0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views5 pages

04 Problem Set Solutions

Uploaded by

dailushi39
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views5 pages

04 Problem Set Solutions

Uploaded by

dailushi39
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 5

Mathematics for Economics ECON10005

SOLUTIONS
4 Problem set – Single-variable optimisation

1 Stationary Points
Please associate the following keywords to the various points listed below: stationary point,
inflection point, local maximum, global maximum, local minimum, global minimum.

a. x = 0 for the function f (x) = x5 , stationary and inflection point,


b. y = 2nπ + π/2, where n is an integer, for the function f (x) = sin(y), stationary and
local/global maxima,
c. z = (1, 2) for the function f (z1 , z2 ) = (z1 −1)2 +(z2 −2)2 , stationary and local/global
minimum.

2 Monopoly pricing
A firm producing violins is a monopoly in Ireland. The unit production cost is c > 0.
Demand for violins is characterized by the following function:

p(q) = − ln(αq)/β,

which can be interpreted as follows: in order to produce q > 0 violins, the monopoly
would need to set the unit price at p = p(q). (α, β) are positive parameters characterising
demand.
a. Write the profit of the firm, as a function of a given produced quantity q > 0.
The profit can be written as follows:

π = ( p(q) − |{z}
c ) q = (p(q) − c)q
|{z} |{z}
unit price unit cost quantity

b. Rewrite the profit of the firm, as a function of the selling price p > 0.
In order to do so, we need to invert the demand function, i.e., write the quantity as
a function of the price, rather than the opposite:

p = − ln(αq)/β

e−βp = αq
e−βp
q=
α
The profit of the firm is then:
e−βp e−βp
π=( p − |{z}
c ) = (p − c)
|{z} α α
unit price unit cost | {z }
quantity

1
c. The firm is maximising its profits; write the corresponding optimisation program.
The firm maximises:
e−βp
 
max π(p) = (p − c)
p α

d. Find the stationary point.


We look for the stationary point of the function π(p):

e−βp e−βp
π ′ (p) = − (p − c)β =0
α α
1 − (p − c)β = 0
p = c + 1/β

e. Find the profit maximising price. Comment on your result.


To check whether the stationary point is a maximum, we can analyse the sign of
π ′ (p):

π ′ (p) > 0
1 − (p − c)β > 0
e−βp e−βp
− (p − c)β >0
α α
p < c + 1/β
We can conclude that π ′ (p) is positive below the stationary point and negative above,
so p∗ = c + 1/β is the profit maximising price.

[Note that π ′′ (p) is not negative everywhere, so profit is not concave. So we cannot
use this to verify that the stationary point is a maximum.]

Comment: The firm sets up a mark-up 1/β over the unit cost of production c. The
smaller β, the less responsive consumers are to changes in prices, and the higher the
mark-up chosen by the firm.
f. Assume that the government subsidizes violins, i.e., the price faced by consumers is
p − τ where p is the price offered by the firm and τ > 0 is a given subsidy. Solve for
the new optimal price: does it increase, decrease?
The firm maximises: n o
max π(p) = (p − c)e−β(p−τ ) /α
p
We look for the stationary point of the function π(p):
π ′ (p) = e−β(p−τ ) /α − (p − c)βe−β(p−τ ) /α = 0
1 − (p − c)β = 0
p = c + 1/β
The firm does not change its price, compared to the situation without subsidy. It
will however sell more violins and make a higher overall profit.

2
3 Maximising tax revenue
The British government decides to impose a tax t per French flag sold to UK consumers.
As a consequence, when the consumer pays the price P , the supplier receives P − t. The
supply and demand for French flags are thus respectively given by:

P − t = Q + 8 and P = −3Q + 80

a. Write down the market equilibrium condition and solve for the equilibrium quantity
and the equilibrium price.
The market equilibrium is characterised by:

Q + 8 + t = −3Q + 80 ⇒ Q = 18 − t/4 and P = 26 + 3/4t

b. Find the expression for the total tax revenue as a function of the tax rate t.
The total tax revenue is:

T R(t) = t × Q = t(18 − t/4)

c. Find the revenue-maximising tax rate.


