Chapter 1
Chapter 1
Chapter 1 of Macroeconomics,
Kaism_tar2006@yahoo.fr
Classroom
• Macroeconomics: 05-2024-2025
mot6sby
As you may recall from course microeconomics last year,
economics is divided into two branches: microeconomics and
macroeconomics.
- Microeconomics is the study of how individual households and
firms make decisions and how they interact with one another
in markets.
- Macroeconomics is the study of the economy as a whole. The
goal of macroeconomics is to explain the economic changes
that affect many households, firms, and markets
simultaneously
• The term « macroeconomis » was coined by Regnar
Frish, Norwegian economist , in 1933 to apply to the
study of relationships between broad economic
aggregates such as national income, inflation, aggregate
unemplyement and so on.
• In 1936, John Maynard Keynes published his
revolutionary book, « The General Theory of
Employement, Interest and Money. This book laid the
foundation of Macroecnomics.
Because the economy as a whole is a collection of
many households and many firms interacting in
many markets, microeconomics and
macroeconomics are closely linked. The basic
tools of supply and demand, for instance, are as
central to macroeconomic analysis as they are to
microeconomic analysis
Learning objectives
This chapter introduces you to :
• They then try to build general theories to explain the data that
history gives them (They then attempt to formulate general theories to explain these
data. Like astronomers studying the evolution of stars or biologists studying the evolution of
species, macroeconomists usually cannot conduct controlled experiments in a laboratory.
Instead, they must make use of the data that history gives them)
Aspects of Macroeconomics
MACROECONOMIC DATA
Macroeconomics
• Macroeconomics is a young and imperfect science
– Macroeconomists were not generally successful in predicting the
global economic crisis of 2008
– Even after the crisis, they were unable to agree on what should be
done to deal with the crisis
• Nevertheless, the importance of the subject is clearer than
ever
Macroeconomic data
• Economists use many types of data to measure the performance of an economy.
Three macroeconomic variables are especially important:
– Real gross domestic product (GDP) measures the total income of everyone in
the economy (adjusted for the level of prices);
– The inflation rate measures how fast prices are rising;
– The unemployment rate measures the fraction of the labor force that is out of
work.
Macroeconomists study how these variables are determined, why they
change over time, and how they interact with one another
Gross Domestic Product
(GDP of the U.S. in billions of chained 1996 dollars)
Expansion
Recessions
The Historical Performance of the U.S.
Economy: Figure 1.1
Source: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/A939RX0Q048SBEA
The Historical Performance of the U.S. Economy: Figure 1.1
Two aspects of this figure are noteworthy.
- First, real GDP grows over time. Real GDP per person today is more than
eight times higher than it was in 1900
- Second, although real GDP rises in most years, this growth is not steady.
There are repeated periods during which real GDP falls, the most dramatic
instance being the early 1930s.
GDP per capita for Tunisia
The Historical Performance of the U.S.
Economy: Figure 1.2
Source: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/A191RI1A225NBEA
The Historical Performance of the U.S. Economy: Figure 1.2
You can see that inflation varies substantially over time.
- In the first half of the twentieth century, the inflation rate averaged only slightly
above zero.
- Periods of falling prices, called deflation, were almost as common as periods of
rising prices.
- By contrast, inflation has been the norm during the past half century
- Inflation became most severe during the late 1970s, when prices rose at a rate of
almost 10 percent per year.
- In recent years, the inflation rate has been about 2 percent per year, indicating that
prices have been fairly stable.
The Historical Performance of the U.S.
Economy: Figure 1.3
Source: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/UNRATE
The Historical Performance of the U.S. Economy: Figure 3
- Notice that there is always some unemployment in the
economy.
- In addition, although the unemployment rate has no
long-term trend, it varies substantially from year to year.
- Recessions and depressions are associated with unusually
high unemployment.
Unemployment rate for Tunisia
How Economists Think
- Economists often study politically charged issues, but they
try to address these issues with a scientist’s objectivity.
