Mathematics Lecture Slides 1
Mathematics Lecture Slides 1
x = y , if xi = yi , i = 1, . . . , n.
x ≥ y , if xi ≥ yi , i = 1, . . . , n.
x > y , if x ≥ y and x ̸= y .
x ≫ y , if xi > yi , i = 1, . . . , n.
Rn+ = {x ∈ Rn | x ≥ 0}
Rn++ = {x ∈ Rn | x ≫ 0}
Given x, y ∈ Rn , the Euclidean inner product of the vectors x and y , denoted x · y ,
is defined as:
n
X
x ·y = xi yi
i=1
The inner product has the following properties for any vectors x, y , z ∈ Rn and
scalars a, b ∈ R :
1. Symmetry: x · y = y · x.
2. Bilinearity: (ax + by ) · z = ax · z + by · z and
x · (ay + bz) = x · ay + x · bz.
3. Positivity: x · x ≥ 0, with equality holding if and only if x = 0.
Mathematical and Statistical Methods
Metric Spaces
|x · y | ≤ (x · x)1/2 (y · y )1/2 .
The Euclidean norm (henceforth, simply the norm) of a vector x ∈ Rn , denoted
∥x∥, is defined as
n
!1/2
X
∥x∥ = xi2
i=1
∥x∥ = (x · x)1/2
for all x ∈ Rn ; in particular, the Cauchy-Schwartz inequality may be written as
|x · y | ≤ ∥x∥∥y ∥.
d(x, y ) = ∥x − y ∥
n
for all x, y ∈ R .
The metric d satisfies the following properties at all x, y , z ∈ Rn :
1. Positivity: d(x, y ) ≥ 0 with equality if and only if x = y .
2. Symmetry: d(x, y ) = d(y , x).
3. Triangle Inequality: d(x, z) ≤ d(x, y ) + d(y , z) for all x, y , z ∈ Rn .
A is called a closed set if it contains all its limit points. Notice a set need not
include it’s limit points. (0, 1) - here 0 and 1 are limit points (verify) but they are
not in the set.. So (0, 1) is not closed..
All points of a set need not be limit points(0, 1) ∪ {2} − 2 is in the set but not a
limit point..
[0, 1] ∪ {2} - closed or not?
Limit point vs boundary point..
Boundary Point: A point x is called the boundary point of the set S if every Bϵ (x)
contains some point from S and S c .
{1, 2, 3, 4, . . .},
1 1
1, 2 , 3 , . . . ,
1
1, 2 , 4, 81 , 16, . . . ,
1 − n1
xn → x & yn → y ⇒ xn + yn → x + y .
xn → x & yn → y ⇒ xn yn → xy
xn ≤ b ∀n and xn → x, then x ≤ b
xn ≥ b ∀n and xn → x, then x ≥ b
(notice the weak inequality here.)
L {(x1 , x2 , · · · , xn ) ∈ Rn : f (x1 , x2 , · · · , xn ) = c}
for some given number c ∈ R.
Better/Superior/Upper Contour set..
Worse/Inferior/Lower Contour set..
Indifference curves, isoquants..
x > y =⇒ f (x) ≥ f (y )
x < y =⇒ f (x) ≤ f (y )
Generally when we mention monotonic function in econ, we refer to positively
monotonic function.
g (u) : x → g [u(x)]
is a monotonic transformation of u.
∂u
∂x1
MRS = ∂u
∂x2
Elasticity of a function-
% change in f (x)
% change in x
Quasiconvex Function
A function f with domain X ⊆ Rn is quasiconvex if, for every point in X , the
worse/inferior set W of that point is a convex set. It is strictly quasiconvex if W is
strictly convex.
A function f : Rn → R is quasiconvex if, for all x, x ′ ∈ Rn and all λ ∈ [0, 1],
f (x) = x α , α > 0
f (x, y ) = xy
f (x, y ) = x + y
f (x, y ) = min x, y
f (x, y ) = x 2 + y − 10
f (x, y ) = (x − 10)(x − 25)
y = 0 for x = 0, y = 1 for x = 1
∂x ∂x
Similarly, in the case of firm’s behaviour, we interested in ∂p and ∂w .
. here x in input demand, p is output price, and w is input price.
Before proceeding with the derivative, we need to make sure that the
function is well-delined in the relevant neighborhood.. cont. and
differentiable.
Example: x 2 + y 2 = 1
x > 1, y =?
Consider the function g (x, y ) = k.
Suppose this function is well-defined at (x0 , y0 ).
g (x0 , y0 ) = k
g (x, y (x)) = k
differentiating it w.r.t x at x0 , we have
∂g dx ∂g dy
(x0 , y (x0 )) + (x0 , y (x0 )) (x0 ) = 0
∂x dx ∂y dx
or,
∂g
dy ∂x (x0 , y (x0 ))
(x0 ) = − ∂g
dx
∂y (x0 , y (x0 ))
dy
The notation y ′ (x0 ) is also used for dx (x0 ).
Implicit Function Theorem: Let G (x, y ) be a C ′ function on a ball
about (x0 , y0 ) in R2 . Suppose that G (x0 , y0 ) = c and consider the
expression
G (x, y ) = c.
If (∂G /∂y ) (x0 , y0 ) ̸= 0, then there exists a C 1 function y = y (x)
defined on an interval I about the point x0 such that:
(a) G (x, y (x)) = c for all x in I ,
(b) y (x0 ) = y6 , and
∂G
(x ,y )
(c) y ′ (x0 ) = − ∂G
∂x 0 0
(x ,y )
.
∂y 0 0
G (x1∗ , . . . , xk∗ , y ∗ ) = c
∂G ∗
and that (x , . . . , xk∗ , y ∗ ) ̸= 0
∂y 1
Then, there is a C ′ function y = y (x1 , . . . , xn ) defined on an open
ball B about (x1∗ , . . . , xk∗ ) so that:
(a) G (x1 , . . . , xk , y (x1 , . . . , xk )) = c for all (x1 , . . . , xk ) ∈ B,
(b) y ∗ = y (x1∗ , . . . , xk∗ ), and
(c) for each index i,
∂G ∗ ∗ ∗
∂y ∗ ∂xi (x1 , . . . , xk , y )
(x1 , . . . , xk∗ ) = − ∂G ∗ ∗ ∗
∂xi ∂y (x1 , . . . , xk , y )
f −1 (V ) = {x ∈ S | f (x) ∈ V }.
In particular, if S is an open set in Rn , f is continuous on S if and
only if f −1 (V ) is an open set in Rn for each open set V in Rl .
2 ′′
D f (x) is denoted as f (x) whenever n = 1 (i.e., if S ⊂ R )
∂2f ∂2f
(x) = (x)
∂xi ∂xj ∂xj ∂xi
for all i, j = 1, . . . , n, and for all x ∈ D.
An n × n symmetric matrix A is
negative definite if and only if (−1)k |Ak | > 0 for all k ∈ {1, . . . , n}.
positive definite if and only if |Ak | > 0 for all k ∈ {1, . . . , n}.
A symmetric n × n matrix A is
positive semidefinite if and only if |Aπk | ≥ 0 for all k ∈ {1, . . . , n} and
for all π ∈ Π.
negative semidefinite if and only if (−1)k |Aπk | ≥ 0 for all
k ∈ {1, . . . , n} and for all π ∈ Π.