Microeconomics 1 AAU Final Module
Microeconomics 1 AAU Final Module
CHAPTER ONE
THEORY OF CONSUMER BEHAVIOR
1.1 Introduction
Economics is the study of efficient allocation of resources in order to attain the
maximum fulfillment of unlimited human wants or needs. It is also defined as the study
of how people make choices to cope with scarcity. Economics studies how people choose
to use scarce resources to produce various commodities, how people consume goods and
services and how they trade.
In the above definition, efficiency, unlimited human wants, scarce resources and choices
are the key phrases in the study of the subject matter of economics.
Unlimited wants and scarce resources
Human beings want food, clothes, shelter and other variety of goods and services for their
survival. These human wants are unlimited and increase from time to time; however,
economic resources that include Land, Labor, Capital and Entrepreneurship are scarce by
their nature. Although using these economic resources society produces what it wants, it
will not be able to produce and consume all the goods and services it wants. Thus,
economics describes various sets of tools that enable societies to use their scarce
resources efficiently in order to achieve the highest possible standard of living.
Microeconomics deals with the behavior of individual economic units. Any individual or
entity such as consumers, workers, firms etc that play a role in the functioning of our
economy considered as an economic unit. Microeconomics explains how and why these
economic units make economic decisions. It also explains how consumers and firms buy
out puts and sale inputs and how their choices are affected by changing prices/costs and
incomes/revenues. Consumers, workers, firms etc are interested to know causes of price
and output instability as well as unemployment. Moreover, most of our issues and
problems are related to economic matters. In general, an individual who does not
understand basic economic principles will not appreciate and evaluate public issues that
are most of them are related with economics.
1
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
As a consumer, we take numerous decisions in our daily life: should we take tea or coffee
in the morning? Should we carry lunch packet or take lunch in the cafeteria? The way
-making
behavior.
The theory of consumer choice lies on the assumption of the consumer being rational to
maximize his level of satisfaction. The consumer makes choices by comparing bundle of
goods to maximize utility. Therefore consumers utility maximizing decision does not
only depend on the level of income but also determined by his preferences. Thus
preferences + budget constraint = choice of goods that can give maximum satisfaction.
Given any two consumption bundles (groups of goods) available for purchase, how a
consumer compares the goods? Does he prefer one good to another, or does he be
indifferent between the two groups?
Given any two consumption bundles, the consumer can either decide that one of
consumption bundles is strictly better than the other, or decide that he is indifferent
between the two bundles. Accordingly we will have two types of preferences.
Strict preference
Given any two consumption bundles(X1,X2) and (Y1,Y2),if (X1,X2)>(Y1,Y2) or if he
chooses (X1,X2) when (Y1,Y2) is available the consumer definitely wants the X-bundle
than Y and we can say that (X1,X2) is strictly preferred to (Y1,Y2).
Weak preference
Given any two consumption bundles(X1,X2) and (Y1,Y2),if the consumer is indifferent
between the two commodity bundles or if (X1,X2) (Y1,Y2),the consumer would be
equally satisfied and if he consumes (X1,X2) or (Y1,Y2) we can say (X1,X2) is weakly
preferred to (Y1,Y2,) or the reverse.
Assumptions on preferences
Completeness
For any two commodity bundles X and Y, a consumer will prefer X to Y,Y to X or will
be indifferent between the two.
Transitivity
2
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
It means that if a consumer prefers basket A to basket B and to basket C, then the
consumer also prefers A to C.
More is better than less given that all goods are desirable
Consumers always prefer more of any good to less and they are never satisfied or
satiated. However, bad goods are not desirable and consumers will always prefer less of
them.
1.3 Utility
Economists use the term utility to describe the satisfaction or enjoyment derived from the
consumption of a good or service.
Definition
Utility is the level of satisfaction that is obtained by consuming or having a commodity or
undertaking an activity.
In defining strict preference, we said that given any two consumption bundles(X1,X2)
and (Y1,Y2),the consumer definitely wants the X bundle than the Y bundle if (X1,X2) >
(Y1,Y2).This means, the consumer preferred bundle (X1,X2) to bundle (Y1,Y2) if and
only if the utility (X1,X2) is larger than the utility of (Y1,Y2).
The concept of utility is characterized with the following properties:
3
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Can we measure utility? If yes how do we measure the satisfaction level (Utility) that we
get from goods and services?
1.4. Approaches to measure Utility
Utility maximization theories are important to deal with consumer behavior. Thus, in this
section, you will learn about the Utility theories. There are two major approaches of
measuring utility, Cardinal and ordinal approaches.
1.5 The Cardinal Utility theory
Neo classical economists (cardinal utility theorists) argued that utility is measurable like
weight, height, temperature and they suggested a unit of measurement of satisfaction
called utils. A util is a cardinal number like 1,2,3 etc simply attached to utility. Hence,
utility can be quantitatively measured.
Assumptions of Cardinal Utility theory
4
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
5. Diminishing Marginal Utility (DMU).The utility derived from each from each
successive units of a commodity diminishes. In other words, the marginal utility
of a commodity diminishes as the consumer acquires larger quantities of it.
6. The total utility of a basket of goods depends on the quantities of the individual
commodities.
If there are n commodities in the bundle with quantities, X 1 , X 2 ,... X n the total
utility is given by:
TU=f ( X 1 , X 2 ...... X n )
1.6. Total and Marginal Utility
Definitions
Total Utility (TU): It refers to the total amount of satisfaction a consumer gets from
consuming or possessing some specific quantities of a commodity or commodities at a
particular time. TU=U1+U2+U3 s.
TU=TUx+TUy+TUz
As the consumer consumes more of a good per time period, his/her total utility increases.
However, there is a saturation point for that commodity in which the consumer will not
be capable of enjoying any greater satisfaction from it.
Marginal Utility (MU): It refers to the additional utility obtained from consuming an
additional unit of a commodity. In other words, marginal utility is the change in total
utility resulting from the consumption of one or more unit of a product per unit of time.
Graphically, it is the slope of total utility.
Mathematically, the formula for marginal utility is:
TU
MU Where, TU is the change in Total Utility, and,
Q
Q is change in the amount of product consumed.
5
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
explained in the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility which is stated as as the quantity
consumed of a commodity increases per unit of time, the utility derived from the
successive unit decreases, given consumption of all other commodities remaining
constant .
The LDMU is best explained by the MU curve that is derived from the relationship
between the TU and total quantity consumed.
Table 1.1 Hypothetical table showing TU and MU of consuming Oranges (X)
Units of
0 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th 6th
Quantity(x)
consumed Unit Unit unit unit Unit Unit
unit
TUX 0 util 10 utils 16 utils 20 utils 22 utils 22 utils 20 utils
MUX 0 10 6 4 2 0 -2
20
TUX
15
Total Utility
10
Quantity X
Marginal Utility
10
Quantity X
1 2 3 4 5
MUX
6
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
The total utility curve reaches its pick point (Saturation point) at point A. This Saturation
point indicates that by consuming 5 oranges, the consumer attains its highest satisfaction
of 22 utils. However, Consumption beyond this point results in Dissatisfaction, because
consuming the 6th and more orange brings a lesser additional utility than the previous
orange. Point B where the MU curve reaches its maximum point is called an inflexion
point or the point of Diminishing Marginal utility.
The law of diminishing marginal utility holds only under certain given conditions. These
conditions are
I. The unit of the consumer goods must be standard i.e It the units are too small
or large, the law may not hold.
II.
consumption.
III. There must be continuity in consumption and where break in continuity
necessary, it must be appropriately short.
IV. The mental condition of the consumer must remain normal during the period
of consumption of a commodity.
1.7. Equilibrium of a consumer
A consumer that maximizes utility reaches his/her equilibrium position when allocation
of his/her expenditure is such that the last birr spent on each commodity yields the same
utility.