We just need to maximise the following program:

max {T R(t) = t(18 − t/4)}


t

′′
It is easy to show that T R (t) = −1/2: the function is concave. As a consequence, we
can apply a theorem seen during the lectures: if we find one stationary point, it will be
the maximum.
The stationary point verifies,

T R (t∗ ) = 18 − t∗ /2 = 0

and thus t∗ = 36 is the maximum.

3
4 Lesotho and Laffer
The Lesotho government would like to raise tax revenues in order to finance a large in-
dustrialisation program. Letting t denote the flat tax rate, we assume that the tax base,
Y (t), decreases with t.

a. Write the expression for tax revenues, R(t).

R(t) = t · Y (t)

b. Under which condition are these tax revenues concave in t?


R is concave if R′′ (t) ≤ 0. We take the derivatives:

R′ (t) = Y (t) + t · Y ′ (t)


R′′ (t) = Y ′ (t) + Y ′ (t) + t · Y ′′ (t) = 2Y ′ (t) + t · Y ′′ (t)

So R is concave if 2Y ′ (t) + t · Y ′′ (t) ≤ 0.


c. Under the previous condition, which relationship should be verified by the optimal finite
tax rate, if it exists?

The government maximises


max t · Y (t)
t
If R is concave, the optimal finite tax rate t∗ would be a stationary point and verify the
first-order condition:
R′ (t∗ ) = 0 ⇒ Y (t∗ ) + t · Y ′ (t∗ ) = 0
Bonus Info:
• The FOC can be re-written as:
t · Y ′ (t∗ )
−1 = = εY
Y (t∗ )
This is the elasticity of the tax base w.r.t. t
• The graph of R(t) is called the Laffer curve:

R(t)

t t

4
5 Income and substitution
Consider a worker paid at a given hourly wage w > 0; the labour income is her only
income, and she consumes her whole income. The worker gets (strictly) concave utility
u(c) from consumption c and (strictly) convex disutility v(l) from working l hours. (I.e.,
We assume: u′ (c) > 0, u′′ (c) < 0, v ′ (l) > 0, v ′′ (l) > 0.)

a. Write the worker’s maximisation program.

The worker wishes to maximise u(c) − v(l) where c = w × l by choosing l:

max u(w · l) − v(l)


l

b. Find the optimal hours worked, l∗ , for a given wage rate w.


At the optimum the worker should be indifferent between slightly increasing or decreas-
ing hours:

∂u(w · l) ∂v(l)
=
∂l ∂l
⇒ w · u′ (w · l∗ ) = v ′ (l∗ ) (1)


c. Find dl
dw and interpret the different effects affecting its sign. [Hint: You need to use
implicit differentiation.]
Equation 1 implicitly relates l∗ to w. I.e. we can now understand l∗ as a function of w:

w · u′ (w · l∗ (w)) = v ′ (l∗ (w)) (2)

We differentiate both sides of equation 1 w.r.t w


(using both product rule and chain rule):
 
′ ∗ ′′ ∗ ∗ dl dl
u (w · l ) + w · u (w · l ) · l + w = v ′′ (l∗ )
dw dw

We re-arrange:
dl u′ (wl∗ ) − wl∗ (−u′′ (wl∗ ))
= ′′ ∗
dw v (l ) + w2 (−u′′ (wl∗ ))
Remember we assume: u′ (c) > 0, u′′ (c) < 0, v ′ (l) > 0, v ′′ (l) > 0, so dw
dl
could be
positive or negative, depending on the sign of the numerator u (wl ) − wl (−u′′ (wl∗ ))
′ ∗ ∗

So, the effect of the hourly wage is ambiguous:

• Substitution u′ (wl∗ ): as w increases, the opportunity cost of not working in-


creases. I want to substitute leisure with work. (positive effect)
• Income −wl∗ (−u′′ (wl∗ )): as w increases, I become richer with the same number
of hours worked. With decreasing returns to consumption, I want to work less.
(negative effect)

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy