total profit (£m)
9 0
10 -7
11 -10
12 -15
13 -7
14 -7
15 -7
16 -7
17 -3
18 -13
19 -13
20 -13
21 -10
22 -13
23 -18
We can now carry out the second step of the decision tree solution procedure where we
work from the right-hand side of the diagram back to the left-hand side.
Step 2
Consider chance node 2 (with branches to terminal nodes 10, 11 and 12 emanating from
it). The expected monetary value (EMV) for this chance node is given by 0.1 x (-7) + 0.3
x (-10) + 0.6 x (-15) = -12.7
Hence the EMV for chance node 1 is given by 0.25 x (0) + 0.75 x (-12.7) = -9.525
Similarly the EMV for chance node 7 is given by 0.1 x (-7) + 0.3 x (-7) + 0.6 x (-7) = -7
which leads to an EMV for chance node 3 of 0.25 x (-7) + 0.75 x (-7) = -7
The EMV for chance node 8 is 0.1 x (-13) + 0.3 x (-13) + 0.6 x (-13) = -13
and the EMV for chance node 6 is 0.1 x (-10) + 0.3 x (-13) + 0.6 x (-18) = -15.7
Hence for decision node 5 we have the two alternatives:
(4) vaccinate EMV = -13
(5) no vaccination EMV = -15.7
Hence the best alternative here is to vaccinate (alternative 4) with an EMV of -13.
The EMV for chance node 4 is therefore 0.25 x (-3) + 0.75 x (-13) = -10.5
and at the initial decision node (node 0) we have the three alternatives:
(1) no program EMV = -9.525
(2) program EMV = -7
(3) early warning EMV = -10.5
Hence the best alternative is alternative 2, institute a program costing £7m, leading to an
EMV of -£7m.
Note here that it is clear that the concept of the vaccination program being an insurance
against all possible losses could have enabled us to have drawn a much simpler decision
tree (e.g. chance node 3 could be transformed into a "terminal" node of cost -£7m and
nodes 7,13,14,15 dropped altogether (similarly for nodes 8,18,19,20)). However, for
clarity, we have presented the decision tree as given above.
With respect to the last part of the question mention discounting, alternative value for a
chance node (other than EMV), changing the decision node ("choose highest EMV
alternative") rule and utility and briefly discuss whether appropriate/inappropriate.
Problem : 6
XYZ company is considering whether it should tender for two contracts (C1 and C2) on
offer from a government department for the supply of certain components. If tenders are
submitted, the company will have to provide extra facilities, the cost of which will have to
be entirely recouped from the contract revenue. The risk, of course, is that if the tenders
are unsuccessful then the company will have to write off the cost of these facilities. The
extra facilities necessary to meet the requirements of contract C1 would cost £50,000.
These facilities would, however, provide sufficient capacity for the requirements of
contract C2 to be met also. In addition the production costs would be £18,000. The
corresponding production costs for contract C2 would be £10,000. If a tender is made for
contract C2 only, then the necessary extra facilities can be provided at a cost of only
£24,000. The production costs in this case would be £12,000. It is estimated that the tender
preparation costs would be £2,000 if tenders are made for contracts C1 or C2 only and
£3,000 if a tender is made for both contracts C1 and C2. For each contract, possible tender
prices have been determined. In addition, subjective assessments have been made of the
probability of getting the contract with a particular tender price as shown below. Note here
that the company can only submit one tender and cannot, for example, submit two tenders
(at different prices) for the same contract.
Possible Probability
tender of getting
prices (£) contract
Tendering for C1 only 120,000 0.30
110,000 0.85
Tendering for C2 only 70,000 0.10
65,000 0.60
60,000 0.90
Tendering for both C1 and C2 190,000 0.05
140,000 0.65
100,000 0.95
In the event that the company tenders for both C1 and C2 it will either win both contracts
(at the price shown above) or no contract at all.
What do you suggest the company should do and why?
What is the "downside" of your suggested course of action?
Solution
The decision tree for the problem is shown below.
Below we carry out step 1 of the decision tree solution procedure which (for this
example) involves calculating the total profit for each of the paths from the initial node to
the terminal nodes.
