0% found this document useful (0 votes)
9 views

Building Effective Cluster and IP

Uploaded by

Gashe
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
9 views

Building Effective Cluster and IP

Uploaded by

Gashe
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 20

IFPRI Discussion Paper 01590

December 2016

Building Effective Clusters and Industrial Parks

Xiaobo Zhang

Development Strategy and Governance Division


INTERNATIONAL FOOD POLICY RESEARCH INSTITUTE
The International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), established in 1975, provides evidence-based
policy solutions to sustainably end hunger and malnutrition and reduce poverty. The institute conducts
research, communicates results, optimizes partnerships, and builds capacity to ensure sustainable food
production, promote healthy food systems, improve markets and trade, transform agriculture, build
resilience, and strengthen institutions and governance. Gender is considered in all of the institute’s work.
IFPRI collaborates with partners around the world, including development implementers, public
institutions, the private sector, and farmers’ organizations, to ensure that local, national, regional, and
global food policies are based on evidence.

AUTHOR
Xiaobo Zhang (x.zhang@cgiar.org) is a senior research fellow in the Development Strategy and
Governance Division of the International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC and
distinguished chair professor of economics at Peking University, Beijing.

Notices
1.
IFPRI Discussion Papers contain preliminary material and research results and are circulated in order to stimulate discussion and
critical comment. They have not been subject to a formal external review via IFPRI’s Publications Review Committee. Any opinions
stated herein are those of the author(s) and are not necessarily representative of or endorsed by the International Food Policy
Research Institute.
2.
The boundaries and names shown and the designations used on the map(s) herein do not imply official endorsement or
acceptance by the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) or its partners and contributors.
This publication is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (CC BY 4.0),
3.

https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Copyright 2016 International Food Policy Research Institute. All rights reserved. Sections of this material may be reproduced for
personal and not-for-profit use without the express written permission of but with acknowledgment to IFPRI. To reproduce the
material contained herein for profit or commercial use requires express written permission. To obtain permission, contact
ifpri-copyright@cgiar.org.
Contents

Abstract v
Acknowledgments vi
1. Introduction 1
2. Building Clusters 3
3. Building Industrial Parks 6
4. General Remarks 9
References 10

iii
Boxes

2.1 The origin of the Wenzhou footwear cluster 3


2.2 Building a logistics center in the Puyuan Cashmere Cluster 4

iv
ABSTRACT

It is a daunting task to build institution and infrastructure over a short time period in developing countries.
But in the absence of sound institutions and adequate infrastructure, it is difficult for economic
transformation to take place. An alternative is to facilitate existing industrial clusters or build industrial
parks by creating an enabling environment in a limited place. This paper reviews the commonly used
strategies to build effective clusters and industrial parks. Clusters and industrial parks are location
specific. Because they have an informational advantage, local governments are in a better position than
the central government to identify and solve the bottlenecks that affect clusters and industrial parks. As
clusters and industrial parks evolve, new bottlenecks emerge, thereby requiring new solutions. This in
turns calls for continuous tinkering by local governments. It is important to place local governments and
business communities in the driver’s seat of local economic growth so that they can watch out for and
adjust to the bumps in the road ahead.

Keywords: industrial cluster, industrial park, special economic zones, quality upgrades, go-as-a-
group

v
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I am grateful for Chi Man Cheung’s excellent research assistance. A version of this paper is forthcoming
in the publication Oxford Handbook of Structural Transformation, edited by Justin Lin and Celestin
Monga. This work was supported by the Natural Science Foundation of China (Approval numbers
71441008, 71341002, and 71350002).
This paper was undertaken as a part of the CGIAR Research Program on Policies, Institutions,
and Markets (PIM), which is led by IFPRI and funded by CGIAR Fund Donors. This paper has not gone
through IFPRI’s standard peer-review process. The opinions expressed here belong to the authors and do
not necessarily reflect those of PIM, IFPRI, or CGIAR.

vi
1. INTRODUCTION

Industrial clusters and industrial parks are a worldwide phenomenon. Clusters and industrial parks in
developed countries are the subject of a large body of literature. Michael Porter popularized the concept
of “clustering” in 1980 through his seminal article Clusters and the New Economics of Competition,
where he explained the advantages of industrial agglomeration in developed countries. Subsequent studies
have primarily analyzed economic agglomeration that spans regions and industries in the context of
developed countries, where institutions and infrastructure are relatively well developed (Porter 1990;
Saxenian 1994; Markusen 1996). 1
In fact, the ideas behind clustering have a long pedigree. Smith (1776), using the example of linen
shirts, illustrated how the putting-out system was widely practiced in the United Kingdom prior to the
Industrial Revolution. 2 The putting-out system was popular not only in the United Kingdom but also in
Western Europe. Marshall devoted four chapters in his seminal book Principles of Economics (1920) to
industrial districts, a term preceding clusters. Similar arrangements have been observed in the Japanese
garment industry during the 19th century (Nakabayashi 2006).
Clusters are also ubiquitous in developing countries. For example, in Thailand, the “One Tambon,
One Product” program has been widely promoted. Under it, each Thai tambon (subdistrict) is encouraged
to develop its industry centering around one key product. The Philippines also adopts a similar “One
Town, One Product” program. Long and Zhang (2011) show that the cluster-based model has been a
defining feature of Chinese industrial growth over the past several decades. Sonobe and Otsuka (2006)
discuss both the pattern and the mechanism of cluster-based industrialization in Asian countries.
Oyelaran-Oyeyinka and McCormick (2007) present nine case studies of clusters across seven African
nations, suggesting that clusters are common across the world.
In this chapter, we review clusters and industrial parks in developing countries for two reasons.
First, compared with the rich body of literature on clustering in developed countries, the literature on the
phenomenon in developing countries is more scant. Second, the strategy of creating clusters and industrial
parks fits particularly well with certain comparative advantages often found in developing countries.
The absence of formal institutions, such as contract enforcement, is an endemic problem in the
developing world. In addition, entrepreneurs face financial constraints when starting and running a
business. The task of fixing institutional problems and developing sound financial systems overnight in
developing countries is daunting. Despite such challenges, developing countries do have some
comparative advantages, such as strong social capital in communities and abundant labor. In close-knit
communities in developing countries, people often know each other well and develop strong social trust.
Compared with the scarcer financial capital, labor is generally more abundant. Clustering offers an
alternative way for developing countries to make better use of their existing strengths (abundant labor and
strong social capital) to overcome the seemingly insurmountable financial and institutional constraints.
Marshall (1920) highlighted the three major advantages of industrial districts (clusters): better
access to suppliers and markets, labor market pooling, and spillovers of technological know-how. When
final-goods and intermediate-input markets are nearby, firms save on marketing and purchasing costs.
When a large number of firms work in the same sector, workers are more willing to invest in their skills
because they are portable across firms in the cluster. Proximity to other producers enables one to quickly
learn the technologies prevalent in the cluster. All these advantages lower the transaction costs of
operating a business in a cluster. Apart from the three major advantages Marshall identified, clusters have
a few additional advantages. In clusters, a production process can be divided into many incremental steps,
which are undertaken by various family workshops. Such a fine division of labor largely reduces the

1 See Ciccone and Hall (1996) and Ciccone (2002) for reviews of the clustering effect in the United States and Europe,

respectively. See Fisher and Peters (2002) for a review of special economic zones in the United Kingdom and the United States.
2 The putting-out system operated as follows: merchants acquired orders from the market and organized production by

outsourcing incremental steps to nearby skilled workers and farmers, who finished the work in small-scale family workshops
(Hounshell 1984). The concept of the putting-out system predates the concept of clusters. But, in essence, the two are similar.

1
capital requirement to start a business in each step of production (Ruan and Zhang 2009; Long and Zhang
2011). In addition, due to strong social capital and proximity to each other, businesses in clusters
extensively use inter-firm trade credit, which reduces their reliance on external funding for working
capital. With a lower starting capital requirement and less working capital constraints, many previously
financially constrained entrepreneurs can set up businesses in clusters, enabling them to create more
employment opportunities, which developing countries desperately need.
Mainstream economic theory suggests that the frequent subcontracting and fine division of labor
within clusters would involve higher coordination costs (Becker and Murphy 1992; Williamson 1975, 26–
30). However, in reality it is widely observed that in clusters, thanks to repeated transactions, freely
flowing information, and a strong social trust embedded in communities, entrepreneurs rely heavily on
relational contracts to get around the problem of weak contracts (Greif 1993; Ruan and Zhang 2009; Long
and Zhang 2011). They rarely sign any formal contract in clusters. The transaction costs are much lower
than previously thought in the literature. Private ordering becomes a major means to sort out contract
disputes in the absence of formal institutions. 3
China’s industrialization offers a good example in support of this story. China has become
industrialized in just a few decades despite an initial lack of sound institutions and a well-developed
financial system. The conventional wisdom in textbook economics cannot explain the puzzles behind
China’s rapid growth.4 Long and Zhang (2011) provide evidence that clustering plays a key role in
driving China’s rapid industrialization by lowering starting capital barriers and reducing reliance on
working capital.
Clusters are often organically formed from existing industries as determined by historical legacy
(Miller and Cote 1985). The role of government is normally limited at the initial stage. Yet governments,
and in particular local governments, can help facilitate the growth of existing clusters. In some parts of
the developing world, clusters are absent. Due to lacks of good infrastructure and sound institutions at the
national level in developing countries, it is hard to create a new industry from scratch on a large scale.
Instead, governments or business communities in developing countries often prefer to build industrial
parks in a limited geographic area, in which adequate infrastructure and an enabling business environment
can be provided. They aim to attract foreign or domestic direct investment in the industrial parks in order
to promote employment and facilitate technology transfer. Whereas clusters and industrial parks share the
advantages of economic agglomeration, they differ fundamentally in terms of origin, entry barriers,
composition of enterprises, and their entrepreneurship impacts on the local economy. The most prominent
distinction is the degree of government intervention at the initial stage. In this chapter, we review the
experiences of and lessons learned from building clusters and industrial parks.

3 Private ordering is the process of setting up of social norms by parties involved in the regulated activity (in some manner),
and not by the State. Private Ordering aims to achieve public goals, such as efficiency, enhancing the market, and protecting
rights
4 In fact, developed countries faced the same problem in their early stages of development: small- and medium-sized

enterprises in Northern and Western Europe and North America were rarely able to obtain credit from large national or regional
financial institutions (Cull et al. 2006).

2
2. BUILDING CLUSTERS

Sonobe and Otsuka (2006) characterize the process of industrial development as taking place in three
stages—namely, initiation, quantity expansion, and quality improvement. We can write this intuitively as
0→1→N→Q. The step of 0→1 stands for the initiation phrase; 1→N means the stage of quantity
expansion; and the quality improvement step can be written as N→Q, where N and Q refer to quantity
and quality, respectively. This section is organized according to the three stages.

0→1
Most clusters form organically. To illustrate how historical legacy determines cluster formation, the
Chinese example can be explored. Many of the clusters in China nowadays originated from township and
village enterprises (TVEs) or state-owned enterprises (SOEs). In the 1970s and 1980s, the Chinese
constitution did not recognize and protect private ownership. Largely due to the central government’s
failure to protect property rights, TVEs blossomed (Xu and Zhang 2009). The township and village
governments provided local de facto protection for the TVEs. By registering as a TVE, enterprises could
circumvent the problem of weak institutions at the time, and they quickly expanded in response to rising
market demand, which resulted from the success of rural reform in the 1980s. Some workers who grasped
the technology know-how in TVEs or SOEs began to set up workshops at home and sell the same product
in the market. After observing the success of those private endeavors, other villages followed suit,
triggering the birth of a cluster.
The footwear cluster in Wenzhou is a good example, and we describe its origins in Box 2.1
(Huang, Zhang, and Zhu 2008). Similar stories can be found in the cashmere sweater cluster in Puyuan
(Ruan and Zhang 2009) and the children’s garment cluster in Zhili (Fleisher et al. 2010).

Box 2.1 The origin of the Wenzhou footwear cluster

At the beginning of the 1980s, when China began its transition from a command economy to a
market economy, footwear products were in seriously short supply. The strong market demand
prompted many employees of state-owned or collectively owned footwear factories to set up their
own footwear stalls or family workshops and produce whole shoes by themselves. Due to the
highly technological requirements for whole-shoe production, most of the early newcomers to the
industry were former technicians from the state or collective firms.
A good example of technical diffusion may be seen in the state-owned Dongfanghong
Leather Footwear Factory, which gave rise to three major enterprises, namely Jierda Footwear,
China Aolun Shoes, and Wenzhou Dashun Footwear Machinery Manufacture, as well as many
smaller enterprises, such as the Tailong Footwear Last Factory.
Having the experience of apprenticeship was found to be a major asset in setting up
shoemaking businesses. The most prominent example of that is Yu Ashou, the founder of Jierda
Footwear. Yu had 16 apprentices, 15 of whom set up their own companies, while the last one
became his son-in-law and worked in Jierda Footwear.
Copying and spin-offs further increased footwear production and the rate of technological
diffusion. Aokang and Hongqingting are two typical examples of spin-offs. Wang Zhentao and
Qian Jinbo first worked as carpenters and later sold shoes together until 1988, when they co-
founded a leather shoe factory. In 1995, the factory split into the Aokang Group and the
Hongqingting Group, which still exist today. After the split, both groups grew into leading footwear
companies. The formation of an industrial cluster is a process of production and technological
diffusion through the copying of others. The success of one enterprise often lures others to imitate
it, resulting in numerous enterprises being duplicated. As far as Wenzhou’s diffusion channels are
concerned, this process was accomplished primarily through relatives and friends.

Source: Adapted from Huang, Zhang, and Zhu (2008).

3
The birth of clusters is primarily due to bottom-up responses to expanding market opportunities.
Governments have played little role in initiating such clusters. More often than not, only after noticing the
dynamics of the clusters did the local governments start to facilitate their growth.
Most clusters in other countries also have a historical origin. For example, in Santa Catarina,
Brazil, clustering is a prominent feature of industrial production. European immigrants started most of the
clusters there. The textile cluster was developed by German immigrants who possessed experience in that
trade and arrived in the state in the 1880s (Meyer-Stamer 1998).

1→N
Because the barriers to entry are low, clusters often initially enjoy a period of fast growth. However, the
explosion in the number of businesses in a limited area quickly creates some bottlenecks, such as
insecurity, lack of marketplaces, and inadequate infrastructure. Because an individual enterprise will have
trouble addressing large, external problems, collective action is needed. Compared with the limited role of
individual firms, local governments and the local business community can play a more important role in
leading collective action, as the case studies of a cashmere cluster (Ruan and Zhang 2009) and a potato
production cluster (Zhang and Hu 2014) in China illustrate.
Box 2.2 describes the establishment of a logistics center in the Puyuan cashmere cluster in China.
As the example shows, the local government in Puyuan responded to infrastructure bottlenecks by
building a large logistics center through a private–public partnership.

Box 2.2 Building a logistics center in the Puyuan cashmere cluster

As production grew, so did the volume of transportation into and out of Puyuan. Initially many
small, private logistics companies, each operating only one or two routes, served the cluster. It was
not economical for each transport company to build separate loading docks and parking lots,
meaning that trucks often blocked the streets when loading goods. Some of the companies even
hired thugs to fight for the most lucrative routes. In 1995, to reduce chaos and improve efficiency,
the local government intervened and organized 27 private logistics and transport companies into a
shareholding company with the local government as the largest shareholder. The company
invested 40 million yuan to build a logistics business center, a loading dock, a 150,000-square-
meter warehouse, and a parking lot. The company has auctioned off 109 routes to more than 140
major Chinese cities to private investors. Although the company would seem to have a natural
local monopoly, shipping costs through the Puyuan logistics center have decreased since the
company’s inception. This may be due to competition from the neighboring Honghe Township’s
logistics center.
Source: Adapted from Ruan and Zhang (2009).

As clusters evolve, bottlenecks arise successively at later stages. New constraints become binding
and require continuous tinkering by governments. Indeed, government interventions should differ
according to specific situations and be based on a bottom-up, demand-driven approach. Since clusters
exist largely at the local level, it is the local government, rather than the central government, that should
play the key role in providing necessary public goods and services, thanks to its informational advantage.

N→Q
As clusters expand, the scale of production increases, depressing prices. Consequently, firms in clusters
tend to engage in race-to-the-bottom price competitions. It is a great challenge for an individual firm to
upgrade product quality because others in the clusters can easily imitate its new product. Moreover, firms
have no incentive to train workers because the trained workers can easily jump ship and go to work for
competitors. Local governments can play an active role in shifting the equilibrium of competing for prices

4
to competing for better quality (Sonobe and Otsuka 2006). For example, providing training to workers at
the cluster level and encouraging enterprises to establish brand names are possible ways to improve the
innovation capability of the cluster as a whole.
In normal times, building up supporting institutions to encourage innovation is hard because the
proposed changes likely will produce losers, who will block the changes. Institutional reforms are more
likely to occur after a crisis strikes.
When a crisis emerges, the opportunity costs of producing high-quality goods, namely the profit
of producing low-quality goods, fall. Based on surveys in clusters in China’s Zhejiang Province, Ruan
and Zhang (2010) show that collective action related to quality upgrading is more likely to occur after a
crisis. This appears to hold true in other developing countries as well: for example, the ban on imports of
surgical instruments from developed countries led to an upgrade in quality in a surgical instruments
cluster in Pakistan (Nadvi 1999).
However, crisis is not a sufficient condition for a quality upgrade. Not all clusters can transform
crises into opportunities and allow for quality upgrading—failures do happen. An insulated mug cluster in
Yongkang, China, arose in 1995 and grew so quickly that the excess supply drove prices below
production costs by 1996. The crisis came so quickly that collective action could not be taken promptly,
which resulted in the collapse of the whole cluster (Ruan and Zhang 2010). Schmitz (1999) provides
another example. In the 1980s, integration into the American footwear value chain allowed an export-
oriented leather footwear cluster in Brazil’s Sino Valley to improve the quality of its products, its
flexibility, and its speed of response. Yet the cluster’s exports and profits fell in the 1990s under global
competitive pressure since it failed to upgrade in other areas that require coordination between
stakeholders. There were two reasons: conflicting interests among entrepreneurial alliances and business
associations, and the lack of participation of leading enterprises. This example again highlights how local
governments could act as a coordinator to lower transaction costs that arise in complicated networks of
businesses within clusters.
The above-cited literature mainly focuses on upgrading processes that occur within localities,
especially collaboration between local producers and provision of public goods by governments. External
linkages can also be used as a means to spur quality upgrades (Nadvi and Schmitz 1999). When working
with global buyers, local producers must follow the often higher quality standards of foreign buyers. The
more stringent global standards pose an imperative for local firms to improve their product quality. For
instance, Taiwanese contract manufacturers in the electronics industry used the knowledge they had
acquired working for their main global buyer for the purpose of supplying other markets. They even took
over other lucrative functions such as process development and product design at later stages (Lee and
Chen 2000). A similar story is found in the blue jeans industry in Torreon, Mexico, which performed
functional upgrading in the 1990s (Bair and Gereffi 2001).
Like crises, a connection with global buyers is not a sufficient condition for quality upgrades.
Bazan and Navas-Alemán (2001) show that customized specification prevents Brazilian footwear
suppliers of big US buyers from entering national or Latin American markets. Manufacturing to tight
specifications for the main customers requires the whole production plant to gear for that specific
purpose. Enterprises wishing to participate have to build up highly developed but narrow capabilities.
This hinders their ability to appropriately fine-tune product specifications to adapt to local markets.

5
3. BUILDING INDUSTRIAL PARKS

The major difference between building clusters and building industrial parks is the degree of government
intervention at the initial stage. Whereas industrial clusters usually form organically without government
intervention, industrial parks are initiated by governments to jump-start economic growth in a specific
geographic region. Since improvement of the business environment of the country as a whole is neither
economically nor politically viable, governments in developing countries often prefer to build industrial
parks on a smaller scale. When constructing an industrial park, the government aims to attract investment
by offering potential entrants geographically limited benefits of various kinds.
UNIDO (1997) defined an industrial park, or the more general term special economic zone
(SEZ), 5 as “a tract of land developed and subdivided into plots according to a comprehensive plan with
provision for roads, transport and public utilities with or without built-up (advance) factories, sometimes
with common facilities and sometimes without them.” In addition to hard infrastructure, industrial parks
often grant preferential policy and have different institutional arrangements from the rest of the country—
such as tax and tariff reductions, looser labor regulations, different sets of laws, and many other practices
that provide convenience and lower the costs of doing business. 6 While the policy instruments that
governments could use to lure investment are known, there are a few strategies they could follow to
increase the chances of success: targeting international firms, targeting grouped businesses, incentivizing
first movers, and adopting a step-by-step approach.

Targeting International Firms


The high lump-sum costs of investment suggest that firms operating in industrial parks in developing
countries are generally large in size. Because domestic markets in developing countries are often in their
infancy, they cannot absorb the production of firms in industrial parks. It is therefore more reasonable for
industrial parks to target firms that bring in international market orders from abroad and finish the orders
in the parks. Doing so has a few advantages. First, firms in the industrial parks can focus on their
production without worrying too much about the thin domestic market. Second, many global buyers
provide intermediate inputs for their orders and just put out the assembly step to domestic firms. Firms in
industrial parks in developing countries are therefore less subject to the supply chain problems inherent in
many developing countries. Over time, as domestic markets grow and as firms build their reputation
locally, they can gradually expand their domestic market shares and subcontract more tasks to other
domestic firms, even outside the industrial parks. In doing so, they generate positive technological
spillover to existing firms and contribute to overall economic growth (Greenstone, Hornbeck, and Moretti
2010; Glaeser and Gottlieb 2009).

Targeting Grouped Businesses


Given the limited number of multi-establishment firms, the strategy of targeting only fully vertically
integrated firms may not always be viable. As industrial production needs upstream and downstream
supply chains, it is often hard for a small- or medium-sized firm to survive in an isolated place. As a
result, the “go-as-a-group” model has come into being in recent decades: a powerful enterprise or
business association takes the initiative to establish an overseas trade center and industrial park, as a
means of attracting domestic enterprises to go as a group. The use of the strategy is to maintain the
original production connections overseas by investing as a group of upstream and downstream production
enterprises and preserving the domestic industrial chain in the host country. Such a strategy has several
advantages for enterprises in the group: achieving market internalization of intermediate products,
formulating internalization advantages, reducing international market risk, reducing export tariffs, and

5 In this chapter the terms are used interchangeably for convenience.


6 See Aggarwal (2005) for a review of fiscal incentives provided by governments in India, Sri Lanka, and Bangladesh.

6
optimizing the international investment environment. During trade dispute settlements, the grouped
enterprises can negotiate and resolve trade quarrels with better bargaining power. We offer the example of
Yue Mei, a Chinese textile and garment company. In 2004, Nigeria banned the import of textile and
garment products from China. Yue Mei in response planned to set up a processing plant in Nigeria but
soon realized that the incomplete supply chain would make it hard to survive as an isolated business in the
foreign business environment. In 2007 Yue Mei invited 15 upstream and downstream enterprises
originally from China and invested US$50 million to set up a textile and garment industrial park in a
Nigerian free trade zone. 7 Governments in developing countries might exploit the increasingly popular
use of the go-as-a-group strategy by private enterprises and target such groups of foreign businesses.

Incentivizing First Movers


Rodriguez-Clare (2007) and Lin (2011) emphasized the importance of ensuring that place-based
development programs are compatible with comparative advantages. Although the principle is clear, there
are few clues as to which industry a government should support. Mapping from principle to action is not
an easy task for a government. Instead of relying on governments to pick winners, an alternative strategy
is to encourage private enterprises to discover a profitable business model. The process of cost structure
discovery poses massive positive externality. Once first movers figure out a profitable business
opportunity, others can easily imitate it. Therefore, the first movers cannot capture the positive
externality. Being aware of that, firms are often reluctant to be first movers, lowering their chances of
discovering new business models and resulting in socially less-than-optimal outcomes. It makes economic
sense to subsidize the first movers (Hausmann and Rodrik 2003; Lin 2010) by offering them special
treatment—such as tax breaks and free land. However, to avoid rent-seeking behavior, there needs to be a
stick in the incentive program: it ought to be designed with a predetermined exit strategy, and linked
directly to individual company performance or a time window. Whereas both elements of carrot and stick
are present behind the success of cluster-based development in East Asia, Latin America has had “too
much of the carrot and too little of the stick” in its industrial policies. This could explain the discrepancy
of industrial growth between the two (Rodrik 2004).

Step-by-Step Approach
Xing and Zhang (2013) suggest that the successes of place-based policies in China are characterized by a
gradual approach coupled with an experimental mentality. The development of China’s SEZs have
followed a step-by-step approach: first came Shekou industrial park in 1979 (only 11 square kilometers),
followed by the larger-scale Shenzhen SEZ (328 square kilometers) in 1980, followed by 14 coastal
opening-up cities in 1984, and culminating in China’s joining the World Trade Organization in 2001. But
building industrial parks (or SEZs) is a new endeavor for many governments, and they are concerned
about potential failures and negative spillovers. By starting small, governments can learn whether the idea
of the industrial park works in local soil. If it fails, the negative spillover effect is limited to a narrow area.
If it succeeds, it will boost governments’ confidence to scale up industrial parks to wider regions.
Malaysia, Jamaica, Kuwait, and Jordan have adopted this gradual and experimental approach in testing
the impacts of SEZs (Akinci and Crittle 2008). As an extreme case, Honduras in Central America has
gradually increased the scale of its SEZs since the 1970s, and the government declared the whole country
a “free zone area” in 1998 (Farole and Akinci 2011).

Industrial Park Failures


Despite evidence that confirms the positive impacts of place-based policies in China and other countries,
such as Indonesia, Malaysia, Sri Lanka, and South Korea (Jayanthakumaran 2003), such policies have
failed in other locales.

7 “Yue Mei Group: From Product Export to Industrial Cluster Export” 2009.

7
The political economy of land poses challenges to Indian’s SEZs. Legal restrictions remain and
discourage private developers from assembling necessary lands for development. The Indian Zone
Authority was not granted autonomy over zone development and approval clearance until 2005. Despite
the launch of the 2005 SEZ Act, state governments and public-sector actors retain significant control over
land procurements and transactions. Due to the strict legal enforcement, including of land ceiling and land
use clauses, private developers need governmental patronage for land acquisition (Seshadri 2012). Even if
they succeed, the size of a zone is limited to 5,000 hectares (Mitra 2007). Conflicting interests over land
acquisition between citizens and firms operating in industrial parks is another hindrance. 8 Issues of
dislocation and rehabilitation, coupled with the fact that India is a democratic country, make the problem
even more complicated. Similar to the Indian SEZs, which are managed by public-sector actors, the
industrial zones in Egypt are managed by the central government. The failures of Egyptian industrial
parks stem from information gaps between the central government and grassroots entrepreneurs. The
bureaucratic SEZ system constitutes numerous layers and leads to a mismatch between government and
SEZ firms. Worse still, as the zone policies evolve from time to time, SEZ firms must expend
unnecessary energy to understand and deal with repetitive policy changes. In contrast, Zeng (2010)
attributes the success of China’s SEZs to the active and pragmatic facilitation of the local governments
and a strong commitment by the state. As demonstrated by Shenzhen, China’s first SEZ, fiscal
decentralization incentivized better-informed provincial and municipal governments to tailor policies and
regulations to local needs, such as providing a sound judicial system, constructing infrastructure, and
granting preferential policies.
A number of others failed for less complicated reasons. For example, an export processing zone
in Senegal was unable to blossom because of high electricity costs, expensive labor, excessive
bureaucracy, and lack of transportation infrastructure (Cling and Letilly 2001). In general, the studies on
the failure of industrial parks and SEZs are scant. More research is needed to understand such failures.

8In 2008, with the aim of mass producing the Tata Nano, the world’s cheapest car at the time, the Indian vehicle
manufacturer Tata Motors established a factory in an SEZ in Singur, West Bengal. The West Bengal government offered
compensation to more than 10,000 farmers and acquired 1,000 acres of land for the project, while another 2,000 farmers refused.
Their protest ultimately forced Tata Motors to abandon the plant. The protest in Singur is merely one of the many cases reflecting
the wider problem in the implementation of place-based policies in India: industrialization needs land but local farmers are not
willing to give it up (“Tata Abandons Cheapest Car Plant” 2008).

8
4. GENERAL REMARKS

Clusters and industrial parks are location specific. Because of an informational advantage, local
governments are in a better position than the central government to identify the bottlenecks that afflict
clusters and industrial parks and figure out solutions. As clusters and industrial parks evolve, new
bottlenecks emerge, requiring new solutions. This in turn calls for continuous tinkering by local
governments. It is important to place local governments and business communities in the driver’s seat of
local economic growth so that they can watch out for and adjust to bumps in the road. However, it is
challenging to strike a balance between autonomy and embeddedness (Rodrik 2004): to reduce corruption
and rent-seeking a government as a whole needs to maintain its autonomy with regard to private interests,
but to elicit information from the private sector the government should be embedded in a close
relationship with it.
China has used fiscal decentralization and evaluation of officials’ performance as the major
instruments to align local officials’ incentives with local economic development (Xu 2011). An essential
element of the fiscal decentralization in China is that career competition between regional officials at the
same level is based on fiscal performance, which effectively mitigates the problem of incentive
misalignment. However, the incentive design used in China may not apply to other countries. Due to
differences in institutions, the forms of incentive mechanisms are likely to vary across countries and over
time.
In a country with strong state capacity like China, it is not an issue to earmark a certain area as an
industrial park and provide it with favorable policies and infrastructure. But in some democratic countries,
it may not be legitimate to offer special treatment to certain locations. The industrial park concept does
not necessarily transmit well to all developing countries. One should bear in mind the limitations that
apply to using industrial parks as a policy instrument to foster industrial development.

9
REFERENCES

Aggarwal, A. 2005. “Performance of Export Processing Zones: A Comparative Analysis of India, Sri Lanka, and
Bangladesh.” Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations 155: 10–13.
Akinci, G., and J. Crittle. 2008. Special Economic Zones: Performance, Lessons Learned, and Implications for Zone
Development. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Bair, J., and G. Gereffi. 2001. “Local Clusters in Global Chains: The Causes and Consequences of Export
Dynamism in Torreon’s Blue Jeans Industry.” World Development 29 (11): 1885–1903.
Bazan, L., and L. Navas-Alemán. 2001. Comparing Chain Governance and Upgrading Patterns in the Sinos Valley,
Brazil. Porto Alegre, Brazil: Federation of Industries of Rio Grande do Sul.
BBC News. 2008. “Tata Abandons Cheapest Car Plant.” Accessed on December 22, 2016.
http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/south_asia/7651119.stm.
Becker, G., and K. M. Murphy. 1992. “The Division of Labor, Coordination Costs, and Knowledge.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 107 (4): 1137–1160.
Ciccone, A. 2002. “Agglomeration Effects in Europe.” European Economic Review 46 (2): 213–227.
Ciccone, A., and R. E. Hall. 1996. “Productivity and the Density of Economic Activity.” American Economic
Review 86 (1): 54–70.
Cling, J. P., and G. Letilly. 2001. Export Processing Zones: A Threatened Instrument for Global Economy
Insertion? Working Paper DT/2001/17. Paris: Développment Institutions and Mondialisation (DIAL).
Cull, R., L. E. Davis, N. R. Lamoreaux, and J. L. Rosenthal. 2006. “Historical Financing of Small- and Medium-
Size Enterprises.” Journal of Banking and Finance 30 (11): 3017–3042.
Farole, T., and G. Akinci, eds. 2011. Special Economic Zones: Progress, Emerging Challenges, and Future
Directions. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Fisher, P. S., and A. H. Peters. 2002. State Enterprise Zone Programs: Have They Worked? Kalamazoo, MI: Upjohn
Institute for Employment Research.
Fleisher, B., D. Hu, W. McGuire, and X. Zhang. 2010. “The Evolution of an Industrial Cluster in China.” China
Economic Review 21 (3): 456–469.
Glaeser, E. L., and J. D. Gottlieb. 2009. “The Wealth of Cities: Agglomeration Economies and Spatial Equilibrium
in the United States.” Journal of Economic Literature 47 (4): 983–1028.
Greenstone, M., R. Hornbeck, and E. Moretti. 2010. “Identifying Agglomeration Spillovers: Evidence from Winners
and Losers of Large Plant Openings.” Journal of Political Economy 118 (3): 536–598.
Greif, A. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’
Coalition.” American Economic Review 83 (3): 525–548.
Hausmann, R., and D. Rodrik. 2003. “Economic Development as Self-Discovery.” Journal of Development
Economics 72 (2): 603–633.
Hounshell, D. A. 1984. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press.
Huang, Z., X. Zhang, and Y. Zhu. 2008. “The Role of Clustering in Rural Industrialization: A Case Study of the
Footwear Industry in Wenzhou.” China Economic Review 19 (3): 409–420.
Jayanthakumaran, K. 2003. “Benefit–Cost Appraisals of Export Processing Zones: A Survey of the Literature.”
Development Policy Review 21 (1): 51–65.
Lee, J. R. and J. S. Chen. 2000. “Dynamic Synergy Creation with Multiple Business Activities: Toward a
Competence-Based Business Model for Contract Manufacturers.” In Theory Development for Competence-
Based Management, Advances in Applied Business Strategy, edited by R. Sanchez and A. Heene, 209–228.
Stanford, CT, US: Jai Press.

10
Lin, J. Y. 2010. “Six Steps for Strategic Government Intervention.” Global Policy 1 (3): 330–331.
———. 2011. New Structural Economics: A Framework for Rethinking Development and Policy. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
Long, C., and X. Zhang. 2011. “Cluster-Based Industrialization in China: Financing and Performance.” Journal of
International Economics 84 (1): 112–123.
Markusen, A. 1996. “Sticky Places in Slippery Space: A Typology of Industrial Districts.” Economic Geography 72
(3): 293–313.
Marshall, A. 1920. Principles of Economics, 8th ed. London: Macmillan. (Original work published 1890.)
Meyer-Stamer, J. 1998. “Path Dependence in Regional Development: Persistence and Change in Three Industrial
Clusters in Santa Catarina, Brazil.” World Development 26 (8): 1495–1511.
Miller, R., and M. Cote. 1985. “Growing the Next Silicon Valley.” Harvard Business Review 63 (4): 114–123.
Mitra, S. 2007. Special Economic Zones in India: White Elephants or Race Horses. Accessed on December 20,
2016. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=969274.
Nadvi, K. 1999. “The Cutting Edge: Collective Efficiency and International Competitiveness in Pakistan.” Oxford
Development Studies 27 (1): 81–107.
Nadvi, K., and H. Schmitz. 1999. “Clustering and Industrialization: Introduction.” World Development 27 (9):
1503–1514.
Nakabayashi, M. 2006. Flexibility and Diversity: The Putting-Out System in the Silk Fabric Industry of Kiryu.
Discussion paper. Osaka, Japan: Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University.
Oyelaran-Oyeyinka, B., and D. McCormick, eds. 2007. Industrial Clusters and Innovation Systems in Africa.
Tokyo: United Nations University Press.
Porter, M. E. 1990. “The Competitive Advantage of Notions.” Harvard Business Review 68 (2): 73–93.
Rodriguez-Clare, A. 2007. “Clusters and Comparative Advantage: Implications for Industrial Policy.” Journal of
Development Economics 82 (1): 43–57.
Rodrik, D. 2004. Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century. Working paper. John F. Kennedy School of
Government. Cambridge, MA, US: Harvard University.
Ruan, J., and X. Zhang. 2009. “Finance and Cluster-Based Industrial Development in China. Economic
Development and Cultural Change 58 (1): 143–164.
———. 2010. “Made in China”: Crisis Begets Quality Upgrade. IFPRI Discussion Paper 1025. Washington, DC:
International Food Policy Research Institute.
Saxenian, A. 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge,
MA, US: Harvard University.
Schmitz, H. 1999. “Global Competition and Local Cooperation: Success and Failure in the Sinos Valley, Brazil.”
World Development 27 (9): 1627–1650.
Seshadri, T. 2012. “An Analysis of the Feasibility of Private Land Assembly for Special Economic Zones in India.”
Urban Studies 49 (10): 2285–2300.
Smith, A. 1776. The Wealth of Nations. London: W. Strahan and T. Cadell.
Sonobe, T., and K. Otsuka. 2006. Cluster-Based Industrial Development: An East Asian Model. London: Palgrave
Macmillan UK.
UNIDO (United Nations Industrial Development Organization). 1997. Industrial Estates: Principles and Practice.
Vienna.
Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. New York: Free Press.

11
Xing, H., and X. Zhang. 2013. The Logic of Adaptive Sequential Experimentation in Policy Design. IFPRI
Discussion Paper 1273. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
Xu, C. 2011. “The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development.” Journal of Economic Literature
49 (4): 1076–1151.
Xu, C., and X. Zhang. 2009. The Evolution of Chinese Entrepreneurial Firms: Township-Village Enterprises
Revisited. IFPRI Discussion Paper 854. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
Xiquan, Z. R. S. 2009. “Yue Mei Group: From Product Export to Industrial Cluster Export.” Beijing: Xinhua.
http://jjckb.xinhuanet.com/gnyw/2009-07/01/content_166586.htm.
Zeng, D. Z., ed. 2010. Building Engines for Growth and Competitiveness in China: Experience with Special
Economic Zones and Industrial Clusters. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Zhang, X., and D. Hu. 2014. Overcoming Successive Bottlenecks: The Evolution of a Potato Cluster in China.
World Development 63: 102–112.

12
RECENT IFPRI DISCUSSION PAPERS

For earlier discussion papers, please go to www.ifpri.org/publications/discussion_papers.


All discussion papers can be downloaded free of charge.

1589. Nepal’s 2072 federal constitution: Implications for the governance of the agricultural sector. Jordan Kyle and Danielle
Resnick, 2016.
1588. Entitlement fetching or snatching?: Effects of arbitrage on India’s public distribution system. Suman Chakrabarti,
Avinash Kishore, and Devesh Roy, 2016.
1587. Changing preferences through experimental games: Evidence from sanitation and hygiene in Tamil Nadu. Yaniv
Stopnitzky, 2016.
1586. Climate change, agriculture, and adaptation in the Republic of Korea to 2050: An integrated assessment. Nicola
Cenacchi, Youngah Lim, Timothy Sulser, Shahnila Islam, Daniel Mason-D’Croz, Richard Robertson, Chang-Gil Kim,
and Keith Wiebe, 2016.
1585. The dark side of competition: Gender differences. Simon Chang, Kamhon Kan, and Xiaobo Zhang, 2016.
1584. Harnessing net primary productivity data for monitoring sustainable development of agriculture. Nathaniel P.
Robinson, Cindy M. Cox, and Jawoo Koo, 2016.
1583. Effects of agricultural mechanization on smallholders and their self-selection into farming: An insight from the Nepal
Terai. Hiroyuki Takeshima, Rudra Bahadur Shrestha, Basu Dev Kaphle, Madhab Karkee, Suroj Pokhrel, and Anjani
Kumar, 2016.
1582. The agricultural sector as an alternative to illegal mining in Peru: A case study of Madre de Dios. Valeria Piñeiro, Jenny
Thomas, and Pablo Elverdin, 2016.
1581. What drives diversification of national food supplies?: A cross-country analysis. Samira Choudhury and Derek Headey,
2016.
1580. Identity, household work, and subjective well-being among rural women in Bangladesh. Greg Seymour and Maria S.
Floro, 2016.
1579. Youth employment, agricultural transformation, and rural labor dynamics in Nigeria. Margaret Adesugba and George
Mavrotas, 2016.
1578. Farm size and effects of chemical fertilizer price on farm households: Insights from Nepal terai. Hiroyuki Takeshima,
Sabnam Shivakoti, Binod Bhattarai, Madhab Karkee, Suroj Pokhrel, and Anjani Kumar, 2016.
1577. Energy use and rural poverty: Empirical evidence from potato farmers in northern China. Zihan Li, Yazhen Gong, and
Kevin Z. Chen, 2016.
1576. Does a “blue revolution” help the poor?: Evidence from Bangladesh. Shahidur Rashid, Nicholas Minot, and Solomon
Lemma, 2016.
1575. Do development projects crowd out private-sector activities?: A survival analysis of contract farming participation in
northern Ghana. Isabel Lambrecht and Catherine Ragasa, 2016.
1574. Strong democracy, weak state: The political economy of Ghana’s stalled structural transformation. Danielle Resnick,
2016.
1573. Storage and handling among smallholder potato farmers in southwestern Uganda. Bjorn Van Campenhout, Senne
Vandevelde, Wiberforce Walukano, and Piet Van Asten, 2016.
1572. What drives input subsidy policy reform?: The case of Zambia, 2002–2016. Danielle Resnick and Nicole M. Mason,
2016.
1571. Using household consumption and expenditure surveys to make inferences about food consumption, nutrient intakes and
nutrition status: How important is it to adjust for meal partakers? John L. Fiedler and Dena M. Mwangi, 2016.
1570. Improving household consumption and expenditure surveys’ food consumption metrics: Developing a strategic approach
to the unfinished agenda. John L. Fiedler and Dena M. Mwangi, 2016.
1569. Microcredit in Viet Nam: Does it matter? Jonathan Haughton and Shahidur R. Khandker, 2016.
INTERNATIONAL FOOD POLICY
RESEARCH INSTITUTE

www.ifpri.org

IFPRI HEADQUARTERS
2033 K Street, NW
Washington, DC 20006-1002 USA
Tel.: +1-202-862-5600
Fax: +1-202-467-4439
Email: ifpri@cgiar.org

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy