04 Problem Set Solutions
04 Problem Set Solutions
SOLUTIONS
4 Problem set – Single-variable optimisation
1 Stationary Points
Please associate the following keywords to the various points listed below: stationary point,
inflection point, local maximum, global maximum, local minimum, global minimum.
2 Monopoly pricing
A firm producing violins is a monopoly in Ireland. The unit production cost is c > 0.
Demand for violins is characterized by the following function:
p(q) = − ln(αq)/β,
which can be interpreted as follows: in order to produce q > 0 violins, the monopoly
would need to set the unit price at p = p(q). (α, β) are positive parameters characterising
demand.
a. Write the profit of the firm, as a function of a given produced quantity q > 0.
The profit can be written as follows:
π = ( p(q) − |{z}
c ) q = (p(q) − c)q
|{z} |{z}
unit price unit cost quantity
b. Rewrite the profit of the firm, as a function of the selling price p > 0.
In order to do so, we need to invert the demand function, i.e., write the quantity as
a function of the price, rather than the opposite:
p = − ln(αq)/β
e−βp = αq
e−βp
q=
α
The profit of the firm is then:
e−βp e−βp
π=( p − |{z}
c ) = (p − c)
|{z} α α
unit price unit cost | {z }
quantity
1
c. The firm is maximising its profits; write the corresponding optimisation program.
The firm maximises:
e−βp
max π(p) = (p − c)
p α
e−βp e−βp
π ′ (p) = − (p − c)β =0
α α
1 − (p − c)β = 0
p = c + 1/β
π ′ (p) > 0
1 − (p − c)β > 0
e−βp e−βp
− (p − c)β >0
α α
p < c + 1/β
We can conclude that π ′ (p) is positive below the stationary point and negative above,
so p∗ = c + 1/β is the profit maximising price.
[Note that π ′′ (p) is not negative everywhere, so profit is not concave. So we cannot
use this to verify that the stationary point is a maximum.]
Comment: The firm sets up a mark-up 1/β over the unit cost of production c. The
smaller β, the less responsive consumers are to changes in prices, and the higher the
mark-up chosen by the firm.
f. Assume that the government subsidizes violins, i.e., the price faced by consumers is
p − τ where p is the price offered by the firm and τ > 0 is a given subsidy. Solve for
the new optimal price: does it increase, decrease?
The firm maximises: n o
max π(p) = (p − c)e−β(p−τ ) /α
p
We look for the stationary point of the function π(p):
π ′ (p) = e−β(p−τ ) /α − (p − c)βe−β(p−τ ) /α = 0
1 − (p − c)β = 0
p = c + 1/β
The firm does not change its price, compared to the situation without subsidy. It
will however sell more violins and make a higher overall profit.
2
3 Maximising tax revenue
The British government decides to impose a tax t per French flag sold to UK consumers.
As a consequence, when the consumer pays the price P , the supplier receives P − t. The
supply and demand for French flags are thus respectively given by:
P − t = Q + 8 and P = −3Q + 80
a. Write down the market equilibrium condition and solve for the equilibrium quantity
and the equilibrium price.
The market equilibrium is characterised by:
b. Find the expression for the total tax revenue as a function of the tax rate t.
The total tax revenue is:
′′
It is easy to show that T R (t) = −1/2: the function is concave. As a consequence, we
can apply a theorem seen during the lectures: if we find one stationary point, it will be
the maximum.
The stationary point verifies,
′
T R (t∗ ) = 18 − t∗ /2 = 0
3
4 Lesotho and Laffer
The Lesotho government would like to raise tax revenues in order to finance a large in-
dustrialisation program. Letting t denote the flat tax rate, we assume that the tax base,
Y (t), decreases with t.
R(t) = t · Y (t)
R(t)
t t
4
5 Income and substitution
Consider a worker paid at a given hourly wage w > 0; the labour income is her only
income, and she consumes her whole income. The worker gets (strictly) concave utility
u(c) from consumption c and (strictly) convex disutility v(l) from working l hours. (I.e.,
We assume: u′ (c) > 0, u′′ (c) < 0, v ′ (l) > 0, v ′′ (l) > 0.)
∂u(w · l) ∂v(l)
=
∂l ∂l
⇒ w · u′ (w · l∗ ) = v ′ (l∗ ) (1)
∗
c. Find dl
dw and interpret the different effects affecting its sign. [Hint: You need to use
implicit differentiation.]
Equation 1 implicitly relates l∗ to w. I.e. we can now understand l∗ as a function of w:
We re-arrange:
dl u′ (wl∗ ) − wl∗ (−u′′ (wl∗ ))
= ′′ ∗
dw v (l ) + w2 (−u′′ (wl∗ ))
Remember we assume: u′ (c) > 0, u′′ (c) < 0, v ′ (l) > 0, v ′′ (l) > 0, so dw
dl
could be
positive or negative, depending on the sign of the numerator u (wl ) − wl (−u′′ (wl∗ ))
′ ∗ ∗