Getting Interventions Right South Korea Taiwan
Getting Interventions Right South Korea Taiwan
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
, , and Oxford University Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to Economic Policy
Get
how South Korea and Taiwan
grew rich
Dani Rodrik
Columbia University
1. INTRODUCTION
To any economist interested in growth, the East Asian experience since the earl
1960s poses enduring challenges. In 1960, South Korea was poorer than man
sub-Saharan African countries, and Taiwan not all that much richer (Table 1).
Since then, these two countries have experienced average increases in per-capit
income of 6.8% and 6.2% respectively, with the result that they have left far
behind not only these African countries, but also others like Mexico and Argenti
which had been much richer. How these two countries managed to transform
themselves from economic basket cases into economic powerhouses remain
something of an enigma.
The standard story to which most orthodox economists subscribe is one
export-led growth (see, for example, Tsiang, 1984; Kreuger, 1985; World Bank
1993; Little, 1994). During the 1950s, the story goes, both of these countri
engaged in traditional import substitution policies, with multiple exchange rate
high levels of trade protection, and repressed financial markets. By the late 1950
each country had exhausted the 'easy stage' of import substitution. This, togeth
with the impending reduction in US aid - which had been the main source
I am grateful toJagdish Bhagwati, Paul de Grauwe, Ann Harrison, Arvind Panagariya, Andr6s Rodriguez-Clar
Robert Wade, Adrian Wood, Alwyn Young, Panel members and especially Gene Grossman and Charles Wyplos
for helpful comments, Eytsung Kim for excellent research assistance, and the CEPR MIRAGE project f
financial assistance.
Dani Rodrik
Economic Policy April 1995 Printed in Great Brita
? CEPR, CES, MSH, 1995.
Table 1. Co
foreign exchange for both economies - led policy-makers in the two countries to
alter their economic strategy and adopt export-oriented policies. These policies
included the unification of exchange rates accompanied by devaluations, various
other measures to stimulate exports (including most significantly duty-free access
for exporters to imported inputs), higher interest rates, and some liberalization of
the import regime. As a consequence of these measures, as well as a broadly
supportive policy environment (encompassing macroeconomic stability and public
investment in infrastructure and in human capital), exports took off in the mid-
1960s. Export orientation led both economies to specialize according to
comparative advantage, resulting in rising incomes, investment, savings and
productivity.
This orthodox account has been criticized for downplaying the active role of
governments in Taiwan and South Korea in shaping the allocation of resources.
Observers like Amsden (1989) and Wade (1990) have argued that the reforms of
the 1960s went considerably beyond giving markets and comparative advantage
free rein. According to these authors, governments in both countries had clear
industrial priorities and they did not hesitate to intervene (through subsidies, trade
restrictions, administrative guidance, public enterprises or credit allocation) to
reshape comparative advantage in the desired direction. Interestingly, however,
the orthodox and revisionist accounts converge on the importance of the export-
oriented strategy in having disciplined firms and enhanced productivity growth.
The World Bank's detailed recent study, The East Asian Miracle (1993), has
attempted to incorporate some of the revisionist objections (particularly on the role
of directed credit) into the standard account.
I will argue in this paper that the standard story, as sketched above, is
incomplete and quite misleading on the importance it attaches to the role of export
orientation in the growth performance. It also has backward the causal
relat
othe
mid-
initi
increase in this ratio.
A much more plausible explanation for the economic take-off is the sharp
increase in investment demand that took place in the early 1960s. The reason for
this investment boom is the key issue addressed in this paper. I will argue that in
the early 1960s and thereafter the Korean and Taiwanese governments managed
to engineer a significant increase in the private return to capital. They did so not
only by removing a number of impediments to investment and establishing a
sound investment climate, but more importantly by alleviating a coordination
failure which had blocked economic take-off. The latter required a range of
strategic interventions - including investment subsidies, administrative guidance
and the use of public enterprise - which went considerably beyond those discussed
in the standard account. That government intervention could play such a
productive role was conditioned in turn by a set of advantageous initial conditions:
namely, a favourable human capital endowment and relatively equal distribution
of income and wealth.
I will elaborate on these arguments below. It is useful to set the stage first by
reviewing some of the key elements of the Taiwanese and Korean miracles (section
2). Next, I discuss the shortcomings of the export-based explanations of these
miracles (section 3). I then turn to some of the distinctive initial conditions -
relative abundance of human capital and equitable income and wealth distribution
- which appear to have played a role in both countries' economic performance
(section 4). Section 5 lays out the paper's central arguments on coordination failure
and the governments' role in removing it. Section 6 discusses the investment-
stimulating policies followed by the two governments in light of the preceding
analytical framework. Section 7 asks how it became possible for detailed
interventions to be carried out efficiently and with little rent seeking. In section
8, I discuss a number of objections to the arguments. Section 9 closes the paper by
offering some concluding remarks. The formal model providing the foundation for
the central argument is presented in the appendix.
We begin by reviewing some of the key facts about the two countries' econ
performance over the last three decades. Figure 1 shows their spectacular g
performance since the early 1960s. We note that economic growth has fluc
widely around a high mean. Both economies were particularly hard hit by t
oil shocks of the 1970s, but in each case output recovered remarkably quick
[ Kore
-2 1 I I I I I i I I i I i I i I I I I I I I
1954 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90
Figure 2 is the chief exhibit for the export-led growth hypothesis. The
export-GDP ratio rose from virtually zero in Korea to more than 30% by the
early 1980s, and from around 10% in Taiwan to over 40%. In both countries, the
increase in export orientation was particularly rapid in the decade from the mid-
1960s to the mid-1970s, and has abated somewhat since then.
%30
0 i -T rI - I ,-- l t I l i I I I I I I I I I i t I i t I I I I I
1952 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90
I- Ko
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
0 I I I I t I I I I I t t I I I I I I
1951 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89
Less discussed but certainly more important is the spectacular increase in the
investment effort, shown in Figure 3. Investment rose from around 10% of GDP in
the late 1950s in both countries to 30% in 1980. Since 1980, investment has
continued its upward trend in Korea, but has declined somewhat in Taiwan. This
investment effort has been matched by a roughly equivalent increase in savings.
* Non-agricultural economy.
Source: Young (1994). Latin American
Consequ
(Taiwan)
Finally,
Taiwanes
countrie
careful c
Taiwan, a
TFP figu
countries
a 'meta-p
finding:
essentiall
that onc
taken int
inescapab
is capital
As pointed out in the introduction, the standard account gives priority to the r
of export orientation in explaining the economic performance summarized in
previous section. A particularly clear statement comes from Ian Little (1994):
the outstanding success of Korea and Taiwan from the early 1960s to the m
1970s was based on a phenomenal growth of labour-intensive manufacture
This branch of manufacturing took off because exports were highly profita
once the bias against manufacturing for export was removed. The hi
profitability also depended on a relatively well-educated hard working doc
labour force which was, apart from the natural rate of increase, fed by a lar
movement out of agriculture ... High profits and increased earnings f
recruits to the industrial labour force led to a very rapid rise in savings. The
was thus a virtuous circle.
Upon a closer look, however, this account is not quite convincing for a number of
reasons discussed below.
1 The World Bank (1993) study mentioned above reports high TFP growth in these countries, but its analysis has
been seriously challenged by Young (personal communication) and Little (1994).
2 This statement does not contradict the fact that both countries have managed to increase greatly the
sophistication of the manufactured goods they produce, from toys and apparel to consumer electronics and
semiconductors. What it suggests is that this transformation has been fully paid for by investments in physical and
human capital.
3.1. The sw
significan
Countries
almost alw
profitabili
Taiwan is h
export tak
already be
boom got u
exports di
rise, often
following
3.1.1. Kor
preoccupie
particular
1980). Th
programm
retain a s
consumpti
free-mark
incentives w
materials
exporters
of the curr
rate.
Later, after President Park took over in a military coup on 16 May 1961, the
scope of export subsidization was greatly enlarged. The subsidy on export credits
was increased and exporters were exempted from the commodity tax and the
business activity tax. The income tax on export earnings was reduced. There were
also direct cash grants on exports, but these were phased out by 1965 (Frank et al.,
1975). However, the incentive effects of the devaluations and the cash grants were
eroded by expansionary macroeconomic policies that led to rising inflation in
1962-3 and a renewed gap between official and parallel exchange rates in 1963. A
large devaluation in May 1964 served once again to unify the currency. After
1965, export subsidy programmes were expanded further. In that year, the
existing practice of giving priority to exporters in acquiring import licences was
formalized and expanded. Exporters were allowed automatic access to duty-free
imports of raw materials and intermediate inputs up to a limit. This limit was
determined administratively, on the basis of firms' and industries' input-output
coefficients plus a margin of 'wastage allowance' (Frank et al., 1975). Since the
imports acquired under the wastage allowance could be sold in the domestic
market, th
credit to ex
that the w
average, a
virtually un
varied from
There is n
exporting c
However, i
around 195
is largely d
link system
official and
export inc
widening sc
1960 only p
This can b
Korean exp
monetary
import link
like), and w
relative to
index is th
captured to
prices of ex
We note th
1964-5 was
actually be
from 1964
until the
export-GDP
relative pr
policies we
guise (see,
policies in
3 At first sight
would act as an
dollar earnings t
the system.
4 The subsidy equivalent of the export incentives are taken from Kim (1988). This, and the earlier Frank et al.
(1975) study on which these estimates are based, are the most authoritative and widely cited sources on the
quantitative aspects of Korea's trade regime.
30 120
Relativ
25- - 100
20 80 .
n a ct, 0
15- -60 8
Q.
w
10 - - -40
Exports/GDP - -4
5 - -20
0 n n , , , , , , , , , n, , ,I o
55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75
3.1.2. Taiwan. In Taiwan most of the export incentives were put in place in the mid-
to late-1950s, even earlier than in Korea, and the currency was unified during
1958-61. By 1954-5, the system of import duty and commodity tax rebates for
exportable production had already been implemented. In 1956, manufacturers
were allowed to retain up to 80% of the foreign exchange they earned from
exports and use it for their own import needs. (This ratio was raised to 100% of
export earnings for most items after the exchange rate reform of 1958.) In 1957, a
relatively generous export credit programme was started. Finally, the multiple
exchange rate system was unified during 1958-61 in several stages: (1) in April
1958, the multiple buying rates were consolidated into two buying rates, in parallel
with two selling rates; (2) in November 1958, exports and imports under the lower
rate were brought up to the higher rate; and (3) further minor devaluations and
simplifications were undertaken during the following two years (Hong, 1993; Lin,
5 It is true that, in the presence of sunk costs associated with exporting, uncertainty in the pre-1964 period may
have prevented entrepreneurs from switching existing production from the home market to world markets.
However, the export boom that took place was not a matter of switching production: it entailed the establishment
of new capacity specifically oriented towards foreign markets. With greater stability in relative incentives, the first-
order effect should have been to enhance the profitability of investing in new capacity for both foreign and home
markets.
6 In discussing the same issue, Frank et al. (1975) draw what is in my judgement the correct conclusion: 'it is
plausible to hypothesize that South Korean exports were constrained more by the capacity to produce goods than
by the relative profitability of producing for export instead of domestic markets'. To extend this to its logical
conclusion, we must therefore search for explanations for why it became profitable to invest and expand
productive capacity.
50 130
45^ -120
\\ 40J- -110
L 35 - Real exchange rate -0
40 -100 1
. 30- 0
-90 o
g 25- c
x -80
W 20 - Exports/GDP _
15 - - 70 t0
a:
10 --60
5- -50
0 I I I I1 1 I I 40
1960 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80
payme
could n
Could
incenti
evidenc
The ex
compa
Turkey
have b
than an
latter i
more t
Of cou
export
and Tai
place in
import
export
3.2. Ex
It is no
an inve
either
boom.
of expo
180 25
160 - - 23
140 -e
60 - -1
40 - rPrivate investment/GDP -9
20 - J -7
0 ; I I I I I I I I 5
1979 81 83 85 87 89
180 18
100- 0
(D1
0 I i I I I I Ii 0O
1980 82 84 86 88 90
3.3. The
Since th
of expor
least. Ex
10% in T
for only
small b
decompo
domesti
coefficie
have acc
reports
domesti
was mor
Such dem
unsatisf
relates e
with ma
an incre
caused b
increase
any sign
Korea an
the mod
increase
A usefu
(CGE) m
treat the
that the
agricult
the econ
export-o
Korean g
outward
(1992). T
small p
measure
3.4. Prod
It is not
cumulat
argumen
came no
technolo
perform
East Asi
outward
CGE mo
Asian d
The tro
were as
provide
themsel
Rodrik,
of produ
correla
industr
nothing
such fin
product
this sco
been sp
growth
develop
periods
[includ
suspicio
technolo
Moreov
made in
1993; Pa
from w
countri
around
income.
strong
3.5. The
As men
hypothe
experie
causal r
Box 1
The in
by po
deman
capita
U1, w
respec
terms
expan
econo
panel.
move
impor
trade
The f
impor
relativ
in do
increa
increa
relativ
for th
reduc
mark
rate d
7 The g
intertem
non-trad
price of
profitab
by th
Box 1.
c: c..
t
0 0
0.
E E
Exportables Exportab
Figure 8. Consequences of an in
40
35
Imports
30
25
a. / /\^y< Investment
O 20
0 15 15 /
0 I I I I I I t I I I I I I I I I t I l I I
1960 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88
45
40
Imports /
35
30
(I 25
'5 Investment
20
, 20 _ //
15 0 _'
0 I i I I I I I I I I I I f I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I
1952 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90
14
12
I'\M
10 /
? / . /
8 /F\ !
/ \ *."' /1 \
6 /
? / // ^, \
16
14
\ Machinery and transp. equip. \
12 \ \
/
'...,
,
."--' \'
8 * Agric. products \
6 Chemicals .
4
2; '\Basic
.--' ,metals
--\ ,,,
clear t
and tr
mainly
ratio.
with i
and fr
3.6. T
In bot
to pro
consti
develo
export
having
demo
1993).
Government policy was helpful as well. Real interest rates were raised for
depositors to levels that were either positive or only mildly negative (Taiwan in the
1950s and Korea in the 1960s). In addition, an increase in public savings made an
important contribution to total savings in both countries. In Taiwan, the increase
in the savings rate in the early 1960s coincided with a sharp increase in
government saving after 1961 (Kuo, 1983). This was enabled in turn by a
reduction in government consumption. And in Korea, 'it was the rapidly
increasing contribution of government savings and the steady inflow of foreign
savings which enabled Korea to achieve the very high rate of investment during
the 1962-73 period' (Hong, 1976).
3.7. Recapitulation
The proposition that Korea's and Taiwan's economic performance can be
ascribed to export orientation faces serious difficulties. The switch towards export-
oriented policies cannot account for the sustained export boom since the mid-
1960s, and even less for the equally impressive and sustained investment boom.
Export growth itself can explain only a limited part of the early growth in output.
The increasing share of exports in GDP is quite consistent with a story of
8 According to Box 1, the openness of the economy must necessarily decline once the investment ratio stabilizes.
However, there are a number of confounding features in the Korean and Taiwanese experiences. Foremost
among these is the large-scale import liberalization that has taken place in both countries during the 1980s.
9 As Robert Wade has reminded me, the argument about investment-led exports is not new. However, I have had
difficulty locating sources in the published literature which place priority on investment demand and at the same
time explain the rising export-GDP ratio. Bradford (1990), for example, seems to suggest a causal role for
investment, but it is unclear as to why the investment was allocated disproportionately in export-oriented sectors.
investm
search f
private
argues
conside
rather s
While South Korea and Taiwan were both quite poor around 1960, their s
indicators placed them among the ranks of countries at several times their inc
levels. Table 3 shows Adelman and Morris's (1967) index of socioeconom
development for a range of countries, as measured around the late 1950s and e
1960s. This index is derived from factor analysis and is based on a large numb
indicators meant to capture characteristics of social structure and soc
organization. (The indicators include the extent of dualism, urbanizati
importance of an indigenous middle class, social mobility, literacy, m
communications, cultural and ethnic homogeneity, fertility, national integrat
and sense of national unity, and modernization of outlook.) Adelman and Mo
place Taiwan and Korea in their most advanced group, even though their per
capita incomes are considerably below average.
If we focus specifically on indicators of educational attainment, we see the s
discrepancy with the level of per-capita income. Table 4 displays data on thr
educational indicators which are commonly employed as explanatory variable
cross-country growth regressions. The table shows the actual school enrolment
literacy rates in Korea and Taiwan in 1960, as well as the corresponding rates
would have been expected on the basis of these countries' per-capita income le
alone. The latter are derived from cross-section regressions of educatio
indicators on per-capita income and its square. We find that both countries
year around 1960. Korea and Taiwan are the two countries closest to the origin:
that is, with the lowest overall inequality.
These initial conditions can account, in a statistical sense, for a large part of the
two countries' economic performance since 1960. Table 5 shows the results of
regressing growth and investment rates on initial primary enrolment and
0.70
0.65
*
0.60
0 .
E Az MMg
8 ,t ,
0.50
0.50 Finlnd *
0.45 .
* 9
*_
C 0.40
.5
0.35
0 Korea Taiwan ?
0.30 *^^~~~ **
0.25
0.20
C ).3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Table 5. G
excl
the
Kor
noth
Arg
grow
they
cond
10 Another possibly important initial condition, emphasized by Adrian Wood in personal correspondence, is the
lack of a good natural resource base in Korea and Taiwan. This is in part related to the high educational
attainment ratios relative to income: as Wood points out, countries with the same level of education per worker
but more land would have had a higher GNP per capita and lie closer to the regression line. But in addition, the
meagre natural resources gave these countries a clear comparative advantage in manufactures, allowing them to
enjoy both rapid industrialization and rapid trade expansion.
Fifth
(with
had
insul
thes
critic
Sixth
neit
appr
adeq
Seve
payi
incre
than
5.2.
Ther
econ
a coo
the m
pres
reaso
exist
pres
are.
Imag
trad
secto
relie
inpu
well-
they
mod
(in p
Such
mod
were
labou
to sp
scale
prof
in th
moder
the pr
dema
produ
Coord
with b
sector
econom
capita
the fi
Taiwan
capita
Marke
econom
activit
about
resour
about)
pecun
policie
(1984
Matsu
Rodri
One p
presen
frame
prereq
of non
sector
endow
and T
activit
Upon
tradab
count
throu
moder
are fo
workm
these
tradab
(as wh
comple
are ne
techn
techn
bluepr
The ta
distan
all - o
world)
advert
Only
channe
in tran
such
impro
aspect
interac
produc
Some e
to life.
Hyundai used its cement plant as a laboratory to train its managers with
background in construction, before assigning them to other manufacturing
affiliates. Trainees gained experience in inventory management, quality and
process control, capacity planning, and so on, thus spreading basic production
skills throughout the Hyundai organization. After Hyundai Cement, the next
manufacturing affiliate in the group was founded in 1967 and named Hyundai
Motors. Twenty years later it became the first independent automaker from a
late-industrializing country to export globally. The first president of Hyundai
Motors was a former president of Hyundai Cement.
Hyu
imp
com
foun
ship
only
that
cons
capa
but
Mor
wou
Only
(int
depe
The
an i
and
ship
by
capt
The
in th
My
no c
jars,
run
box
pro
into
com
the
insu
rela
in A
The
well
thus
so b
In b
man
and Sako
to capita
1962-6,
manufac
1957-62,
became m
rates rose
the not
industrie
post-196
sector m
enterpri
how Lin
The dom
produce
increase
chemical
glutama
well as f
In other
linkages
We note
the econ
failure. A
governm
bringing
enterpri
(1986):
" Little (1994) calculates that the annualized return to investment in Korea was 31.1% during the period
1963-73. However, his calculations also show a reduction in the rate of return subsequently, to 18.3% during
1974-9. He attributes the decline to the HCI drive.
Indeed, T
For furt
chemical
steel pro
developm
income e
should b
specializa
economy
Hence, w
with the ideas discussed here.
Under the conditions discussed in the previous section, there exists a large role fo
government intervention. Such intervention can take many different forms. Mos
directly, policy-makers can coordinate private-sector production and investment
decisions through their control over credit allocation, the tax regime and trade
policy, as well as through 'administrative guidance'. Government policies t
subsidize investment in the modern sectors of the economy have a large payof
because they get the private sector to internalize the coordination externalities
The same outcome can also be obtained through investments by public enterprise
themselves. The Korean and Taiwanese governments used a combination of thes
interventions, thereby raising the private return to capital in the modern sectors to
the level of the social return.
During much of the 1950s, economic goals did not rank particularly high with
the Taiwanese leadership. The government was preoccupied instead with the
reconquest of the mainland. By the end of the decade, it became clear that the
communist regime was firmly entrenched: '[Taiwan's] party elders came to see
that economic development could be a better guarantee of the party's survival'
(Wade, 1990). Thereafter, the government turned its energies to eliminating many
investment-deterring distortions (such as multiple exchange rates and macro-
economic
Program
investmen
juncture
towards
nineteen-
climate be
the libera
an officia
new plant
The story
military c
his prede
attention
economic
to econom
These pr
matters, a
and Sakon
who unde
while othe
of the na
Wealth A
regime. T
commitm
businessm
episode se
productiv
In Korea, the chief form of investment subsidy was the extension of credit to lar
business groups at negative real interest rates. Korean banks were nationali
after the military coup of 1961, providing the government with exclusive co
over the allocation of investible funds in the economy. 'Allocation of under-p
credit [became] by far the most important single instrument of governme
microeconomic control' Jones and Sakong, 1980). Korean firms were hi
dependent on external credit, as borrowing made up two-thirds of their cash
during 1963-74. According toJones and Sakong, 'the general bank [lending]
has typically been half of the curb-market rate; and second, the real bank ra
often been negative and generally below even the most conservative estimate
the opportunity cost of capital'.
With ban
was need
role in th
on the bas
activities
technolog
be award
favoured
in Taiwan
growth o
1971, the
to 72% (T
chaebol as
industria
Another
through t
most nota
would b
circumsta
governme
neurs, an
groups, i
governm
industry
of Presid
eventually
the firm'
and suppl
discussed
could activ
Year Percentage
1955 0.4
1956 0.7
1957 0.8
1958 1.5
1959 3.4
1960 5.6
1961 9.8
1962 8.5
1963 12.4
1964 12.4
1965 13.1
1966 14.9
1967 18.0
1968 17.2
regulation forcing Ko
implicit investment
consequence of the fin
undertaken in the sec
chemical industries).
In Taiwan, investmen
generally positive and
enterprises did get c
socialize investment ri
the form of tax incent
in 1960 in conjunction
represented a 'sweepin
for investment. The
reduced to 18% of ann
holiday for new invest
was given to undistrib
earnings, and to proce
exempt from stamp ta
import duties on pla
instalments after star
1965, at which time t
listed in the investmen
electrical machinery
chemical fertilizers, p
exempt
is take
The qu
observ
relevan
associat
tally, t
around the same time.
financing a
production
Private firms
Finally, the
electronics in
Organization
it to local fir
and entered a
later moved to
commerciali
It is interest
industries to
concepts', su
extensions -
Wade mention
1980s was to
electronics a
highlights ga
linkages may
resonate with
In Korea, as
internalize so
had to nurtu
was not hesit
coordination
The state m
fertilizers, o
profitability
alive some un
that eventua
shipbuilding i
light to heav
iron and ste
heavy machi
The case of s
the governm
products wer
with the res
shipbuilding
Daewoo] foun
arm t
Koje i
says M
out of
is now
6.4. U
Public
privat
They
produ
establ
select
cemen
many
indust
countr
as dir
Not o
outpu
the cr
data o
accoun
countries as India and Tanzania.
Jones an
enterpris
set of pr
summariz
[were] ch
output-m
substitut
with a hi
The case
not entir
down by
World Ba
steel. Th
governm
subsidies
generati
supporte
POSCO ev
most eff
mills wi
stimulate
to spare
from 44 to 75%.
To any economist with experience in the developing world, what is striking about
the policies discussed in the previous section is their similarity to those commonly
employed in many other, considerably less successful economies. Why have these
interventions, along with many others not specifically discussed (such as
quantitative trade barriers or local content requirements), been successful in
Taiwan and Korea and not elsewhere? One part of the answer to this question has
already been given: the imbalance between a well-educated labour force and a low
endowment of physical capital meant that the return to coordinated investments -
and therefore government policy aimed at coaxing these investments - was quite
high.
This is an important part of the story, but not the entire story. While the initial
human capital advantage may have been a necessary condition for intervention to
work, it was not sufficient. On top, what was required was a competent, honest and
efficient bureaucracy to administer the interventions, and a clear-sighted political
leadership that consistently placed high priority on economic performance. In
Korea and Taiwan, unlike in so many other developing countries, these additional
requir
of rel
additi
the ot
How e
thing
landed
occup
refor
insula
growt
centra
and ag
institu
pressu
could
organ
Secon
imme
the p
inequa
(Alesi
pursui
which
leader
Third
focus
This i
having
gener
is inc
burea
sticki
restri
politi
burea
Park,
his ec
mome
Hence
played
is pro
intervention c
seeking.
12 However, the analytical basis for this argument has, to my knowledge, never been properly laid out. If ful
an export target is the price to be paid for hefty subsidies, many firms will willingly pay the price. There is
inherently efficient or desirable about the resulting exports.
why did
which o
that th
policy b
range o
8.2. Doe
enough
Investm
other S
from e
system
allocatio
where
govern
with th
Overloo
and gro
empiric
14. Con
accumu
experien
0.40 -
0.35 -
0.30- * .
.0.25 ** * * * **
? 0 *," *K*?* eKorea
E Taiwan
?/* . *. * * ?
0.15 -
0.10 t
* ^ * * * *
0.05 -
I0 i 0 I o 1
-0.04 -0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08
Growth
overall corre
(like South K
8.3. Isn't the evidence on coordination failures too weak in view of failed
government interventions elsewhere?
As already noted, the case for coordination failures is based on circumstan
rather than direct, evidence. This is not the kind of evidence that will move any
with strongly held priors on the inefficiency of government interven
Traditional arguments against it abound. The 'big push' ideas of the 1950s
led nowhere. How is it possible for governments to 'pick the winners'? And
about the example of free-market, yet successful, Hong Kong?
Without disagreeing on the need for more evidence, I would point o
number of things. First, I have tried to be explicit about the conditions u
which a coordination failure is most likely to exist, and have not treated
generic issue, as in much of the early (and current) literature. There is no
implausible about the presence of these conditions in the South Korea and T
of the 1960s. Second, I have tried to bring a considerable amount of case s
evidence to bear on these issues. In fact, so voluminous is the case study lite
on government interventions (and their apparent success) in these countrie
one may as well regard the main problem as being one of finding an adeq
theory on which to hang this evidence, rather than locating the evide
support a particular theory. The framework I have proposed here helps us
sense of the findings of this case study literature, something that is hard to do
the conventional approach.13
This approach also clarifies why 'picking winners' was not so difficult in
early years of the Korean and Taiwanese experience. Policy-makers in
countries only had to look at Japan and more advanced countries to see th
future. Of course, once the catch-up is nearly complete, it becomes more dif
to play the same game.
Finally, Hong Kong's experience is not as telling as it may seem at first gl
and not only because Hong Kong is a small city state, with significant geogr
and historical advantages in foreign trade. Hong Kong was already a h
investment country by 1960: its investment ratio stood above 20% (of GD
1960, almost double the figure for Korea and Taiwan at the time. Consequ
Hong Kong never faced the challenge of raising investment. And the abse
government policy in this regard reveals itself in an investment ratio tha
remained virtually flat since 1960. Therefore, one might as well read the
13 A clear example is the need to square the Korean and Taiwanese governments' emphasis on inter-
linkages with the complete neglect of such linkages in standard welfare economics.
Kong evid
governme
8.4. Doesn
an even si
Recent th
physical
growth is
capital ho
market fa
not need
countries.
Table 10
translate
roughly
indicator
Paraguay
Korea and
has much
Table 10. C
Per- Prim
capita ratio
growth,
1960-89 Predicted Actual Predicted Actual Predicted Actual
Dominican
Republic 2.48 0.64 0.98 0.13 0.07 0.39 0.65
Philippines 1.58 0.62 0.95 0.12 0.26 0.36 0.72
Paraguay 2.72 0.65 0.98 0.14 0.11 0.40 0.75
Sri Lanka 1.83* 0.65 0.95 0.14 0.27 0.39 0.75
*1960-85.
Source: Same as Table 4.
9. CONCLUDING REMARKS
14 With thanks to Gene Grossman, for laying out these different positions. I am borrowing his wording he
overcame it n
it either; (3)
which woul
experience o
because the
throughout th
countries to m
economists t
foreseeable f
policies made
I have argued
best be under
they were d
investments w
had a high pa
where the lat
educated wo
distribution
and allowed i
policies (and c
they enable
orientation a
This approach
miserably w
resemblance
Taiwan share
attainment r
these other c
government
Discussion
Gene Grossman
Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University
It is always a pleasure to read one of Dani Rodrik's papers. They are clear, well
organized and well argued. And they are always provocative.
This paper is no exception. Dani challenges the view that trade policy 'explains'
the success of South Korea and Taiwan. In fact, he takes the orthodoxy head on,
and tries to demolish it entirely. Export orientation could not deserve pride of
place in these stories, he argues, because: the timing of the export booms was not
right t
large
orient
surely
growt
activit
empiri
Having
to rep
conditi
relativ
a coor
modern
more f
arise,
conditi
policy
discuss
the ey
shows
success
I find
could
change
movem
improv
large b
Barro
a relat
specif
regres
second
of regr
of per
and fe
ratio; t
spendi
of (on
numbe
possibl
growt
marke
Table 11.
Korea Taiwan
The table shows that, with the possible exception of Taiwan in the period from
1975 to 1985, the short list of regressors 'explains' most of these two countries'
growth experience; perhaps there is no 'miracle' here. Moreover, the biggest
contribution to growth comes from the 'net convergence effect', i.e. the fact that
these countries had low initial per-capita GDP levels, but high initial levels of
human capital per worker (and thus, by implication, low initial physical capital to
worker ratios). The relatively modest levels of government consumption also
seemed to play a role. Apparently, the elimination of price distortions, to the
extent that this is captured in the change in the black market premium, is not a big
part of the story.
The argument that there existed coordination failures that inhibited investment
in the moder manufacturing sectors in Korea and Taiwan until the government
intervened to overcome them is intriguing, but requires further elaboration and
empirical investigation. I am not sure how one would definitively establish the
existence of a coordination failure, let alone the potential for one in a
counterfactual world where government policy was different. I am naturally
15 The Barro and Lee paper does not report the decomposition for individual countries. The table here is based
on calculations performed by Robert Barro, to whom I am grateful.
inclin
trade
such
mark
have
extern
Dani
could
Sala-i
where
phys
equili
growt
huma
fact t
Dani
predi
the P
somew
that,
by th
count
the 'im
I wou
(1994)
econo
high
capit
differ
more
super
be sm
In th
gover
My ow
I susp
that s
this v
start
that w
in pla
chang
targeted
coordina
were nec
know th
surely be
Victor Norman
Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration
There are two main arguments in this paper. One is that the success of South
Korea and Taiwan had little to do with export orientation. The other is that
government intervention, to overcome a coordination failure, had a lot to do with
their success. The arguments are linked, but it is useful to consider the two
separately.
In the Adam Smith view then, market size is a prerequisite for growth. It is not
the cause of growth, however. Access to large markets is of no help unless the
internal conditions, such as the quality of the labour force, market infrastructure,
savings, etc., are right. The point is simply that internal conditions are not
sufficient, unless the market is large enough. That may explain why exports and
growth are strongly correlated for small countries, while countries such as
Germany and the USA could combine industrialization with protection.
Rodrik suggests an entirely different explanation for the correlation between
exports and growth - that growth generated import demand, which in turn
generated exports. That cannot be correct. As shown in Rodrik's Figures 4 and 11
(for Korea) and 5 and 12 (for Taiwan), the export boom preceded the import
boom. For Korea, for example, the ratio of exports to GDP trebled from the early
to the mid-1960s - from a level of around 2% to 6% in 1965, and roughly 7% in
1966-7. Imports of capital goods, on the other hand, did not take off until the
second half of the decade. They amounted to between 2 and 4% of GDP from
1960 to 1966, then rose to around 7% in 1967 and more than 9% in 1968. It takes
exceptional belief in the foresight of policy-makers if this is to be seen as consistent
with the view that 'thanks to appropriate macroeconomic and exchange rate
policies, export supply was adequate to meet the increase in import demand, and
rose alongside imports'.
'high f
concent
exports
instruct
also cur
governm
intensiv
The oth
cosmet
insuran
me. The
inputs f
equally
for exam
A centra
was pos
from pr
a lot of
business
the con
depend
regulat
military
public s
The asse
remains
General discussion
Several Panel members wondered under exactly which conditions the results
claimed by Rodrik would obtain. Thus there were discussions about whether it was
a story about two sectors (one backward, one moder) or about capital
accumulation. The role of human capital was often explicitly mentioned.
In establishing a favourable climate for investment, George Alogoskoufis
pointed out, the political regime is important. It is essential to have a regime that
guarantees that there will not be expropriation. David Begg made a similar point
regarding the role of the exchange regime, including restrictions to capital
movements, and the risk of partial expropriation through devaluation and inflation
as well as limits to where to hold incomes from profit. Mathias Dewatripont
stressed the importance of the initial distribution of wealth, which is one of the
preconditions listed by Rodrik. Unequal distribution of wealth may create pressure
for re
the m
growt
exceptions.
Hans-Werner Sinn thought that the paper dismissed too quickly the
Hecksher-Ohlin theory. He observed that this theory is compatible with the
stylized facts used by Rodrik. If the economy starts from a situation where only the
labour-intensive commodity is produced, then allowing capital movements
immediately triggers capital inflows. These inflows have nothing to do with
government intervention; they simply reflect natural scarcities.
Assaf Razin raised another issue. He questioned the treatment of relative prices
of exports as exogenous. On the contrary, he expected that a push for exports
would lead to an exchange rate appreciation. Dani Rodrik responded that it is
possible to treat that relative price as exogenous as long as it is acceptable to treat
Korea as a small country with no market power. Inderjit Singh wondered about
the role of the size of military spending. He noted that a country with less military
expenses should perform better. He also thought that the paper should have
looked at the importance of the homogeneity of society. Much as with equality, a
homogeneous society is often characterized by less social conflict. Alessandra
Casella questioned measures used to evaluate equality. She further asked whether
the policy which had been carried out had increased inequality.
Xavier Vives drew a parallel with Japan. In this case, he felt that the
coordination of investment had indeed been important, as stressed by Rodrik. Yet,
in his view, the role of public subsidies has been mostly symbolic as their size has
been quite modest. He was seconded by Michel Keen, who asked Rodrik to
provide more information on the size of investment subsidies.
APPENDIX
The model discussed here is taken from Rodrik (1993), to which the reader is referr
further details (see also Rodriguez-Clare, 1993). We focus on a small, open econom
can produce two tradable final goods. Both of these goods are produced under con
returns to scale. The first of these is a labour-intensive good, requiring labour and c
which we associate with the 'traditional' sector. Its unit cost function is given by O
with w and r standing for the wage and rental rates prevailing in the economy. The
good, produced in the 'modem' sector, uses capital and a range of intermediate go
(producer services and specialized inputs) that are imperfect substitutes for each oth
use the Dixit-Stiglitz-Ethier specification for the way that these intermediates ent
production function of the modern good. In a symmetric equilibrium in wh
intermediate goods are available at price p, the unit cost function of the modern g
given by q(r,pn-1/(1-l), where a > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between any
the intermediate goods. Note that the productivity of the modern sector is linked
number of input varieties available: as n increases, unit costs in the moder sector d
As discusse
They are pr
production
the workfor
function of
the skill le
representat
economies
monopolisti
p = wA(h)c
- MC]/p =
intermedia
be written
marginal re
(z) = (Al)
This fixes the ou
alone. Hence, an
change in n. Le
and K and L fo
prices of the m
equations of th
intermediate
be competi
intermedia
intermediat
modern sect
produced.
But when h
economy s
uncompetiti
active. The
economy is i
enter the m
though a lar
profitable. T
sufficiently
intermediat
When there
at least as h
generally the
the equilibri
just explaine
returns; and
resources in
return to ca
REFERENCES
Adelman, I. and C. Taft Morris (1967). Socie!y, Politics and Economic Development: A Quantitative Approach,
Hopkins Press, Baltimore, MD.
Alesina, A. and D. Rodrik (1994). 'Distributive Politics and Economic Growth', Qzarterly Journal of Econ
Amsden, A. H. (1989). Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization, Oxford University Press, Ne
Barro, R.J. andJ.-W. Lee (1993). 'Losers and Winners in Economic Growth', NBER Working Paper
Bosworth, B., R. Dorbusch and R. Laban (1994). The Chilean Economy: Policy Lessons and Challenges, B
Institution, Washington, DC.
Bradford, C. I., Jr (1990). 'Policy Interventions and Markets: Development Strategy Typologies a
Options', in G. Gereffi and D.L. Wyman (eds.), Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin A
East Asia, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Ciccone, A. and K. Matsuyama (1993). 'Start-up Costs and Pecuniary Externalities as Barriers to
Development', NBER Working Paper No. 4363.
Collins, S. (1991). 'Saving Behavior in Ten Developing Countries', in B. D. Bernheim andJ.B. Shov
National Saving and Economic Performance, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
and W.-A. Park (1989). 'External Debt and Macroeconomic Performance in South Korea', inJ.
S. Collins (eds.), Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance, vol. 3, University of Chic
Chicago, IL.
de Melo,J. and S. Robinson (1992). 'Productivity and Externalities: Models of Export-Led Growth', International
Trade and Economic Development.
Elias, V. (1990). Sources of Growth: A Study of Seven Latin American Economies, ICS Press, San Francisco, CA.
Faini, R. (1984). 'Increasing Returns, Non-Traded Inputs, and Regional Development', Economic Journal.
Frank, C. R., Jr, K. S. Kim and L. Westphal (1975). Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: South Korea,
Columbia University Press, New York.
Haggard, S. (1990). Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries, Cornell
University Press, Ithaca, NY.
Hasan, P. (1976). Korea: Problems and Issues in a Rapidly Growing Economy, The Johns Hopkins University Press,
Baltimore, MD, and London.
Hong, W. (
(1977). 'Tr
(1993). 'Tr
Trade and
Hou, C.-M
Economie
8-10 June.
Jones, Leroy and 1n Sakong (1980). Government, Business, and Entrepreneurship in Economic Development: The Korean Case,
Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Kim, J.-I. and L.J. Lau (1992). 'The Source of Economic Growth of the Newly Industrialized Countries on the
Pacific Rim', unpublished manuscript, Stanford University, CA.
Kim, K. S. (1988). 'The Timing and Sequencing of Trade Liberalization Policy: The Case of Korea', unpublished
manuscript, World Bank.
Krueger, A. O. (1985). 'The Experience and Lessons of Asia's Super Exporters', in V. Corbo et al. (eds.), Export-
Oriented Development Strategies: The Success of Five Newly Industrializing Countries, Westview Press, Boulder, CO, and
London.
Krugman, P. (1991). 'History versus Expectations', Quartery journal of Economics.
Kuo, S. (1983). The Taiwan Economy in Transition, Westview Press, Boulder, CO.
Lin, C.-Y. (1973). Industrialization in Taiwan, 1946-72: Trade and Import-Substitution Policies for Developing Countries,
Praeger, New York.
Little, I. M. D. (1994). 'Trade and Industrialization Revisited', unpublished paper, Nuffield College, Oxford.
Mason, E. S., M. J. Kim, D. Perkins, K. S. Kim and D. Cole (1980). The Economic and Social Modernization of the
Republic of Korea, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Matsuyama, K. (1991). 'Increasing Returns, Industrialization and Indeterminacy of Equilibrium', Quarterly ournal
of Economics.
Mulligan, C. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1993). 'Transitional Dynamics in Two-Sector Models of Endogenous
Growth', Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Murphy, K., A. Shleifer and R. Vishny (1989). 'Industrialization and the Big Push', Journal of Political Economy.
Nagatsuka, S. (1994). 'Recent changes in the South Korean shipbuilding industry and its future prospects',
JAMRI Report No. 49, Japan Maritime Research Institute.
Pack, H. and L. E. Westphal (1986). 'Industrial Strategy and Technological Change: Theory versus Reality',
Journal of Development Economics.
Page,J. (1994). 'The East Asian Miracle: Four Lessons for Development Policy', in S. Fischer andJ. Rotemberg
(eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1994, Cambridge, MA.
Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (1994). 'Is Inequality Harmful to Growth?' American Economic Raiew.
Rodriguez-Clare, A. (1993). 'The Division of Labor and Economic Development', unpublished manuscript,
Stanford University, CA.
Rodrik, D. (1992). 'Closing the Technology Gap: Does Trade Liberalization Really Help?', in G.K. Helleiner
(ed.), Trade Policy, Industrialization and Development: New Perspectives, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
(1993). 'Coordination Failures and Government Policy in Intermediate Economies: A Model with
Applications to East Asia and Eastern Europe', unpublished manuscript, Columbia University, New York.
- (1994). 'King Kong Meets Godzilla: The World Bank and The East Asian Miracle', in A. Fishlow, C. Gwin, S.
Haggard, D. Rodrik and R. Wade, Miracle or Design? Lessonsfrom the East Asian Experience, Overseas Development
Council, Washington, DC.
- (1995). 'Trade Strategy, Exports, and Investment: Another Look at East Asia', Institute of Policy Reform
Discussion Paper, Washington, DC.
Rosenstein-Rodan, P. (1943). 'Problems of Industrialization of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe', Economic
Journal.
Scitovsky, T. (1954). 'Two Concepts of External Economies', Journal of Political Economy.
Short, R. (1983). 'The Role of Public Enterprises: An International Statistical Comparison', International
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Trela, I. andJ. Whalley (1992). 'The Role of Tax Policy in Korea's Economic Growth', in T. Ito and A. Krueger
(eds.), The Political Economy of Tax Reform, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, and London.
Tsiang, S.C. (1984). 'Taiwan's Economic Miracle: Lessons in Economic Development', in A.C. Harberger (ed.),
World Economic Growth, ICS Press, San Francisco, CA.
Ventura, J. (1994) 'Growth and Interdependence', mimeo., Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.
Wade, R. (1990). Governing the Market: Economic Theoy and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization, Princeton
University Press, Princeton, NJ.
World Bank (1993). The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy, Oxford University Press for the World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Young, A. (1993). 'Lessons from the East Asian NICs: A Contrarian View', NBER Working Paper No. 4482.
(1994). 'The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth
Experience', unpublished paper.