0% found this document useful (0 votes)
6 views

An Introduction To State and Local Public Finance

Uploaded by

ch
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
6 views

An Introduction To State and Local Public Finance

Uploaded by

ch
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 72

Web Book of Regional Science Regional Research Institute

2020

An Introduction to State and Local Public Finance


Thomas A. Garrett

John C. Leatherman

Follow this and additional works at: https://researchrepository.wvu.edu/rri-web-book

Recommended Citation
Garrett, T.A., & Leatherman J.C. (2000). An Introduction to State and Local Public Finance. Reprint. Edited
by Scott Loveridge and Randall Jackson. WVU Research Repository, 2020.
All Web Book material, including text and graphics, is available to users for personal use and may not be
redistributed in whole or in part, in print, online, or on electronic media (e.g., CD). Permission for reprinting
images and text from the Web Book of Regional Science must be obtained from the Regional Research
Institute to which all users must comply.

This Book is brought to you for free and open access by the Regional Research Institute at The Research
Repository @ WVU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Web Book of Regional Science by an authorized
administrator of The Research Repository @ WVU. For more information, please contact
researchrepository@mail.wvu.edu.
The Web Book of Regional Science
Sponsored by

An Introduction to State and Local


Public Finance
By
Thomas A. Garrett
John C. Leatherman
Published: 2000
Updated: October, 2020

Editors: Scott Loveridge Randall Jackson


Professor, Extension Specialist Director, Regional Research Institute
Michigan State University West Virginia University
<This page blank>
The Web Book of Regional Science is offered as a service to the regional research community in an effort
to make a wide range of reference and instructional materials freely available online. Approximately 30
books and monographs have been published as Web Books of Regional Science. These texts covering diverse
subjects such as regional networks, land use, migration, and regional specialization, include descriptions
of many of the basic concepts, analytical tools, and policy issues important to regional science. The
Web Book was launched in 1999 by Scott Loveridge with RRI directors serving as Web Book editors.
Scott Loveridge performed that role through 2000 and Randall Jackson served as editor from 2001 through 2022.

All Web Book material, including text and graphics, is available to users for personal use and may not be
redistributed in whole or in part, in print, online, or on electronic media (e.g., CD). Permission for reprinting
images and text from the Web Book of Regional Science must be obtained from the Regional Research
Institute to which all users must comply.

When citing this book, please include the following:

Garrett, T.A., & Leatherman, J.C. (2000). An Introduction to State and Local Public Finance. Reprint.
Edited by Scott Loveridge and Randall Jackson. WVU Research Repository, 2020.
<This page blank>

4
Contents
Overview 9

PART 1 - GOVERNMENT GROWTH, TAXES AND TAX THEORY 11

I. The Growth of State and Local Governments - Revenues and Expenditures 11


A. Evidence on the Growth of State and Local Governments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
B. Explaining the Growth of State and Local Governments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
C. The Changing Responsibilities of State Governments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
i. Education . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
ii. Highways . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
iii. Public Welfare . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
iv. Health Care . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
v. Corrections . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
vi. Other Expenditures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
D. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

II. Funding State and Local Government - State and Local Taxes 16
A. State and Local Government Revenue . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
i. State Government Revenue . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
ii. Local Government Revenue . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
B. The Sales Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
i. State Sales Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
ii. Local Sales Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
iii. Generating Sales Tax Revenues - Issues for State and Local Governments . . . . . . . 18
a. Taxing Electronic Commerce . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
b. Cross-Border Shopping . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
C. The Personal Income Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
i. The Marginal Tax Rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
ii. The Average Tax Rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
iii. Tax Incidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
a. Regressive, Progressive and Proportional Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
D. The Corporate Income Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
E. Excise Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
F. Property Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
i. Computing the Property Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
ii. Advantages and Disadvantages of the Property Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
G. Other Revenue Sources - Intergovernmental Revenues, User Fees and State Lotteries . . . . . 26
H. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

III. Principles of Tax Analysis 28


A. Distributional Effects of Taxation - Tax Incidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
i. Single-Market Analysis of Tax Incidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
a. A Unit Tax on Buyers and Sellers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
b. A General Rule of Tax Incidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
B. Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
i. Computing The Efficiency Loss From a Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
a. Efficiency Loss From A Unit Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
b. Efficiency Loss From an Ad Valorem Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
ii. The Efficiency/Equity Tradeoff . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
C. Two Models of Optimal Taxation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
i. The Ramsey Rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
ii. Tax Rates, Tax Bases and Tax Revenues - The Laffer Curve . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

5
a. Empirical Estimation of the Optimal Tax Rate Using the Laffer Curve . . . . . . . 38
D. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

PART 2 - SELECTED APPLICATIONS IN PUBLIC FINANCE 40

IV. Revenue Forecasting 40


A. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
B. The Forecasting Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
C. Forecasting Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
i. Qualitative Forecasting Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
a. Judgmental Forecasting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
ii. Quantitative Forecasting Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
a. Time Series Approaches . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
b. Descriptions of Time Series Forecasting Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
1. Naive Forecasting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
2. Moving Average Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
3. Exponential Smoothing Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
4. The Holt Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
5. Damped Trend Exponential Smoothing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
6. Holt-Winter’s Linear Seasonal Smoothing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
7. Box-Jenkins ARIMA Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
8. Causal Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
D. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

V. Cost-Benefit Analysis 48
A. Steps in Performing Cost-Benefit Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
i. Identifying Stakeholders to the Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
ii. Identify Alternative Policies to be Included . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
iii. Identify Likely Physical Impacts and Indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
iv. Predict the Impacts over the Life of the Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
v. Monetize All of the Impacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
vi. Find the Present Value of Dollar Amounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
vii. Add up the Costs and Benefits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
viii. Perform a Sensitivity Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
ix. Select the Preferred Alternative . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
B. Theoretical Foundations in Cost-Benefit Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
C. Net Present Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
D. Estimating Values . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
i. Social Surplus . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
ii. Estimating Values in Cost-Benefit Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
a. Values from Observed Behavior . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
1. Project Revenues as Benefits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
2. Estimating Demand Curves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
3. Market Analogy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
4. Intermediate Goods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
5. Asset Values . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
6. Hedonic Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
7. Travel Cost Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
8. Defensive Expenditures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
b. Contingent Valuation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
c. Shadow Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
E. Common Errors in Cost-Benefit Analyses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
i. Errors of Omission . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
ii. Forecasting Errors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55

6
iii. Measurement Errors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
iv. Valuation Errors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
v. Indirect Impacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
vi. Double-Counting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
vii. The Value of Labor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
F. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56

VI. Fiscal Impact Analysis 57


A. Planning Approaches . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
i. Projecting Population . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
ii. Projecting Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
iii. Projecting Revenues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58
iv. Considerations in the Use of Planning Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
B. Case Study Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
i. Summary of Procedures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
C. Econometric Approaches . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
i. Econometric Specification of Public Sector Supply and Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
ii. Conjoined Modeling Approaches . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
D. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62

VII. Chapter Conclusion 64

References 65

Glossary 68

7
<This page blank>

8
Overview
Public finance is the field of economics that studies government activities and the various means of financing
these activities. In general, public finance deals with any of the three levels of government: federal, state,
and local. While the basic theories of public finance apply regardless of the level of government studied, state
and local public finance has emerged as an important sub-field of public finance in recent years. An increased
emphasis on state and local public finance is due to several factors. First, the past forty years have seen
a dramatic rise in state and local government expenditures. State and local (city and county) government
expenditures topped $1.1 trillion in 1996, a 500 percent increase in real dollars since 1960. In 1996, state and
local government expenditures comprised over 16 percent of the Gross Domestic Product of the United States.
Second, there are nearly 87,000 separate state and local governments in the United States, each having its
own fiscal responsibilities and revenue sources. Unlike the federal government, changes in the taxing and
expenditure behavior of one state or local government has impacts on surrounding localities as residents are
mobile between state and local government jurisdictions. Third, the major services provided by state and
local governments - education, public welfare, health care, and highway construction and maintenance - are
those which most directly impact the daily lives of residents.
While the public sector is characterized by both revenues and the expenditure of these revenues on public
goods and services, the focus of this chapter is on the revenue, or financing, side of government. The chapter
is designed to provide the reader an understanding of the basic principles, theories and issues in state and
local public finance. The chapter consists of two major parts each consisting of three sections. The first
part includes three sections that provide an introduction to government growth, taxes, and tax theory, in
addition to several important issues facing state and local governments. Selected applications in public
finance are covered in sections four, five and six. While the chapter as a whole is written to provide a
continuum between topic areas, each section may be read independently without a loss of understanding.
The first two sections are written for the general reader and require only a minimal background in economics.
Section three requires a background in undergraduate microeconomics, and a portion of the third section also
requires a basic knowledge of differential calculus and econometric modeling. The fourth and sixth sections
contain mathematical formulas and econometric models, but these formulas and econometric models can be
skipped without loss of continuity. The fifth section is appropriate for the general reader and those having a
background in basic microeconomics. For a further analysis of each section presented in this chapter, the
reader is referred to several excellent texts on public finance. These include: State and Local Public Finance
by Ronald C. Fisher, Public Finance by Harvey Rosen, and Public Finance: A Contemporary Application of
Theory to Policy by David Hyman.
Section I provides numerical and graphical evidence on the growth of state and local governments in recent
years. Several explanations for the dramatic increase in the size of state and local governments are also
presented. The section then focuses on the major categories of state government expenditures and discusses
the major historical trends for each expenditure category. Although this section contains a substantial amount
of data for illustrative purposes, the reader should not focus on memorizing every bit of data, but rather
concentrate on acquiring an overall understanding of the changes in state and local government over the past
several decades.
Section II discusses the primary revenue sources for state and local governments. The section begins by
providing background on the changing revenue sources for state and local government revenues. The revenue
sources addressed include the sales tax, the property tax, the personal income tax, the corporate income tax
and excise taxes. Attention is also given to the incidence of a tax in terms of the income distribution and
revenue generation. States’ historical reliance on each tax as a source of revenue is discussed, along with
critical issues and ideas surrounding each tax. Important issues surrounding sales tax revenues, such as cross
border shopping and taxing electronic commerce, are also discussed within the section.
Section III provides an overview of tax theory. The distributional impacts of taxation and the effects of
taxation on the efficiency of markets are discussed. Both issues should be considered by public officials when
evaluating taxes in their state or community. A short background on efficiency is presented along with an
analysis of the impact taxes have on the efficiency of market operations. Graphical analyses and differential
calculus are used to derive expressions used to compute the efficiency costs of taxation. The section ends by

9
presenting two popular models of optimal taxation - the Ramsey Rule and the Laffer curve.
Section IV provides a general background on revenue forecasting for state and local governments. The
section begins by discussing the forecasting process. Further portions introduce the reader to the various
forecasting methods available, differentiating between qualitative forecasting methods and quantitative
forecasting methods. The benefits and drawbacks of each method are also discussed. Attention is given to
the Box-Jenkins ARIMA model and the causal forecasting model.
Section V presents an overview of cost-benefit analysis, paying specific attention to evaluating the costs and
benefits of public projects. The important concepts of present value, discount rates, and how to value costs
and benefits are also included. The section concludes by addressing several pitfalls common to cost-benefit
analysis.
Fiscal impact analysis is discussed in section VI. This sub-area of cost-benefit analysis is concerned with
only the tangible effects of a policy or event on public sector costs. Several different planning approaches are
presented, including methods for projecting public revenues and costs. Several econometric models often used
in fiscal impact analysis are also discussed.

10
PART 1 - GOVERNMENT GROWTH, TAXES AND TAX THE-
ORY
I. The Growth of State and Local Governments - Revenues and
Expenditures
A. Evidence on the Growth of State and Local Governments
Historically, state governments have produced higher education, welfare, public health and state-wide highway
maintenance and improvements, whereas local governments produced elementary and secondary education,
local infrastructure, parks, and police and fire protection. While the roles of both levels of government have
remained the same over time, the past forty years have seen a dramatic increase in state and local government
expenditures. Per capita state and local expenditures from 1960 to 1996, in real 1993 dollars, are shown in
Figure 1.

In 1960 state governments were spending roughly $740 per person while local governments spent about $670
per person. As seen in Figure 1, both state and local expenditures per capita have increased dramatically. Per
capita state expenditures topped $2,600 in 1996, nearly a 350 percent increase from 1960. Local expenditures
per capita increased 250 percent between 1960 and 1996, with 1996 local expenditures per capita reaching
$1,600.
The growth in state and local governments can also be shown by considering state and local government
expenditures and revenues as a percent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of the United States. Expenditures
and revenues as a percent of GDP highlights the growing role of state and local governments in producing a
higher percentage of the country’s total output. The measure also reveals the percentage of total income that
is used by state and local governments. State and local government revenues and expenditures as a percent
of GDP from 1960 to 1996 are provided in Table 1.
Local expenditures and revenues as a percent of GDP increased nearly 50 percent over the past forty years,
while state expenditures and revenues as a percent of GDP nearly doubled between 1960 and 1996. It is
interesting to compare this increase in state and local government expenditures with expenditures of the
federal government. Local, state, and federal government expenditures as a percent of GDP are shown in
Figure 2.

11
Table 1: State and Local Government Expenditures and Revenues - 1960 to 1996
As a Percent of Gross Domestic Product

Expenditures Revenues
Year State and State and
Local State Local Local State Local
1960 10.11 5.30 4.81 9.84 5.33 4.51
1965 10.63 5.76 4.87 10.53 5.82 4.71
1970 12.99 7.68 5.31 12.94 7.69 5.25
1971 13.73 8.12 5.61 13.21 7.76 5.45
1972 13.96 8.19 5.77 13.99 8.17 5.82
1973 13.44 8.01 5.43 14.09 8.38 5.71
1974 13.64 8.22 5.42 14.24 8.39 5.85
1975 14.55 8.72 5.83 14.39 8.49 5.90
1976 14.52 8.69 5.83 14.49 8.60 5.89
1977 13.89 8.33 5.56 14.44 8.57 5.87
1978 13.30 8.05 5.25 14.15 8.47 5.68
1979 13.16 8.06 5.10 13.79 8.36 5.43
1980 13.63 8.43 5.20 14.12 8.63 5.49
1981 13.44 8.37 5.07 13.97 8.52 5.45
1982 13.87 8.56 5.31 14.53 8.73 5.80
1983 13.71 8.37 5.34 14.30 8.53 5.77
1984 13.39 8.21 5.18 14.39 8.77 5.62
1985 13.71 8.55 5.16 14.81 9.05 5.76
1986 14.19 8.82 5.37 15.03 9.22 5.81
1987 14.47 8.90 5.57 15.13 9.23 5.90
1988 14.38 8.82 5.56 14.83 9.08 5.75
1989 14.54 8.95 5.59 14.99 9.21 5.78
1990 15.12 9.20 5.92 15.38 9.38 6.00
1991 15.99 9.77 6.22 15.89 9.72 6.17
1992 16.10 10.13 5.97 16.11 10.02 6.09
1993 16.18 10.14 6.04 16.31 10.25 6.06
1994 16.31 10.18 6.13 16.42 10.32 6.10
1995 16.39 10.28 6.11 16.51 10.38 6.13
1996 16.57 10.31 6.26 16.64 10.45 6.19
Source: Tax Foundation, Facts and Figures on Government Finance, various years, U.S. Census
Bureau, State Government Finances, various years, and (Holcombe and Sobel, 1997,8-9).
Figure 2: Expenditures By Level of Government
As a % of GDP

12
Historically, federal expenditures as a percent of GDP have been higher than both state and local governments
combined, but Figure 2 shows the gap between federal and state and local government expenditures has
decreased in recent years. In 1960, state and local government expenditures totaled about 10 percent of GDP,
whereas federal government expenditures reached 18 percent of GDP, nearly 80 percent greater than state
and local governments. As of 1996, however, state and local government expenditures reached 17 percent of
GDP, whereas federal government expenditures only increased to roughly 21 percent of GDP.

B. Explaining the Growth of State and Local Governments


There are several factors that explain the dramatic growth of state and local governments over the past four
decades. Individual income rose significantly during this period. With higher incomes, individuals demand
more goods and services, including those traditionally provided by state and local governments. An important
point, however, is that while incomes and government expenditures experienced an overall increase during
this period, the growth in state and local expenditures slowed and even decreased during the recessionary
periods of the mid 1970s and early 1980s and 1990s. Growth in income slowed during these periods, and as
a result state and local governments received relatively less revenues, thereby reducing expenditures. This
marked decrease in the growth of state and local government expenditures during recessionary periods can be
seen in Figure 1.
Another factor that explains the overall growth of state and local governments is that the population of
the United States increased during this period, in part due to the baby-boom occurring after World War
II. State and local expenditures rose during this period to meet the increasing demands for state and local
government services created by the growing population. Life expectancies also increased during this period.
As individuals continued to live longer, there was an increase in demand for government goods and services
such as health care and public welfare.
The initial increase in state expenditures during the 1960s was in part due to states’ rapid introduction of
new taxes during the 1950s, 1960s, and early part of the 1970s. New taxes led to an increase in revenues to
state governments and thus an increase in state government expenditures. Between 1951 and 1969, sixteen
states adopted sales taxes. Since 1969, no state has adopted a sales tax. Ten states adopted personal income
taxes between 1961 to 1976, and eleven adopted a corporate income tax between 1957 and 1971. Only two
states adopted a personal income tax since 1971, and no state has adopted a corporate income tax since 1971
(ACIR, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, various years).
A final explanation for the growth of state and local governments is devolution - the transfer of responsibilities
from higher levels of government to lower levels of government. Recently, state governments have taken a
more active role in providing services such as education and public welfare, activities traditionally funded
by the federal government. Although there has been much research and debate on devolution, one of the
primary explanations for increased state and local responsibilities is the public’s decreasing confidence in
the federal government’s ability to effectively provide goods and services, along with the growing desire for
decentralization and competition that is part of the capitalistic mentality (Tannenwald, 1998). As long as
state and local governments gain greater responsibility in providing goods and services, increases in state and
local government expenditures can be expected.

C. The Changing Responsibilities of State Governments


While there has been an overall increase in state expenditures in recent history, this does not imply that
expenditures on each function of state government have increased. To the contrary, state expenditures on
certain functional areas have decreased over time, while others, as expected, have increased. State expenditures
can be categorized into five functional areas: higher education, highways, public welfare, health care, and
correctional facilities. Expenditures on each functional category as a percent of total state expenditures are
shown in Table 2.

13
Table 2: State Expenditures By Category - Percent of Total
Year Education Highway Public Health Care Corrections Other
Welfare
1950 21.33 19.56 17.91 7.73 1.50 31.97
1960 31.79 26.87 13.62 7.66 1.56 18.50
1970 39.75 17.36 17.01 6.90 1.42 17.56
1980 38.53 10.98 19.38 8.04 1.95 21.12
1990 36.38 8.71 20.65 8.39 3.40 22.47
1996 35.33 7.82 26.44 8.43 4.16 17.82
Source: U.S. Census Bureau State Government Finances, various years,
and (Holcombe and Sobel, 1997, 24-25)

i. Education
Education expenditures, specifically on higher education, comprise the greatest percentage of total state
expenditures, although this percentage has decreased slightly in the past two decades. In the 1960s and early
1970s there was a significant increase in the public’s demand for higher education over earlier years, increasing
from 21 percent of state expenditures in 1950 to nearly 40 percent of state expenditures in the late 1960s and
early 1970s. This increase in demand resulted from two factors: 1) society began to place a greater weight on
the importance of higher education beginning in the 1960s, and 2) the baby-boomers reached college age.
The combination of these two factors raised the demand for higher education, thus forcing states to spend
an increasing percentage of their total budget on education during this time period. Although states are
currently spending a smaller percentage of their total budget on higher education expenditures than in the
past, higher education still remains the greatest priority of state governments as roughly 35 percent of state
expenditures are currently allocated to higher education.

ii. Highways
Unlike education expenditures, states have spent a declining portion of their total budget on highways. From
over 25 percent of total expenditures in 1960, expenditures on highways have decreased to only about eight
percent of total expenditures in recent years. This decrease is due to several factors. First, the 1950s and
1960s saw a dramatic increase in the number of highways constructed, in part due to the creation of the
Federal Interstate System. Although highways require periodic maintenance, highways are durable goods
lasting for many years. Once the initial cost of new highway construction is met, states require relatively less
funds to maintain roadways. Second, highway construction and maintenance are financed through motor fuels
taxes which are usually levied as a certain number of cents per gallon. Motor fuel taxes are thus not indexed
by inflation, meaning that as the price of fuel increases the tax collected does not increase because it is not
linked to the price of fuel, just the quantity of fuel purchased. As the price level increases, states receive a
higher percentage of their funds from inflation-linked taxes like the sales tax and income tax rather than
gasoline taxes. As a result expenditures on non-inflation indexed items decrease relative to other expenditure
categories. A continual increase in tax rates on non-indexed items would increase tax revenues, however this
option is not frequently considered by officials given the probable public opposition.

iii. Public Welfare


Since the early 1960s, public welfare has been an increasing portion of total state expenditures. Totaling
roughly 14 percent of state expenditures in 1970, welfare expenditures as a percent of total state expenditures
reached over 26 percent in 1996. The Medicaid program, which began in 1965, has been the predominant
cause of the increase in state welfare expenditures (Holcombe and Sobel, 1997, 29). Although Medicaid is
typically viewed as health care rather than welfare, a state makes a payment to an individual for health care
rather than directly spending the money on health care for the individual. Thus, Medicaid is considered
a welfare expenditure in terms of state budgeting. In 1970, less than one-half of all welfare expenditures
consisted of public medical payments. By the 1990s, however, nearly three-quarters of all public welfare
expenditures could be attributed to the Medicaid program.