MU X 1 MU X 2 MU X n
......... MU m Where: MUm marginal utility of money
PX1 PX 2 PX n
Diagrammatically,
C
PX
MUX
7
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Note that: at any point above point C like point A where MUX> Px, it pays the consumer
to consume more. At any point below point C like point B where MUX< Px the
consumer consumes less of X. However, at point C where MUx=Px the consumer is at
equilibrium.
Marginal utility
Quantity of Marginal utility of
Total utility Marginal utility per Birr(price=2
Orange money
birr)
0 0 - - 1
1 6 6 3 1
2 10 4 2 1
3 12 2 1 1
4 13 1 0.5 1
5 13 0 0 1
6 11 -2 -1 1
For consumption level lower than three quantities of oranges, since the marginal utility of
orange is higher than the price, the consumer can increase his/her utility by consuming
more quantities of oranges. On the other hand, for quantities higher than three, since the
marginal utility of orange is lower than the price, the consumer can increase his/her
utility by reducing its consumption of oranges.
Mathematically, the equilibrium condition of a consumer that consumes a single good X
occurs when the marginal utility of X is equal to its market price.
MU X PX
8
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
a
P1
b
P
Price
c
P2
MUX
O Quantity
P1
Price
P
Demand
P2 Curve
O Quantity
Q1 Q Q2
Figure 2.3 Derivation of Demand curve
9
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
10
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
4. The total utility of the consumer depends on the quantities of the commodities
Bundle A B C D
(Combination)
Orange(X) 1 2 4 7
Banana (Y) 10 6 3 1
Each combination of good X and Y gives the consumer equal level of total utility. Thus,
the individual is indifferent whether he consumes combination A, B, C or D.
Indifference Curves: an indifference curve shows the various combinations of two goods
that provide the consumer the same level of utility or satisfaction. It is the locus of points
(particular combinations or bundles of good), which yield the same utility (level of
satisfaction) to the consumer, so that the consumer is indifferent as to the particular
combination he/she consumes.
11
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
10 A
Indifference
B
Banana (Y)
6 Curve (IC)
Good B
C
2 IC3
D IC2
1
IC1
1 2 4 7 Good A
OrangeX
meat, we can graph a set of indifference curves called an indifference map. In other
words it is the entire set of indifference curves is known as an indifference map, which
reflects the entire set of tastes and preferences of the consumer. A higher indifference
curve refers to a higher level of satisfaction and a lower indifference curve shows lesser
satisfaction. IC2 reflects higher level of utility than that of IC1.Any consumer has lots of
indifference curves, not just one.
Properties of Indifference Curves:
Indifference curves have certain unique characteristics with which their foundation is
based.
1. Indifference curves have negative slope (downward sloping to the right).
Indifference curves are negatively sloped because the consumption level of
one commodity can be increased only by reducing the consumption level of
the other commodity. That means, if the quantity of one commodity increases
with the quantity of the other remaining constant, the total utility of the
12
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
B
Banana
Banana
E
D IC2
C
A
IC1
X
Orange Orange
Fig.1.5 positively sloped and intersected indifference curves
As we discussed earlier, Indifference curves cannot intersect each other. If they did, the
consumer would be indifferent between C and E, (Right panel of figure 2.6) since both
are on indifference curve one (IC1). Similarly, the consumer would be indifferent
13
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
between points D and E, since they are on the same indifference curve, IC2.By
transitivity, the consumer must also be indifferent between C and D. However, a rational
consumer would prefer D to C because he/she can have more Orange at point D (more
Orange by an amount of X).
The Marginal rate of substitution (MRS)
To quantify the amount of one good that a consumer will give up to obtain more of
another, we often use marginal rate of substitution as a measurement (MRS).
Definition: Marginal rate of substitution of X for Y is defined as the number of units of
commodity Y that must be given up in exchange for an extra unit of commodity of X so
that the consumer maintains the same level of satisfaction.
Number of units of Y given up
MRS X ,Y
Number of units of X gained
It is the negative of the slope of an indifference curve at any point of any two
commodities such as X and Y, and is given by the slope of the tangent at that point:
i.e., Slope of indifference curve
y
MRS X ,Y
x
In other words, MRS refers to the amount of one commodity that an individual is willing
to give up to get an additional unit of another good while maintaining the same level of
satisfaction or remaining on the same indifference curve. The diminishing slope of the
indifference curve means the willingness to substitute X for Y diminishes as one move
down the curve.
Note that ( MRS X ,Y ) measures the downward vertical distance (the amount of y that the
individual is willing to give up) per unit of horizontal distance (i.e. per additional unit of
Y
x required) to remain on the same indifference curve. That is, MRS X ,Y because of
X
the reduction in Y, MRS is negative. However, we multiply by negative one and express
MRS X ,Y as a positive value.
subjective willingness to substitute A for B (or B for A) will depend on the amounts of B
and A he/she possesses.
14
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Banana (Y) 10 6 3 1
Y 4
MRS X ,Y (between points A and B 4
X 1
, in the above case the consumer is willing to forgo 4 units of Banana to obtain 1 more
unit of Orange. If the consumer moves from point B to point C, he is willing to give up
only 2 units of Banana(Y) to obtain 1 unit of Oran
Having still less of Banana and more of Orange at point D, the consumer is willing to
give up only 1 unit of Banana so as to obtain 3 units of Orange. In this case, the MRS
reases, the marginal utility of additional units
of Y decreases. Similarly, as the quantity of X decreases, its marginal utility increases. In
addition, the MRS decreases as one move downwards to the right.
Marginal Utility and Marginal rate of Substitution
It is also possible to show the derivation of the MRS using MU concepts. The MRS X ,Y is
15
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
MU Y dX
Or, MRS Y , X
MU X dY
Example
X4
U .Compute the MRSX ,Y .
Y 2
MU X
MRS X ,Y
MU Y
dU dU
MU X and MU Y
dX dY
Therefore, MU X 4 1 2
4( X Y ) 4( X 3Y 2 ) and MU Y 2( X 4Y 2 1 ) 2 X 4Y
MU X 4 X 3Y 2 Y
MRS X ,Y 4
2
MU Y 2X Y X
Special Indifference Curves
Convexity or down ward sloping is among the characteristics of indifference curve and
this shape of indifference curve is for most goods. In this situation, we assume that two
commodities such as x and y can substitute one another to a certain extent but are not
perfect substitutes. However, the shape of the indifference curve will be different if
commodities have some other unique relationship such as perfect substitution or
complementary.
Here, are some of the ways in which indifference curves/maps might be used to reflect
preferences for three special cases.
I. Perfect substitutes: If two commodities are perfect substitutes (if they are essentially
the same), the indifference curve becomes a straight line with a negative slope. MRS for
perfect substitutes is constant. (Panel a)
IC2
IC1
Right shoe
IC3
Total
IC2
IC1
16
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
II. Perfect complements: If two commodities are perfect complements, the indifference
curve takes the shape of a right angle. Suppose that an individual prefers to consume left
shoes (on the horizontal axis) and right shoes on the vertical axis in pairs. For example, if
an individual has two pairs of shoes, additional right or left shoes provide no more utility
for him/her. MRS for perfect complements is zero (both MRS XY and MRS XY is the same,
i.e. zero).
III.A useless good: Panel C in the above figure shows an ind
for food (on the horizontal axis) and an out-dated book, a useless good, (on the vertical
axis). Since they are totally useless, increasing purchases of out-dated books does not
increase utility. This person enjoys a higher level of utility only by getting additional
food consumption. For example, the vertical indifference curve IC 2 shows that utility will
be IC 2 as long as this person has some units of food no matter how many out dated books
he/she has.
1.11 The Budget Line or the Price line
I o goods but
they can not tell us which combinations of the two goods will be chosen or bought..
In reality, the consumer is constrained by his/her money income and prices of the two
commodities. Therefore, in addition to consumer preferences, we need to know the
consumer while maximizing utility is constrained by the amount of income and prices of
goods that must be paid. This constraint is often presented with the help of the budget
line constructing by alternative purchase possibilities of two goods. Therefore, before we
The budget line is a line or graph indicating different combinations of two goods that a
consumer can buy with a given income at a given prices. In other words, the budget line
17
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
In order to draw the budget line facing the consumer, we consider the following assumptions:
1. there are only two goods, X and Y, bought in quantities X and Y;
2. each consumer is confronted with market determined prices, Px and Py, of good X and
good Y respectivley; and
3. the consumer has a known and fixed money income (M).
By assuming that the consumer spends all his/her income on two goods (X and Y), we
can express the budget constraint as:
M PX X PY Y Where, PX=price of good X
PY=price of good Y
X=quantity of good X
Y=quantity of good Y
This means that the amount of money spent on X plus the amount spent on Y equals the
money income.
Suppose for example a household with 30 Birr per day to spend on banana(X) at 5 Birr
each and Orange(Y) at 2 Birr each. That is, PX 5, PY 2, M 30birr .
Therefore, our budget line equation will be:
5X 2Y 30
Table 1.6 Alternative purchase possibilities of the two goods
Consumption
A B C D E F
Alternatives
Kgs of banana (X) 0 1 2 3 4 6
Kgs of Orange(Y) 15 12.5 10 7.5 5 0
Total Expenditure 30 30 30 30 30 30
At alternative A, the consumer is using all of his /her income for good Y. Mathematically
it is the y-intercept (0, 15). And at alternative F, the consumer is spending all his income
for good X. mathematically; it is the x-intercept (6, 0). We may present the income
constraint graphically by the budget line whose equation is derived from the budget
equation.
M PX X PY Y
M XPX YPY
By rearranging the above equation we can derive the general equation of a budget line,
18
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
M PX
Y X
PY PY
M
= Vertical Intercept (Y-intercept), when X=0.
PY
PX
= slope of the budget line (the ratio of the prices of the two goods)
PY
The horizontal intercept (i.e., the maximum amount of X the individual can consume or
purchase given his income) is given by:
M PX
X 0 M/PY
PY PY
M PX
X B
PY PY
M A
X
PX
M/PX
Fig.1.7 Derivation of the Budget Line
Therefore, the budget line is the locus of combinations or bundle of goods that can be
purchased if the entire money income is spent.
If the income of the consumer changes (keeping the prices of the commodities
unchanged) the budget line also shifts (changes). Increase in income causes an upward
shift of the budget line that allows the consumer to buy more goods and services and
decreases in income causes a downward shift of the budget line that leads the consumer
to buy less quantity of the two goods. It is important to note that the slope of the budget
line (the ratio of the two prices) does not change when income rises or falls. The budget
line shifts from B to B1 when income decreases and to B2 when income rises.
19
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
M2/Py
M1/Py
B B2
B1
Y Y
B1 B1
B
B
X X
Fig.a Fig.b
20
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
What would happen if price of x falls, while the price of good Y and money incme
remaining constant?
M/py A
B B
M/Px M/Px ' X
Fig. 1.10 Effect of a decrease in price of x on the budget line
Since the Y-intercept (M/Py) is constant, the consumer can purchase the same amount of
Y by spending the entire money income on Y regardless of the price of X. We can see
from the above figure that a decrease in the price of X, money income and price of Y
held constant, pivots the budget line out-
What would happen if price of x rises, while the price of good Y and money incme
remaining constant?
Since the Y-intercept (M/Py) is constant, the consumer can purchase the same amount of
Y by spending the entire money income on Y regardless of the price of X. We can see
from the figure below that an increase in the price of X, money income and price of Y
held constant, pivots the budget line in-
A
M/Py
M/Px1 M/Px2
21
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
What would happen if price of Y rises, while the price of good X and money incme
remaining constant?
Since the X-intercept (M/Py) is constant, the consumer can purchase the same amount of
X by spending the entire money income on X regardless of the price of Y. We can see
from the above figure that an increase in the price of Y, money income and price of X
held constant, pivots the budget line in-ward, a
Y
A
M/py
M/py'
B
M/Px X
M/py A
B
M/Px X
22
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
The above figure shows what happens to the budget line when the price of Y increases while the
price of good X and money income held constant. Since Py decreases, M/Py increases thereby the
budget line shifts outward.
Numerical Example
A person has $ 100 to spend on two goods(X,Y) whose respective prices are $3 and $5.
a) Draw the budget line.
b) What happens to the original budget line if the budget falls by 25%?
c) What happens to the original budget line if the price of X doubles?
d) What happens to the original budget line if the price of Y falls to 4?
from our previous discussion the budget line for two commodities was expressed as:
PX X PY Y M
3X 5Y 100
5Y 100 3 X
100 3
Y X
5 5
3
Y 20 X
5
When the person spends all of his income only on the consumption of good Y,we can get
the Y intercept that is(0,20).However, when the consumer spends all of his income on the
consumption of only good X,then we get the X intercept that is (33.33,0). Using these
two points we can draw the budget line. Thus, the budget line will be:
A
Y
20
B
33.33 X
If the budget decreases by 25%, then the budget will be reduced to 75.As a result the
budget line will be shifted in-ward forces the person to
23
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
buy less quantity of the two goods. The equation for the new budget line can be solved as
follows:
3X 5Y 75
5Y 75 3 X
75 3
Y X
5 5
3
Y 15 X
5
Therefore, the Y-intercept is 15 while the X-intercept is 25.However, since the ratio of
the prices does not change the slope of the budget line remains constant.
If the price of good X doubles the equation of the budget line will be 6 X 5Y 100and
if the price of good Y falls to 4, the equation for the new budget line will
be 6 X 4Y 100 .
1.13. Optimum of the Consumer: What a consumer Choose
A rational consumer seeks to maximize his utility or satisfaction by spending his or her
income. It maximizes the utility by trying to attain the highest possible indifference
curve, given the budget line. This occurs where an indifference curve is tangent to the
budget line so that the slope of the indifference curve ( MRS XY ) is equal to the slope of
24
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Y
A
B
E
IC4
C IC3
IC2
D
IC1
X
Figure 1.14 Consumer equilibrium
25
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
ICC
Commodity Y
E3
E2
E1
Commodity X
Engle Curve
I3
I2
Income
I1
X1 X2 X3 Commodity X
Figure 1.15 the income consumption and
the Engle curves
26
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
From the Income Consumption Curve we can derive the Engle Curve. The Engle curve is
named after Ernest Engel, the German Statistician who pioneered studies of family
budgets and expenditure positions
The Engle Curve is the relationship between the equilibrium quantity purchased of a
good and the level of income. It shows the equilibrium (utility maximizing) quantities of
a commodity, which a consumer will purchase at various levels of income; (ceteris
paribus) per unit of time.
In relation to the shape of the income-consumption and Engle curves goods can be
categorized as normal (superior) and inferior goods. Thus, commodities are said to be
normal, when the income consumption curve and its Engle curve are positively sloped;
meaning that more of the goods are purchased at higher levels of income. On the other
hand, commodities are said to be inferior when the income consumption curve and Engle
curve is negatively sloped, i.e. their purchase decreases when income increases.
For example, in the figure below good Y is a normal good while good X is a normal good
until the person level of income reaches M2 .Thus, when income increases beyond M2,
the person will buy less of good X as his income increases. Therefore, good X is a normal
good Up to point A and becomes an inferior good as the income consumption curve
bends backward.
M3/Py M3/Py
M2/Py M2/Py
M1/Py
M1/Py
27
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
We now look at the second factor that affects the equilibrium of the consumer that is
price of the goods. The effect of price on the consumption of good is even more
important to economists than the effect of changes in income. Here, we hold money
income constant and let price change to analyze the effect on consumer behavior.
In our previous discussion, we have seen that an increase in the price of good X, for
example, increases the absolute value of the slope of the budget line, but it does not affect
the vertical (Y) intercept of the line. Thus, the change in the price of x will result in out
ward shift of the budget line that makes the consumer to buy more of good x.If we
connect all the points representing equilibrium market baskets corresponding to each
price of good X we get a curve called price-consumption curve.
The price-consumption curve is the locus of the utility-maximizing combinations of
products that result from variations in the price of one commodity when other product
prices, the money income and other factors are held constant.
We can derive the demand curve of an individual for a commodity from the price
consumption curve. Below is an illustration of deriving the demand curve when price of
commodity X decreases from Px1 to Px 2 to Px 3 .
Commodity Y
PCC
Commodity X
Px1
Price of X
Px2
Individual
Px3 demand curve
X1 X2 X3 Commodity X
28
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Suppose that the consumer consumes two commodities X and Y given their prices by
spending level of money income M. Thus, the objective of the consumer is maximizing
his utility function subject to his limited income and market prices. In utility
maximization, the function that represents the objective that the consumer tries too
achieve is called the objective function and the constraint that the consumer faces is
represented by the constraint function.
The maximization problem will be formulated as follows:
MaximizeU f ( X , Y )
Subject to PX X PY Y M
We can rewrite the constraint as follows:
M PX X PY Y 0 or PX X PY Y M 0
Multiplying the constraint by Lagrange multiplier
(M PX X PY Y ) 0
U ( X ,Y ) (M PX X PY Y )
The first order condition requires that the partial derivatives of the Lagrange function
with respect to the two goods and the langrage multiplier be zero.
U U
PX 0; PY 0 and ( PX X PY Y M) 0
X X Y Y
From the above equations we obtain:
U U
PX and PY
X Y
U U
MU X and MU Y
X Y
Therefore, substituting and solving for we get the equilibrium condition:
29
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
MU X MU Y
PX PY
By rearranging, we get:
MU X PX
MU Y PY
The second order condition for maximum requires that the second order partial
derivatives of the Lagrange function with respect to the two goods must be negative.
2
U2 2
U2
0 and 0
X2 X2 Y2 Y2
Example
A consumer consuming two commodities X and Y has the following utility function
U XY 2 X .If the price of the two commodities are 4 and 2 respectively and his/her
budget is birr 60.
a) Find the quantities of good X and Y which will maximize utility.
b) Find the MRS X ,Y at optimum.
Solution
The Lagrange equation will be written as follows:
XY 2X (60 4 X 2Y )
Y 2 4 0
X
X 2 0
Y
60 4 X 2Y 0 (3)
From -dfrrequation, (1) we get Y 2 4 and from equation (2) we get X 2 .Thus,
Y 2 1
we can get that X and equation (2) gives as X.
2 2
Y 2
By substituting X in to equation (2) we get Y 14 and X 8.
2
MU X
MRS X ,Y
MU Y
30
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Y 2
X
After inserting the optimum value of Y=14 and X=8 we get 2 which equals to the price
PX 4
ratio of the two goods ( 2) .
PY 2
I/py1
Note that:
1 X 1 X 3 =NE= Total (net) effect
A B IC2
X 1 X 2 = SE=Substitution effect
C IC1 X 2 X 3 = IE=Income effect
Figure 1.18 Income and
Substitution effect for a normal good
x1 x2 IE x3 I/px2
1
SE
NE
31
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Suppose initially the income of the consumer is I 1 , price of goodY is Py1 , and Price of
I I
good X is Px1 , we have the budget line with y-intercept and X-intercept . The
Py1 Px1
A that indicates the point of tangency between the
budget line and indifference curve IC1 . As a result of a decrease in the price of X
I I
from Px1 to Px2 the budget line shifts outward with y-intercept & X-Intercept .
Py1 Px 2
new equilibrium will be on point B.
The total change in the quantity purchased of commodity X from the 1st equilibrium
point at A to the second equilibrium point at B shows the Net effect or total effect of the
price decline (change).
The total effect of the price change can be conceptually decomposed into the substitution
effect and income effect.
The Substitution Effect
The substitution effect refers to the change in the quantity demanded of a Commodity
resulting exclusively from a change in its price wh
along the original indifference curve. The decline in the price of X results in an increase
enced by the movement to a higher indifference
curve even though money income remains fixed.
return to the same level of satisfaction enjoyed before the price decline. Graphically, this
is accomplished by drawing a fictitious (imaginary) line of attainable combinations with a
Px 2
slope corresponding to new ratio of the product price so that it is just tangent to the
Py1
32
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
33
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
theory alone. In most cases, one would expect that increases in real income would result
in increases in consumption of a good. This is the case for so called Normal goods.
In short in the case of normal goods, the income effect and the substitution effect operate
in the same direction they reinforce each other. But not all goods are normal. Some
goods are called inferior goods because the income effect is the opposite (of that of a
normal good) for them-they operate in opposite direction. For an inferior good, a
decrease in the price of the commodity causes the consumer to buy more of it (the
substitution effect), but at the same time the higher real income of the consumer tends to
cause him to reduce consumption of the commodity (the income effect). We usually
observe that the substitution effect still is the more powerful of the two; even though the
income effect works counter to the substitution effect, it does not override it. Hence, the
demand curve for inferior goods is still negatively sloped.
Let us consider the following diagram that shows the income, substitution and net effect
for an inferior commodity in the case of a decline in the price of good X
Y KEY:
X1X3= NE=Net effect
X1X2= SE=Substitution effect
X2 X3= IE=Income effect
E3
E1
E2 IC2
X1 X3 X2 IC1 X
IE
NE
SE
Figure 2.19 Income, Substitution, and Net effect for an inferior commodity
In very rare occasions, a good may be so strongly inferior that the income effect actually
overrides the substitute effect. Such an occurrence means that a decline in the price of a
good would lead to a decline in the quantity demanded and that a rise in price will induce
an increase in quantity demanded. In other words, price and quantity move in the same
direction. The name given to such a unique situation is Giffen paradox; and it constitutes
34
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
an exception to the Law of demand. That is for Giffen goods the income effect (which
decreases the quantity demanded) is so strong that it offsets the substitution effect (which
increases the quantity demanded), with the result that the quantity demanded is directly
related to the price, at least over some range of variation of price.
E3
IC2
E1
E2
IC1
X3 X1 X2 X
SE
NE
IE
. Figure 1.20 Income, Substitution and net effects for a Giffen good,
When there is a price decline.
35
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
200
Therfore,his demand for good X will be 20 28 per month.
52
Suppose that the price of the good falls to 4 per kilogram.Therfore,the new demand at the
200
new price will be: 20 32.5 per month.
42
Thus,the total change in demand is 4.5 that is 32.5-28.
When the price falls the purchasing power of the consumer changes.Hence,iin order to
make the origiinal consumption of good X,the consumer adjusts his income.This can be
calculated as follows:
M1 P1' X P2 Y
M P1 X P2Y
Subtracting the second equation from the first gives:4-
M1 M X [ P1' P1 ]
M X P1
Therfore,new income to make the original consumption affordable when price falls to 4
is:
M X P1
M 28 * [ 4 5] 28
Hence,the level of iincome necessary to keep purchasing power constant is
M1 M M 200 28 172
The consumers new demand at the new price and income will be :
172
X ( 4,172) 20 30.75
42
Therfore,the substitution efffect will be:
X X (4,172) X (5,200) 30.75 28 2.75
The income effect will be:
X (4,200) X (4,172) 32.5 30.75 1.75
Since the result We obtained is positive we can conclude that the good is a normal good.
1.17 The Consumer Surplus:
While consumers purchas goods and services,they offten pay less than what they are
willing to pay.Thus,the difference between what they are willing to pay and what they
actually paid is considered as their surplus.
36
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
CS
P E
0
Q
Numerical Example
Suppose the demand function of a consumer is given by: Q 15 p
a. Compute the consumer surplus when the price of the good is 2
b. Compute the consumer surplus when the price of the good is 4
c. Compute the change in consumer surplus when the price changes from 2 to 4.
Solution
When Price is zero the demand for quantity purchased will be 15 and when the demand
for quantity is put to zero then the price level will be 15.And finally,when we insert the
given price level 2 in the demand equation we get the level of qunatity demanded that is
13.Hence,we can easily compute the area of the triangle that is found above the given
price level that is 2.
15 Panel a. Panel b
15
2
4
13 15 11 15
37
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
In panel a, the area of the triangle above price that is the consumer surplus is
1
* 13 * 13 84.5 and in panel b the consumer surplus is 60.5.Therfoere,due to a change
2
in the price level the consumer surplus will be 84.5 60.5 24.5
Summary
Consumers given their income and prices of the commodities, they spend their income so
as to attain the highest possible satisfaction or utility from commodities. Utility is thus the
satisfaction obtained from the consumption of a good. The maximization of utility is
referred to as the axiom of utility maximization. To attain this utility maximization
objective, the consumer must be able to compare the utility of the various baskets of
goods, which they can buy with their income. In order to explain the comparison of these
commodities we have two approaches. These are: cardinal approach and the Ordinal
approach.
Cardinalist believed that cardinal numbers could be used to express the utility derived
from the consumption of a commodity while ordinalists believed that utility is not
measureable, but is an ordinal magnitude. The main ordinal theories are the indifferece
curves approache and the revealed preferences hypothesis.These approaches are also
known as the indifference curve theories .
An indifference curve is the locus of points which provide the same level of satisfaction
to the consumer. The slope os an indifferece curve shows the marginal rate os
substitution between goods.
The consumer aims at maximization of utility, given his/her income and market prices of
the commodities available for consumption. Therefore, to determine the equilibrium of
the consumer, we have to bring together the indifference map and the budget line facing
the consumer on the same diagram.
There are two effects of a price change. If price falls (rises), the good becomes cheaper
(more expensive) relative to other goods; and consumers substitute toward (away from)
the good. This is the substitution effect
purchasing power increases (decreases). Since the set of consumption opportunities
increases (decreases) as price changes, the consumer changes the mix of his or her
consumption bundle. This effect is called the income effect.
38
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
CHAPTER TWO
THE THEORY OF PRODUCTION
39
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
In economics, short run refers to that period of time in which the quantity of at least one
input is fixed. For example, if it requires a firm one year to change the quantities of all
the inputs, those time periods below one year are considered as short run. Thus, short run
is that time period which is not sufficient to change the quantities of all inputs, so that at
least one input remains fixed.
One thing to be noted here is that short run periods of different firms have
different duration. Some firms can change the quantity of all their inputs with in a month
while it takes more than a year to change the quantity of all inputs for another type of
firms. For example, the time required to change the quantities of inputs in an automobile
factory is not equal with that of flour factory. The later takes relatively shorter time. Long
run is that time period (planning horizon) which is sufficient to change the quantities of
all inputs. Thus there is no fixed input in the long -run.
2.2 Production in the short run: Production with one variable input
Production with one variable input (while the others are fixed) is obviously a short run
phenomenon because there is no fixed input in the long run.
Assumption of short run production analysis
In order to simplify the analysis of short run production, the classical economist assumed
the following:
1. Perfect divisibility of inputs and outputs
This assumption implies that factor inputs and outputs are so divisible that one can hire,
for example a fraction of labor, a fraction of manager and we can produce a fraction of
output, such as a fraction of automobile.
2. Limited substitution between inputs
Factor inputs can substitute each other up to a certain point, beyond which they cannot
substitute each other
3. Constant technology
They assumed that level of technology of production is constant in the short run.
Suppose a firm that uses two inputs: Capital (which is a fixed input) and labor (which is
variable input). Given the assumptions of short run production, the firm can increase
output only by increasing the amount of labor it uses.
Hence, its production function is
40
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
41
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
total output resulting from using this additional worker (holding other inputs constant) is
the marginal product of the worker. If output changes by q when the number of workers
Thus, MPL measures the slope of the total product curve at a given point. In the short
run, the MP of the variable input first increases reaches its maximum and then tends to
decrease to the extent of being negative. That is, as we continue to combine more and
more of the variable inputs with the fixed input, the marginal product of the variable
input increases initially and then declines.
Average Product (AP)
The AP of an input is the ratio of total output to the number of variable inputs.
totalproduct TP
APlabour
numberofL L
The average product of labor first increases with the number of labor (i.e. TP increases
faster than the increase in labor), and eventually it declines.
Graphing the short run production curves
The following figures shows how the TP, MP and AP of the variable (labor) input vary
with the number of the variable input.
42
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Output
TP3
TP2 TP
TP1
L1 L2 L3
APL, MPL
APL
L1 L2 L3
MPL
Fig 2.1 Total product, average product and marginal product curves:
As the number of the labor hired increases (capital being fixed), the TP curve first rises,
reaches its maximum when L3 amount of labor is employed, beyond which it tends to
decline. Assuming that this short run production curve represents a certain car
manufacturing industry, it implies that L3 numbers of workers are required to efficiently
43
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
run the machineries. If the numbers of workers fall below L3, the machine is not fully
operating, resulting in a fall in TP below TP3. On the other hand, increasing the number
of workers above L3 will do nothing for the production process because only L3 number
of workers can efficiently run the machine. Increasing the number of workers above L3,
rather results in lower total product because it results in over crowded and unfavorable
working environment.
Marginal product curve increases until L1 number of labor reaches its maximum at L1,
and then it tends to fall. The MPL is zero at L3 (when the TP is maximal); beyond which
its value assumes zero indicating that each additional worker above L3 tends to create
over crowded working condition and reduces the total product. Thus, in the short run
(where some inputs are fixed), the marginal product of successive units of labor hired
increases initially, but not continuously, resulting in the limit to the total production.
Geometrically, the MP curve measures the slope of the TP. The slope of the TP curve
increases (MP increases) up to L1, it decreases from L1 to L3 and it becomes negative
beyond L3.
The average product curve increases up to L2, beyond which it continuously declines.
The AP curve can be measured by the slope of rays originating from the origin to a point
on the TP curve. For example, the APL at L2 is the ratio of TP2 to L2. This is identical to
the slope of ray a.
The relationship between AP and MP of the variable input
The relationship between MPL and APL can be stated as follows:
For all number of workers (Labor) below L2, MPL lies above APL.
At L2, MPL and APL are equal.
Beyond L2, MPL lies below the APL
Thus, the MPL curve passes through the maximum of the APL curve from above. This
relationship between APL and MPL can be shown algebraically as follows:
Suppose the production function is given as
TP = f (L), K -being constant
Given the total product function,
dTP df ( L) TP f ( L)
MPL and APL =
dL dL L L
44
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
To determine the relationship between APL and MPL, consider the slope of the APL
function.
f ( L) df ( L) dL
d( ) .L . f ( L)
dAPL L dL dL
Slope of APL = = = -------- (quotient rule of
dL dL L2
differentiation)
df ( L)
.L
dL f ( L) a b a b
Slope of APL = 2
- 2
----------------------------- (note that )
L L c c c
df ( L) f ( L)
= dL - L
L L
MPL APL df ( L) f ( L)
Slope of APL = , because = MPL and = APL
L dL L
Now when MPL > APL, Slope of APL is positive (APL rises)
When MPL = APL, Slope of APL is zero (APL is at its maximum).
When MPL < APL, Slope of APL is negative (APL falls)
The law of diminishing marginal returns (LDMR): short run law of production
The LDMR states that as the use of an input increases in equal increments (with other
inputs being fixed), a point will eventually be reached at which the resulting additions to
output decreases. When the labor input is small (and capital is fixed), extra labor adds
considerably to output, often because workers get the chance to specialize in one or few
tasks. Eventually, however, the LDMR operates: when the number of workers increases
further, some workers will inevitably become ineffective and the MPL falls (this happens
when the number of workers exceeds L1 in fig 2.1)
Note that the LDMR operates (MP of successive units of labor decreases) not because
highly qualified laborers are hired first and the least qualified last. Diminishing marginal
returns results from limitations on the use of other fixed inputs (e.g. machinery), not from
decline in worker quality.
The LDMR applies to a given production technology (when the level of technology is
fixed). Over time, however, technological improvements in the production process may
45
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
allow the entire total product curve shift upward, so that more output can be produced
with the same input.
2.5 Efficient Region of Production in the short-run
we are now not in a position to determine the specific number of the variable input
(labor) that the firm should employ because this depends on several other factors than the
productivity of labor such as the price of labor, the structure of input and output markets,
the demand for output, etc. However, it is possible to determine ranges over which the
variable input (labor) be employed.
of production.
Stage I ranges from the origin to the point of equality of the APL and MPL.
Stage II starts from the point of equality of MPL and APL and ends at a point
where MP is equal to zero.
Stage III covers the range of labor over which the MPL is negative.
Now, which stage of production is efficient and preferable?
Obviously, a firm should not operate in stage III because in this stage additional units of
variable input are contributing negatively to the total product (MP of the variable input is
negative) because of over crowded working environment i.e., the fixed input is over
utilized.
Stage I is also not an efficient region of production though the MP of variable input is
positive. The reason is that the variable input (the number of workers) is too small to
efficiently run the fixed input; so that the fixed input is under utilized (not efficiently
utilized)
Thus, the efficient region of production is stage II. At this stage additional inputs are
contributing positively to the total product and MP of successive units of variable input is
declining (indicating that the fixed input is being optimally used). Hence, the efficient
region of production is over that range of employment of variable input where the
marginal product of the variable input is declining but positive.
46
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
47
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Capital
q3
2 q2
1 q1
1
1 3 6 Labor
Fig 2.2 Isoquant and isoquant map. Isoquants show the fact that long run production
process is very flexible. A firm can produce q1 level of output by using either 3 capital
and 1 labor or 2 capital and 3 labor or 1 capital and 6 labor or any other combination of
labor and labor on the curve. The set of isoquant curves q1 q2 & q3 are called isoquant
map.
Properties of isoquants
Isoquants have most of the same properties as indifference curves. The biggest difference
between them is that output is constant along an isoquant where as indifference curves
ef
in its definition.
1. Isoquants slope down ward. Because isoquants denote efficient combination of inputs
that yield the same output, isoquants always have negative slope. Isoquants can never be
horizontal, vertical or upward sloping. If for example, isoquants have to assume zero
slopes (horizontal line) only one point on the isoquant is efficient. See the following
figures.
48
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
100kg
A teff
B
A
Labor A Labor
2 5
A B C
An isoquant can never be In this figure, a firm can produce In this figure, all points above
horizontal. In this figure, the 100kg of wheat by using any point A utilize higher
firm can produce 100kg of combination of labor and capital combination of both inputs to
teff by using either of the along the isoquant. But only point produce the same output (100 kg
following alternatives: 4 A is efficient. For example, point coffee). Point A shows the least
capital and 2 labor,4 capital B shows the same number of combination of inputs that can
and 5 labor or any other labor as point A, but higher yield 100 kg coffees. Thus all
combination of labor and capital. Thus point B is in other points are inefficient and
capital along the curve. efficient because it shows higher not part of the isoquants.
Obviously, only the first combination of inputs. Thus,
alternative is efficient as it isoquants can never be vertical
uses the least possible line
combination of inputs. Thus,
all points, except A, are
inefficient and not part of
Thus, efficiency requires that isoquants must be negatively sloped. As employment of one
factor increases, the employment of the other factor must decrease to produce the same
quantity efficiently.
2. are convex to the origin due to imperfect substitution (declining slope)
3. The further an isoquant lays away from the origin, the greater the level of output
it denotes. Higher isoquants (isoquants further from the origin) denote higher
combination of inputs. The more inputs used, more outputs should be obtained if the firm
is producing efficiently. Thus efficiency requires that higher isoquants must denote
higher level of output.
4. Isoquants do not cross each other. This is because such intersections are inconsistent
with the definition of isoquants.
Consider the following figure.
49
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
K*
L*
This figure shows that the firm can produce at either output level (20 or 50) with the
same combination of labor and capital (L* and K*). The firm must be producing
inefficiently if it produces q = 20, because it could produce q = 50 by the same
combination of labor and capital (L* and K*). Thus, efficiency requires that isoquants do
not cross each other.
Shape of isoquants
Isoquants can have different shapes (curvature) depending on the degree to which factor
inputs can substitute each other.
1-Linear isoquants
Isoquants would be linear when labor and capital are perfect substitutes for each other. In
this case the slope of an iso quant is constant. As a result, the same output can be
produced with only capital or only labor or an infinite combination of both. Graphically,
K
Fig.2.6 linear isoquant. Capital
and labor can perfectly substitute
10 each other so that the same
output (q=100) can be produced
by using either 10k or 8K and
12L or 15L or an infinite
8 combinations of both inputs.
q=100
L
12 15
50
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
q3
Fig. 2.7 L-shaped isoquant
q2
K2
q1
K1
L
L1 L2
When isoquants are L-shaped, there is only one efficient way of producing a given level
of output: Only one combination of labor and capital can be used to produce a given
level of output. To produce q1 level of output there is only one efficient combination of
labor and capital (L1 and K1). Output cannot be increased by keeping one factor (say
labor) constant and increasing the other (capital). To increase output (say from q1 to q2)
both factor inputs should be increased by equal proportion.
3. Kinked isoquants
This assumes limited substitution between inputs. Inputs can substitute each other only at
some points. Thus, the isoquant is kinked and there are only a few alternative
combinations of inputs to produce a given level of output. These isoquants are also called
linear programming isoquants or activity analysis isoquants. See the figure below.
51
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
12 A
7
B
5
C
3
D
L
1 3 5 9
Fig. 2.8 kinked isoquant in this case labor and capital can substitute each other only at
some point at the kink (A, B, C, and D). Thus, there are only four alternative processes of
producing q=100 out put.
4. Smooth, convex isoquants
This shape of isoquant assumes continuous substitution of capital and labor over a
certain range, beyond which factors cannot substitute each other. Basically, kinked
isoquants are more realistic:
There is often limited (not infinite) method of producing a given level of output.
However, traditional economic theory mostly adopted the continuous isoquants because
they are mathematically simple to handle by the simple rule of calculus, and they are
approximation of the more realistic isoquants (the kidded isoquants). From now on we
use the smooth and convex isoquants to analyze the long run production.
52
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Fig: 2.9 the smooth and convex isoquant. This type of isoquant is the limiting case of the
kinked isoquant when the number kink is infinite. The slope of the iso quant decrease as
we move from the top (left) to the right (bottom) along the isoquant. This indicates that
the amount by which the quantity of one input (capital)can be reduced when one extra
unit of another inputs(labor)is used ( so that out put remains constant) decreases as more
of the latter input (labor)is used.
53
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
units of capital ( K=4), to increase labor from 2 to 3, the firm reduce 2 unit of capital
( K=2), and so on. Hence, the firm reduces lower and lower number of capital for the
successive one unit of labor. , why does this happen?
The reason is that when the number of capital is large and that of labor is low, the
productivity of capital is relatively lower and that of labor is higher (due to the low of
diminishing marginal returns). Thus, at this point relatively large amount of capital is
required to replace one unit of labor (or one unit of labor can replace relatively large
amount of capital). As the employment of labor increases and that of capital decreases (as
we move down ward along the isoquant), quite the reverse will happen. That is,
productivity of capital increases and that of labor decreases. Hence, the amount of capital
that needs to be reduced increase when one extra labor is used decreases. The fact that the
slope of an isoquant is decreasing makes an isoquant convex to the origin.
MRTS L, K (the slope of isoquant) can also be given by the ratio of marginal products of
factors. That is,
K MPL
MRTS L, K
L MPK
Given this production function, the equation of a specific isoquant can be obtained by
equating the production function with a given level of output, say q .
q = f (L, K) = q
54
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
q q
(But, MPl and MPk )
L k
Thus, the above equation can be written as:
MPL. dL + MPK.dk = 0
MPL dK
MPk dL
There fore, the slope of an isoquant can be given as the ratio of marginal products of
inputs.
Elasticity of substitution
MRTS as a measure of the degree of substitutability of factors has a serious defect. It
depends on the units of measurement of factors. A better measure of the ease of factor
substituti
defined as
K K
% %
L = L
% MRTS MPL
%
MPK
K
)(
d L
K
= L
MPL MPL
d ( )
MPK MPK
55
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
line through the origin representing the particular process. Thus, the factor intensity is the
capital-labor ratio. The higher the capital-labor ratio is the higher the capital intensity but
the lower the capital-labor ratio is the higher labor intensity of the process.
Capital
A
K1
B
K2 X
O
L1 L2 Labor
Fig 2.10 Process A uses k1 and L1 units of labor and capital to produce x amount of
output. The factor intensity of this process can be measured by the slope of OA, which
OK1 K1
equals AL1/OL1 =
OL1 L1
K2
Similarly, factor intensity of process B is given by
L2
K1 K2
Since , process A is more capital intensive than process B or B is more labor
L1 L2
intensive than A. The upper part of the isoquant includes more capital intensive processes
and the lower part, labor intensive techniques.
56
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
= b0.APL
2K
MPK = b 2b0 Lb1 K b 2 1
2L
X
= bo b0.APK
L
2. Marginal rate of technical substitution
X
b1
MPL L b1 K
(MRT SLK) = .
MPK X b2 L
b2
K
3. The elasticity of substitution
k l
d
l k
MPl MPk
d
MPk MPl
k
d( ) k /l
= l 1
b1k
d( ) b1K / b2l
b2l
4. Factor intensity is measured by the ratio b1/b2. The higher the ratio, the more labor
b1
intensive the technique. Similarly, the lower the ratio the more capital intensive the
b2
technique
5. The efficiency of production. This is measured by the coefficient b0. Obviously it is
clear that if two firms have the same K, L, b1 and b2 and still produce different quantities
of output, the difference could be due to the superior organization and entrepreneurship
of one of the firms, which results in different efficiencies. The more efficient firm will
have a larger b0 than the less efficient one.
2.8 The efficient region of production: long run
In principle the marginal product of a factor may assume any value, positive, zero or
negative. However, the basic production theory concentrates only on the efficient part of
the production function, i.e. over the range of out put over which the marginal product of
57
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
factors are positive and declining. In the short run production function efficient region of
MPL
production prevails in stage two (stage II), where MPL >O, but < 0.
L
Similarly, efficient region of production in the long run prevails when the marginal
product of all variable inputs is positive but decreasing. Graphically this can be
represented by the negatively slopped part of an isoquant. The locus of points of
isoquants where the marginal products of factors are zero form the ridge lines. The upper
ridge line implies that the MP of capital is zero. MPk is negative for all points above the
upper ridge line and positive for points below the ridge line. The lower ridge line implies
that the MPL is zero. For all points below the lower ridge line the MPL is negative and
positive for points above the line. Production techniques are technically efficient inside
the ridge lines symbolically; in the long run efficient production region can be illustrated
as:
MPL
MPL >0, but <0
L
MPk
MPk >0, but <0
K
Graphically, efficient region of production is shown as follow:
Capital
Upper ridge line
q3
q2
q1
Labor
Fig 2.11: Thus efficient region of production is defined by the range of isoquants over
which they are convex to the origin.
The long run law of production: The law of returns to scale
58
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
The laws of production describe the technically possible ways of increasing the level of
production.
Output may increase in various ways. In the long run output can be increased by
changing all factors of production. This long run analysis of production is called Law of
returns to scale.
In the short run output may be increased by using more of the variable factor, while
capital (and possibly other factors as well) are kept constant. The expansion of output
with one factor (at least) constant is described by the law of variable proportion or the
law of (eventually) diminishing returns of the variable factor.
59
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
q=L K4 4
60
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
c
3k
b
2k
3X
a 2X
k
X
O L
1L 2L 3L
c
3k
b 3X
2k 2.5X
a 2X
k
X 1.7x
O
L 2 3L
L
Fig 2.14 Constant returns to scale: oa< ab < bc
Increasing returns to scale
61
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
The distance between consecutive multiple isoquants decrease, by doubling the inputs,
output is more than doubled.
K
3.75X
3K1
c
B c
2K1
b
3X
a
K1 2.5X
2X
X
L
O
L1 2L1 3L1
Returns to scale are usually assumed to be the same every where on the production
surface i.e., the same along all the expansion product lines. All processes are assumed to
show the same returns to scale over all ranges of output. Either constant returns to scale
every where, or decreasing returns every where, or increasing returns everywhere.
However, the technological conditions of production may be such that returns to scale
may vary over different ranges of output. Over some range we may have constant returns
to scale, while over another range we may have increasing or decreasing returns to scale.
62
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
K 3.75
XX
3K1 b
7X
c
2K1 c 6X
5X
a 4X
K1 3X
2X
X
L
O
L1 2L1 3L1
Fig 2.16 Up to point C, increasing returns to scale prevails in the firm, from C to B
constant returns to scale prevails, and beyond B decreasing returns to scale prevails.
Graphically, this can be shown by upward movement of the total product curve
(indicating higher output level can be achieved from the same input) and down ward
63
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
TP2 TP after
technological
advancement
Isoquant before
TP before technological
technological advancement
K1
advancement
TP1
K2 Isoquant after
technological
advancement
64
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
3. The prices of inputs are given (constant).Price of a unit of labor is w and that of
capital is r .
Now before we go to the discussion of optimal input combination (or economically
efficient combination), we need to know the isocost line, because optimal input is defined
by the tangency of the Isoquant and iso-cost line.
Isocost line
Do you remember what the budget line denotes?
Isocost lines have most of the same properties as that of budget lines, an isocost line is
the locus points denoting all combination of factors that a firm can purchase with a given
monetary outlay, given prices of factors.
Suppose the firm has C amount of cost out lay (budget) and prices of labor and capital
are w and r
C rK wL , where K and L are quantities of capital and labor
respectively.
Given the cost outlay C , the maximum amounts of capital and labor that the firm can
C C
purchase are equal to and respectively. The straight line that connects these points
r w
is the iso-cost line. See the following figure:
Capital
C/r
Iso cost
line
C/w Labor
65
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Fig: 2.18 the iso cost line: shows different combinations of labor and capital that the firm
can buy given the cost out lay and prices of the inputs.
nation. However,
the problem of determining optimal input combination (economic efficiency) takes two
forms. Some times, situations may happen when a firm has a constant cost outlay and
seek to maximize its out put, given this constant and cost out lay and prices of in puts.
Still, there are also situations when the goal of the firm is to produce a predetermined
(given) level of output with the least possible cost. Under we will discuss the two
situations separately.
Case1: Maximization of output subject to cost constraint
Suppose a firm having a fixed cost out lay (money budget) which is shown by its iso-cost
line. Here, the firm is in equilibrium when it produces the maximum possible out put,
given the cost outlay and prices of input. The equilibrium point (economically efficient
-cost line (showing
the budget constraint) with the highest possible isoquant. At this point, the slope of the
w MPL
iso cost line ( ) is equal to the slope of the isoquant ( ).
r MPK
The condition of equilibrium under this case is, thus:
This is the first order (necessary) condition. The second order (sufficient) condition is
that isoquant must be convex to the origin. See the following figure:
Capital
Q3
K1 E
Q2
Q1
L1 B Labor
Fig: 2.19 the optimal combination of inputs ( L1 and K1 ) is defined by the tangency of the
iso-cost line (AB) and the highest possible isoquant ( X 2 ), at point E. At this point the
66
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
w MPL
slope of iso-cost line ( ) is equal to the slope of isoquant X 2 ( ).The second order
r MPK
condition is also satisfied by the convexity of the isoquant.
, do you think that the point of tangency of the iso-cost line and the isoquant represents
equilibrium point when the isoquant is concave?
If isoquant is concave to the origin the point of tangency of the iso cost line and the
isoquant does not define the equilibrium combination of factor inputs. With a concave
isoquant, we have a corner solution. Refer the figure below:
Isoquant: x=100kg
Fig: 2.20 Concave isoquant results in corner solution. The point of tangency between the
isoquant and the iso-cost line does not satisfy the second order condition as the isoquant
is concave. The same level of output(X=100Kg) can be produced with a lower cost out
lay at point A.
Mathematical derivation of the equilibrium condition
The problem can be stated as:
67
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Then we find , , and and set all of them equal to zero to solve for
L K
L and K .
That is,
X ( wL rK C)
X MPL
And, wL 0 MPL w
L L w
X MPK
r 0 MPK r
K K r
wL rK w 0 wL rK C
Solving these equations simultaneously, we obtain the equilibrium condition
MPL MPK w MPL
or
w r r MPK
The second order condition (the convexity of isoquant) would be insured when:
2 2 2 2 2 2
X X X X X
2
0 , 2
0 and 2 2
L K L K L K
Numerical Example
Suppose the production function of a firm is given as X 0.5 L1 / 2 K 1 / 2 prices of labor and
capital are given as $ 5 and $ 10 respectively, and the firm has a constant cost out lay of $
Solution
MPL MPK MPL w
The condition of equilibrium is or
w r MPK r
X
MPL 0.25L 1 / 2 K 1 / 2
L
X
MPK 0.25L1 / 2 K 1 / 2
K
Thus, the equilibrium exists when,
0.25L 1 / 2 K 1 / 2 $5
1/ 2 1/ 2
0.25L K $10
K 1
L 2 K .......... .......... .......... .....(1)
L 2
The constraint equation is:
wL rK C
5 L 10K 600.......... .......... .......... ........( 2)
68
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Solving equation (1) and (2) would give us the optimal combination of L and K.
L 2K
5L 10K 600
L=60 units and K=30 units.
Thus, the firm should use 60 units of labor and 30 units of capital to maximize its
production (out put). (Check the second order condition).
The maximum out put can be found by substituting 60 and 30 for L and K in the
production process.
In this case, consider an entrepreneur (a firm) who wants to produce a given output (for
example a bridge or a building or x tones of a commodity) with minimum cost outlay.
That is, we have a single isoquant which denotes the desired level of output, but there are
a set of isocost lines which denotes the different cost outlays. Higher isocost lines denote
higher production costs. The production costs of a desired level of output will therefore
be minimized when the isoquant line is tangent to the lowest possible isocost line (see
fig) At the point of tangency, the slope of the isoquant and isocost lines are identical.
w MPL
That is
r MPK
Capital
c
a
E
K1 Q
b d f
L1
Labor
69
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
Fig: 2.21 the equilibrium combination of factors is K1 and L1 amounts of capital and
attainable given the desired level of output. So point E shows the least cost combination
of labor and capital to produce X amount of output.
Now let us see the mathematical derivation of the equilibrium condition. As mentioned
earlier, we minimize the cost of producing a given level of output.
Thus, the problem can be stated as:
Minimize C = f (q) = WL + rK ---------------------------------------- (Objective function)
Subject to q = f (L, K) ------------------------------------------------ (Constraint function)
Or f (L, K) q=0
We use the LaGrange an method to obtain the equilibrium condition. Accordingly, the
LaGrange an function will be:
C ( f ( L, K ) q )
WL rK ( f ( L, K ) q )
f ( L, K ) q 0
w r
Thus, the equilibrium condition is
MPL MPK
MPL w
Rearranging the above condition, we obtain
MPK r
70
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
MPL W
This condition is only a necessary condition .
MPK r
The sufficient condition is that the isoquant must be convex to the origin. That is
2 2 2 2 2 2
q q q q X
0, 0and
L2 k2 L2 k2 L K
Numerical example:
Suppose a certain contractor wants to maximize from building one bridge. The
contractor uses both labor and capital, and efficient combinations of Labor and capital
1 1
that are sufficient to make a bridge is by the function 0.25 L 2 K 2 . If the prices of labor
(w) and capital (r) are $ 5 and $ 10 respectively.
Find the least cost combination of L and K, and the minimum cost.
Solution:
The contractor wants to build one bridge. Thus, the constraint equation can be written as
1 1
0.25 L k =1
2 2
1 1
MPL = 0.125 L K 2 2
1 1
MPK = 0.125 L K 2 2
MPL W
The equilibrium condition is
MPK r
1 1
0.125L K 2 2
$5
1 1
$10
0.125L K 2 2
K 1
L 2K
L 2
Substituting L = 2K in the constraint equation we obtain
1 1
0.125 (2K) 2
K =1 2
0.125 2 . K=1
1 8
K= K
0.125 2 2
71
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
16
L = 2K
2
16 8
Therefore, efficient combination (least cost combination) of L and K are and
2 2
respectively.
16 8 160
The least cost is C = 5 + 10 =$
2 2 2
Cost minimization with varying out put levels and the derivation of long run total
cost curve
, in the previous chapter we saw how a cost minimizing firm selects a combination of
inputs to produce a given level of out put. Now we extend this analysis to see how the
Expansion
K path
40 80
70
B
3.5 60
A
3 50
30
2
20
10 L
O
3 5 6
Fig 2.22
In the above figure, the firm is assumed to have increasing returns to scale up to point A
(the distance between successive multiple levels of out put decreases), constant returns to
scale between points A and B (the distance between successive multiple levels of out puts
72
Micro Economics for Management (Econ2021)
is constant) and decreasing returns to scale beyond point B (the distance between
successive multiple levels of out put increases).
s and its
isoquants is called expansion path. The expansion path denotes least cost combination of
labor and capital required to produce different levels of out put.
To produce 10 units of out put, the firm uses 2K and 3L, to produce 20 units, the firm
uses 3K and 5L, to produce 30 units it uses 3.5K and 6L, and so on. Hence, as out put
expands at a constant amount, the units of labor and capital increases at a decreasing rate
up to point A. That is, total cost of production increases at a decreasing rate up to point
A. From point A to B, combination of labor and capital increase at a constant rate as out
put increases at a constant rate. Hence, the long run total cost increases at a constant rate
up to point B.
Beyond point B, to expand out put at a constant rate, combination of labor and capital
should be increased at an increasing rate. Assuming that the prices of inputs are constant,
the long run total cost of production increases rapidly (at increasing rate) beyond point B.
From the above discussion, we infer that the long run total cost curve assumes an inverse
S-shape.
Summary
In economics, production means the act of creating those goods or services that have
exchange values. The process of production requires inputs such as land, labor, capital
and entrepreneurial ability, Fixed inputs are those inputs whose quantity can not readily
be changed when market conditions indicate that an immediate change in out put is
required, Variable inputs are those inputs whose quantity can be changed almost
instantaneously in response to derived changes in output.
A production function describes the maximum out put that a firm can produce for each
specified combinations of inputs. In the short run, one or more inputs to the production
process are fixed. In the long run, all inputs are potentially variable.
In the short run the firm is said to be efficient when it operates over the range of
employment of the variable inputs where marginal product of the variable input is
positive but declining.
73