Step 1
path to terminal node 12 - we decide to tender for C1 only at a price of 120K and
are successful
Total revenue = 120
Total cost = 50 + 18 + 2 = 70
Total profit = 50 (all figures in £K)
path to terminal node 13 - we decide to tender for C1 only at a price of 120K but
are unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 50 + 2 = 52
Total profit = -52
path to terminal node 14 - we decide to tender for C1 only at a price of 110K and
are successful
Total revenue = 110
Total cost = 50 + 18 + 2 = 70
Total profit = 40
path to terminal node 15 - we decide to tender for C1 only at a price of 110K but
are unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 50 + 2 = 52
Total profit = -52
path to terminal node 16 - we decide to tender for C2 only at a price of 70K and
are successful
Total revenue = 70
Total cost = 24 + 12 + 2 = 38
Total profit = 32
path to terminal node 17 - we decide to tender for C2 only at a price of 70K but
are unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 24 + 2 = 26
Total profit = -26
path to terminal node 18 - we decide to tender for C2 only at a price of 65K and
are successful
Total revenue = 65
Total cost = 24 + 12 + 2 = 38
Total profit = 27
path to terminal node 19 - we decide to tender for C2 only at a price of 65K but
are unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 24 + 2 = 26
Total profit = -26
path to terminal node 20 - we decide to tender for C2 only at a price of 60K and
are successful
Total revenue = 60
Total cost = 24 + 12 + 2 = 38
Total profit = 22
path to terminal node 21 - we decide to tender for C2 only at a price of 60K but
are unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 24 + 2 = 26
Total profit = -26
path to terminal node 22 - we decide to tender for C1/C2 at a price of 190K and
are successful
Total revenue = 190
Total cost = 50 + 18 + 10 + 3 = 81
Total profit = 109
path to terminal node 23 - we decide to tender for C1/C2 at a price of 190K but are
unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 50 + 3 = 53
Total profit = -53
path to terminal node 24 - we decide to tender for C1/C2 at a price of 140K and
are successful
Total revenue = 140
Total cost = 50 + 18 + 10 + 3 = 81
Total profit = 59
path to terminal node 25 - we decide to tender for C1/C2 at a price of 140K but are
unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 50 + 3 = 53
Total profit = -53
path to terminal node 26 - we decide to tender for C1/C2 at a price of 100K and
are successful
Total revenue = 100
Total cost = 50 + 18 + 10 + 3 = 81
Total profit = 19
path to terminal node 27 - we decide to tender for C1/C2 at a price of 100K but are
unsuccessful
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 50 + 3 = 53
Total profit = -53
path to terminal node 28 - we decide not to tender at all
Total revenue = 0
Total cost = 0
Total profit = 0
Hence we can form the table below indicating for each branch the total profit involved in
that branch from the initial node to the terminal node.
Terminal node Total profit (£K)
12 50
13 -52
14 40
15 -52
16 32
17 -26
18 27
19 -26
20 22
21 -26
22 109
23 -53
24 59
25 -53
26 19
27 -53
28 0
We can now carry out the second step of the decision tree solution procedure where we
work from the right-hand side of the diagram back to the left-hand side.
Step 2
Consider chance node 1 (with branches to terminal nodes 12 and 13 emanating from it).
The expected monetary value (EMV) for this chance node is given by 0.3 x (50) + 0.7 x
(-52) = -21.4
Consider chance node 2, the EMV for this chance node is given by 0.85 x (40) + 0.15 x (-
52) = 26.2
Then for the decision node relating to the price for C1 we have the two alternatives:
(5) price 120K EMV = -21.4
(6) price 110K EMV = 26.2
It is clear that, in £ terms, alternative 6 is the most attractive alternative and so we can
discard the other alternative.
Continuing the process the EMV for chance node 3 is given by 0.10 x (32) + 0.9 x (-26) =
-20.2
The EMV for chance node 4 is given by 0.60 x (27) + 0.40 x (-26) = 5.8
The EMV for chance node 5 is given by 0.90 x (22) + 0.10 x (-26) = 17.2
Hence for the decision node relating to the price for C2 we have the three alternatives:
(7) price 70K EMV = -20.2
(8) price 65K EMV = 5.8
(9) price 60K EMV = 17.2
It is clear that, in £ terms, alternative 9 is the most attractive alternative and so we can
discard the other two alternatives.
Continuing the process the EMV for chance node 6 is given by 0.05 x (109) + 0.95 x (-
53) = -44.9
The EMV for chance node 7 is given by 0.65 x (59) + 0.35 x (-53) = 19.8
The EMV for chance node 8 is given by 0.95 x (19) + 0.05 x (-53) = 15.4
Hence for the decision node relating to the price to charge for C1 and C2 we have the
three alternatives:
(10) price 190K EMV = -44.9
(11) price 140K EMV = 19.8
(12) price 100K EMV = 15.4
It is clear that, in £ terms, alternative 11 is the most attractive alternative and so we can
discard the other two alternatives.
Hence for the decision node relating to the tender decision we have the four alternatives:
(1) C1 only EMV = 26.2
(2) C2 only EMV = 17.2
(3) C1 and C2 EMV = 19.8
(4) no tender EMV = 0
It is clear that, in £ terms, alternative 1 is the most attractive alternative and so we can
discard the other three alternatives.
Hence we recommend that the company tenders for contract C1 only, with a tender price
of £110K because this alternative has the highest EMV of £26.2K.
If the company follows this recommendation the actual outcome will be one of the
terminal nodes 14 or 15 (depending upon chance events) i.e. the outcome will be one of
[40, -52]. Hence the downside is that the company may lose £52K (if their tender is
unsuccessful).