14
iv. Health Care
Health care expenditures include those expenditures on hospitals, contributions to local clinics and public
health programs. Medicaid payments are not included in health care since they are considered a public welfare
expenditure rather than a health care expenditure. Unlike other categories of state government expenditures,
health care expenditures have remained a relatively constant percentage of total state expenditures. While
health care costs have consistently increased over time, state health care expenditures have hovered between
seven and eight percent of total state expenditures over the past several decades.

v. Corrections
Correctional expenditures predominately consist of expenditures on state prisons. Although current correc-
tional expenditures consist of only four percent of total state expenditures, this amount has nearly tripled
since the 1950s when correctional expenditures accounted for only 1.5 percent of total state expenditures.
States’ increased responsibility for correctional facilities can be attributed to: 1) the ‘war on drugs’ beginning
in the early 1980s, which led to an increase in the number of convicted drug offenders, 2) an increase in the
violent crime rate, which, according to the U.S. Bureau of the Census, has increased from 571 incidents per
100,000 population to over 750 incidents per 100,000 population in the mid 1990s, and 3) an increase in the
overall state and federal prison population, increasing from 100 per 100,000 population in 1970 to over 400
per 100,000 population in 1997.

vi. Other Expenditures


Although higher education, welfare, health care, highways and correctional facilities are the five main
expenditure categories, states do provide funding for other functional areas as well.
Some of the areas include library services, veteran’s services, parks and recreation and public utilities.
Expenditure on these categories has averaged about 20 percent of total state expenditures.

D. Conclusion
This section provided evidence on the rapid growth in state and local governments over the past forty
years. Attention was given to explaining those factors responsible for the dramatic increase in state and
local government size. These factors include increases in income, an increase in the overall population, an
increase in life expectancies, the introduction of new taxes, and the transfer of fiscal responsibility from
the federal government to state and local governments. The section then addressed the main categories of
state government expenditures and discussed the major historical trends for each of these five expenditure
categories.
Although the future cannot be predicted with certainty, a growing, older population along with the decentral-
ization of government decision making all suggest that the current trends in the growth of state and local
governments will continue. State and local governments will be asked to provide more goods and services for
the populations they represent. Only in the unlikely event that populations decide the free-market can better
provide the goods and services once provided by local governments, there is little doubt the 21st century will
see an increase in the size of state and local governments.

15
II. Funding State and Local Government - State and Local Taxes
Each state and local government in the United States uses a variety of taxes to raise the revenues necessary
to meet required expenditures. These taxes include the sales tax, personal income tax, property tax, excise
taxes, and the corporate income tax. In addition to choosing between different taxes, the tax rates vary
across state and local governments. The combination of taxes and tax rates used by each state or local
government is termed the tax mix. This section first presents an overview of the major sources of state and
local government tax revenue. The reader will see that individual state or local governments differ greatly in
their reliance on each tax as a source of revenue. This is primarily due to varying economies of scale in the
provision of goods and services and differences in voters’ tax preferences across localities and states. After
providing an overview of the major tax sources for state and local governments, each of the five major taxes
used by state and local governments is discussed as are other common sources of state and local government
revenue.

A. State and Local Government Revenue


Traditionally, state and local governments use five types of taxes to raise revenues. These taxes include the
general sales tax, the personal income tax, the corporate income tax, the property tax and excise taxes (taxes
such as alcohol and tobacco taxes and the motor fuels tax). Although these five taxes are all used by both
state and local governments, the importance of each tax in contributing to total tax revenues differs between
both levels of government.

i. State Government Revenue


In 1998, state governments generated almost $475 billion in state tax revenues. Tax revenues by state are
shown in Table 1. Considering total taxes, it is not surprising that high population states like California,
New York, Texas and Florida generated the most tax revenues. However, on a per capita basis things appear
much different. Connecticut, Delaware and Hawaii generated the most tax revenue per person, while tax
revenues per capita in some higher population states are near the lowest in the nation.

Table 1: 1998 State Tax Revenues


State Total Per Per Capita State Total Taxes Per Capita Per
Taxes Capita Rank ($ mill.) ($) Capita
($ mill.) ($) Rank
Alabama 5,734 1,318 46 Montana 1,332 1,514 39
Alaska 1,186 1,932 12 Nebraska 2,633 1,583 33
Arizona 6,949 1,488 42 Nevada 3,228 1,848 15
Arkansas 4,057 1,598 31 New 1,009 851 50
Hampshire
California 67,713 2,073 9 New Jersey 15,605 1,923 13
Colorado 5,898 1,485 43 New Mexico 3,575 2,058 10
Connecticut 9,394 2,869 1 New York 36,155 1,989 11
Delaware 1,981 2,663 2 North 13,869 1,838 16
Carolina
Florida 22,513 1,509 41 North Dakota 1,078 1,690 23
Georgia 11,589 1,517 38 Ohio 17,643 1,574 35
Hawaii 3,176 2,662 3 Oklahoma 5,301 1,584 32
Idaho 2,057 1,674 25 Oregon 4,999 1,523 37
Illinois 19,771 1,641 29 Pennsylvania 20,629 1,719 22
Indiana 9,747 1,652 27 Rhode Island 1,784 1,806 18
Iowa 4,803 1,678 24 South 5,683 1,482 44
Carolina
Kansas 4,648 1,768 21 South Dakota 834 1,130 49
Kentucky 7,115 1,808 17 Tennessee 6,996 1,288 47
Louisiana 6,082 1,392 45 Texas 24,629 1,246 48

16
Table 1: 1998 State Tax Revenues
State Total Per Per Capita State Total Taxes Per Capita Per
Taxes Capita Rank ($ mill.) ($) Capita
($ mill.) ($) Rank
Maine 2,370 1,905 14 Utah 3,458 1,647 28
Maryland 9,190 1,790 19 Vermont 958 1,620 30
Massachusetts 14,488 2,357 5 Virginia 10,543 1,552 36
Michigan 21,693 2,210 6 Washington 11,806 2,075 8
Minnesota 11,504 2,435 4 West Virginia 3,012 1,663 26
Mississippi 4,343 1,578 34 Wisconsin 11,150 2,134 7
Missouri 8,222 1,512 40 Wyoming 856 1,779 20
Source: Federation of Tax Administrators

General sales taxes have historically been the greatest source of revenues for state governments. In 1996, over
37 percent of state revenues came from general sales taxes. Personal income taxes were second in importance
to the general sales tax, followed by the corporate income tax and excise taxes on alcohol, tobacco and motor
fuels. Individual source state tax revenues as a percent of total state tax revenues from 1950 to 1996 are
shown in Table 2.

Table 2: State Tax Revenues By Source - Percent of Total


Year General Sales Personal Income Corporate Alcohol/Tobacco Motor Fuels Other
Income
1950 21.06 9.13 7.39 11.49 19.47 31.46
1960 23.85 12.25 6.54 9.19 18.49 29.68
1970 29.56 19.15 7.79 8.12 13.10 22.28
1980 31.49 27.06 9.72 4.67 7.09 19.97
1990 33.18 31.97 7.24 2.99 6.45 18.17
1996 37.53 31.91 7.01 2.62 6.21 14.72
Source: U.S. Census Bureau State Government Finances, various years, and (Holcombe and Sobel, 1997, 36)
Although sales taxes have been the greatest revenue source for state governments, the personal income tax
has increased in importance in recent years, now only contributing slightly less to total revenues than the
sales tax. Corporate income tax revenues as a percentage of total tax revenues have remained relatively
constant except for a slight increase in the 1980s. Alcohol, tobacco and motor fuel taxes have become a less
significant portion of total state tax revenues over time. As previously mentioned, this is primarily a result of
these taxes not being linked to inflation as are the other three taxes. Unlike local governments, the property
tax currently contributes a very smaller percentage to overall state tax revenues, although historically this
percentage has been higher. The property tax only accounted for about two percent of total state tax revenues
in 1996. States’ decreasing reliance on the property tax is reflected in the falling percentages of other tax
sources shown in the last column of Table 2.

ii. Local Government Revenue


The major tax revenue sources for local governments are quite different than that of state governments. The
predominant source of tax revenue for local governments has been the property tax. In 1996, the property tax
accounted for 74 percent of local government tax revenues. Recall the property tax accounted for only two
percent of state tax revenues. Local governments also rely on general sales taxes, but much less than state
governments. Sales taxes currently account for about 15 percent of local tax revenues. The personal income
tax is also a smaller percentage of local tax revenues than state tax revenue, with only about five percent of
local tax revenues coming from personal income taxes. Local governments receive about five percent of total
taxes from excise taxes, whereas state governments receive approximately 15 percent of tax revenues from
excise taxes.

17
B. The Sales Tax
A general sales tax imposes the same tax rate on the purchase of all commodities. Another common name
for a general sales tax is the retail sales tax, as the tax applies to most retail sales. The sales tax is considered
an ad valorem tax because it is levied as a percentage of the sales price. Although this is the true definition
of a general sales tax, it is important to realize that the sales tax really only applies to most commodities
rather than all commodities. Many state and local governments exempt services, food, and prescription drugs
from the sales tax. However, because the tax applies to most consumption goods, the term general sales tax
is used.

i. State Sales Taxes


As of 1999, only five states did not have a general sales tax. These states were Alaska, Delaware, Montana,
New Hampshire and Oregon. Sales tax rates in the other forty-five states and the District of Columbia range
from three percent to seven percent. Colorado has the lowest sales tax rate at three percent, while Mississippi
and Rhode Island both have sales tax rates of seven percent. State sales tax rates as of 1999 are shown in
Figure 1.
Figure 1: State Sales Tax Rate - 1999

ii. Local Sales Taxes


Thirty-one states have a local-taxing option which allows local governments to levy a local sales tax in
addition to the state sales tax. In this case, the total sales tax the consumer pays is the state sales tax rate
plus the local sales tax rate. Local rates are usually less than the state rate. In Kansas, for example, local
sales taxes range from 0.25 percent to 2.25 percent (city plus county), whereas the state sales tax rate is
4.9 percent. Local sales taxes are collected with state sales taxes at the time of purchase and are remitted
to the state, usually on a monthly basis. The state then returns the local portion of the sales tax collected
back to the originating local government. In essence, the state government acts as the tax collector for local
governments.

iii. Generating Sales Tax Revenues - Issues for State and Local Governments
As shown previously in Table 2, sales tax revenues have been an increasing percentage of total state tax
revenues. Not only have states placed an increasing reliance on sales tax revenues, sales tax revenues
themselves have increased over the past several decades. In 1960, sales tax revenues were roughly one percent
of GDP, whereas by 1996 sales tax revenue neared four percent of GDP. State and local governments can
increase sales tax revenues two ways: 1) by expanding the tax base, which is the activity being taxed (general
consumption or retail sales in the case of the sales tax), or 2) increasing the tax rate. As most state and local
sales taxes already apply to general consumption, expanding the tax base would not significantly increase
revenues, although removing certain exemptions would increase sales tax revenues. Initial sales tax rates for

18
many states ranged between two and three percent. However, the need for additional revenues forced states
to double or triple their initial sales tax rates to the current levels shown above in Figure 1.
By law, a state is not allowed to collect sales tax revenue from an out-of-state seller. Sales taxation requires
in-state ‘nexus,’ or physical presence of both buyer and seller in the state. So, for example, if a consumer in
New York purchases a product in Oklahoma, the state of New York cannot by law require Oklahoma to collect
New York sales tax on the purchase. The purchase is thus not subject to any sales tax. Compensating use
taxes are used by states to collect tax revenues from out-of-state purchases. Use tax rates are the same as
the sales tax rate. Use taxes are usually imposed on the consumption or storage of tangible personal property
within the state, regardless of where the property was purchased. So, for example, if a consumer buys a
vehicle from another state, the consumer does not have to pay the home state sales tax since the purchase
was made out-of-state, but the buyer is legally required to pay the home state use tax on the purchase since
the product will be used in the home state. Unfortunately, most consumers are not aware of the use tax
and their responsibility in remitting it. Also, unlike businesses which are routinely audited, evading the
compensating use tax is relatively easy because of the low probability of detection. Thus, compensating use
taxes are usually only collected on large-ticket durable purchases such as cars, boats, etc. that can be easily
documented and traced.

a. Taxing Electronic Commerce


As state and local government rely heavily on sales tax revenues, the explosion of electronic commerce,
often called e-commerce, in recent years has created significant concerns for local retailers and state and
local government officials. Only totaling several billion dollars in 1996, the National Governors Association
(NGA) estimates that e-commerce will grow to over $300 billion by 2002. Local retailers and state and local
governments tend to favor taxing electronic commerce. Local merchants fear the increased competition from
Internet shopping, and state and local governments project large sales tax revenue losses (over $20 billion
according to NGA) due to consumers purchasing products on-line rather than locally. Opponents of taxing
the Internet argue that the Internet is the last remaining sector of the economy where free trade is present.
They attribute the rapid growth in e-commerce and technology to the fact that there are no major taxes
on e-commerce to hinder growth. They suggest that e-commerce is just another form of competition for
local retailers, and as such local retailers should devise strategies to remain competitive in an electronic
marketplace. Furthermore, opponents of taxing electronic commerce argue that state and local governments
should become more fiscally responsible rather then relying on the Internet to provide extra tax revenues.
The biggest fear of state and local governments is the loss in sales tax revenue due to increases in e-commerce.
Traditionally, the sales tax is collected at the point of purchase. A well-defined nexus, or physical presence, is
required for a state or local government to collect sales taxes. To levy and collect sales taxes in any state
requires that both the buyer and the seller be physically located in that state. According to the Interstate
Commerce clause of the U.S. Constitution, if the seller is in a different state than the buyer, the buyer’s
state cannot by law attempt to collect sales tax from the out-of-state seller. Notice, however, that the nexus
problem applies not only to Internet commerce, but mail order purchases as well.
To overcome the nexus problem many states impose a use tax that is equal in value to the state’s sales tax
rate. When a remote seller does not collect a state’s sales tax, consumers who make remote purchases are
required to pay a use tax on the value of their remote purchase. In Kansas, a use tax is imposed “for the
privilege of using, storing, or consuming within this state any article of tangible personal property.” (K.S.A.
79-3703). Unfortunately, collecting use tax revenue from consumers is a problem, regardless of whether
consumption occurs locally or on-line. Because most businesses are aware of this use tax and are subject to
audits, the reporting and collection of use tax from businesses is not a problem. What is a problem is that
most consumers are not aware of the use tax so the tax revenue goes uncollected. Furthermore, there is little
incentive for consumers to remit this tax, as enforcing this tax at the individual consumer level would be
next to impossible. So although most states have a use tax to overcome the nexus problem arising from the
sales tax, the ignorance of consumers regarding the existence of this tax, the high costs of enforcing this tax
and the extremely low probability of detection from not remitting the tax all currently make the use tax an
ineffective alternative to collect lost sales tax revenues.

19
One question is why state and local governments have become so concerned about revenue losses from
e-commerce when they have been facing a similar problem with mail order purchases. State and local
governments are concerned with tax losses due to e-commerce because, unlike mail order, e-commerce is
projected to increase dramatically in the near future. While mail order sales reached $55 billion in 1998 (U.S.
Census Bureau Monthly Retail Sales), e-commerce is projected to reach over $300 billion by 2002. With $300
billion in untaxable electronic commerce, the $20 billion loss in sales tax revenue translates into about a ten
percent loss in state and local government tax revenues.
Although the projections for e-commerce and sales tax revenue losses are quite large, retailers and state and
local governments should be aware of several factors leading to a possible over-estimation of e-commerce
and tax revenue losses (see Goolsbee and Zittrain, 1999, 413-428; McClure, 1997, 731-749; Hellerstein, 1997,
593-606). First, the National Governors Association’s e-commerce projections include business-to-business
sales. Whether or not businesses buy from each other on-line is irrelevant because any sales between businesses
are tax exempt, regardless of the medium in which the purchase occurs. Second, just because a consumer
purchases a product on-line does not automatically imply that the product substituted for a locally sold
product. The Internet has made available to consumers a greater variety of products, many of which are not
available locally. If a consumer purchases a product that he could not buy locally, then local retailers and
local governments are not losing any revenues. Using data from the Forrester Research Company, (Goolsbee
and Zittrain, 1999, 413-428) empirically tested whether Internet sales divert retail purchases away from local
retailers. They found no significant evidence that on-line shopping substitutes for local retailing.
Another reason for the possible over-estimation of revenues losses is a failure to consider the type of product
purchases. The Boston Consulting Group (BCG, 1998) reports that roughly 40 percent of business-to-
consumer e-commerce involves purchases of food, apparel, travel and financial services. In the majority of
state these purchases are exempt from the sales tax. So any substitution between local consumption and
on-line consumption of these items will not result in a revenue loss for state and local governments. Of
the remaining 60 percent of e-commerce, almost half is comprised of computer sales (BCG, 1998). Many
on-line computer sellers already pay sales tax because they have in-state repair services, thus creating nexus.
Also, not every on-line computer purchase came from a local retailer - some purchases were made through
mail-order, in which case no tax collection was required anyway. However, while local governments may
not lose sales tax revenues in the usual amounts projected, they may lose revenue from other sources, i.e.
property taxes (loss of establishments) and income taxes (fewer employees or employees with lower incomes)
if consumers substitute from local commerce to electronic commerce.
Despite the possible over-estimation of revenue losses, state and local governments are concerned that if
e-commerce continues to grow and no tax plan is in place, it will be increasingly difficult if not impossible
to levy taxes on the Internet. There are several additional problems state and local governments face in
taxing the Internet. The Internet Tax Freedom Act (ITFA) enacted by congress in 1998 placed a three-year
moratorium on levying new taxes on the Internet. The ITFA has recently been extended until 2006. The
purpose of the ITFA was to allow the Internet and Internet technology to grow and remain unimpeded by
taxation and regulation. An important point, however, is that the ITFA only prevents new taxes from being
levied on e-commerce. Officials fear that new taxes would discriminate against certain parties involved in
Internet commerce and technology, while leaving other areas of Internet technology untaxed. The ITFA does
not apply to sales and use taxes because these are not new taxes for those state and local governments already
having sales and use taxes. So, state and local governments could levy state and local sales and use taxes
on e-commerce. The problem is the Interstate Commerce clause of the U.S. Constitution, which currently
prohibits states from collecting revenues from out-of-state sellers (the nexus problem) and the inability of
states to enforce and collect use tax on consumer purchases.
Technological constraints and the vast number of taxing jurisdictions are two other problems facing state and
local governments. Even if taxation of out-of-state sellers was possible, how do state and local governments
collect the tax revenue? Sellers would have to know the location of the buyer and the state and local tax rates
in the buyer’s state and community. Currently there are over 6,400 different tax rates in the United States.
Determining the tax for every single buyer at the time of purchase would place a huge cost on sellers. Also,
one basic principle of taxation is that taxation should only occur if compliance costs are low. If compliance
costs are high, then there is a greater chance of tax avoidance. As of now there is no low-cost method for

20
determining a buyer’s tax rates at the time of an on-line purchase. This may not be a problem in the future,
however, as plans for tax rate database software exist. With this software, sellers would be given all applicable
tax rates after the buyer enters his or her delivery address. The software would automatically compute the
tax based on the buyer’s address.
E-commerce and Internet taxation will undoubtedly continue to be important issues for state and local
governments as well as local retailers. Questions remain as to magnitude of tax revenue losses and the impact
of e-commerce on local retailers. On a simpler level, the question of whether the Internet should be taxed
at all is at the heart of many debates on taxing e-commerce. Officials will have to deal with the Interstate
Commerce clause of the Constitution to gain the opportunity to tax out-of-state sellers. Even if state and
local governments could legally tax out-of-state sellers, an efficient method of tax collection needs to be
developed to prevent tax avoidance.

b. Cross-Border Shopping
There are nearly 87,000 state and local government taxing jurisdictions in the United States. Thirty-one
states have a local sales tax option which gives counties and cities the authority to levy local sales taxes in
addition to the state tax rate. Within a state and across cities and counties one will encounter different tax
rates. The proximity of regions having different tax rates produces a situation where the economic activity
in one region is dependent on the tax activity or tax policy change occurring in nearby regions. If a sales
tax change occurs in one region, then all neighboring regions can be impacted by the change, even if these
regions made no change in their own sales tax policies. This dependence is primarily due to cross-border
shopping, which occurs because economic agents in one region adjust their behavior in response to a tax
change and the impacts of this behavioral change spill over into neighboring regions.
Many studies have been conducted to examine the degree to which sales tax differentials between regions
cause cross-border shopping and a resulting revenue gain or loss. Mikesell and Zorn (1986) examined the
impact of a sales tax increase (0.5 percent) in a small city in Mississippi relative to surrounding areas in
which the tax remained at 5 percent. They found that the tax rate differential caused a significant reduction
in sales within the city, namely a one-half percentage rate differential caused a 1.1 percent decrease in city
sales. Fisher (1980) examined the impact of tax rate differentials between Washington, D.C. (higher rate)
and the surrounding Maryland and Virginia suburbs (lower rate). He found that the tax rate differential had
no impact on overall sales between the regions, but did have a negative and significant impact on food sales.
Every one percentage point increase in the rate differential between Washington. D.C. and the suburban area
was predicted to cause a seven percent drop in food sales in Washington, D.C.
The general impact of cross-border shopping can be shown graphically. Consider the market for gasoline in
two neighboring regions A and B, both selling gasoline in a competitive market. This scenario is depicted in
Figure 2. Before the imposition of any tax (or tax change), the markets in both regions are in equilibrium at
price P0 . Now, suppose area A decides to a levy a per unit tax on gasoline. The imposition of a tax by area
A is shown by the ecrease in the supply curve (Supply1 ) for gasoline in area A. Now, the price of gasoline
in area A is higher (P0 + t) than before the tax, and the quantity of gasoline sold is now lower. One of the
basic principles of tax analysis is that individuals attempt to change their behavior to avoid a tax. Given
the price increase in area A, some consumers will substitute gasoline in area A with the now lower-priced
gasoline in area B. This substitution from A to B increases the demand for gasoline in area B shown by
Demand1 . Substitution will continue from A to B until the tax inclusive price of gasoline in area A, P0 + t,
is equal to the price of gasoline in area B, P1 , assuming no transportation costs, product differentiation, or
information costs between the two regions. When these prices are equal, there no longer remains an incentive
for consumers to substitute between products.
What Figure 2 shows is that a tax increase in one area actually leads to a price increase in neighboring areas.
Although taxes were not raised in area B, the imposition of a tax in area A caused a substitution from area
A to B, thus increasing the demand and the price for gasoline in area B. This highlights an important aspect
of local public finance - prices and product availability in one region are dependent upon tax policy and price
changes in neighboring regions.

21
Not only are one region’s prices impacted by neighboring tax changes, revenues to a local government can
also be impacted. As shown in Figure 2, the tax increase in area A led to an increase in the price of gasoline
and the quantity of gasoline sold in area B. With an increase in the quantity of gasoline sold, area B would
experience an increase in gasoline tax collections if a tax is in place, as gasoline taxes are levied per gallon.
Also, if gasoline was subject to the sales tax, sales tax revenues would increase in area B because the price of
gasoline increased in area B. Although area B did not increase taxes on gasoline, the tax increase in area A
resulted in a higher price and quantity of gasoline sold in area B, thereby increasing gasoline tax revenues
and sales tax revenues, if both applicable. Thus, a locality’s tax revenue, in addition to prices and quantity
sold, are also dependent on any tax change occurring in a neighboring region.

C. The Personal Income Tax


States have increased their reliance on the personal income tax as a source of revenue more than any other
tax. As shown above in Table 2, personal income tax revenues accounted for less than 10 percent of state
tax revenues in 1960 and more than 30 percent of state tax revenues in 1996. As of 1999, seven states did
not have a personal income tax on earnings. These states were Alaska, Florida, Nevada, South Dakota,
Texas, Washington and Wyoming. Two states, New Hampshire and Tennessee, only tax dividend and interest
income. Not only have states increased their reliance on the personal income tax, income tax revenues as a
percentage of GDP increased from less than one percent of GDP in 1960 to more than three percent of GDP
in 1996. Thus, the amount of personal income tax revenues received by states has also increased dramatically
over the past several decades.
Personal income tax rates and income brackets for each rate vary greatly across states. Income brackets refer
to a certain range of income that is taxed at a certain rate. As a simple example, a state may have two
income brackets, one ranging from $0 to $25,000 and the other ranging from $25,001 and higher. The tax
rate for the first bracket might be five percent and may be ten percent for the second bracket. Some states
have a flat tax rate, meaning all income is taxed at the same rate.

i. The Marginal Tax Rate


The marginal tax rate (MTR) measures the additional tax liability for every additional dollar in income.
Marginal tax rates are adjusted by state and local officials (as well as federal officials for the federal personal
income tax) to influence personal income tax revenues. In fact, the dramatic increase in personal income tax
revenues generated by states is a result of increases in marginal tax rates over time. Marginal tax rates are
computed as:

22
∆T axliability
MTR =
∆T axableincome

where ∆ is the Greek letter Delta and means “change in.” M T R is simply the change in tax liability due to a
change in taxable income, or the additional tax owed for each additional dollar in taxable income. Marginal
tax rates and tax brackets for a sample of state are shown in Table 3.
Table 3: Selected Marginal Personal Income Tax Rates - 1999
State Tax Rate (%) Income Brackets ($)
Lowest Highest # Brackets Lowest Highest
Georgia 1.0 6.0 6 750 7,500
Maine 2.0 8.5 4 4,150 16,500
New York 4.0 6.85 5 8,000 20,000
Utah 2.3 7.0 6 750 3,750
Wisconsin 4.77 6.77 3 7,500 15,001
Source: Federation of Tax Administrators. Income brackets in some states are different for single, married, and joint filers.
The income bracket ranges presented above are for single filers.

To see how marginal tax rates and income brackets are used to compute an individual’s overall tax liability,
consider the following tax schedule for a hypothetical state.
Income Range Marginal Tax Rate
$0 - $10,000 10 %
$10,001 - $50,000 15 %
$50,001 - $70,000 20 %
$70,001 + 25 %
According to the above tax schedule, the individual’s first $10,000 is taxed at 10%, his next $40,000 is taxed
at 15%, his next $20,000 is taxed at 20%, and any income over $70,000 is taxed at 25%. So, for his first
$10,000 each additional dollar between $1 and $10,000 is taxed at 10%, each additional dollar between $10,001
and $50,000 is taxed at 15%, and so on.
Suppose an individual is earning $60,000 a year. What is his tax liability? Based on the above schedule,
his first $10,000 is taxed at 10%, so his tax liability for his first $10,000 is $1,000 ($10,000 × 10%). His
next $40,000 is taxed at 15%, so his tax liability for his next $40,000 in income ($50,000 - $10,000) is $6,000
($40,000 × 15%). To this point the first $50,000 of the individual’s $60,000 has been taxed. He has $10,000
remaining ($60,000 - $50,000) which is taxed at 20%. His tax liability for the remaining $10,000 would be
$2,000 ($10,000 × 20%). His total tax liability is simply found by adding the tax liabilities for each income
bracket: $1,000 + $6,000 + $2,000 = $9,000. So, an individual earning $60,000 a year and facing the above
tax schedule would pay $9,000 in personal income taxes.

ii. The Average Tax Rate


The average tax rate (AT R) is simply a measure of an individual’s tax liability as a percentage of his
income. The AT R is computed as:

T axliability
AT R = × 100
T axableincome

For example, if an individual owes $5,000 in state personal income taxes and has a taxable income of $40,000,
his AT R is 12.5% ($5,000 For example, if an individual owes $5,000 in state personal income taxes and has a
taxable income of $40,000, his AT R is 12.5% ($5,000 ÷ $40,000) × 100. Having AT Rs across individuals
allows a comparison of which individuals are paying a higher or lower percent of their income in state personal
income taxes.

23
iii. Tax Incidence
Tax incidence refers to which individuals bear the burden of a tax after the economy has adjusted to
changes caused by the taxes. In general, incidence is concerned with the revenue burden of the tax, namely
which groups of individuals are paying a larger percentage of tax revenue than other groups. An important
point in tax incidence analysis is that taxes cause changes in individuals’ behavior. Those individuals bearing
the ultimate burden of the tax may be different than the individuals on whom the tax was initially levied.
The more a group of individuals is willing to change their behavior to avoid the tax, the smaller the burden
of taxation will be for those individuals. For example, if a tax is levied on a group of individuals, say buyers
of gasoline, but a portion these individuals alter their behavior by consuming no gasoline (thus avoiding the
tax), then the burden of taxation falls on those individuals still consuming gasoline.
Although incidence tells us which groups bear the burden of the tax, evaluating incidence in terms of good
or bad or high or low is done by comparing the incidence of a tax relative to something else. The most
common method of comparison is to compare the incidence of one tax to that of another tax that raises the
same amount of revenues. This is called differential incidence. Another method of comparison is that
of budgetary incidence, which considers the incidence of a tax only after the revenue benefits of the tax
(such as income transfers, educational benefits) have been considered.

a. Regressive, Progressive and Proportional Taxes


Once the economy has adjusted to changes in prices caused by the tax and the final tax burden is known, the
burden of the tax is sometimes characterized by its impact on the income distribution. The terms regressive,
progressive, and proportional are often used to define the burden of taxation on income distributions. A tax
is considered regressive if the burden of taxation decreases with income, that is, higher income individuals
spend a smaller percentage of their income on the tax than lower income individuals. For a progressive tax,
the burden of taxation increases with income, meaning higher income individuals spend a greater percentage
of their income on the tax than lower income individuals. Finally, a tax is considered proportional if the
burden of taxation remains the same over all levels of income. Under a proportional tax, each income group
spends an equal percentage of their income on the tax.
Although these definitions seem straightforward, there remains some uncertainty about the impact of a tax
on the income distribution. The income distribution could refer to current income or to lifetime income.
Depending on which definition of the income distribution one uses, the conclusions regarding regressivity,
progressive, and proportionality may be different as incomes generally increase over one’s lifetime. Studies by
Pechman (1985) and Fullerton and Rogers (1993, chapter 1-7) compute the tax incidence in terms of the
income distribution for the major taxes used in the United States. Pechman, using current income, finds that
sales and excise taxes are regressive, the property tax and corporate income tax tend to be proportional or
slightly progressive, and the personal income tax is progressive. The regressivity of sales and excise taxes is
not surprising as lower income individuals tend to spend a higher portion of their income on consumption
goods (which are the tax bases for sales and excise taxes) than wealthier individuals. The proportionality
or progressivity of the other taxes are a result of political manipulation. In terms of lifetime income, the
tax incidence of these taxes differs slightly. Fullerton and Rogers, using lifetime income rather than current
income, find that, as does Pechman, sales and excise taxes are regressive. They also find the personal income
tax to be moderately progressive. However, Fullerton and Rogers find that the corporate income tax is
regressive for the lowest income individuals when considering lifetime income. They also find the property tax
is regressive for the lowest income individuals, proportional for middle income individuals, and progressive
for the wealthiest individuals. Clearly, although the methodologies used by both authors provide similar
conclusions, determination of tax incidence does to some degree depend upon one’s definition of income.

D. The Corporate Income Tax


Unlike other revenue sources, corporate income tax revenues have remained a relatively constant proportion of
total state tax revenues. Only during the 1980s did corporate income tax revenue contribute to a significantly
larger percentage of state tax revenues. In addition to being a relatively constant percent of total state tax
revenues, corporate income tax revenues have remained a small percentage of GDP, comprising 0.4% of GDP

24
in 1960 and 0.7% of GDP in 1996. As of 1999, six states did not have a corporate income tax. These states
were Michigan, Nevada, South Dakota, Texas, Washington and Wyoming.
The corporate income tax is structured the same as the personal income tax, except the marginal tax rates
are slightly higher and, of course, the income brackets are larger. Unlike the personal income tax, thirty-two
states have a flat corporate income tax rate, meaning there is a single tax rate for all levels of corporate
income. Although this flat rate may appear proportional, deductions and exemptions can create a progressive
corporate income tax even with a constant marginal tax rate.

E. Excise Taxes
An excise tax is a tax that is levied on a specific commodity, such as alcohol, tobacco and gasoline. Excise
taxes are also called selective sales taxes. Unlike general sales taxes, excise taxes on the above commodities
can also be a fixed amount per unit sold rather than a percentage of the total sales price. For example, an
excise tax on gasoline is, say, 30 cents a gallon, or the excise tax on cigarettes is 50 cents a pack. The vast
majority of states and those local governments given a local tax option have excise taxes on alcohol, tobacco,
and gasoline. In fact, most states have different tax rates for beer, liquor, and wine; cigarettes and other
tobacco; and gasoline and diesel fuel. In addition, not only do a majority of states have excise taxes, many of
the commodities taxed under an excise tax are also subject to the general sales tax. Excise taxes for selected
states and commodities are shown in Table 4.
Table 4: Selected State Excise Tax Rates - 1999
Beer Wine Liquor Cigarettes Gasoline Diesel
(cents/gal.) (cents/gal.) (cents/gal.) (cents/gal.) (cents/gal.) (cents/gal.)
Alabama 53 170 (a) 165 18 19
Illinois 7 23 200 58 19 22
Nebraska 23 75 300 34 25 25
Ohio 18 32 (a) 24 22 22
Washington 26 87 (a) 83 23 23
Source: Federation of Tax Administrators. Note: all values rounded to the nearest cent.
(a) Liquor sales are run through state-controlled stores. Revenues from liquor sales are obtained from stores’ net profits.

Of all state tax revenues, excise tax revenues have been a decreasing percentage of total state tax revenues.
Furthermore, the amount of excise tax revenues collected has fallen from 1.6% of GDP in 1960 to less than 1%
of GDP in 1996. This decrease in state excise tax revenues is because excise taxes are not linked to inflation.
One way to increase excise tax revenues is to increase the excise tax rate. However, as prices continually rise
this would require an unending increase in excise tax rates or a broadening of the tax base. Clearly, constant
increases in excise tax rates would be quite unpopular with the public, thus explaining why state and local
officials do not continually increase excise tax rates. As a result, states have decreased their reliance on excise
tax revenues and moved to other available revenue sources, such as the sales tax, personal income tax, and
corporate income tax.

F. Property Taxes
The property tax is the predominant source of revenues for local governments. In 1996, nearly three-quarters
of local government revenue came from property taxes, whereas the property tax only accounted for two
percent of total state tax revenues. Property taxes are usually paid annually, although quarterly and monthly
payments are also common. Local governments tax residential property, commercial property, and agricultural
property. Not only are the property tax rates on these properties different, tax rates across cities and counties
are different.

i. Computing the Property Tax


Unlike sales and income taxes, computation of the property tax liability is much more difficult. Although the
computation of property taxes can differ across states, most states follow a common model. Property tax
rates are based on the appraised market value of one’s property, the assessment rate, and the mill levy. The

25
first step in property tax collection requires an appraisal of one’s property. This property appraisal is done
by a city or county official and is an appraisal of the market value of one’s property. Local governments then
have an assessment rate which is used to determine what percentage of the property’s appraised value is
taxed. The percentage of the property’s appraised value is termed the assessment value, which is simply
the appraised value times the assessment rate. Once the assessment value is determined, the final tax owed is
determined by the mill levy. One mill is equal to 1/1000 of assessed value. The final property tax owed is
computed by multiplying each $1,000 in assessed value by the mill levy. Mill levies vary by city and county,
but a range of 90 to 150 mills ($90 to $150 in tax for every $1,000 in assessed value) is common. Officials can
increase property tax revenues by increasing the assessment rate, the mill levy, or both.
To understand how property taxes are computed, consider the following example for a homeowner whose
home is appraised at $150,000:

Appraised Value of Property: $150,000


Assessment Rate (set by local government): 10%
Assessed Property Value: $15,000 ($150,000 × 10%)
Mill Levy (set by local government): 120 mills
Property Tax Owed: $1,800 ($15,000 ÷ $1,000) × 120

ii. Advantages and Disadvantages of the Property Tax


As all property owners are subject to the property tax and the tax is the predominant source of local
government revenues, plans to change property tax rates are usually met with much public debate and local
media attention. Although debate surrounding the property tax involves the mill levy and the assessment
rate, the property tax has one main advantage and one main disadvantage that are frequently raised during
property tax debates. The main advantage of the property tax is that it provides a much more stable source
of revenue over other taxes. Revenue stability is important as state and local governments rely on tax
revenues to fund goods and services. Revenues from personal income taxes, corporate income taxes, and
sales taxes move with economic conditions. In recessionary periods, individuals consume less goods, thus
reducing sales tax revenues. Also, because individuals are consuming less, corporate and personal incomes
fall which reduces personal and corporate income tax revenues. In turn, tax revenues from these sources
rise during an economic expansion. Unlike consumption and income, property tax revenues are immune to
short-run changes in economic conditions because assessed values are not impacted by economic changes. As
local governments rely on property tax revenues much more than state governments, local governments have
a more stable revenue source than state governments.
The primary disadvantage of the property tax is the unequal treatment of individuals in terms of market value.
All property is not appraised annually due to the massive administrative costs that would be involved. The
problem of market value and unequal treatment comes into play when, for example, one individual’s home is
appraised at a higher value but another individual’s home, while having the same true market value, is not
appraised. Therefore, although the true market value of both homes may be the same, the individual whose
home was appraised at a higher value will pay higher property taxes. This problem also occurs frequently
during the selling of a home which requires a current property value appraisal. If two homes were both
appraised at $100,000 three years ago, and one homeowner decides to sell his house which is now appraised at
$115,000, the new homeowner will pay higher property taxes than the person whose home is still appraised at
$100,000, even though the appraisal value for this home should now be $115,000.

G. Other Revenue Sources - Intergovernmental Revenues, User Fees and State


Lotteries
Besides the five major tax sources discussed above, state and local governments receive revenues from other
sources as well. One important source of total state and local revenues is the contribution of funds from the
federal government. Funds exchanged between levels of government, usually from the federal government to

26
state governments or from state governments to local government, are called intergovernmental revenues.
In 1996, nearly 20 percent of total state revenues consisted of intergovernmental revenues from the federal
government.
User fees are another source of state and local government revenues. User fees are payments for the use of
a publicly provided service, such as state parks, sewage and water services and toll roads. Tax dollars are
used for the fixed start-up costs, such as road paving, building construction, etc. However, user fees are then
used to cover the variable costs of operation once projects are completed. In some instances revenues from
user fees may exceed the variable costs of operation and may serve as a source of general fund revenue for
state governments.
An additional revenue source for state governments in recent years has been state lotteries (see Clotfelter
and Cook, 1989; Borg, Mason and Shapiro, 1991). Since New Hampshire introduced the first state-operated
lottery in 1964, thirty-seven states and the District of Columbia were operating a lottery as of 2000. In most
states, lottery adoption occurs through a public referendum (see Hersch and McDougall, 1989; Garrett, 1999).
In 1997, lottery sales in the United States topped $35 billion, or roughly $120 per capita. For each lottery
ticket purchased, a portion of the purchase price (usually a one-dollar purchase price) is used to cover prize
payouts, administrative costs, and retailer commissions. After covering all expenses, the portion remaining
with the state is termed net lottery revenue. Net lottery revenues are roughly 30 percent of total lottery
sales, totaling about $12 billion in 1997. Net lottery revenues are used to fund various social programs within
a state. In Pennsylvania, net lottery revenues are allocated to senior citizen care, whereas West Virginia
divides its net lottery revenues between tourism and education. Other states like Ohio, Illinois and Florida
allocate 100 percent of their net lottery revenues to education. Historically, net lottery revenues account for
only about three percent of total state revenues. However, increasing fiscal pressures and a growing public
opposition to increasing tax rates have made lotteries a more popular avenue for generating revenues in recent
years.

H. Conclusion
This section discussed trends in state and local government revenue and the various taxes used by state and
local governments to raise revenues. The section began by providing evidence on state and local government
revenue collections, sources of revenues from various taxes, and state and local governments’ changing reliance
on various taxes. Time was spent discussing revenue issues involving electronic commerce and cross-border
shopping. The remainder of the section focused on the five main taxes used by state and local governments
to raise revenues, as well as a discussion on tax incidence. The following section of the chapter deals with
principles of tax analysis and discusses several important issues state and local officials should use when
evaluating a tax. Two popular models for optimal taxation are also presented in the next section.

27
III. Principles of Tax Analysis
State and local governments use a variety of taxes to raise revenues. State governments favor sales taxes,
excise taxes and personal income taxes, whereas local governments predominately rely on property taxes. On
the surface it appears that raising revenues is a fairly benign process - state and local government officials
simply adopt a tax or change an existing rate and the required revenues are obtained. What is missed in this
simple process are the impacts tax adoption and changes have on individuals, markets and other government
revenues. Effective tax policy requires understanding the basic economics of taxation. This chapter explores
the basic principles of tax analysis.
The first section discusses the distributional effects of taxation, focusing primarily on evaluating the burden of
taxation on selected groups of individuals. Efficiency concerns are presented next, with a look at the efficiency
costs of taxation and the efficiency-equity trade-off. The final section introduces two models of taxation,
the Ramsey Rule and the Laffer curve. While both models focus on revenue generation, each model makes
different assumptions regarding the motives and goals of governments in raising revenues. Full understanding
of this chapter requires some knowledge of microeconomics, calculus and econometrics. The calculus portions
can be skipped, however, without a loss of understanding the basic theoretical ideas.