- Like any science, economics has its own set of tools —
terminology, data, and a way of thinking — that can seem
foreign and arcane to the layperson.
How Economists Think
- Economists use models to understand the world, but an economist’s
model is more likely to be made of symbols and equations than
plastic and glue.
- Economists build their “toy economies” to explain economic
variables, such as GDP, inflation, and unemployment.
Where :
Q d = quantity of pizza demanded by consumers
P = price of pizza
Y = aggregate income
Example of a model:
The supply function for the pizza
• Similarly, the economist supposes that the quantity of pizza supplied by
pizzerias Q s depends on the price of pizza P and on the price of materials Pm
, such as cheese, tomatoes, flour, and anchovies. This relationship is the
supply function.
Where :
Q s= quantity of pizza supplied by pizzerias
P = price of pizza
Pm = price of materials (an input)
Example of a model:
The pizza market : equilibrium
Equilibrium
Qd = Q s
Example: the pizza market
- Endogenous variables: price and quantity
• The theory also needs :
– Graphs that show how the endogenous variables are linked to each
other (model)
– Exogenous variables (shift variables)
Example: the pizza market
The Model of Supply and Demand
• The economist illustrates the model with a supply-and-demand
diagram,
• The most famous economic model is that of supply and demand for a
good or service — in this case, pizza.
5. Changes in expectations
49
Graphs: Supply and Demand
Income ↑
prices of competing goods ↑
prices of complementary goods ↓
population ↑
Preference for pizza ↑
Shift variables for demand
Income
prices of competing goods
prices of complementary goods
population
Preference for pizza
Shift variables for demand
Income ↑
Demand of pizza↑ (from D1 to D2)
Equilibrium price ↑ (from P1 to P2)
Equilibrium quantity↑(from Q1 to Q2)
Technology
prices of raw materials
Wages
Shift variables for supply
Technology ↓
prices of raw materials ↑
Wages ↑
Shift variables for Supply
• And when the price of materials increases,
The model shows that in this case, the
equilibrium price of pizza rises, while the
equilibrium quantity of pizza falls as in the next
figure.
Shift variables for Supply
Price of materials ↑
Supply of pizza ↓ (from D1 to D2)
Equilibrium price ↑ (from P1 to P2)
Equilibrium quantity ↓ from Q1 to Q2)
Income ↑
prices of competing goods ↑
prices of complementary goods ↓
population ↑
Predictions Grid P Q
Income + +
prices of competing goods
prices of complementary
goods
population
ad spending by pizzerias
At this point, you should do problem 3
Sales tax rate ↓
on page 15 of the textbook.
Predictions: demand shifters
Income ↑
prices of competing goods ↑
prices of complementary goods ↓
population ↑
Predictions Grid P Q
Income + +
prices of competing goods + +
prices of complementary - -
goods
population + +
ad spending by pizzerias + +
At this point, you should do problem 3
Sales tax rate ↓ - -
on page 15 of the textbook.
Predictions: supply shifters
Technology ↓
prices of raw materials ↑
Wages ↑
Predictions Grid P Q
Technology
Prices of raw materials
Wages
Predictions: supply shifters
Technology ↓
prices of raw materials ↑
Wages ↑
Predictions Grid P Q
Technology - +
Prices of raw materials + -
Wages + -
HOW ECONOMISTS THINK:
ALGEBRA
How Economists Think: algebra
• Every economic theory consists of
– Endogenous variables
– Exogenous variables and parameters (shift variables)
– Equations that show how the variables and parameters are linked to
each other (model)
• The theory predicts how changes in the exogenous variables
and parameters affect the endogenous variables
Equations
• Each equation algebraically represents one
idea/assumption about how the (endogenous and
exogenous) variables and parameters are linked to
each other
Solving the equations
• If we have a set of equations such that the number of
equations is equal to the number of endogenous variables in
the equations, then we can usually solve the equations and
express each endogenous variable in the equations in terms of
the exogenous variables and parameters
• These solutions predict the likely effects of the exogenous
variables and parameters on the endogenous variables
Example of a model:
The supply & demand for new cars
• Explains the factors that determine the price of cars and the quantity
sold
• Assumes the market is competitive: each buyer and seller is too small
to affect the market price
• Variables:
Q d = quantity of cars that buyers demand
Q s = quantity that producers supply
P = price of new cars
Y = aggregate income
Ps = price of steel (an input)
The demand for cars
A list of the
variables
that affect Q d
Digression: Functional notation
• General functional notation
shows only that the variables are related:
Q Quantity
of cars
The market for cars: supply
P
Price
of cars S
equilibrium
price
D
Q Quantity
of cars
equilibrium
quantity
The effects of an increase in income:
P
Price
of cars S
D
Q Quantity
…which increases the market Q2 Q1 of cars
price and reduces the
quantity.
Endogenous vs. exogenous variables:
• The values of endogenous variables
are determined in the model.
• The values of exogenous variables
are determined outside the model:
the model takes their values & behavior
as given.
• In the model of supply & demand for cars,
A Multitude of Models
No one model can address all the issues we care about. For
example,
▪ If we want to know how a fall in aggregate income affects new
car prices, we can use the S/D model for new cars.
▪ But if we want to know why aggregate income falls, we need a
different model.
A Multitude of Models
• So we will learn different models for studying different issues (e.g.,
unemployment, inflation, long-run growth).
• For each new model, you should keep track of
– its assumptions,
– which of its variables are endogenous and which are exogenous,
– the questions it can help us understand, and those it cannot.
Prices: flexible versus sticky
• Economists normally presume that the price of a good or a service
moves quickly to bring quantity supplied and quantity demanded
into balance.
• In other words, they assume that markets are normally in
equilibrium, so the price of any good or service is found where the
supply and demand curves intersect.
• This assumption, called market clearing (is central to the model of
the pizza market discussed earlier).
• For answering most questions, economists use market-clearing
models.
Prices: flexible versus sticky
• Market clearing: an assumption that prices are flexible and adjust
to equate supply and demand.
• Although market-clearing models assume that all wages
and prices are flexible, in the real world some wages and
prices are sticky.
Prices: flexible versus sticky
• In fact, many wages and prices adjust slowly.
– Labor contracts often set wages for up to three years.
– Many firms leave their product prices the same for long periods
of time; for example, magazine publishers change their
newsstand prices only every three or four years.
• Although market-clearing models assume that all wages
and prices are flexible, in the real world some wages and
prices are sticky.
Prices: flexible versus sticky
• Short run : in the short run, many prices are sticky-
they adjust only sluggishly in response to supply/demand
imbalances.
For example :
– labor contracts that fix the nominal wage
for a year or longer
– magazine prices that publishers change
only once every 3-4 years
Prices: flexible versus sticky
• Market-clearing models might not describe the economy at every instant, but they
do describe the equilibrium toward which the economy gravitates.
Over short periods, many prices in the economy are fixed at predetermined
levels. Therefore, most macroeconomists believe that price stickiness is a better
assumption for studying the short-run behavior of the economy.
Prices: flexible versus sticky
• The economy’s behavior depends partly on whether prices are
sticky or flexible:
• If prices are sticky, then demand won’t always equal supply. This
helps explain
– unemployment (excess supply of labor)
– the occasional inability of firms to sell what they produce.
• Long run: prices are flexible, markets are clear, economy behaves
very differently
Conclusion:
• Market-clearing models might not describe the economy at
every instant, but they do describe the equilibrium toward
which the economy gravitates.
• Therefore, most macroeconomists believe that price
flexibility is a good assumption for studying long-run issues,
such as the growth in real GDP that we observe from decade
to decade.
Conclusion:
• For studying short-run issues, such as year-to-year fluctuations in real
GDP and unemployment, the assumption of price flexibility is less
plausible.
• Over short periods, many prices in the economy are fixed at
predetermined levels.
• Therefore, most macroeconomists believe that price stickiness is a
better assumption for studying the short-run behavior of the
economy.