A. Distributional Effects of Taxation - Tax Incidence


Tax incidence is concerned with which groups of individuals are paying a larger percentage of tax revenue
than other groups. An important point in tax incidence analysis is that taxes cause changes in individuals’
behavior. Those individuals bearing the ultimate burden of the tax may be different than the individuals on
whom the tax was initially levied. The more a group of individuals is willing to change their behavior to
avoid the tax, the smaller the burden of taxation will be for those individuals.

i. Single-Market Analysis of Tax Incidence


Evaluating tax incidence is most commonly done using a competitive, single-market framework. Although the
impacts of taxation on other markets is ignored here for simplicity, the reader should be aware that changes
in one market always have impacts on other markets. Single-market analysis is termed partial equilibrium
analysis.

a. A Unit Tax on Buyers and Sellers


Suppose that before the imposition of a tax the gasoline market is in equilibrium and the equilibrium price
per gallon is $1.00 and the equilibrium quantity is 1,000 gallons. As will be shown, the economic impact
of a tax is the same regardless of whether the tax is levied on buyers or sellers. However, first consider the
situation where a tax of $0.30 per gallon is levied on sellers of gasoline. This scenario is shown in Figure 1a.
Initial market equilibrium is shown by point A at the intersection of Demand0 and Supply0 . Imposing a
tax on sellers of gasoline causes the supply curve for gasoline to decrease by the amount of the tax. The
new supply curve is Supply1 , with the distance between Supply0 and Supply1 equal to the amount of tax.
With the tax in place, consumers are now paying $1.15 per gallon, an increase of $0.15 per gallon before the
tax. Sellers now receive $1.15 per gallon, shown by the intersection of Demand0 and Supply1 at point B.
However, sellers are responsible for paying the tax, so the $1.15 received by sellers is the tax inclusive price.
As shown by point C, sellers receive only $0.85 per gallon of gasoline after paying the tax. Note that the
imposition of the gasoline tax has reduced the quantity of gasoline bought and sold from 1,000 gallons to 900
gallons.
The revenue burden of consumers and sellers is determined by the rectangular areas shown in Figure 1a.
Consumers’ share of tax revenue is $135, computed from the area of the top rectangle. Similarly, sellers’ share
of tax revenue is also $135, computed from the area of the bottom rectangle. Total tax revenues collected
equal $270, which is the sum of the consumers’ share and sellers’ share. In this example both consumers and
sellers bear the same revenue burden.

28
Before proceeding, it is important to note that the above burden on sellers is really a burden on individuals
rather than a physical business entity. A burden on sellers may result in lower profits, lower employee wages,
etc. So although we say the burden of taxation falls on ‘sellers,’ the reader should realize that the burden
really falls on all individuals associated with the taxed business.
The economic impact of the tax is the same regardless of which group is initially taxed. Consider Figure 1b
which shows the economic impact of a $0.30 gasoline tax now levied on buyers rather than sellers. Again, the
initial equilibrium price of $1.00 per gallon and equilibrium quantity of 1,000 gallons is shown by point A, the
intersection of Demand0 and Supply0 . Imposing a $0.30 tax on buyers of gasoline decreases the demand for
gasoline by the amount of the tax, shown by the new demand curve Demand1 . As a result of the tax, sellers
now receive $0.85 per gallon, shown by the intersection of Demand1 and Supply0 at point C. Consumers
also pay $0.85 per gallon, but this is the tax exclusive price. With the $0.30 tax, consumers ultimately pay
$1.15 per gallon ($0.85 plus $0.30 tax). In this case, sellers receive $0.85 per gallon, the same as they received
net-of-tax when the tax was levied on sellers. Consumers also pay $0.85 per gallon, but this is net-of-tax.
With the tax levied on consumers, consumers must pay $1.15 per gallon, the same price paid when the tax
was levied on sellers.

29
The revenue burden for consumers and suppliers is the same as before. Both consumers and sellers each
face a burden of $135, with the total burden again equal to $270. The results from both examples highlight
an important aspect of tax incidence - in a competitive market, a unit tax levied on sellers has the same
market effects as a unit tax levied on buyers. Thus, the revenue burdens of buyers and sellers will be the
same regardless of whom the tax is initially levied upon.

b. A General Rule of Tax Incidence


An important point regarding tax incidence is that those individuals less likely to change their behavior will
ultimately bear a greater burden of the tax. The price elasticity characterizes willingness to change behavior.
Figures 2a and 2b illustrate the importance of price elasticity and tax incidence. In Figures 2a, the price
elasticity of supply is less than the price elasticity of demand. This is determined by examining the slope
of the supply and demand curves - a change in price has a smaller impact on the quantity supplied than it
does on the quantity demanded. Using the previous example of a $0.30 gasoline tax levied on suppliers, the
imposition of a $0.30 tax per gallon on suppliers results in a final price to consumers of $1.05 and a net-of-tax
price received by sellers of $0.75. The quantity of gasoline supplied again falls to 900 gallons. The revenue
burden to consumers is now $45 (area of top rectangle), whereas the revenue burden on suppliers is $225
(area of bottom rectangle). Notice that the overall revenue burden is still $270. Because suppliers change
their behavior less than consumers, suppliers bear a larger portion of the final tax burden.

30
31
Figure 2b considers the case where demand is more inelastic than supply. That is, consumers are less
responsive to changes in price than suppliers. The result of a $0.30 tax levied on suppliers reduces the initial
supply, resulting in a price to consumers of $1.25. Sellers also receive $1.25, but this is the tax inclusive price.
The net-of-tax price received by sellers is now $0.95. The revenue burden to consumers is now $225 and the
burden on suppliers is only $45, with the overall revenue burden again remaining the same at $270. Because
demand is less responsive to price changes than is supply, consumers will bear a greater portion of the overall
tax burden.
The final revenue burden will primarily fall on those individuals less likely to change their behavior in the
presence of a price increase. In other words, the group of individuals having a smaller price elasticity of
demand or supply will bear the greater burden of taxation.

B. Efficiency
Recall from microeconomics that competitive markets result in an efficient allocation of resources. Efficiency
is said to occur when 1) the marginal social benefits of consuming a good are equal to or are greater than the
marginal social costs of producing that good, or similarly 2) any additional consumption or production of
a good is not possible without making another party worse off. A graphical depiction of efficiency in the
market for milk is shown in Figure 3.

The supply curve for a commodity can be equated to the marginal social costs (M SC) of production - it
reveals the additional costs for producing additional gallons of milk. As we are considering a competitive
market, the price a seller receives is equal to the marginal costs of production. As we are also assuming
no spill-over costs to other parties, the marginal cost of production is equal to the marginal social costs of
production. Similarly, the demand curve reveals the marginal social benefits of consumption (M SB), or
the additional benefits received from consuming additional units of a commodity, with the price reflecting
consumers’ willingness to pay for additional units of the commodity. Marginal benefits of consumption
decrease due to decreasing marginal utility of consumption.

32
The equilibrium price for a gallon of milk is $2.00 and the equilibrium quantity is 100 gallons. This is an
efficient outcome because M SB = M SC. Any further production over 100 gallons would create a situation
where M SC > M SB, suggesting that society should decrease milk production Similarly, any production
less than 100 would create a situation where M SB > M SC, suggesting that milk production should be
increased. Notice that any other price besides $2.00 is not sustainable in a competitive market. At $3.00 a
gallon, quantity supplied (150) exceeds quantity demanded (50), and M SB > M SC. This excess supply puts
downward pressure on prices. Likewise, at only $1.00 a gallon, quantity demanded (150) exceeds quantity
supplied (50) and again M SB > M SC. Excess demand puts upward pressure on prices. Only at $2.00 is the
market in equilibrium, and at this equilibrium the market produces an efficient outcome.
Tax policy often creates market inefficiencies because the tax inclusive price is fixed above the equilibrium
price. For example, suppose that in Figure 3 a $1.00 a gallon tax is levied on milk, raising the total price to
$3.00 and decreasing the quantity of milk to 50 gallons. With the tax, M SB > M SC. Although society would
be better off with increased milk production, the tax prevents this increase in production from occurring.
Both consumers and suppliers are harmed by the tax. The loss to consumers is represented by triangle ABD,
which shows the loss in consumer surplus - the benefits to society from consumption. Without the tax, the
consumer surplus would be the area under the demand curve above the price of $2.00. With the tax, however,
consumers lose ABD in consumption. Similarly, the loss to producers is represented by a loss in producer
surplus, or the benefits to producers from increased production. Producer surplus in the absence of the tax
would be the area below the price of $2.00 and above the supply curve. The loss in producer surplus resulting
from the tax is area ACD. The total loss to society is the sum of consumer losses and producer losses and is
termed the excess burden of taxation, or deadweight loss of taxation.
The reader should see the relationship between efficiency and tax incidence. If a tax does not force individuals
to change their behavior, then no efficiency cost is created. The tax incidence simply falls on those individuals
directly taxed. However, if the tax does force individuals to alter their behavior then an efficiency cost is
created and determining tax incidence is more difficult as consumers and sellers change their behavior to
avoid the tax.
Although the above analysis has demonstrated the inefficiencies caused by taxation, the imposition of a tax
may actually restore market efficiency in some cases. This predominately occurs in the case of externalities,
which are negative (or sometimes positive) unintended spill-over effects to third parties. In essence, the
producers of a negative externality, such as a steel producer emitting pollution from its factory, do not
consider the external costs of steel production (the pollution) when determining its production decisions. As
a result, the market provides an amount of steel production that is greater than the efficient amount because
the external costs of steel production are not considered. A tax levied on steel producers that is equivalent
to the external costs of steel production (pollution) will decrease the supply curve for steel producers and
restore efficiency conditions at M SB = M SC. In the case of a market failure, such as a negative externality,
governments can use taxes to restore market efficiency.

i. Computing The Efficiency Loss From a Tax


This section derives the expressions for computing the efficiency loss in a single-market due to the imposition
of a unit tax and an ad valorem tax. Efficiency loss was shown graphically in Figure 3. The analysis here
makes two assumptions. The first assumption is that of a linear demand curve. Second, a horizontal supply
curve is assumed, meaning any amount of the product can be supplied at the market price, but that none
will be supplied if the price falls below the equilibrium price (perfectly elastic supply). The analysis becomes
more complicated with an upward sloping supply curve.

a. Efficiency Loss From A Unit Tax


First consider the imposition of a unit tax, T , such as an excise tax on gasoline, shown in Figure 4. At point
A, M SB = M SC. With the tax, however, the new price is P + T and now M SB > M SC. The deadweight
loss of taxation is represented by area ABC. A general expression for the deadweight loss of taxation, or
excess burden (EB), is outlined below.

33
The excess burden is triangle ABC. The area of any triangle is found by finding 1/2 • base • height. The base
of the triangle is the change in quantity demanded, or dQ. Similarly, the height of the triangle is the change
in price, or dP . Thus,
EB = 1/2 • base • height = 1/2 • dQ • dP
The change in price is simply the tax, T (from P + T − P ). An expression for dQ can be obtained from the
formula for the price elasticity of demand, ∈:
dQ P
∈= •
dP Q
Solving the price elasticity of demand expression for dQ gives:
∈ • dP • Q
dQ =
P
Plugging the expressions for dP and dQ into the formula for EB and rearranging terms yields the following
expression for excess burden:
1 T 2• ∈ • Q
EB = •
2 P
The excess burden of taxation is dependent upon the price elasticity of demand and the tax rate. The reader
should note, however, the expression above suggests that the excess burden of taxation is zero if the price
elasticity of demand is zero. This is an artifact of the single-market analysis done here. In reality, even if the
price elasticity of demand for the taxed commodity is zero, there will still be an impact on other markets as
consumers change their consumption of other commodities.

34
b. Efficiency Loss From an Ad Valorem Tax
Deriving the expression for the efficiency loss from an ad valorem tax, t, is almost identical to that of a unit
tax. The only difference is in the expression for dP . Under an ad valorem tax, dP equals P • t rather than just
T under a unit tax. With an ad valorem tax, the tax-inclusive price is P (1 + t), so dP = P (1 + t) − P = P t.
With a new expression for dP and the same expression for dQ as under a unit tax, the expression for the
excess burden of an ad valorem tax is:

1 2
EB = • t • ∈ • Q • P
2

ii. The Efficiency/Equity Tradeoff


The above sections have shown that the imposition of tax generally creates market inefficiencies. It is
important to realize, however, that there exists an efficiency/equity tradeoff when evaluating taxes. Although
most taxes create inefficiencies, tax revenues are used in the production of social goods, such as education
and public welfare. The main idea behind these programs is to create a more ‘equitable’ society in terms
of providing all individuals a subsistence level of education and income. It should be clear as to why the
efficiency/equity tradeoff exists. Without taxes, markets would function more efficiently. Production levels
would be higher, consumers would have more goods available to them, prices would be lower and mean
incomes would be higher, although there would be a greater variance in incomes across individuals. With
greater efficiency there will exist greater societal inequality because there are no revenues to be allocated
from one portion of society to another. If we are concerned with equity, however, the distribution of tax
revenue will result in a more equitable distribution of income (a lower variance) across individuals, but the
inefficiencies created will cause relatively higher prices, lower mean incomes, and a lower availability of goods.
Whether we should have a more equitable or more efficient society is a matter of opinion and is frequently a
topic of political debate.

C. Two Models of Optimal Taxation


This portion of section III presents two famous models of optimal taxation. The first model considered is the
Ramsey Rule. This model assumes that governments attempt to minimize the excess burden (efficiency loss)
of taxation subject to given revenue requirements. The ‘optimal’ tax rate under the Ramsey rule is the rate
that minimizes the excess burden of taxation while still generating the required revenues.
The Laffer curve is the second model of taxation presented. This model assumes that governments will
attempt to generate as much revenue as possible without any regard to the efficiency losses caused by taxation.
Only constitutional constraints and other legislation can limit the government’s desire for increased revenue.
This view of government has been coined the “Leviathan” model of government (see Brennan and Buchanan,
1977). The Laffer curve considers the inverse relationship between tax rates and tax bases and the impact of
this relationship on tax revenues. The analysis reveals that a higher tax rate is not always the maximizing
rate - a lower tax rate may actually raise more tax revenues than a higher tax rate.

i. The Ramsey Rule


The previous sections have shown that while taxes do generate revenue benefits, taxes also create an excess
burden on society. Obviously policy makers are confronted with an assumed trade-off - they need to generate
a given amount of revenue, but generating this revenue will impose an additional cost on society. Within this
framework, the problem for policy makers is to find tax rates that satisfy their revenue constraints but also
minimize the deadweight loss to society. The following model of optimal taxation derives an expression for
the ‘optimal’ commodity tax, optimal in terms of generating the required revenue while at the same time
minimizing the deadweight loss to society. The model, termed the Ramsey Rule, produces the conditions set
forth by (Ramsey, 1927), who argued that the excess burden of taxation will be minimized by setting the
ratio of tax rates inversely proportional to price elasticities of demand for both products.

35
Suppose there are two goods X and Y. Assume that policy makers wish to levy ad valorem taxes on both
goods and the supply curves for both goods are perfectly elastic (horizontal). While these taxes will generate
revenues, they will also create a loss to society. The problem for the policy maker then becomes selecting tax
rates that minimize the excess burden given certain revenue constraints. This problem can be expressed as:

min{EBX + EBY } subject to R = tX • PX • X + tY • PY • Y

where EBX and EBY are the excess burdens from taxing good X and from taxing good Y , each equal to
the expression of the excess burden under an ad valorem tax shown in the previous section. R is the revenue
raised from goods X and Y , tX • PX • X is the revenue raised from good X (where X is the quantity of good
X), and tY • PY • Y is the revenue raised from good Y (where Y is the quantity of good Y ). The Lagrangian
for the above problem is:

1
 
min L = • t2Y • ∈Y •Y • PY + λ R − tX • PX • X − tY • PY • Y
tX tY 2

Taking first-order conditions yields:

δL
= tX • ∈X •X • PX − λ • PX • X = 0 (1)
δtX
δL
= tY • ∈Y •Y • PY − λ • PY • Y = 0 (2)
δtY
From (1), λ =∈X • tX . From (2), λ =∈Y • tY
Equating λ’s provides ∈ • tX =∈Y • tY
Rearranging terms yields the conditions for optimal commodity taxation:

tX ∈Y
=
tY ∈X

Taxes on goods X and Y should be levied so that the ratio of tax rates is equal to the inverse ratio of the
price elasticities of demand for both goods. If the above conditions are satisfied, the excess burden of taxation
will be minimized and the revenue constraints will be met.
Although insightful, the Ramsey Rule has some limitations. The above model assumes there are only two
commodities in the economy, a rather unrealistic assumption. The analysis also becomes more complicated if
the assumption of a perfectly elastic supply curve is dropped. In this case, the expressions for the excess
burden will include a term for the price elasticity of supply. Furthermore, satisfying the above rule assumes
knowledge of the price elasticities of demand for both commodities. Finally, the above model assumes that
policy makers actually care about minimizing the deadweight loss to society when levying taxes. Much of
the literature in the field of public choice casts doubt on this assumption, arguing that government officials
attempt to generate as much revenue as possible to further their political agendas without any regard for the
efficiency costs created by taxation.
Despite several drawbacks, the model presented above illustrates the problem of optimal commodity taxation.
It nicely incorporates the concepts of efficiency and highlights the efficiency/equity tradeoff discussed in the
previous section. As an exercise, the reader may wish to perform the above analysis for a per unit tax rather
than an ad valorem tax. This requires the assumption that both a unit tax and an ad valorem tax will
generate the same amount of revenues, or T = t • P , where T is the per unit tax rate and t is the ad valorem
tax rate. Working through the above problem using per unit taxes should provide the reader the same final
expression for the optimal tax rates.

36
ii. Tax Rates, Tax Bases and Tax Revenues - The Laffer Curve
Basic microeconomic theory suggests that an increase in price reduces the quantity of the product consumed
because consumers substitute from the higher priced good to a lower priced good. Imposing a tax or increasing
a tax rate leads to a reduction in consumption as consumers substitute away from the now higher price
good. A detailed analysis of this behavior change was presented earlier in this section. The important issue
addressed here, however, is the impact this substitution away from the taxed product has on tax revenues.
Recall that the tax base is the activity being taxed - retail sales is the tax base for the sales tax, income is
the tax base for the personal income tax, etc. There is a negative relationship between tax rates and tax
bases. For example, consider yourself and the personal income tax. If the personal income tax rate was zero,
you would work a given number of hours a week, say 45 hours. As the tax rate increases (approaching 100
percent) you will slowly work fewer hours, substituting leisure for work. This substitution will continue as
tax rates are continually increased until some point where you would choose not to work at all. At this point
you will have completely substituted leisure for work. In this extreme case there is no longer a wage income
tax base.
This substitution away from the taxed activity directly impacts tax revenues. Tax revenues are equal to the
tax rate multiplied by the tax base, or R = t • B, where R = revenues, t = the tax rate, and B = the tax
base. So, if the personal income tax rate is 10 percent and personal income is $100,000, personal income tax
revenues are $10,000. Recalling the inverse relationship between tax rates and tax bases and using the above
revenue formula, the reader should see that the revenue impact of a tax change depends upon the magnitude
of the change in t or B. Suppose tax rates are increased. Holding the tax base constant, the rate increase
should increase revenues. But the tax base is not constant, and will in fact become smaller under the tax
rate increase. Thus, t rises but B falls. The final impact on revenues is not clear. If t rises more than B falls
revenues will increase, whereas if t rises less than B falls revenues will fall. An equal change in t and B will
keep revenues constant.
What the above example shows is that tax revenues are impacted by changes in the tax rate and the tax base.
The economist Arthur Laffer suggested that beyond some tax rate, higher tax rates will shrink the tax base
so much that revenues will actually decline. The Laffer curve shows the relationship between tax rates and
tax bases and their impact on revenues. The derivation of a hypothetical Laffer curve is shown in Figure 5.

The left-hand side figure shows the inverse relationship between tax rates and tax bases. A Laffer curve is
constructed using the relationship between tax rates and tax bases and the above revenue formula. At a tax
rate of zero revenues will be zero. As the tax rate initially increases, revenues increase because the initial
increase in the tax rate does not cause a greater substitution away from the taxed activity. However, as the

37
tax rate continues to increase, more individuals will substitute away from the taxed activity until at some
point, represented by point B in Figure 5, tax revenues actually begin to fall. The process also works in
reverse. At very high tax rates, revenues will be relatively low. As the tax rate falls, more people substitute
into the taxed activity, increasing the tax base. Beyond a certain point, however, the decrease in the tax rate
will be greater than the increasing tax base and revenues will fall.
The Laffer curve relationship gained much popularity in the 1980s under Ronald Reagan. His reduction in
marginal federal income tax rates from 70 percent to 33 percent was criticized as being a gift to the rich
at the expense of the poor. However, according to data from the IRS, tax revenues from the top 1 percent
of income earners actually increased by over 50 percent between 1980 and 1990. Although tax rates were
reduced, the rich as a group actually paid more in taxes under the 33 percent rate than under the 70 percent
rate because the tax reduction caused a massive increase in work and investment.
What Figure 5 and the above discussion suggest is that there is a revenue maximizing tax rate, and because
of the inverse relationship between tax rates and tax bases, generating additional revenues may not always be
obtained by simply increasing tax rates. A continual increase in tax rates by state and local officials may not
guarantee an increase in tax revenues - beyond some point tax rate revenues will actually begin to fall. Thus,
within the context of the Leviathan view of government, although governments will attempt to generate as
much revenue as possible, additional revenue is not always had by a simple increase in the tax rate.

a. Empirical Estimation of the Optimal Tax Rate Using the Laffer Curve
State and local officials should understand the relationship between tax rates, tax bases and tax revenues
when conducting tax policy. However, just an understanding of the Laffer curve may not be adequate for tax
policy. Ghaus (1995) finds that a well-defined sales tax Laffer curve does exist at the local level, and that
the optimal sales tax rate is dependent upon the property tax rate, housing preferences, the wage rate, and
income. Actually estimating a Laffer curve and finding the optimal tax rate (optimal in terms of revenue
maximization) will provide state and local officials evidence about whether an increase or decrease in rates
will cause revenue to rise or fall.
As a foundation for empirically estimating a Laffer curve, consider the following mathematical derivation for
a Laffer curve:
Tax revenues, R, are equal to the tax rate, t, times the base, B, or

R=t•B (1)

The inverse relationship (assumed linear) between tax rates and tax bases can be expressed as:

B = α − γt (2)

Substituting (2) into (1) provides:

R = t • (α − γt) = α • t − γt2 (3)

As the assumed goal of governments is to maximize revenues, differentiating (3) with respect to t
gives the following first-order condition:

δR
= α − 2 • γt = 0 (4)
δt
Note that the second derivative of (4), −2 • γ , is < 0, confirming that the optimal is indeed a maximum.
Solving (4) for the optimal tax rate, t∗ , results in the following expression:

α
t∗ = (5)
2•γ

38
Empirical estimation of a Laffer curve is based on the revenue equation (3). Specified as a linear regression
model, equation (3) for a single tax becomes:

Revenuei = δ + α taxratei + γtaxrate2i

The subscript i denotes the units of observation, such as individual counties or states. A regression of tax
revenues on the tax rate and the tax rate squared will provide estimates for the coefficients α and γ (an
overall constant term, δ, should also be included in the model). Using these estimates, the optimal tax rate
can be computed by using (5).
There are some assumptions inherent in the above methodology, however. First, equation (3) assumes only
tax rates impact tax revenues - no other explanatory variables are included in the model (see Ghaus, 1995).
Omitting relevant variables can result in biased and inconsistent estimates for and . Second, the regression
results from (3) assume that the optimal tax rate is the same over all units of observation. So for an analysis
of say, 50 counties, only one optimal tax rate for all counties can be computed. To allow optimal tax rates
to differ across units of observation, additional independent variables such as socioeconomic or government
characteristics need to be interacted with the tax rate and included in equation (3). This will provide a more
complicated expression for t∗ , but t∗ will now vary across units of observation. Third, the above regression
model assumes a cross-sectional analysis, that is, data across units of observation for a single time period.
It is also possible to have time series data on tax revenues and tax rates for a single city, county or state.
Empirical estimation is the same, except now the appropriate subscript would be a t, denoting each time
period. The optimal tax computed from a time series model would provide a single optimal rate for all time
periods included in the analysis.
The Laffer curve framework for finding the optimal tax assumes that the goal of governments is to maximize
revenues with no concern about the societal costs of taxation. Under the Ramsey Rule, the optimal tax was
found under the assumption that governments try to minimize the deadweight loss of taxation subject to
a revenue constraint. Clearly, the optimal tax for both models may not be the same given the underlying
assumptions of each model.

D. Conclusion
This section provided an introduction to the principles of tax analysis. Tax incidence was first addressed,
with an emphasis on determining the revenue burden of taxation. The key point regarding tax incidence is
that individuals who are less likely to alter their behavior to avoid the tax will bear a higher burden of the
tax. So although a tax may be initially levied on one group, if members of this group change their behavior
to avoid the tax, the final incidence of the tax will fall on other groups. After discussing tax incidence, the
inefficiencies created by taxation were discussed. This portion of the section began by first providing an
overview of efficiency and then provided graphical and mathematical derivations for the excess burden, or
deadweight loss, of taxation. The next issue addressed was the efficiency/equity tradeoff of taxation. Here,
time was spent addressing the tradeoff between efficient markets and a more equitable society. The final
sections presented the Ramsey Rule and the Laffer curve, two models of optimal taxation. Given the revenue
needs of governments and the inefficiencies of taxation, each model was used to derive an expression for the
optimal tax rate, optimal in terms of 1) minimizing the efficiency costs of taxation while subject to a revenue
constraint in the case of the Ramsey Rule, or 2) revenue maximization in terms of the Laffer curve.

39
PART 2 - SELECTED APPLICATIONS IN PUBLIC FINANCE
IV. Revenue Forecasting
A. Introduction
Revenue forecasting involves the use of analytical techniques to project the amount of financial resources
available in the future. In the public sector, revenues come from taxes, fees, license sales or intergovernmental
transfers. Forecasting attempts to identify the relationship between the factors that drive revenues (tax
rates, building permits issued, retail sales) and the revenues government collects (property taxes, user fees,
sales taxes). The ability to accurately project future resources is critical to avoiding budgetary shortfalls or
collecting excess taxes or fees. For the federal government, even small errors in projecting revenue can result
in serious budget problems such as large surpluses or deficits. Thus, revenue forecasting is fundamental to
both state and federal governments, as well as many larger municipalities. As local governments continue to
shift reliance from the property tax to user fee-based revenues, forecasting will be increasingly important to
smaller units of government and department administrators.
Revenue forecasts can apply to aggregate total revenue or to single revenue sources such as sales tax revenues
or property tax revenues. There is no single method for projecting revenues. Rather, different methods tend
to work better depending on the type of revenue. Similarly, there is no standard time-frame over which to
attempt a forecast. State government might look ahead to the next year’s budget, while managers of a city
water system may be concerned about a twenty year time horizon. Finally, revenue forecasting is intimately
tied to the public policy process and is thus subject to considerable scrutiny and even political pressure.

B. The Forecasting Process


Government fiscal policy is affected by the context in which it is formed. It deals with not only economic but
also political concerns. It is essential to establish assumptions and procedures that concerned parties agree
upon, as well as a mechanism for evaluating the validity of revenue forecasts. Thus, a disciplined process is
needed. Guajardo and Miranda (2000) suggest a seven step process. The following steps are applied to each
type of revenue to be forecast.
• The first step involves selecting a time period over which revenue data is examined. The length of time
depends on the availability and quality of data, the type of revenue to be forecasted, and the degree of
accuracy sought.
• In the second step, the data is examined to determine any patterns, rates of change, or trends that may
be evident. Patterns may suggest that the rates of change are relatively stable or changing exponentially.
Once the trend is identified, the forecaster needs to decide to what degree the revenue is predictable.
This is done by examining the underlying characteristics of the revenue, such as the rate structures
used to collect the revenue, changes in demand, or seasonal or cyclical variation.
• Forecasters next need to understand the underlying assumptions associated with the revenue source.
They need to consider to what degree the revenue is affected by economic conditions, changing citizen
demand, and changes in government policies. These assumptions help determine which forecasting
method is most appropriate.
• The next step is to actually project revenue collections in future years. The method selected to perform
the projection depends on the nature and type of revenue. Revenue sources with a high degree of
uncertainty, such as new revenues and grants or asset sales, may employ a qualitative forecasting
method, such as consensus or expert forecasting. Revenues that are generally predictable will typically
be forecast using a quantitative method, such as a trend analysis or regression analysis.
• After the projections have been made, the estimates need to be evaluated for their reliability and
validity. To evaluate the validity of the estimates, the assumptions associated with the revenue source
are re-examined. If the assumptions associated with existing economic, administrative, and political
environment are sound, the projections are assumed valid. Reliability is assessed by conducting a

40
sensitivity analysis. This involves varying key parameters used to create the estimates. If large changes
in the estimates result, the projection is assumed to have a low degree of reliability.
• In the sixth step, actual revenue collections are monitored and compared against the estimates.
Monitoring serves both to assess the accuracy of the projections and to determine whether there is
likely to be any budget shortfall or surplus.
• Finally, as conditions affecting revenue generation change, the forecast will need updating. Fluctuations
in collections may be caused by unexpected changes in economic conditions, policy and administrative
adjustments, or in patterns of consumer demand.

C. Forecasting Methods
There are a wide range of forecasting techniques available (Frank, 1993; Makridakis and Wheelwright, 1987,
1989; Guajardo and Miranda, 2000). They range from relatively informal qualitative techniques to highly
sophisticated quantitative techniques. In revenue forecasting, more sophisticated does not necessarily mean
more accurate. In fact, an experienced finance officer can often “guess” what is likely to happen with a great
deal of accuracy. In general, forecasters use a variety of techniques, recognizing that some perform better
than others depending on the nature of the revenue source.

i. Qualitative Forecasting Methods


Qualitative forecasting methods rely on judgements about future revenue collection. These techniques
are often referred to as judgmental or nonextrapolative approaches. In addition to their relatively small
dependence on numbers, these techniques frequently do not provide a rigorous specification of underlying
assumptions.

a. Judgmental Forecasting
Among the most commonly used methods of forecasting is judgmental forecasting. This technique involves
having an individual or small group of people make assessments of likely future conditions. While sounding
ad hoc, the technique can produce very good estimates, especially when experienced persons are involved.
The forecaster will utilize experience in conjunction with consideration of historical trends, current economic
conditions, and other factors relevant to the revenue source.
Judgmental approaches tend to work best when background conditions are changing rapidly. When economic,
political or administrative conditions are in flux, quantitative methods may not capture important information
about factors that are likely to alter historical patterns.
A variation of the judgmental approach is consensus forecasting. Here, experts familiar with factors
affecting a particular type of revenue meet to discuss near-term conditions in order to reach agreement about
what is likely to happen to revenue collections. For example, municipal public administrators might meet with
persons familiar with the local real estate market, economists monitoring local, state and national conditions,
and representatives of local financial institutions to come up with a consensus forecast of future building
permit applications. Consensus forecasting tends to work best when there is little historical information to
draw upon that might be used with a quantitative forecasting method.
Judgmental forecasting approaches certainly have their place among forecasting methods. To some extent, a
judgmental perspective needs to supplement any forecasting technique, even the most quantitatively rigorous
methods. As might be suspected, however, judgmental approaches can be subject to bias and other sources
of error. Guajardo and Miranda (2000) provide the following list of the major weaknesses of qualitative
forecasting methods:
• anchoring events – allowing recent events to influence perceptions about future events, e.g. the city
hosting a recent major convention influencing perceptions about future room taxes
• information availability – over-weighting the use of readily available information

41
• false correlation – forecasters incorporating information about factors that are assumed to influence
revenues, but do not
• inconsistency in methods and judgements – forecasters using different strategies over time to make their
judgements, making them less reliable
• selective perceptions – ignoring important information that conflicts with the forecaster’s view about
causal relationships
• wishful thinking – giving undue weight to what forecasters and government officials would like to see
happen
• group think – when the dynamics of forming a consensus tends to lead individuals to reinforce each
other’s views rather than maintaining independent judgements
• political pressure – where forecasters adjust estimates to meet the imperatives of budgetary constraints
or balanced budgets.

ii. Quantitative Forecasting Methods


Quantitative methods relay on numerical data relevant to the revenue source. Quantitative methods also
make explicit the assumptions and procedures used to generate forecasts. Finally, quantitative methods
will also generally assign a margin of error to forecasts, providing a indication of the degree of uncertainty
associated with the estimates.
There are two general types of quantitative forecasting methods. The first is a time series approach that
consists of a large number of techniques that generally use past trends to project future revenues. The second
general approach, while still incorporating time series data, constructs causal models that use the variables
assumed to influence the level of a particular revenue.
In general, quantitative methods do a better job of predicting future revenues than do qualitative methods
(Cirincione, et al., 1999; Makridakis and Wheelwright, 1989). Simpler quantitative methods also generally
perform as well as more complex methods (Makridakis, et al., 1984). Finally, the time series approach typically
outperforms the causal modeling approaches, at least in the near-term, given the uncertainty associated with
capturing all the relevant economic factors that influence revenue generation (Frank, 1993).

a. Time Series Approaches


Time series approaches are the “bread and butter” of forecasting. They have been used extensively in
the private sector and have been subject to substantial evaluation. Today, computer software exists that
automatically applies the appropriate technique given the characteristics of the data entered. The underlying
assumption of time series techniques is that patterns associated with past values in a data series can be used
to project future values.
In using time series techniques, Frank (1993) identifies several essential concepts that need consideration prior
to the selection of technique. The first is what constitutes a trend. This fundamentally questions how long a
data series is required for the technique to be able to identify any underlying pattern in the data. There are
no definitive guidelines as to the number of data points required in constructing a data set. Generally, the
data should cover a period of at least several years and, depending on the technique used, should include a
minimum of 24 observations and perhaps as many as 50 or more observations.
Cyclicality in time series refers to the extent to which the revenue source is influenced by general business
cycles. Again, with local governments moving away from the relatively stable and predictable property tax to
sales taxes and user fees, the need to take into consideration the effects of business cycles becomes relatively
more important.
Similarly, seasonality is another cyclic phenomenon that needs consideration. This is typically the case
when the observations are monthly or quarterly. The mathematical formulas employed can be adjusted
to determine both the degree of seasonality that may exist as well as whether seasonality is increasing or
decreasing over time.

42
Randomness is another factor that affects time series data. Randomness refers to unexpected events that
may distort trends that otherwise exist over the long-term. Events such as natural disasters, political crisis,
and the outbreak of war can result in temporary distortions in trends. Randomness can also result from
natural variations around average or typical behavior. When the data series have a constant mean and
variance over time, this is known a stationarity. Stationarity exists if the data series were divided into
several parts and the independent averages of the means and variances of each part were about equal. If the
average of each mean or variance were substantially different, nonstationarity would be suggested. When
randomness tends to characterize a data series time series techniques do not perform very well, as performing
econometric analyses on nonstationary data can often result in biased estimates.

b. Descriptions of Time Series Forecasting Models


There are a large number of time series approaches that are used in forecasting. Cirincione, et al., (1999)
discuss a number of issues in their use and provide a nice summary of a variety of techniques in an appendix
to their article. This presentation builds on the technical description found there.
1. Naive Forecasting
A naive forecasting model simply assumes the revenue available at time t is the same amount available at
time t − 1. This is also known as the random walk approach.

Ft = At−1

where Ft is the forecast at time t, and At−1 is the actual value at time t − 1.
A variation of this involves averaging the two prior periods to generate the estimate. Yet another variation
involves adjusting for any seasonality that may be present. Naive forecasting is often used when the data
series is unpredictable. It is also used in expert forecasting as the starting point for estimates that are then
adjusted mentally.
2. Moving Average Models Moving average models are probably the most commonly used time series approach
among local governments. As implied by the name, the future value to be forecast is based on the average of
N previous periods. It is a moving average because the oldest data points are dropped off as new ones are
added.
PN
At−i
Ft = i=1
N
where Ft is the forecast at time t, At−i is the actual value at time t − i, and N is the number of time periods
averaged.
The length of time to include in the average depends on the degree of variation present in the data series. To
the extent there appears a high degree of randomness in the data, a longer period is used. Similarly, to the
extent cyclicality or seasonality is present in the data, longer time periods are required. An amount of trial
and error will be needed to find the best fitting model, although new software can very rapidly identify the
time period producing the minimum forecast error. While more complex time series techniques can perform
better than the moving average, it does a reasonably good job and is often used as the benchmark against
which other methods are compared.
3. Exponential Smoothing Models The single exponential smoothing model is one of the common forecasting
techniques used in the private sector. The model is a moving average of forecasts that have been corrected
for the error observed in preceding forecasts. In the first smoothing model, there is assumed no trend or
seasonal pattern.
Ft = Ft−1 + α(At−i − Ft−1 )

where Ft is the forecast at time t, At−i is the actual value at time t − i.


The parameter α is the smoothing coefficient and has an estimated value between zero and one. It is referred
to as an exponential smoothing model because the value of tends to affect past values exponentially. As

43
α approaches one, the forecast resembles a short-term moving average, while an α closer to zero tends to
resemble long-term moving averages. Regardless of the value of α, however, exponential smoothing tends to
give more recent values higher implicit weights. Again, α is typically estimated using trial and error to secure
the best fitting model, but software today can rapidly find the model that minimizes forecast error.
4. The Holt Model The single parameter smoothing model presented above can be adapted to take into
account trends that may be present in the data. The form presented here is called the Holt Model. In addition
to the smoothing parameter estimated in the exponential smoothing model, a parameter representing the
trend is also estimated.
Following the exposition found in Cirincione, et al. (1999), the forecast at time t for k periods into the
future equals the level of the series at t plus the product of k and the trend at time t. The level of series is
estimated as a function of the actual value of the series at time t, the level of the series at a previous time,
and the estimated trend at a previous time. The parameter is a smoothing coefficient. The trend at time t is
estimated to be a function of the smoothed value of the change in level between the two time periods and
the estimated trend for the previous time period. The values for the smoothing parameters, α and β, are
between zero and one.

Ft+k = St + kT
St = αAt + (1 − α)(St−1 + Tt−1 )
Tt = β(St − St−1 ) + (1 − β)Tt−1

where Ft+k is the forecast at time k periods in the future, At is the actual value at time t, St is the level of
the series at time t, Tt is the trend at time t, and α and β are smoothing parameters.
5. Damped Trend Exponential Smoothing While the Holt Model takes into consideration the trend that may
be inherent in the data series, it somewhat unrealistically assumes the trend continues in perpetuity. This
means it can overshoot estimates several time periods in the future. A variation known as damped trend
exponential smoothing has the effect of dampening the trend as time continues into subsequent periods. It
includes a third parameter, Φ, with a value between zero and one that specifies a rate of decay in the trend.
k
X
Ft+k = St + φTt
i=1
St = αAt + (1 − α)(St−1 + φTt−1 )
Tt = β(St − St−1 ) + (1 − β)φTt−1

where Ft+k is the forecast at time k periods in the future, At is the actual value at time t, St is the level of
the series at time t, Tt is the trend at time t, and ,α, β, φ are smoothing parameters.
6. Holt-Winter’s Linear Seasonal Smoothing This model adapts Holt’s method to include a seasonal
component in addition to a smoothing coefficient and a trend parameter. The first variant of the model is
additive. This assumes the seasonality is constant over the series being forecast.

Ft+k = St + kTt + It−p+k


St = St−1 + Tt−1 + α(At − St−1 − Tt−1 − It−s )
Tt = Tt−1 + αβ(At − St−1 − Tt−1 − It−s )
It = It−s + δ(1 − α)(At − St−1 − Tt−1 − It−s )

where Ft+k is the forecast at time k periods in the future, At is the actual value at time t, St is the level
of the series at time t, Tt is the trend at time t, It is the seasonal index at time t, s is the seasonal index

44
counter, and α, β, δ and are smoothing parameters.

Ft+k = (St + kTt )It−p+k


α
St = St−1 + Tt−1 + (At − IT −S (St−1 + Tt−1 ))
It−s
αβ
Tt = Tt−1 + (At − It−s (St−1 + Tt−1 ))
It−s
S(1 − α)
It = It−s + (At − It−s (St−1 + Tt−1 ))
St
The multiplicative variant of this model assumes that the seasonality is changing over the length of the series.
Incorporating seasonality, of course, increases the data requirements – typically three to four years of monthly
data. The model is also quite complex, estimating smoothing, trend and seasonal parameters simultaneously.
Because of these difficulties, many communities use simpler methods such as single or double exponential
smoothing methods.
7. Box-Jenkins ARIMA Models ARIMA is an acronym for autoregressive integrated moving average.
Autoregressive and moving average refer to two of the components of the model, while integrated refers to
the process of translating the calculations into a metric that can be interpreted.
ARIMA modeling has three components (Frank, 1993). In the model identification stage, the forecaster
must decide whether the time series is autoregressive, moving average, or both. This is usually done by
visually inspecting diagrams of the data or employing various statistical techniques. In the second stage,
model estimation and diagnostic checks, the forecaster verifies the original model identification is correct.
This requires subjecting the model to a variety of diagnostics. If the model checks out, the forecaster then
proceeds to the third stage, forecasting.
The principle advantage of using the ARIMA approach is that the method can generate confidence intervals
around the forecasts. This actually serves as another check of the validity of the model. If it predicts a high
degree of confidence about a dubious forecast, the modeler may have to respecify the form of the model.
In order to achieve best results using the Box-Jenkins ARIMA approach, three assumptions need be met.
The first is the generally accepted threshold of 50 data points. This tends to be a significant obstacle for
many local governments who may collect data only annually for some types of revenue.
The second assumption is that the data series is stationary, i.e. that the data series varies around a constant
mean and variance. Running a regression on two non-stationary variables can result in spurious results. If
the data is non-stationary, the data series needs differencing and/or the addition of a time trend. If the data
is trend non-stationary only, then adding a linear time trend to the model will render the series stationary.
Trend non-stationary data have a mean and variance that change over time by a constant amount. If the
data is first-difference non-stationary, then first differencing of the data will render the series stationary.
Differencing involves subtracting the observation in time t by the observation in time t-1 for all observations.
Whether the data requires these types of treatment should become apparent at the identification stage, and
is generally easily accomplished with econometric software programs.
The third assumption of ARIMA models is that the series be homoscedastic, i.e. has a constant variance.
If the amplitude of the variance around the mean is great even after differencing, the series is considered
heteroscedastic. The remedy for this problem may be simple or complex and involves measures such as using
the natural logarithm of the data, using square or cubed roots, or truncating the data series (cutting out
certain values).
The first component of the ARIMA process is the autoregressive component. The autoregressive component
predicts future values based on a linear combination of prior values. An autoregressive process of order p can
be shown as:
Ft = α1 At−1 + α2 At−2 + . . . + αp At−p
where Ft is the predicted value at time t, At−p is the actual value at time t, and αp ’s are the estimated
parameters.

45
The moving average component provides forecasts based on prior forecasting errors. The moving average
component of a model for a q-order process can be shown as:

Ft = β1 εt + β2 εt−1 + . . . + βp εt−q

where Ft is the predicted value at time t, εt−q is the forecast error at time t, and the βp ‘s are the estimated
parameters.
These two components together form autoregressive moving average (ARMA) models. ARMA models assume
a stationary data series before first differencing or the inclusion of a time trend. If a series has been rendered
trend or difference stationary, the above models form the Box-Jenkins ARIMA model (Box and Jenkins, 1976).
The number of autoregressive and moving average lags in an ARIMA model is represented as ARIMA(p, d, q),
where d is the degree of difference, i.e. d=1 if the data is first differenced, d=2 if the data is second differenced,
etc. If d=0, the ARIMA model is an ARMA(p, q). Further derivations can also take into account seasonality
by considering autoregressive or moving average trends that occur at certain points in time. In the case
of seasonality the ARIMA model is expressed as ARIMA(p, d, q)(P, Q) where P is the number of seasonal
autoregressive lags and Q is the number of seasonal moving average lags. Seasonality is a consideration with
relatively frequent data, such as weekly, monthly, or possibly quarterly data.
8. Causal Models Causal forecasting models generally tend to be among the more complex techniques, having
large data requirements and requiring a high degree of statistical skill. These approaches tend to work best
for revenues that are heavily influenced by economic factors, such as business license fees, income taxes, and
retail sales taxes. Thus, external data representing relevant economic performance indicators are used to
predict the level of revenue expected. Some of the common economic information incorporated into these
models include local population, income, and price information (Wong ,1995).
The complexity of causal models varies. The simplest type would be a simple linear regression model that
might attempt to project revenue as a function of time, for example. Multiple regression models incorporate
any number of relevant explanatory variables, including important policy variables as binary dummy variables.
Binary variables take the value of one if a specific time period is represented and a value of zero otherwise.
To illustrate, following Cirincione et al. (1999), four common regression models employing ordinary least
squares can be show as:

Ft = α + β1 T1
Ft = α + β1 T1 + β2 Tt2
Ft = α + β1 T1 + γ1 D1 + γ2 D2 + . . . + γs Ds
Ft = α + β1 T1 + β2 Tt2 + γ1 D1 + γ2 D2 + . . . + γs Ds

where Ft is the predicted value at time t, Tt is the value of the time at time t, Tt2 is the squared value of
time at time t, β1 is the linear trend parameter associated with time, β2 is the quadratic trend parameter
associated with time squared, Ds is a binary dummy variable for each of the s seasons, and γ is the parameter
value associated with each season. The estimated values on the dummy variables reveal the average level of
the dependent variable during the designated time period. Testing the equality of the dummy coefficients can
reveal whether there are significant differences in the average level of the dependent variable across seasonal
periods.
Econometric forecasts are structured similar to regression equations, but can include estimates of change
across multiple dimensions. Thus, complex events and relationships can be modeled where the output from
one equation is fed into another equation as they are solved simultaneously. The types of revenue for which
econometric forecasts are most useful include corporate tax, personal income tax, real estate tax, sales tax,
and user charges and fees, such as building and construction permits.

D. Conclusion
This brief overview of revenue forecasting belies the fact that forecasting is a major field of economics. The
intricacies and variations can not be represented thoroughly in a brief section. Yet, for those concerned with

46
public finance, the topic is one of growing importance, especially at the municipal level. While some of these
techniques are likely beyond the capability of local government managers, improvements in computer software
and assistance available from universities and outreach providers increases the plausibility of using these tools
even in smaller units of government.

47
V. Cost-Benefit Analysis
When choosing any course of action, a person inherently performs cost-benefit analysis. The notion is one
of assessing alternative available courses, anticipating the positive (benefit) and negative (cost) impacts
associated with the alternatives, and selecting the course that provides the greatest net benefit. In making
decisions related to public spending, the process is much the same. More formally, it is a process intended
to enhance social decision-making related to the efficient allocation of scarce public resources. Typically,
cost-benefit analyses (CBA) are used in the selection of alternative policies related to programs, projects or
regulations.

A. Steps in Performing Cost-Benefit Analysis


Conceptually, the steps in performing a CBA are simple. Boardman, et al. (1996) list them as shown in
Table 1. As might be expected,however, actually doing each step can be very difficult. Each of these steps
and a few of the issues associated with completing a CBA will be discussed in greater detail in this section.

i. Identifying Stakeholders to the Analysis


The analyst begins by deciding whose costs and benefits will be counted, i.e. who has “standing.” In reality,
this is often determined by the project sponsor, and can be a contentious issue. The project sponsor typically
is concerned about how a project will affect the sponsoring jurisdiction. Project impacts, however, often spill
over space and time, causing what are often called externalities. Acid rain caused by coal-fired generators,
for example, can cause problems across state and national borders. Similarly, use of fossil fuels today may
preclude options for energy generation in the future.

Table 1. Basic Steps of a Cost-Benefit Analysis

1. Determine which stakeholders will be included in the analysis


2. Identify the alternative policies to be considered
3. Identify the likely physical impacts and select the appropriate measurement indicators
4. Predict the impacts over the life of the project
5. Attach a dollar amount to all of the impacts
6. Find the present value of the dollar amounts over time
7. Add up the costs and benefits
8. Perform a sensitivity analysis of the results
9. Select the alternative with the largest net social benefits
Source: Boardman, Greenberg, Vining and Weimer, 1996, page 7.

ii. Identify Alternative Policies to be Included


The alternative policies need to be evaluated relative to the status quo. Generally, a project sponsor will
have well-defined alternatives in mind. But, depending how the problem is stated, the alternatives can be
almost infinite. If the question is “should we build a highway?” the analysis is fairly straightforward. If the
question is “how do we solve our transportation needs?” the task becomes much more complex. Generally,
the project sponsors will have used other means of decision-making to narrow the choices to one or a few.

iii. Identify Likely Physical Impacts and Indicators


All of the anticipated impacts (positive and negative) need to be identified and quantified in some form.
In CBA, the perspective is homocentric, i.e. from the perspective of human values. Generally, we need to
know something about cause-effect relationships. In many cases, the relationships and impacts are fairly

48
straightforward, e.g. if we build the highway, we reduce the numbers of miles traveled, we increase the time
saved, reduce the lives lost, and spend so much money.
In other cases, neither the nature of the relationship nor the type of impact is readily known. Whether a
given program will reduce crime, for example, is difficult to anticipate because the causal factors underpinning
crime are varied and not well understood. Sometimes, we need proxy indicators for the impacts of interest,
e.g. reductions in the number of convictions as opposed to reduced crime. Similarly, if an animal species is
generally considered an indicator of the health of an ecosystem, valuing a reduction of ecosystem viability is
a difficult task. There are times people will look at the same information and interpret it in exactly opposite
ways.

iv. Predict the Impacts over the Life of the Project


Most public projects will extend over a period of time. The next task is to quantify the impacts over the life
of the project and beyond if residual effects are expected. Here again, our ability to predict the future is
at question. Most of the texts on CBA discuss relationships in theoretical or hypothetical terms, but very
few studies of how well a CBA actually anticipates the future impacts have been performed. Some of the
common errors in performing CBA’s are identified later in this section.

v. Monetize All of the Impacts


A dollar amount needs to be assigned to all of the anticipated impacts. The challenge is valuing impacts that
are intuitively important but for which there are no markets or only poorly functioning markets to observe.
Environmental impacts and impacts to human health and well-being are two cases in point.

vi. Find the Present Value of Dollar Amounts


For any project that extends over a period of years, all dollar amounts assigned need to be converted into a
common metric. Future costs and benefits need to be discounted to obtain a present value . This is done
to compare our choice of consuming resources now versus deferring that consumption to some future time.
Given our assumption the CBA applies to public decision-making, we need to establish a social discount
rate . Here again, determining the aggregate value all of a jurisdiction’s affected citizens place on current
versus future consumption is very difficult. While there are a number of theoretical considerations that can
be brought to bear on the question, there is no agreement on what social discount rate should be applied
for a given type of project. For this reason, we generally present results subject to a sensitivity analysis to
demonstrate how alternative discount rates affect valuation.

vii. Add up the Costs and Benefits


The basic decision rule for CBA is simple. In the case of a single project, add up the net present value of the
costs and benefits and, if the benefits minus the costs are greater than zero, go ahead with the project. If two
or more project alternatives are being considered, select the one with the higher positive net present value.
Some advocate using alternative criterion for the decision rule. Sometimes results are reported as an internal
rate of return or a benefit-cost ratio. Both the internal rate of return and the benefit-cost ratio can lead to
erroneous conclusions, however, while use of the net present value of social benefits always yields a correct
answer. Where disagreements typically arise is whether all the social costs and benefits have been monetized
and summed. In cases where it is not possible to reach agreements about the value of a benefit or cost, it
may be appropriate to use an alternative analysis method such as a cost-effectiveness analysis.

viii. Perform a Sensitivity Analysis


The use of sensitivity analysis in the context of CBA is to deal with uncertainties. A sensitivity analysis
simply means inserting alternatives from a range of values related to unknown or uncertain parameters. For
example, if it is uncertain how many lives an intervention will save, a range of numbers can be entered and
compared to the cost. Any number of CBA components can be subject to sensitivity analysis, including who

49
has standing and with what weight, the social discount rate used, or any of the parameters where there is
uncertainty or disagreement.

ix. Select the Preferred Alternative


Finally, the analyst recommends the alternative with the highest positive net present value of social benefits.
It should be kept in mind this is a normative judgement based on an efficiency consideration. Thus, in the
political process of policy choices, decision-makers may choose other alternatives. Here, the analyst is best
advised to present a recommendation rather than a decision.

B. Theoretical Foundations in Cost-Benefit Analysis


There are a number of concepts that help guide the analyst in performing CBA. In this section, we explore
some of the basic assumptions inherent in this type of analysis, including allocative efficiency, willingness-
to-pay, and opportunity costs. Thus far, we have referred to CBA as a means to identify the most efficient
alternative policy or project. Here, we discuss what we mean by efficiency in the allocation of resources with
a few basic concepts from welfare economics.
A simple and compelling concept in welfare economics is the notion of Pareto efficiency. An allocation of
goods is said to be efficient if no alternative allocation scheme will make at least one person better off
without making anyone else worse off. Intuitively, this would be the best alternative in social decision-making,
even if in practice this would be extremely difficult to know. Thus, we equate the notion of the highest net
present value with Pareto efficiency by use of two related concepts: willingness-to-pay and opportunity costs.

Willingness-to-pay is the amount of money a person would be willing to pay to get or avoid something
other than the status quo. The aggregation of all stakeholder’s willingness-to-pay is what is sought in
identifying the net benefits of the policy. If someone were made worse off as the result of the change, we
can introduce the notion of compensation to bring them back to at least the same level of well-being even
if others’ well-being was improved as a result of the policy. If, after performing the analysis, there are any
estimated net benefits, this would imply that the proposed change would be a Pareto improvement over the
status quo.

50
In valuing costs and benefits, the notion of opportunity costs is critical. The opportunity cost of using a
resource is the cost of not using a resource in its next best alternative use. This is functionally what has
to be given up to pursue the policy of interest. If the aggregate opportunity costs exceed the aggregate
willingness-to-pay of stakeholders, the net benefits would be less than zero and the policy would not be a
Pareto improvement.
Using these concepts, we would suggest that if all impacts were measured as an aggregate willingness-to-pay,
and all resources used as inputs into the policy were valued as opportunity costs, an analysis showing a net
present value would imply that it was at least theoretically possible to compensate those who had to give
something up with policy implementation and still make someone better off. Thus, the policy change would
be Pareto efficient. In practice, we apply this rule by suggesting we adopt only policies that have positive net
present benefits. When one policy affects another, we would seek the combination of policies with highest net
benefits. When policies are mutually exclusive, we choose the one with the highest net benefits.

C. Net Present Value


Many public programs are implemented over the course of years. Taking time into account when we estimate
the value of costs and benefits associated with a project is essential. Not only are we concerned about the
effects of inflation, time also influences how we perceive the value of money. Discounting is fundamental to
CBA, and calculating the correct discount rate can make all the difference in the outcome of an analysis. We
discount future values to determine a net present value .
The net present value criterion suggests proceeding with the project if the net present value is positive if the
alternative is the status quo, or to proceed with the project alternative with the largest net present value.
Thus far, we have been ignoring the effects of inflation; we have only considered the time value of money.
Of course, the purchasing power of money declines over time with price inflation. The question arises as to
whether it is best to express the financial information presented in nominal dollars or in inflation-adjusted
real dollars.
While some analysts use nominal dollars in CBA, in public sector financial analysis it is probably best to
express the information in real dollars. The financial information to be dealt with is usually more intuitively
clear when expressed in real terms. When working with real dollars, however, it the becomes necessary to
apply a real discount rate rather than a nominal discount rate.
Because of uncertainties related to what discount rate to apply, and because the discount rate chosen can
have a substantial affect on the outcome of a CBA, it is generally appropriate to subject the discount rate to
a sensitivity analysis by varying it within a range of values.

D. Estimating Values
In many cases, estimating the values of costs or benefits is fairly straight-forward. Project expediters
can estimate construction costs with a great deal of accuracy, notable exceptions on some public projects
notwithstanding. Similarly, we can infer a great deal where we can make direct observations of behavior
in undistorted private markets. Many times, however, directly observable behavior is not readily available.
Further, there are no markets for many goods, such as pollution, or the markets are imperfect. This section
provides an introductory discussion of some concepts, methods, and issues associated with establishing values
for costs and benefits.

i. Social Surplus
In the private sector, a reasonable measure of benefit to a producer is simply net profit. The producer deducts
from gross sales the cost of goods sold plus taxes. The money remaining after paying these bills would be
considered the “surplus” to the producer. This surplus has a value – the profit. It is measurable, meaningful,
and can be aggregated across many producers. Thus, we equate the notion of a cost or benefit in terms of
changes in surplus, all of which can be conceptually linked to the notion of willingness-to-pay. In this case,

51
for the opportunity to change the producer’s “surplus,” his willingness to pay would be exactly equal to the
amount of the profit.
For public projects, valuing costs and benefits is not so simple. To the extent a project affects private
producers, the analyst would be interested in measuring changes in producer surplus. But, public projects
are often intended to benefit consumers (citizens), as well. To the extent a project benefits non-producers, we
are also interested in measuring consumer surplus. The CBA attempts to capture changes for both groups.
Together, the sum of producer and consumer surplus is social surplus, and this concept is what the analyst is
trying to measure.

If there existed perfect markets for all goods and services, and supply and demand curves were known,
measuring social surplus would be easy. Unfortunately, markets do not always work perfectly, for many types
of goods markets do not exist, and we seldom have sufficient information to accurately depict supply and
demand curves. Thus, we use a variety of methods to approximate markets to estimate supply and demand.

ii. Estimating Values in Cost-Benefit Analysis


There are a variety of methods to estimate the values of costs and benefits associated with public projects.
Sometimes, a demonstration project or social experiment is conducted, studied and extrapolated to a larger
initiative. In other cases, costs are estimated based on observations, or inferred from survey information or
secondary data sources. This section will explore several of the basic methods used for estimating values in
CBA.

a. Values from Observed Behavior


There are a number of practical methods available to estimate values based on observable behavior. These

52
methods focus principally on changes in consumer surplus. Several are briefly outlined in this section.
1. Project Revenues as Benefits
In the private sector, counting revenues generated by a project as benefits makes sense. Project revenues
may undercount the value of the benefits of public projects, however, because they do not consider changes
in social surplus. In the example of introducing electricity to a remote area, we would grossly undervalue
benefits if we only counted government-subsidized rates. Clearly, residents of the area would experience
benefits beyond the fees generated if the alternative was no electricity. Project revenues, therefore, are not
always a good indicator of benefit.
2. Estimating Demand Curves
If we have information about the quantity of a good demanded at different prices, it may be possible to make
a direct estimation of the consumer demand curve (Barnett, 1988). For example, if we have data related to
changes in bus ridership at various fare rates, we have all the information needed to estimate the consumer
demand curve using econometrics – price of the service, quantity of rides demanded, the elasticity of demand
at various prices. We can extrapolate from the available data the marginal benefit to the consumer of the
service at a given price with a reasonable degree of confidence.
3. Market Analogy
For many public goods and services, there is no well-functioning market. Public education, recreational
facilities, and many types of health services are cases in point. We can look for a private sector equivalent
to extrapolate to the public sector, such as observing the prices paid at private universities, private camp
sites, or private health care providers. Sometimes, it may even be possible to use information gathered from
informal (illegal) markets when no legal private market exists.
4. Intermediate Goods
Governments sometimes produce goods that are used as inputs into production. An agricultural irrigation
project is a good example. In a reasonably well-functioning agricultural commodities market, we can observe
the incomes of dry-land versus irrigated farming producers. After taking into account the relative differences
in input costs, we can reasonably estimate the “value added” to agricultural production associated with the
government irrigation project.
5. Asset Values
Government projects can sometimes affect the price of assets such as land and capital. Once again, agriculture
is a good case to illustrate this point. Land values will be quite different between land having access to
irrigation water and land without. Similarly, differences in the market value of comparable homes near an
airport versus those more distant can provide an indication of the value of a negative externality such as
noise.
6. Hedonic Pricing
Building on the methods previously outlined, hedonic price functions use a regression method to value
attributes that affect asset values, such as the value of a scenic vista in a housing market (Rosen, 1974). The
method would first estimate the additional value of a house with a marginally better view, holding other
factors that affect values constant. Secondly, willingness-to-pay is estimated, controlling for income and other
socioeconomic factors. Using this method, consumer surplus can be estimated for projects that might improve
or worsen a scenic vista.
7. Travel Cost Method
The travel cost method recognizes that the fees generated by an event or facility are only a small part of a
consumers’ willingness-to-pay. To enjoy the experience of a visit to a national park, for example, people will
forego the opportunity to work, travel great distances, and incur significant food and lodging expenses. Thus,
the value of the experience will exceed the gate admission many times over. The travel cost method uses the
total cost of the trip, instead of the admission price, as an explanatory variable in estimating demand. As
might be expected, this method is most often used in recreation-related studies.

53
8. Defensive Expenditures
Many people are willing to take defensive action in response to a situation (Bartik, 1988). For example,
people will install home water purification systems or purchase bottled water in response to concerns related
to water quality. If government takes action to maintain or improve water quality, some people will forego
the expense they previously incurred. We can value water quality by observing the full costs incurred to take
defensive action, and the value of government intervention by observing the changes in defensive behavior.

b. Contingent Valuation
Sometimes, there are no markets or proxies available with which to infer a value. In such instances it may be
necessary to elicit people’s perceptions of value using survey methods. The survey methods used in CBA are
referred to as contingent valuation.
There are a number of survey techniques available to elicit people’s estimates of value (Bishop and Heberline,
1990; Cummings, et al., 1986). Open-ended questionnaires will simply ask how much a person would be
willing to pay for a good. Closed-ended iterative bidding surveys specify a specific but variable amount
and inquire whether a person would be willing to pay it. A third type of survey will ask people to rank
order specific combinations of quantities of a good and associated payments. The dichotomous-choice
method randomly assigns a price to a given quantity of a good, and people are asked whether they would be
willing to pay the amount. Finally, there are several variations of the payment card method where people
indicate a willingness to pay based on comparable goods or based on the hypothetical maximum amount they
would pay. All of these approaches have been used with in-person interviews, telephone surveys and mail
surveys (Mitchell and Carson, 1989).
As with all survey techniques, contingent valuation methods are subject to a number of potential problems
(Hausman, 1993; Arrow, et al., 1993), including sample bias, non-response bias, and interviewer bias. In
addition, contingent valuation methods have been criticized as being inaccurate in establishing a true
willingness-to-pay. One of the principal criticisms is that a person’s response to a hypothetical situation may
be quite different than their response if faced with the reality of actually having to pay. Similarly, it can be
very difficult to establish a meaningful context for the provision of a public good. A person would be willing
to pay very different amounts to cross a bridge to go to a movie versus getting to a hospital emergency room.
Contingent valuation methods are frequently used in valuing environmental resources (Bateman and Willis,
1999). In this application, it has proven difficult to establish a context for questioning that people with
differing views agree is neutral.
Given the hypothetical nature of the situations described in contingent valuation surveys, there have also
been concerns related to respondents’ inability to adjust their views by learning. We may think we value
a good accurately, but may change that view after having had experience in its actual consumption. In
marketing, it is well known that people tend to overvalue items with which they have had no prior experience.
There are a number of other criticisms related to contingent valuation methods. Each of the survey techniques
has inherent strengths and weaknesses. In general, there is less criticism of contingent valuation methods
when the survey is conducted while the respondent is actually engaged in the behavior of interest, as when
recreating. Conversely, there is a great deal of controversy associated with studies that employ “non-use” or
hypothetical situations. Clearly, a great deal of care is needed to conduct valid contingent valuation studies.

c. Shadow Prices
As the previous sections imply, conducting a CBA can be complex, costly, and time consuming. Whatever
can be done to simplify and speed up completion of the study is generally accepted. Thus, many analysts
adapt the results of previous research for use in CBA. Using values associated with preexisting studies is
referred to as using shadow prices . A considerable amount of work has been conducted in three areas
where it would otherwise be very difficult to estimate a value: the value of life, the value of time , and the
negative values associated with particular crimes.

54
The table from Boardman et al. 1996, summarizes the results of major work in establishing various shadow
prices frequently used in CBA. The wide variance of the values reported in the studies represented suggest
the difficulty and imprecision with which we are currently able to establish such values.

E. Common Errors in Cost-Benefit Analyses


Invariably, errors occur when the task is to predict the future. Yet, there is considerable benefit in trying
to anticipate the likely consequences of alternative courses of action in a rigorous fashion. It is legitimate
to question how good our CBA methods actually perform. Few have taken the effort to compare CBA
predictions with the actual outcomes. Despite the paucity of evidence, we can identify some of the common
errors that have been observed in CBA (Boardman, et al.,1996; Rosen, 1985).

i. Errors of Omission
Errors of omission can arise from several sources. The first may be with whose interests we are concerned.
Without adequate consideration or concern about who is affected by externalities, both costs and benefits
may be undercounted. Similarly, some potential impacts may be considered either so remote or uncertain
they are not counted at all. Such may be the case with industry air quality regulations and global warming.

ii. Forecasting Errors


There are a host of difficulties in forecasting future events. Generally, as the complexity of the project and
the time horizon of the forecast increases, errors are more likely. Anticipating the rate of technical change or
comprehending cause-effect relationships make forecasting difficult. Similarly, when the project is large, it is
not uncommon for specifications to evolve over time.

iii. Measurement Errors


Even measuring events in the present is subject to the limitations of our measuring devices, the accuracy with
which they are used, and our capacity to statistically analyze and interpret results. It is easy to forget the
limitations of our primary data-gathering techniques and secondary data sources, and then further compound
errors though data analysis.

iv. Valuation Errors


As indicated in earlier sections, the capacity to generate values associated with impacts is difficult and
imprecise. Many of our measurement techniques are problematic, and their use is sometimes flawed. Similarly,
the stock of available information related to shadow prices is relatively scarce. The range of values calculated
across studies and methods attests to the imprecision of our current knowledge.

v. Indirect Impacts
In some cases, indirect economic impacts are counted as additional benefits, while indirect costs are ignored.
If there is an effort to trace secondary and other tertiary impacts on the positive side to enhance the benefits,
a similar effort is needed to trace the costs. In most cases, the effects are offsetting without a significant
change in the net result (Rosen, 1985).

vi. Double-Counting
Double-counting is the opposite of the error by omission. Here, too many impacts are counted. In the case
where a project both increases the value of land and the income generated by farming it, both should not be
counted. In a competitive market, the value of the land is equal to the present value of the income generated
by farming it. Counting increased land value and increased farm income represents double-counting.

55
vii. The Value of Labor
The value of labor associated with a government-funded project, such as road building, is sometimes counted
as a benefit. The labor purchased with public funding should be considered a cost to the project, unless the
new labor was formerly from the ranks of the long-term unemployed.

F. Conclusion
The utility of cost-benefit analysis is that it introduces the notion of comprehensively accounting for the
positive and negative impacts associated with public projects. It introduces a methodology that fosters rigor
in thinking. Clearly, this represents an improvement over much state and local policy-making that is based
on supposition and ideology.
The techniques associated with CBA are far from perfect, but there continue to be advances in technique
and application. Still, it remains the responsibility of the analyst to employ the theory and techniques in
a conscientious manner and help policy-makers understand the full impact of the decisions made. Even if
applied in only a partial fashion, cost-benefit analysis can help state and local government officials improve
the quality of decision-making.

56
VI. Fiscal Impact Analysis
Fiscal impact analysis is concerned with the tangible effects of a policy or event on public sector costs and
revenues. Fiscal impact analysis is frequently used in the context of local decision-making related to land use
changes, such as new housing or business development. It can help local policy-makers determine whether
the public benefits of a development proposal or land use policy outweigh the public costs, thereby enhancing
local fiscal conditions. Alternatively, it can help establish fair and equitable impact fees for developments
that demonstrate a fiscal deficit.
In this section, we discuss common fiscal impact analysis techniques. The three types of analyses included
are planning approaches, case studies, and econometric approaches. We provide a brief overview of each
approach and discuss some of the considerations in their use. While we focus on public sector finance, each of
the approaches can be adapted for use with other types of local impacts associated with economic events and
policies, including social and demographic impacts.

A. Planning Approaches
Robert Burchell, David Listokin and their colleagues are probably the best known for their periodic summaries
of the evolving state-of-the-art techniques in applied fiscal impact analysis (1978, 1980, 1994). They provide a
practical guide to a series of approaches used by planners and other practitioners who deal with development
proposals. Their focus is at the municipal and school district levels, attempting to estimate how population
and employment changes are likely to affect demand for public services and generate local government
revenues. Thus, the task is to estimate how a particular type of development is likely to affect local population
(number of residents, employment and school-aged children) and to translate those changes into public service
costs and public sector revenues. Here, we focus on the use of various multiplier approaches they outline.

i. Projecting Population
There are several ways to project population increases associated with development based on the use of
demographic multipliers. In the case of a residential development proposal, we are interested in estimating
the number of new residents and public school-aged children. For non-residential development proposals, we
are interested in the number of new employees to be hired. The demographic multipliers are obtained from
either national standards for population and school-aged children by housing type, or from local surveys.
In the case of non-residential development, national standards are also available for employment by type of
establishment, typically expressed as employees per thousand square feet. Changes in employment, then,
would be used to project changes in population and school-aged children, based on assumptions of new worker
in-migration and commuting patterns. While locally-derived multipliers are clearly preferable, gathering the
necessary data can be a formidable challenge.

ii. Projecting Costs


The next task is to translate the estimated population, school children and employment changes into public
service costs. Burchell and Listokin (1978, 1980) identify several methods that may be appropriate, depending
on the type of community, the type of proposed development, and the existing service capacity in the
municipality and school district. In general, in moderate-sized cities (10,000 to 50,000) with relatively stable
growth patterns and some excess service capacity, average service cost methods do a reasonably good job of
projecting expenditures associated with “typical” business development/housing projects. In larger, older
cities or rapidly growing suburban/urban communities that have either significant excess or deficient capacity,
a marginal service cost method is more appropriate. Marginal cost methods would also be appropriate where
the project would be considered atypical in employment or household patterns.
The average cost method simply calculates the average cost per unit of service and multiplies this cost by the
number of new units (housing, pupils, workers) generated by the project. This assumes the project does not
generate demands that cross a threshold requiring major capital investments for such things as upgrading the
sewer system or building new schools. Average cost methods include per capita multipliers, service standards,
and proportional valuation.

57
The per capita multiplier is the most common average cost approach. Simply, it is the current per capita
or per unit cost of providing services multiplied by the projected new population or housing unit increment.
For the school district, total annual school costs or the total local tax levy would be divided by the district
enrollment to obtain an average cost/tax levy per pupil.
Residential and nonresidential service costs are obtained by first apportioning a share of total municipal service
costs to residential development versus business development. This is done by averaging two proportional
values. The first is the ratio of residential to total parcels in the community. The second is the proportion of
residential to total assessed valuation in the community. The average of these two ratios creates a factor to
divide service costs between residential and nonresidential development. A cost per person for new residents
and a cost per worker can then be applied to the projected increases.
Other less frequently used average cost approaches include the service standard and proportional valuation
methods. The service standard method applies information from the U.S. Census of Governments to
derive ratios of staffing and capital expenditures per person for several municipal functions. There are several
sources for data related to service standards by municipal population size (Burchell, et al., 1994).
The proportional valuation method is applied to “typical” nonresidential development. It simply appor-
tions a share of municipal service costs based on the proportion of new property valuation to total municipal
valuation. This method does not work well with either very large or small development projects, or those
that otherwise have an unusual employment pattern.
A marginal cost approach is more suitable in cases where there is either substantial deficient or excess service
capacity, rapidly changing population, or the project is somehow atypical. It is also appropriate whenever
there is need for a more intimate understanding of how the project is likely to affect municipal finance.
Marginal cost approaches include the case study approach, the comparable city method, and the employment
anticipation method.
As the name implies, the case study approach requires carefully investigating the impacts of the development
and the current municipal service capacity. Interviews would be conducted with municipal service managers
and school district officials to get a better estimate of costs than can be derived using an average cost. In
older, stable cities with established infrastructure, the additional increment of service may have a marginal
cost near zero. In rapidly growing fringe communities, the thresholds tipping new infrastructure investments
may be readily crossed. Additional comments on case study approaches are offered later in this section.
The comparable city method is used in cases similar to where the case study approach is appropriate, but
is simpler to employ. It involves using city and school district expenditure ratios derived from U.S. Census
of Governments data categorized by cities of comparable population and growth rates. Where a pending
economic change is going to alter the municipal size category and historic growth rate, the ratio of the new
city class/growth multiplier to the old multiplier is multiplied by existing per capita expenditures to estimate
new expenditures.
Finally, the employment anticipation method is a regression technique that predicts changes in employ-
ment and is appropriate for nonresidential development projects, particularly those with unusual employment
patterns. Preexisting per capita public service multipliers by type of business are available (Burchell, et al.,
1994). The analyst might simply apply one of these preexisting multipliers or create a regression model to
use with a particular community. More will be said about utilizing econometric methods later in this section.

iii. Projecting Revenues


Economic policies and events also affect municipal and school district revenues. Burchell, et al (1994) identify
the following own-source and intergovernmental revenues that may be affected:

58
Table 1 - Common Municipal Tax Revenues
Own Source Revenues Own Source Revenues
Taxes Charges, Fees and Miscellaneous
real property interest, rents, royalties
personal property licences and permits
utility charges for services
income fines
other sales of fixed assets
other
Intergovernmental Revenues
State Aid
Federal Aid
Source: Burchell, Listokin, Dolphin, Newton and Foxley, 1994, page 131.

The analyst needs to consider the basis for each type of revenue. Many revenues are formula-driven, and
the projection requires applying the appropriate rate to the expected change. For example, total assessed
valuation changes are multiplied by the current real property tax rate. Similarly, many state and federal
aids are distributed on a per capita basis and expected population changes would be inserted into the aid
distribution formula. Of course, many aid formulas, such as those applied to school district funding, may be
quite complex and change over time.
Other types of revenues are generated by changes in the population. Historical trends in taxable retail sales,
user fees, or fines can be charted, converted to a per capita or per unit basis, and applied to the projected
population or unit change. The final step is simply to compare the costs to the benefits to determine whether
there is likely to be a net fiscal surplus or deficit.

iv. Considerations in the Use of Planning Methods


The methods discussed in this section provide a reasonably efficient way to project municipal fiscal impacts
associated with economic policies and events. Care should be taken, however, to check that the underlying
assumptions inherent in their application are reasonable in light of a given situation. Three cautions deserve
specific mention.
There needs to be a reasonably good estimate of the likely direct changes associated with the economic policy
or event. The change “scenario” needs to be carefully constructed and checked. In almost any type of policy
analysis, the accuracy of assumptions associated with the direct impacts determine whether the analysis
output is valid.
Similarly, consideration is needed to determine whether the development or other change is “typical,” and
whether it is reasonable to use multipliers or other parameters based on averages or national norms. It may
be appropriate for the analyst to adjust the parameters if the standard approach is likely to result in under-
or over-estimates. Similarly, there may be instances where it is appropriate to subject certain parameters to
a sensitivity analysis.
Finally, there also needs to be an accurate understanding of the existing capacity within the municipality. If
the change of interest trips the threshold where new municipal investment in staff, facilities or infrastructure
are required, the costs to the municipality will change dramatically. In such a case, it is essential to use a
marginal-cost, rather than an average-cost approach.

B. Case Study Approach


The case study is also categorized as a planning approach by Burchell and Listoken (1978, 1980). Here, it
is highlighted to emphasize the importance of understanding the municipality’s existing situation prior to
performing the analysis. Too often there is an assumption that existing municipal staff and facilities have
sufficient capacity to absorb changes. The fallacy of this assumption, however, is where many impact analyses

59
fall short. It is essential to consider the irregular, but often substantial staff and capital costs that accompany
growth. It is for this purpose that many growing communities have instituted growth impact fee policies.
As indicated earlier, the case study approach is a marginal-cost impact analysis method, best suited for
use when there is significant over- or under-capacity in local public services. This will typically be the case
in older central cities with stable or declining populations, and in newer urban communities with rapidly
growing population. It can also be useful in established cities where the addition of a major new employer is
likely to lead to rapid in-migration of new workers and their families.
As might be expected, the procedure is time and resource intensive. Scheduling and interviewing public
service managers, documenting capacity, and confirming the results makes this among the least efficient
impact analysis procedures. It has also been criticized as ad hoc, with analysts making up procedures as they
go along. Some question whether service managers actually know the capacity of the systems they manage.
Here it is assumed a hybrid case study approach needs to be incorporated into an analysis using a combination
of techniques. Over time, an experienced city planner will have a generally good idea where the municipality
stands with regard to service capacity and will recognize when additional investigation is warranted. External
consultants, however, will not have that benefit and may need additional time to understand the local
situation. In either case, it is incumbent of the analyst to explicitly address the question of existing capacity
related to key municipal and school district services.

i. Summary of Procedures
The case study approach can be summarized in Table 2, where the assumption is one of identifying impacts
associated with new growth.
The process outlined here is intuitively straightforward. Care needs to be exercised when gathering the
information to ensure service managers provide accurate assessments. In some cases, service managers may
act in a self-serving manner in an effort to look good or maintain and/or enhance budgets. The important
point here is to make a conscious and systematic effort to identify potential “hidden” future service costs
associated with new development.
Table 2 - Steps in the Case Study Approach and Notes in the Execution of Procedures
Analysis Notes
Contact key local public The analyst needs the endorsement of chief policy-makers and administrators
service administrators and to ensure timely response from department heads and line workers who have
school district officials needed information.
Create a classification system Sufficient detail is needed for understanding, e.g. public works might be
of service functions broken into sanitary sewer, water, storm water, and roads.
Determine excess or deficient Determine desired service level, not the current service level. Convert the
service capacity information into the units of analysis needed, e.g. staff per 1,000 population,
student teacher ratio, etc.
Project population increases These projections are made using the planning techniques identified earlier,
and level of service demand e.g. demographic multipliers, service standards, etc.
Determine anticipated service Given the projected increases, service administrators indicate what, if any,
response actions will be needed to accommodate new service demands.
Project total annual public Convert the administrator’s estimates into a schedule of public service costs
service costs over the relevant time horizon.
Source: Based on Burchell and Listokin, 1978, page 48 and accompanying discussion.

C. Econometric Approaches
Econometric approaches go beyond per capita and case study methods insofar as they attempt to capture the
interaction between components of the economy that determine levels of supply and demand of public goods.
The approach uses statistical techniques that relate public expenditures to the factors that drive demand in a
dynamic context. A series of equations are specified to predict functional expenditures and own-source and
intergovernmental revenues. Such a system of fiscal equations can be used in isolation or can be linked to

60
other components of the economy known to interact with the public sector, such as changes in private sector
employment and the labor market, through so-called conjoined models.

i. Econometric Specification of Public Sector Supply and Demand


Demand for public sector goods is typically modeled using local government (city, county or school district)
expenditures, while supply uses local tax revenues (Deller, 1996). These are the dependent variables of
interest to policy-makers in a series of econometric equations representing local government behavior. The
challenge is to identify the independent variables that determine expenditure and revenue levels given an
existing set of conditions and available data.
Typically, expenditures are modeled as a function of population, income, and a vector of other relevant
variables that are thought to affect local decision-making, such as housing ownership, population dependency
rates, poverty, unemployment, population density, etc. Following Deller (1996), the reduced form of the
demand equation is:
X X
ln E = αE + αE ln n + λE ln Y + βEi Xi + ψE ln y + ωEi wi

where
where E is the level of local expenditures for a particular expenditure category, n is local population, Y is
median income, X is the vector of other relevant variables, y represents a given output level of the public
good, and w represents the prices of inputs into the production of the public good.
Alternatively, the reduced form demand equation can be expressed as:
Expenditures = f (quality, quantity, input conditions, demand conditions)
where quality and quantity are represented by the level of output y, input conditions are the prices of factor
inputs w, and demand conditions are captured by the n population, Y median income, and the X vector of
other relevant variables.
On the revenue side, the reduced form equation is:

X X
ln τ = ατ + γτ ln n + λ ln Y + βτ i Xi + ψτ ln γ + ωτ i wi

where τ is the tax price, and other variables are defined as above. Theoretically, the revenue equation is more
difficult to model because revenues are typically determined by accounting formulas, e.g. state aid formulas
and set tax rates. Johnson, et al. (1997) have had considerable applied experience estimating these equations,
and indicate that certain local characteristics can be used to estimate local revenues across most places. They
illustrate the alternative reduced form equations for individual revenue sources as:
Non-local Aids = f (expenditures, income, personal property, real property)
Sales Tax Revenues = f (income, employment, in-commuters)
Other Tax Revenues = f (sales tax revenues, income)
Real Property Tax = f (income, employment, out-commuters)
Personal Property Tax = f (income, out-commuters)
The specific form of these equations can vary considerably across states depending on the legal and institutional
rules in place. The specification is offered only to provide a sense of the types of explanatory variables used.
Analysts will need to experiment to obtain the best fitting model for any given state.
In estimation these models, cross sectional data for a state are used to create a pool of data for estimating
the equations. Most of the data related to revenues, expenditures, income, etc. are used in a per capita form.
To introduce a dynamic to the model, the output from one year is used to ‘boot-strap’ the input into the
next year. This recursive procedure is repeated for several years thought to coincide with the time where the
impacts of interest are assumed to occur. Typically, a base line scenario would be run assuming no change

61
in the current economic conditions. Then, a change scenario would be run assuming the employment or
population change associated with a policy of economic event, and would be compared to the base line to
estimate impacts to public finances.

ii. Conjoined Modeling Approaches


Local government fiscal models can be specified and used as a “stand-alone” impact analysis tool. Recently,
however, a number of researchers have been working to develop systems that link local government fiscal
models to other economic models to increase their accuracy given known economic relationships. As implied
by the equations presented, local governments respond to a series of signals related to supply and demand.
Thus, there have been important recent advances in modeling systems that conjoin an input-output model
with separate econometric models that deal with various spheres of community economic activity (e.g. labor
market, housing, retail sales, etc.). Input-output models trace the economic linkages between sectors. For
a complete discussion of input-output modeling, see Schaffer (1999). A principal benefit of this approach
is combining the dynamics of econometrics with the industrial disaggregation available from input-output
tables (Rey, 1999). Such an approach is thought to be more “holistic” in capturing the interrelationships
between local economic entities (Deller, 1996).
The premise of these models is that employment is a fundamental driver behind local levels of population and,
thus, public service supply and demand. Policies or economic events that affect employment will influence
the level of local population and the demand for, and the capacity to support, public services. Thus, in a
basic form of this modeling system, employment changes derived from an input-output model are fed into an
econometric model representing the local labor market and public-sector finance to estimate fiscal impacts.
Given the open nature of the economy, labor market behavior is an important determinant of local fiscal
conditions. People readily commute across municipal boundaries between work and home. To ignore this fact
introduces potentially significant error into impact estimates. Thus, it becomes appropriate to consider use of
an integrated modeling approach to estimate fiscal impacts.
Johnson, et al. (1997; see also Swenson and Eathington, 1998) have spearheaded an initiative to create a
standard procedure for conjoining input-output models with fiscal and labor market models. Employment
changes are estimated using standard input-output procedures. These employment changes are introduced
into an econometric model that simultaneously solves labor market and fiscal impacts. The labor market
module uses the following identity:
Unemployed = Labor Force + In-commuters - Employment - Out-commuters
In the basic model, the equations used to derive the components of this identity are:
Labor Force = f (employment, housing conditions, cost of living, public services, taxes, industry
mix, area)
Out-commuting = f (employment, external employment, external labor force, housing conditions,
cost of living, public services, taxes, industry mix, area, distance to jobs)
In-commuting = f (employment, external employment, external labor force, housing conditions,
cost of living, public services, taxes, industry mix, area, distance to residence)
By extending these models, researchers have endeavored to conjoin a number of modules that affect local
conditions, including housing demand, retail sales, and demographic composition (an ambitious example is
found in Shields, 1998). In this way, policy-makers are presented with a wider range of impacts known to be
associated with economic policy and change.

D. Conclusion
Local officials have long been concerned with the impact of growth and change on local public finances.
Often, there has been a presumption that economic growth of any sort would have a beneficial impact on
local fiscal conditions. Experience has shown, however, that this is not always true. Over time, planners and

62
other analysts have developed a variety of methods to better anticipate the effects of change on public sector
finances.
Planning approaches, such as per capita multipliers, have long been used as a relatively quick way to project
public fiscal impacts, and are probably still the most common analysis technique used by practitioners.
Recently, there have been important advances in econometric techniques that provide a fuller understanding
of multiple impacts in both the public and private sectors while also capturing the interaction between
economic sectors. These systems hold promise to make fiscal impact analysis a more useful tool insofar as
they encourage a deeper discussion of how policy and economic change are likely to affect local well-being.
Regardless of the method, however, it is necessary to incorporate the spirit of the case study approach into
the analysis to gain a deeper understanding of conditions in the community. This emphasis on knowledge
of local capacity is vital to generating better projections and avoiding potentially significant hidden costs
associated with development.

63
VII. Chapter Conclusion
This chapter provided an introduction to state and local public financing. The chapter began by providing
an overview of the growth of state and local governments over the past forty years. The important sources of
revenue - sales taxes, income taxes, corporate income taxes, excise tax, and property taxes - were all discussed
in the second section of the chapter. With an understanding of the basic trends in state and local governments
and the principle means of financing, the third section introduced the reader to the basic economic tools of
tax analysis. Important concepts such as efficiency and the deadweight loss of taxation were presented. Tax
incidence and the efficiency/equity tradeoff were also discussed. The third section concluded by presenting
two models of optimal taxation. The second part of the chapter presented several applications in public
finance. These included revenue forecasting, cost-benefit analysis, and fiscal impact analysis.
While this chapter covered the basic trends and issues surrounding state and local public finance, there are
many other aspects of state and local public finance that were discussed here. One important issue facing
all state and local governments is revenue stability. The stability of revenues is crucial in order to ensure a
constant revenue stream during changing economic conditions. Each local or state government needs to decide
on the appropriate mix of taxes that will ensure a stable revenue stream. Another area of state and local
public finance is debt financing. Like the federal government, state and local governments often issue bonds
in order to generate monies to fund public projects such as parking lots, libraries, parks, etc. Understanding
the tolerable level of debt in terms of future tax revenues is an issue faced by all localities.
The number of public finance issues impacting state and local governments is almost limitless. While we
cannot do justice to all issues here, we refer the reader to the public finance textbooks presented in the section
of the chapter. These texts not only contain chapters on various issues of state and local public finance, they
also contain many references to scholarly articles covering a myriad of public finance issues.
As the demand for local government goods and services continues to increase, public finance issues will have a
growing impact on all of our lives. Local officials will discuss issues such as tax changes, tax implementation,
debt financing, finance reform, etc. While public finance decisions are often made by these few individuals in
power, their decisions will have a direct impact on the lives of all residents residing in the affected locality.
We hope this chapter has provided the reader with the basic tools necessary to make educated, critical
evaluations of public finance issues that may arise in their community.

64
References
Arrow, K., Solow, R., Portney, P.R., Leamer, E.E., Radner, R., and H. Schuman. 1993. “Report of the
NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation.” Federal Register, 58: 4601-4614.
Barnett, W.F. 1988. “Four Steps to Forecast Total Market Demand.” Harvard Business Review, 88(4): 28-38.
Bateman, I.J. and K.G. Willis. (eds.) 1999. Valuing Environmental Preferences: Theory and Practice of the
Contingent Valuation Method in the U.S., E.U. and Developing Countries. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Bartik, T.J. 1988. “Evaluating the Benefits of Non-marginal Reductions in Pollution Using Information on
Defensive Expenditures.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 15(1): 111-127.
Bishop, R.C. and T.A. Heberlein. 1990. “The Contingent Valuation Method.” Pp. 81-104 in R.L. Johnson and
G.V. Johnson (eds.). Economic Valuation of Natural Resources: Issues, Theory and Applications. Boulder,
CO: Westview Press.
Boardman, A.E., D.H. Greenberg, A.R. Vining and D.L. Weimer. 1996. Cost-Benefit Analysis: Concepts and
Practice. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Borg, M.O., P. Mason, and S. Shapiro. 1991. The Economic Consequence of State Lotteries. Praeger,
Westport, Connecticut.
Boston Consulting Group. 1998. “The State of On-line Retailing.” Boston Consulting Group and Shop.org
Box, G.E.P. and G.M. Jenkins. 1976. Time Series Analysis: Forecasting and Control. Revised Edition. San
Francisco: Holden-Day.
Brennan, G. and J. Buchanan. 1977. “Towards a Tax Constitution for Leviathan.” Journal of Public
Economics 8: 255-274.
Burchell, R.W. and D. Listokin. 1978. The Fiscal Impact Handbook: Estimating Local Costs and Revenues of
Land Development. Center for Urban Policy Research. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers, The State University of
New Jersey.
Burchell, R.W. and D. Listokin. 1980. Practitioner’s Guide to Fiscal Impact Analysis. Center for Urban
Policy Research. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers, The State University of New Jersey.
Burchell, R.W., Listokin, D., Dolphin, W.R., Newton, L.Q., and S.J. Foxley. 1994. Development Impact
Assessment Handbook. Washington, D.C.: ULI - the Urban Land Institute.
Cirincione, C., Gurrieri, G.A., and B. van de Sande. 1999. “Municipal Government Revenue Forecasting:
Issues of Method and Data.” Public Budgeting & Finance, 19(1): 26-46.
Clotfelter, C.T. and P.J. Cook. 1989. Selling Hope: State Lotteries in America. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
Cummings, R.G., Brookshire, D.S., and W.D. Shulze. 1986. Valuing Environmental Goods: An Assessment
of the Contingent Valuation Method. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld.
Deller, S.C. 1996. “Theoretical Foundations of CE Models.” Unpublished paper presented at the Community
Economic Modeling Conference. Madison, WI. June 9-10, 1996.
Fisher, R.C. 1980. “Local Sales Taxes: Tax Rate Differentials, Sales Loss, and Revenue Estimation.” Public
Finance Quarterly 8: 171-188.
Fisher. R.C. 1995. State and Local Public Finance: Institutions, Theory, Policy, Homewood, Illinois: Richard
D. Irwin, Inc.
Frank, H.A. 1993. Budgetary Forecasting in Local Government: New Tools and Techniques. Westport, CT:
Quorum Books.
Fullerton, D. and D.L. Rogers. 1993. “Who Bears the Lifetime Tax Burden?” Washington D.C.: The
Brookings Institution.

65
Garrett, T.A. 1999. “A Test of Shirking Under Legislative and Citizen Vote: The Case of State Lottery
Adoption.” Journal of Law and Economics 62: 189-208.
Ghaus, A.F. Aisha. 1995. “Optimal Local Sales Tax.” Urban Studies 32: 1369-1381.
Goolsbee, A. and J. Zittrain. 1999. “Evaluating the Costs and Benefits of Taxing Internet Commerce.”
National Tax Journal 52: 413-428.
Gramlich, E.M. 1981. Benefit-Cost Analysis of Government Programs. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall,
Inc.
Green, D.L., D.W. Jones, and M.A. Delucchi (eds.) 1997. The Full Costs and Benefits of Transportation:
Contributions to Theory, Method and Measurement. New York: Springer.
Guajardo, S.A. and R. Miranda. 2000. An Elected Official’s Guide to Revenue Forecasting. Chicago:
Government Finance Officers Association.
Hausman, J.A. (ed.). 1993. Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment. New York: North-Holland.
Hellerstein, W. 1997. “Transaction Taxes and Electronic Commerce: Designing State Taxes That Work in an
Interstate Environment.” National Tax Journal 50: 593-606.
Hersch, P.L. and G.S. McDougall. 1989. “Do People Put Their Money Where Their Votes Are? The Case of
State Lottery Adoption.” Southern Economic Journal 56: 32-38.
Holcombe, R.G. and R.S. Sobel. 1997. Growth and Variability in State Tax Revenue - An Anatomy of State
Fiscal Crises. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press.
Hyman, D.N. 1999. Public Finance: A Contemporary Application of Theory to Policy. New York, New York:
The Dryden Press, Harcourt Brace and Company.
Johnson, T.G., Scott, J.K., and J. Ma. 1997. “The Community Policy Analysis System (COMPAS).”
Unpublished manuscript. Community Policy Analysis Center, University of Missouri - Columbia.
Long, D.A., C.D. Mallar, and C.V. Thornton. 1981. “Evaluating the Benefits and Costs of the Job Corps.”
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 1(1): 55-76.
Makridakis, S., Andersen, A., Carbone, R., Fildes, R., Hibon, M., Lewandowski, R., Newton, J., Parzen, E.,
and R. Winkler. 1984. The Forecasting Accuracy of Major Time Series Methods. New York: John Wiley &
Sons.
Makridakis, S. and S.C. Wheelwright. 1987. The Handbook of Forecasting: A Manager’s Guide. (2nd ed.).
New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Makridakis, S. and S.C. Wheelwright. 1989. Forecasting Methods for Management. (5th ed.). New York:
John Wiley & Sons.
Max, W. and D.P. Rice. “Shooting in the Dark: Estimating the Costs of Firearms Injuries.”Health Affairs,
12(4): 171-185.
McClure, C.E. 1997. “Electronic Commerce, State Sales Taxation, and Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations.”
National Tax Journal 50: 731-749.
Mikesell, J.L. and C.K. Zorn. 1986. “Impact of the Sales Tax Rate on Its Base: Evidence From a Small
Town.” Public Finance Quarterly 14: 329-338.
Miller, T.R. 1993. “Costs and Functional Consequences of U.S. Roadway Crashes.” Accident Analysis and
Prevention, 25(5): 593-607.
Miller, T.R., M.A. Cohen and S. Rossman. 1993. “Victim Costs of Violent Crimes and Resulting Injuries.”
Health Affairs, 12(4): 171-185.
Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson. 1989. Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent Valuation
Method. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

66
Moore, M.J. and W.K. Viscusi. 1990. “Models for Estimating Discount Ratesfor Long-term Health Risks
Using Labor Market Data.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 3(4): 381-401.
Nelson, A.C. (ed.).1988. Development Impact Fees. Chicago: Planners Press.
Pechman, J.A. 1985. “Who Paid the Taxes: 1966-1985?” Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Ramsey, F.P. 1927. “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation.” Economic Journal, 37: 47-61.
Rey, S.J. 1999. “Integrated Regional Econometric and Input-Output Modeling,” Unpublished
paper. Department of Geography, San Diego State University. Available on the Internet at
http://www2.econ.iastate.edu/classes/crp274/swenson/URP290/Readings/rey99-1.pdf.
Rice, D.P., MacKenzie, E.J. and Associates. 1989. Cost of Injury in the United States: A Report to Congress.
San Francisco, CA: Institute for Health and Aging, University of California and Injury Prevention Center,
The Johns Hopkins University.
Rosen, H.S. 1985. Public Finance. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.
Rosen, S. 1974. “Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition.” Journal
of Political Economy, 82(1): 34-55.
Schaffer, W.A. 1999. “Regional Impact Models.” In S. Loveridge (ed.). The Web Book of Re-
gional Science. Regional Research Institute, West Virginia University. Available on the Web:
https://researchrepository.wvu.edu/rri-web-book/7/.
Shields, M.L. 1998. “An Integrated Economic Impact and Simulation Model for Wisconsin Counties.”
Unpublished dissertation. Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics, University of Wisconsin-
Madison.
Swenson, D. and L. Eathington. 1998. “A Manual for Community and Fiscal Impact Modeling Systems:
Practical Techniques for Building and Applying Community Level Models.” Unpublished paper. Department
of Economics, Iowa State University.
Tannenwald, R. 1998. “Devolution: The New Federalism - An Overview.” In Devolution: The New Federalism,
New England Economic Review, (May/June): 1-12.
Vuscusi, 1993. “The Value of Risks to Life and Health.” Journal of Economic Literature, 31(4): 1912-1946.
Wong, J.D. 1995. “Local Government Revenue Forecasting: Using Regression and Econometric Revenue
Forecasting in a Medium-Sized City.” Public Budgeting & Financial Management, 7(3): 315-335.

67
Glossary
Cost-Effectiveness Analysis – Cost-Effectiveness Analysis (CEA) and Cost Utility Analysis (CUA) are
sometimes used as an alternative to CBA. Generally, these alternatives are selected when it is preferable, or
the analyst is unable or unwilling, to monetize all of the relevant impacts. This is sometimes the case when
we might prefer to compare programs as to their cost per life saved. CEA utilizes a single quantified, but not
monetized, metric such as per life. CUA does the same, but the measure is a construct consisting of two
(usually) or more benefit categories, such as quality-adjusted life. Here, we might talk about cost per year of
quality life.
Crime – Many public programs are initiated with the intent of reducing crime and criminal behavior. To
estimate the benefits of such programs it is necessary to estimate the number and value of crimes the program
will reduce. Several major studies have been completed that estimate the costs of medical care associated
with various crime-related injuries, the opportunity costs of foregone productivity, and the value of pain and
suffering (Miller, et al., 1993). Other relevant costs include criminal proceedings and incarceration.
Discounted/Present Value –Most are familiar with the idea of compound interest, or calculating the
future value of money. If we save $100 in a bank account at five percent simple annual interest (i = .05),
after one year we have (1 + .05) • $100 = $105. If we continue to save for the second year, we accrue
(1 + .05) • $105 = $110.25. This can also be expressed as (1 + .05) • (1 + .05) • $100 = (1 + .05)2 • $100 = $110.25.
If the money were left in the bank for five years, we can calculate the future value as (1 + .05)5 • $100. More
generally, if $X were invested for T years at interest rate i, we would calculate the future value as $X • (1 + i)T .
With discounting, we do exactly the opposite; we take some future value and calculate what it is worth to us
today. If we agreed to purchase a guarantee of a $100 payment one year from now, how much should we
pay? We might be inclined to pay $100, but that functionally provides the seller an interest-free $100 loan.
In exchange for the promise to receive $100, we would discount that value by an amount representing our
perception of deferring access to our $100 for a year. We would want to calculate the present value of $100
received a year from now.
To find the present value of $100 received a year from now, we find the amount, which when multiplied by
(1 + .05), equals $100. The calculation is simply $100/(1 + .05) = $95.24. If the promise is to pay $100
two years from now, the calculation is $100/(1 + .05)2 = $90.70. In general, when the interest rate is i, the
present value of the promise to pay $X in T years is $X/(1 + i)T . The interest rate i that we apply is called
the discount rate and the term (1 + i)T is the discount factor.
Typically, projects will have a stream of benefits that accrue at different times through the course of the
project and beyond. We can calculate the present value of each year by applying the appropriate discount
factor as illustrated in the table below.
Calculating Present Value
Dollars Years into Discount Present
Payable the Future Factor Value
X0 0 1 X0
X1 1 (1 + i) X1 /(1 + i)
X2 2 (1 + i)2 X2 /(1 + i)2
XT T (1 + i)T XT /(1 + i)T

Source: Adapted from Rosen 1985, page 177.


To get the present value of the stream of payments, we simply add the values in the last column:

X1 X2 XT
P V = X0 + + + ... +
(1 + i) (1 + i)2 (1 + i)T

After calculating the present value of both the benefits and costs over the time period all impacts are assumed
to accrue, the net present value is generated by simply subtracting the costs from the benefits:

68
X BT X CT
NPV = −
(1 + i)T (1 + i)T

Impact fees – Impact fee programs are intended to make additional new growth pay the full cost of additional
public services (Nelson, 1988). While a housing development, for example, may be required to pay the costs
of new streets and storm water drainage, the increase in municipal population also brings new demands
for recreational facilities, traffic improvements, and other services. Failure to apply these costs to the new
development is to provide an implicit subsidy to new residents by existing residents who must help pay the
cost of new facilities. To the extent there is a clear connection between new growth and the need for new
facilities and services, municipalities can implement a fee structure that requires new growth to pay its fair
share of new municipal costs.
Internal Rate of Return – The internal rate of return is the discount rate at which the present value of
a project’s benefits is exactly equal to zero. This will yield some discount rate that can be equated with
a “return on investment.” The decision rule for policy makers would be to select the project if the social
discount rate is less than the internal rate of return.
The benefit-cost ratio is simply the net present value of the benefits divided by the net present value of
the costs. The decision rule would be that if the ratio value is greater than 1.0, go ahead with the project.
There are potentially problems in using either the internal rate of return or the benefit-cost ratio to guide
the policy choice. There may be more than one internal rate of return that equals zero. This arises when
the annual net benefits change from positive to negative more once through the discount period. Similarly,
internal rates of return and benefit-cost ratios are percentages and can not be added across projects as is
possible when the metric is dollars. Finally, the highest benefit-cost ratio is not necessarily the project that
will maximize net benefits. For these reasons, net present value is a better choice to aid decision-making.
Nominal dollars – Nominal dollars reflect the purchasing power of a dollar at the current time of expenditure.
Thus, what a dollar would purchase in 1980 would be very different than what a dollar would purchase in
2005. Real dollars remove the effects if inflation by applying a deflator, the most common of which is the
Consumer Price Index. Once adjusted, the dollars are expressed in the value of a single year, generally very
close to the present because this is the value policy-makers will best understand. It is worth noting, the
proper reference is to “inflation- adjusted dollars” and not “deflated dollars”
Pareto efficiency – The concept of Pareto efficiency is illustrated in Figure 1. In this example, it is supposed
that two people may split a payment up to $100, if they can agree how to do it. They each currently receive
$25 at point a. Point d represents where person 1 receives the entire $100 and point e is where person 2
receives the entire $100. The questions arises whether there may be a way of increasing the payment to
each person without decreasing the payment currently received by the other. At any point in the shaded
area bounded by a − b − c, either person can be made better off without making the other worse off. The
line connecting points d and e represents the distribution of the entire $100 between the two people, but
only between points b and c can one or both be made better off without making one worse off. Finding a
distribution somewhere along this “frontier” makes maximum use of the $100, but any movement toward the
shaded area increases the benefit to both people over where they are currently.
Price Elasticity – Recall that the price elasticity measures the percentage change in quantity demanded or
supplied given a precentage change in price. Thus, a higher price elasticity of demand reveals that a change
in price will be met with a relatively higher change in quantity demanded. Consumers or suppliers with
a relatively higher price elasticity are thus more likely to change behavior than those having lower price
elasticities.
Real discount rate – The real discount rate (r) approximately equals the nominal discount rate (i) minus
the expected rate of inflation (m), and is calculated as:

(i − m)
r=
(1 + m)

69
A common approach to estimation the expected rate of inflation is to assume that real long-term bond
yields will remain stable and to deduct this yield from the current long-term bond yield. If the yield on
current long-term bonds is seven percent and the real long-term bond yield has been about three percent,
the expected rate of inflation would be four percent. The real yield would be calculated over a time period
approximately equal to the expected term of the project impacts.
Many suggest that a discount rate calculated purely on market values is inappropriate to use when considering
public expenditures and argue that we should use a social discount rate. There is reason to believe that
we value the time preference of money as individuals differently than we should as a society. The argument is
that individuals view the opportunity cost of foregoing current consumption as much higher than should
society, resulting in higher discount rates that discourage long-term investment (thus our current low rate of
aggregate savings). Because of concern for future generations, the obligation to consider the general welfare
of the citizenry, and the imperfections of markets, it is often said the social discount rate should be lower
than the market discount rate. Others view these arguments as paternalistic and unconvincing, preferring
something closer to a market discount rate (Rosen, 1985).
Shadow prices –
Summaries of Research Establishing Shadow Prices Frequently Used in Cost-Benefit Analyses
Shadow Price Value
Value of Life $2 to $3 million ($1990)
Monetary Injury Costs per Person (Rice and MacKenzie 1989) ($1990)
eventually fatal $385,000
hospitalized/nonfatal $41,000
non-hospitalized/nonfatal $600
Per Person Cost of Injury (Viscusi 1993) ($1990)
less serious $25,000
more serious $50,000
Motor Vehicle Crash Injuries (Miller 1993) (as a fraction of value of life)
spinal cord 0.66
brain 0.04
lower extremity 0.06
upper extremity 0.03
average for nonfatal crash 0.02
average for fatal crash 1.08
Average Victim Cost per Crime (Miller, Cohen and Rossman 1993) ($1900)
rape $64,000
robbery $26,000
assault $24,000
arson $52,000
Per Person Cost of Firearm Injuries (Max and Rice 1993) ($1990)
fatal injuries $374,000
injuries requiring hospitalizaton $33,000
injuries not requiring hospitalization $500
Per Person Cost of Crime (Long, Maller and Thornton 1981) ($1990)
robbery $27,000
burglary $13,000
larceny $6,000
drugs $6,000
Value of Travel Time Saved (as a fraction of wage rate)
inter-urban (commuting) travel 0.40 to 0.50
work time equal to wage rate
Source: Boardman, Greenberg, Vining, and Weimer, 1996, page. 391.
Social surplus –Figure 2 illustrates the concept of social surplus. In a competitive market with a quantity
of good Q0 at price P ∗ , consumers benefit in the area bounded by points a − b − P ∗ because there would

70
exist consumers who would be willing to purchase good Q at prices higher than P ∗ if quantities were less
than Q0 . Similarly, producers benefit in the area bounded by a − P ∗ − c because they are able to sell a
quantity of good Q greater than they would were the quantity less than Q0 . This is allocatively efficient
because anything that would cause more or less production of good Q to occur would reduce social surplus.
Value of life – There are a number of ways researchers have generated value-of-life estimates (Viscusi, 1993;
Moore and Viscusi, 1990). The most common is to observe the wage premium needed to induce people to
engage in high-risk work activities. Other studies have used contingent valuation methods. Similar studies
have been used to place values on various types of serious injuries.
Value of time – Time, of course, has value. Most of the work related to value of time has dealt with travel in
the context of transportation projects (Green, et al., 1997). These studies typically use contingent valuation
methods or the revealed preference approach, where observations of actual choice behavior are made in the
context of available alternatives. Time values are usually reported as some fraction of wage rates by income
class.

71

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy