Theories On Financial Reporting
Theories On Financial Reporting
Cite: Warue, B. N., Charles B. J. M., & Mwania, P. M. (2018). Theories in Finance
Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review. The University Journal, 1(2), 113-146.
Abstract
The purpose of this paper is to create awareness of a number of existing theories in Finance area
of specialization. The compilation and analyses on the theories will help scholars quickly identify
theories existing in finance and application of the theories in a scholarly manner. However the
theories analyzed are not exhaustive. Scholars are allowed to add to the list of analyses.
Keywords: Theories in Finance, Agency Theory, Portfolio Theory, Arbitrage Pricing
Theory, Divided Theory
Introduction
As a separate subject of discipline, finance is still in its infancy. It was only the latter half of
the twentieth century that witnessed most of major developments in finance with scientific
rigor (Miller, 2001). This means that the whole profession of finance had to digest a very
large amount of new theoretical developments in a relatively short time period. Educators,
scholars, and business people have been continuously introduced to new models, theories,
and empirical results thereof over the recent years and the trend continues (Markowitz, 1952).
Started out as largely a descriptive, institutional field of study, finance has quickly
transformed into a science full of theoretical thrusts. While few would dispute its origin as a
branch of applied microeconomics, finance now is as theoretical as its mother discipline.
The rapid changes in finance have had a profound implication for business education.
Especially, such extensive and rigorous theoretical developments over the recent past have
made finance teaching in college classrooms increasingly challenging (Miller, 1998).
Finance is one of the most quantified and theorized disciplines in business curriculum. The
dynamic and complex nature of finance requires continuous development of new theories. As
intellectual advances in finance continues in the form of more sophisticated theoretical
inquiries, the challenge of teaching finance theories will only grow bigger. Yet, finance is
somewhat unique in terms of the correspondence between theory and evidence. While
students are educated to make independent critical evaluations of the contending points of
views, many finance theories are still at their developmental stage and so they are highly
controversial, debatable, and subject to close scrutiny (Ball, 2001).
~ 113 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
~ 114 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
simple and easy to understand. A diversified portfolio, of uncorrelated asset classes, can
provide the highest returns with the least amount of volatility (Markowitz, 1991).
MPT is the philosophical opposite of traditional asset picking. It is the creation of
economists, who try to understand the market as a whole, rather than looking for that which
makes each investment opportunity unique. The asset allocation problem is one of the
fundamental concerns of financial theory (Cohen & Natoli, 2003). Asset allocation and risk
are vital components in the MPT. Investments are described statistically, in terms of their
expected long-term return rate and their expected short-term volatility. The volatility is
equated with "risk", measuring how much worse than average an investment's bad years are
likely to be. The goal is to identify the acceptable level of risk tolerance, and then find a
portfolio with the maximum expected return for that level of risk (Elton & Gruber, 1997).
firms, finds that when there is a monetary contraction, small firms react by increasing the
amount of trade credit accepted. As financially unconstrained firms are less likely to demand
trade credit and more prone to offer it, a negative relation between a buyer’s access to other
sources of financing and trade credit use is expected. Petersen and Rajan (1997) obtained
evidence supporting this negative relation.
Portfolio Theory
Portfolio theory of investment which tries to maximize portfolio expected return for a given
amount of portfolio risk or equivalently minimize risk for a given level of expected return, by
carefully choosing the proportions of various assets. Although portfolio theory is widely used
in practice in the finance industry and several of its creators won a Nobel prize for the theory
,in recent years the basic portfolio theory have been widely challenged by fields such as
behavioural economics(Markowitz 1952).
Portfolio theory was developed in 1950s through the early 1970’s and was considered an
important advance in the mathematical modelling of finance. Since then, many theoretical
and practical criticisms have been developed against it. This include the fact that financial
returns do not follow a Gaussian distribution or indeed any symmetric distribution, and those
correlations between asset classes (Sproul, 1998).
This theory was revised in the eighties, and called “Tax-adjusted M&M”. It suggested that
highly leveraged structures, which substitute deductible interest payments for non-deductible
dividends could push optimal capital structure to 100% debt (Miller & Modigliani, 1958).
a time when they are perceived to be overvalued, and bought back when they are
undervalued. As a consequence, the perception about the stock price affects the capital
structure of the firm. There are two separate versions of market timing theory that have led to
dynamics in capital structure; first is the assumption that economic agents are rational (Myers
and Majluf, 1984). Companies issue equity directly after a positive information release which
reduces information asymmetry problem between the management of the firm and
stockholders. Then the reduction in asymmetry coincides with a rise in the stock price. This
triggers firms to create their own timing opportunities. The second theory assumes
irrationality of economic agents (Baker and Wurgler, 2002) which results into time varying
mispricing of a firms stock. Therefore managers make new equity issues when they perceive
their costs to be irrationally low and repurchase them when their costs are irrationally high.
Baker and Wurgler (2002) provide supportive evidence that equity market timing has a
persistent effect on the firm’s capital structure. Their study defines a measure for market
timing as a weighted average of external capital needs over a few past years, where the
weights used are market to book values of the firm. Their finding was that changes in
leverage are strongly and positively related to their market timing measure, so their
conclusion was that a firm’s capital structure was a cumulative outcome of attempts in the
past to time the equity market.
management have information on the correct distribution of the firm’s returns while outsiders
don’t, the firm is likely to benefit if the firms securities are overvalued and the converse is
true. They also argue that managers can use higher financial leverage to signal optimistic
future for the company since debt capital involves a contractual commitment to pay back
both principal and interests and failure to do so could result into bankruptcy which may
further result into job losses. Hence, additional debt in the firm’s capital structure may be
interpreted as a positive signal about a firm’s future.
Earning Per Share EPS model that prevailed in America before the 90s (Stern, Stewart &
Chew, 1995) and more real than Return on Equity ROE, Free Cash Flow FCF and other
methods based in the Accounting model (Hatfield, 2002).
It is an integrated financial system used in decision making and different corporate
applications: Performance measurement, determination of shareholder value, valuation of
equity (Hatfield, 2002; Stern, Stewart & Chew, 1995).
In Research & Development, EVA is used to improve the treatment of outlays as investment
given their value creation character. Hatfield (2002) prepared a study to demonstrate the
effect of capitalizing R&D. Outlays for new products when R&D is expensed perform worse
than flows of outlays of a capitalized R&D across time. Firms reported by Stern & Stewart
Co. (n.d) as active users of EVA include: Bausch and Lomb, The Coca Cola Co., Georgia-
Pacific Corp., Monsanto, Rubbermaid Inc. among others (Hatfield, 2002). Application of
EVA requires change in the organizational culture and fiscal responsibility (Hatfield, 2002).
EVA is not a new concept, it is deemed “practical, highly flexible, a refinement of
economists’ concept of residual income’ (Drucker as cited in Stewart, 1991). For other
authors EVA is a financial fiction inoperable unless markets were efficient (Chen & Dodd,
2002). The formula to compute EVA is expressed (Hatfield, 2002).
EVA = NOPAT – CC (1)
NOPAT= Net operating profit after taxes
CC= cost of capital x economic capital
Four steps are required : (1) Determine the Net profit after taxes plus interest charges (2)
Estimate market value of company’s equity (3) Calculate the opportunity cost of the capital
and (4) Compute EVA (Gonzalez, 2006).
that dividends and earnings are non-fundamental to stock pricing determination. Its use in the
computation of EVA also has been challenged (Chen & Dodd, 2002).
Divided opinions classify CAPM as a result of the EMH (Efficient Market Theory) (Ball,
2001); others argue that the assumption that CAPM evaluates only efficient portfolios does
not imply that CAPM derives from Fama’s Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH).
~ 123 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
Portfolio could be reduced by spreading the amount of funds available for investments into a
variety of opportunities, each in a different risk class. Institutional investors have over the
years achieved portfolio diversification using property and equity as their prime investments
(Reddy, 2001).
The proponents of MPT argued Property′s high relative management costs are increased by a
globally-scattered portfolio where no scale efficiencies can be obtained; there are additional
costs in monitoring the local managing agents. Gordon (1991), as a result, the tendency
would be to concentrate holdings on a small number of markets (and on larger units) thus
sacrificing potential diversification gains. Market access may be problematic; particularly
where the market capitalization is small in relation to the size of fund there may simply be no
appropriately sized buildings available. Liquidity problems make it difficult to implement
and actively manage a portfolio strategy (Brown, 1991). Markets with low correlations to the
global portfolio are often those with least research and most restrictive market practices.
Information may be difficult and costly to obtain; it is rare that data will be of good quality
and with a long time-series. Furthermore, there may be comparability problems caused by
differences in ownership and legal structures, valuation methodologies and terminology. In
individual asset selection, local factors may dominate, placing the overseas investor without a
local partner at a relative disadvantage (Ennis & Burik, 1991).
research on the relationship between investment decisions and dividend decisions. His
findings revealed that investment decisions and dividend decisions are not correlated; that
these two types of decision making do not affect each other.
Limitations of the theory are analyzed by Ball (2001) himself and divided in 3 categories:
Empirical anomalies, defects as a model of stock market and problems in testing the
efficiency of the model. Empirical anomalies include problems in fitting the theory to the
data because of seasonal patterns. Defects in efficiency as a model of stock market comprise
not incorporating information costs, transaction costs, oversimplifying academic analysis
and ignoring market microstructure effects (Ball & Brown, 1968 p. 25) Market
microstructure effect explains “how investors’ latent or hidden demands are ultimately
translated into prices and volumes” (Madhavan, 2002). Problems in the model relate to
definition of risk-less rates, market risk premium, individual betas and the volatility of the
stock prices.
~ 126 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
economists are REMM individuals who believe that price system is a self-regulatory
mechanism that responds to needs and wants. Trade-off in the costs of leverage to avoid the
costs of bankruptcy is an example of a REMM action (Brounen et al., 2004).
Corruption in financial markets is addressed by Brunner and Meckling (1977) and explained
from the REMM perspective as the result of corrupt government agencies rather than private
firms. The limitations of the theory are that; REMM does not describe behaviour of particular
individuals and might appear too biased towards the role of government agencies as
controlling entities of corporate governance (Jensen & Meckling, 2001).
Deflation Theory
The concept of debt deflation theory was pioneered by Fisher (1930) following the Wall
Street Crash of 1929 and the ensuing great depression. Debt deflation is a theory of economic
cycles, which holds that recessions and depressions are due to the overall level of debt
shrinking (deflating). Fisher stated that, credit cycle is the cause of the economic cycle.
Fisher developed debt deflation theory by taking hypothetical case by assuming that, at some
point of time, a state of over-indebtedness exists, this would tend to lead to liquidation,
through the alarm either of debtors or creditors or both. In Fisher's formulation of debt
deflation, he states that, when the debt bubble bursts the following sequence of events occurs;
(1) debt liquidation leads to distress selling and to (2) contraction of deposit currency, as
bank loans are paid off, and to a slowing down of velocity of circulation. This contraction of
deposits and of their velocity, precipitated by distress selling, causes (3) a fall in the level of
prices, in other words, a swelling of the dollar. Assuming, as above stated, that this fall of
prices is not interfered with by reflation or otherwise, there must be (4) a still greater fall in
the net worth of business, precipitating bankruptcies and (5) a like fall in profits, which in a
"capitalistic," that is, a private-profit society, leads the concerns which are running at a loss to
make (6) a reduction in output, in trade and in employment of labour. These losses,
bankruptcies and unemployment, lead to (7) pessimism and loss of confidence, which in turn
lead to (8) hoarding and slowing down still more the velocity of circulation. The afore eight
changes cause (9) complicated disturbances in the rates of interest, in particular, a fall in the
nominal, or money, rates and a rise in the real, or commodity, rates of interest.
Financial Theory
Minsky (1974) pioneered financial theory (commonly known as financial instability
hypothesis) and attempted to provide an understanding and explanation of the characteristics
of financial crises. Minsky proposed theories linking financial market fragility, in the normal
life cycle of an economy, with speculative investment bubbles endogenous to financial
markets. Minsky claimed that in prosperous times, when corporate cash flow rises beyond
what is needed to pay off debt, a speculative euphoria develops, and soon thereafter debts
exceed what borrowers can pay off from their incoming revenues, which in turn produces a
financial crisis. As a result of such speculative borrowing bubbles, banks and lenders tighten
credit availability, even to companies that can afford loans, and the economy subsequently
contracts.
Minsky's model of the credit system, which he dubbed the "financial instability hypothesis"
(FIH), incorporated many ideas. He states that, a fundamental characteristic of an economy is
that the financial system swings between robustness and fragility and these swings are an
integral part of the process that generates business cycles. Disagreeing with many mainstream
economists of the day, he argued that these swings, and the booms and busts that can
accompany them, are inevitable in a so-called free market economy – unless government
steps in to control them, through regulation, central bank action and other tools.
~ 128 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
Hyman Minsky's theories about debt accumulation received revived attention in the media
during the subprime mortgage crisis of the late 2000s. Minsky argued that a key mechanism
that pushes an economy towards a crisis is the accumulation of debt. He identified three types
of borrowers that contribute to the accumulation of insolvent debt: hedge borrowers,
speculative borrowers, and Ponzi borrowers. The "hedge borrower" can make debt payments
(covering interest and principal) from current cash flows from investments. For the
"speculative borrower", the cash flow from investments can service the debt, i.e., cover the
interest due, but the borrower must regularly roll over, or re-borrow, the principal. The
"Ponzi borrower" borrows based on the belief that the appreciation of the value of the asset
will be sufficient to refinance the debt but could not make sufficient payments on interest or
principal with the cash flow from investments; only the appreciating asset value can keep the
Ponzi borrower afloat. Because of the unlikelihood of most investments' capital gains being
enough to pay interest and principal, much of this type of finance is fraudulent.
If the use of Ponzi finance is general enough in the financial system, then the inevitable
disillusionment of the Ponzi borrower can cause the system to seize up: when the bubble
pops, i.e., when the asset prices stop increasing, the speculative borrower can no longer
refinance (roll over) the principal even if able to cover interest payments. He further states
that, collapse of the speculative borrowers can then bring down even hedge borrowers, who
are unable to find loans despite the apparent soundness of the underlying investments.
Minsky stated his theories verbally, and did not build mathematical models based on them.
Consequently, his theories have not been incorporated into mainstream economic models,
which do not include private debt as a factor. Minsky's theories, which emphasize the
macroeconomic dangers of speculative bubbles in asset prices, have also not been
incorporated into central bank policy. However, in the wake of the financial crisis of 2007–
2010 there has been increased interest in policy implications of his theories, with some
central bankers advocating that central bank policy include a Minsky factor.
~ 129 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
Regularly recurring transactions and long-term transactions might be good examples. In such
situations longer, incomplete contracts, which are typical for firms, provide much more
flexibility for the parties in a world of uncertainty. These contracts can be left open to be
flexible in case of a changing environment. On the other hand dissimilarities of transactions,
the probability of changes in the market prices for the relevant resources as well as the spatial
distribution of the relevant resources and transactions highlight factors which increase the
costs of using a firm. One might argue in this context that transaction costs would be
minimised in a world without transactions. This could be achieved if rights and duties would
initially be assigned in the “right” way.
Based on this idea Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz built their theory of property rights.
Property can be tangible (e.g. equipment in a firm) and intangible (intellectual property), and
property rights theory argues that the ownership, which includes residual rights to the
benefits of ownership, of productive assets provides a foundation for explaining firms.
According to Oliver Hart, one of the leading scholars in this area, a firm without property is
just a phantom (Hart, 1995). In situations where ordinary contractual relationships fail, firms
arise and the ownership of capital assets puts (collection of) persons in the position to
organise production through the purchase of economic factors, including labour (Hart, 1995).
Applied to corporate governance, this theory provides a supplement to contract theories. The
theory claims that legal systems should assign and secure property rights and additionally
explains that those who invest in or own productive property and capital of the firm, have a
privileged position as legal agents to bargain with other parties such as directors, employees,
suppliers, and other constituencies. Coase, in his theory of the firm, built a connection
between the above discussed property rights and transaction costs. In a world without the
latter, the initial assignment of property rights would be irrelevant as each “error” in the
assignment of these rights could easily be rescinded by additional transactions. This is the
idea of the Coase Theorem for property rights. The applicability of the Coase Theorem to
companies is questionable as the idea rests on the assumptions that there are no legal,
strategic and informational barriers to bargaining. But in modern firms all these barriers
normally exist and make transactions more expensive, i.e. incur transaction costs.
Agency Theory
The 1976 article Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs and Ownership
Structure by Jensen and Meckling helped establish Agency Theory as the dominant
theoretical framework of the CG literature, and position shareholders as the main
stakeholder (Lee et al., 2010, Daily et al., 2003).
The adoption of the agency logic increased during the 1980s as companies started replacing
the hitherto corporate logic of managerial capitalism with the perception of managers as
agents of the shareholders (Zajac et al., 2004). The subsequent stream of literature would
break with the tradition of largely treating the firm as a black box and the assumption that the
firm always sought to maximize value (Jensen 1 994).
AT addressed what had become a growing concern, that management engaged in empire
building and possessed a general disregard for shareholder interest, what Jensen called “the
systematic fleecing of shareholders and bondholders” (1989, p. 64), through providing
prescriptions as to how the principal should control the agent to curb managerial opportunism
~ 131 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
and self-interest (Perrow, 1986; Daily et al., 2003). As the market reacted positively to this
change in logic, with time the agency approach became institutionalized in the practice of
Corporate Governance, within business education, research and media (Zajac et al., 2004;
Shapiro, 2005).
Institutional Theory
Institutional theorists assert that the institutional environment can strongly influence the
development of formal structures in an organization, often more profoundly than market
pressures. Innovative structures that improve technical efficiency in early-adopting
organizations are legitimized in the environment. Ultimately these innovations reach a level
of legitimization where failure to adopt them is seen as "irrational and negligent" (or they
become legal mandates). At this point new and existing organizations will adopt the
structural form even if the form doesn't improve efficiency. Meyer and Rowan (1977) argue
that often these "institutional myths" are merely accepted ceremoniously in order for the
organization to gain or maintain legitimacy in the institutional environment. Organizations
adopt the "vocabularies of structure" prevalent in their environment such as specific job titles,
procedures, and organizational roles. The adoption and prominent display of these
institutionally-acceptable "trappings of legitimacy" help preserve an aura of organizational
action based on "good faith". Legitimacy in the institutional environment helps ensure
organizational survival. However, these formal structures of legitimacy can reduce efficiency
and hinder the organization's competitive position in their technical environment. To reduce
this negative effect, organizations often will decouple their technical core from these
legitimizing structures. Organizations will minimize or ceremonialize evaluation and neglect
program implementation to maintain external (and internal) confidence in formal structures
while reducing their efficiency impact.
Tolbert and Zucker (1996) confirmed the hypothesis that while early organizations adopt the
new form to improve efficiency, later organizations adopt the structural form to maintain
legitimacy. The theory is relevant to the deposit taking SACCOs as it depicts the
environments the SACCOs operate in. Deposit taking SACCOs are regulated by the SACCO
~ 132 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
act though SASRA. The regulations keep changing and SACCOs have to adhere with the
directives. SASRA is a body that influences the operations of the deposit taking. It seeks to
harmonize some operations by issuing some directives that SACCOs are meant to adhere to.
Example of indirect regulations includes the compliance requirements.
Fisher Theory
Fisher (1930) hypothesized that the ex-ante nominal interest rate should fully anticipate
movements in expected inflation, in order to yield the equilibrium real interest rate. The
expected real interest rate is determined by real factors such as the productivity of capital and
time preference of consumers, and is independent of the expected inflation rate. In principle,
the Fisher hypothesis could be extended to any asset, such as real estate, common stock, and
other risky securities. The empirical relationship between inflation and common stocks was
first investigated by Jaffe and Mandelker (1976), Bodie (1976) and Nelson (1976). Although
employing different empirical approaches, these authors all concluded for a significant
negative relationship between the proxies of inflation and stock returns. Following these
pioneering studies, Fama and Schwert (1977) investigate the inflation effect on asset returns
in a number of assets. They concluded that, similar to previous studies, common stocks seem
to perform poorly as hedge against both expected and unexpected inflation. Since these
earlier studies, the empirical literature on the Fisher hypothesis has been prolific, and the
findings have been largely similar (e.g. Gertler and Grinols (1982), Buono (1989), Park
(1997)). The early studies on the Fisher hypothesis mentioned above were mainly concerned
with documenting and describing the nature of the relationship between stock returns and
inflation, and not with any explanation of the results. Several alternative explanations have
emerged. The Tax-Effect Hypothesis proposed by Feldstein (1980) argues that inflation
~ 133 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
generates artificial capital gains due to the valuation of depreciation and inventories (usually
nominally fixed) subject to taxation. This increase corporate tax liabilities and thus reduces
real after-tax earnings. Rational investors would take into account this effect of inflation by
reducing common stock valuation. In this sense, inflation “causes” movement in stock prices.
~ 134 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
force to end financial and economic downturns through monetary or fiscal policies, and
providing aggregate demand to increase the level of economic output, facilitated through a
stable financial system that can spur continued economic stability. Keynes later in 1930s
supported an alternative structure that includes direct government control of investment and
advanced that financial deepening can occur due to an expansion in government expenditure.
Since higher interest rates lower private investment, an increase in government expenditure
promotes investments and reduces private investments concurrently.
Agreeing with the signalling hypothesis theory, Conroy et al. (1999) found excess returns
after stock splits were considerably higher when shareholders were surprised by a larger-
than-expected split. Financial analysts were also found to increase their earnings forecast
notably when the split factor was greater than expected. Excess returns earned by market
participants then tended to be significantly higher when a company’s management decided on
a split factor that the stock price would fall below an expected level.
~ 136 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
Intermediation Theory
Financial intermediation involves matching lenders with excess funds (savings) with
borrowers who need the money and this is done by a third party agent such as a bank. The
intermediation theory is built on models of resource allocation that are based on perfect and
complete markets. The basis of complete perfect markets which this theory is based on comes
from the basic assumptions of the neoclassical model that include lack of competitive
advantages and little or no transaction costs in getting information as it is freely available to
all participants in the market. These assumptions are however not realized in the real world
due to various market imperfections such as asymmetric information which increases
transaction costs and result in other having a competitive edge over others. Financial
Intermediaries therefore exist to remove these imperfections and they do it in many ways.
~ 137 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
Stewardship Theory
Stewardship theory has its roots from psychology and sociology and is defined by Davis et
al., (1997) as “a steward protects and maximizes shareholders wealth through firm
performance, 14 because by so doing, the steward’s utility functions are maximized”. In this
perspective, stewards are bank executives and managers working for the shareholders,
protects and make profits for the shareholders. Unlike agency theory, stewardship theory
stresses not on the perspective of individualism Donaldson and Davis, (1991), but rather on
the role of top management being as stewards, integrating their goals as part of the
organization. The stewardship perspective suggests that stewards are satisfied and motivated
when organizational success is attained. Agyris (1973) argues agency theory looks at an
employee or people as an economic being, which suppresses an individual’s own aspirations.
However, stewardship theory recognizes the importance of structures that empower the
steward and offers maximum autonomy built on trust Donaldson and Davis, (1991). It
stresses on the position of employees or executives to act more autonomously so that the
shareholders’ returns are maximized. Indeed, this can minimize the costs aimed at monitoring
~ 138 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
and controlling behaviors Daviset al., (1997). On the other end, Daily et al. (2003) argued
that in order to protect their reputations as decision makers in organizations, executives and
directors are inclined to operate the firm to maximize financial performance as well as
shareholders’ profits. In this sense, it is believed that the firm’s performance can directly
impact perceptions of their individual performance. Indeed, Fama (1980) contend that
executives and directors are also managing their careers in order to be seen as effective
stewards of their organization, whilst, Shleifer and Vishny (1997) insists that managers return
finance to investors to establish a good reputation so that they can re-enter the market for
future finance. Stewardship model can have linking or resemblance in countries like Japan,
where the Japanese worker assumes the role of stewards and takes ownership of their jobs
and work at them diligently. Moreover, stewardship theory suggests unifying the role of the
CEO and the chairman so as to reduce agency costs and to have greater role as stewards in
the organization. It was evident that there would be better safeguarding of the interest of the
shareholders. It was empirically found that the returns improved by having both these
theories combined rather than separated (Donaldson & Davis, 1991).
Stakeholder Theory
Stakeholder theory can be defined as “any group or individual who can affect or is affected
by the achievement of the organization’s objectives”. Unlike agency theory in which the
managers are working and serving for the stakeholders, stakeholder theorists suggest that
managers in organizations have a network of relationships to serve – this include the
suppliers, employees and business partners. This group of network is important other than
owner-manager-employee relationship as in agency theory Freeman, (1999). On the other
end, Sundaram and Inkpen (2004) contend that stakeholder theory attempts to address the
group of stakeholder deserving and requiring management’s attention. Whilst, Donaldson and
Preston (1995) claimed that all groups participate in a business to obtain benefits.
Nevertheless, Clarkson (1995) suggested that the firm is a system, where there are
stakeholders and the purpose of the organization is to create wealth for its stakeholders.
Freeman (1984) contends that the network of relationships with many groups can affect
decision making processes as stakeholder theory is concerned with the nature of these
relationships in terms of both processes and outcomes for the firm and its stakeholders.
Donaldson and Preston (1995) argued that this theory focuses on managerial decision making
and interests of all stakeholders have intrinsic value, and no sets of interests are assumed to
dominate the others.
Conclusions
Despite major advances in the theories used in finance, there has been scant impact on their
use in relation to strategic financial management. Researchers need to strategically and
accurately apply theories of finance correctly. The theories of finance have been extended in
order to reconcile financial and strategic analysis. It can be summarized by asking how the
present gaps between finance theory and strategic planning might be bridged. Strategic
planning needs finance. Present value calculations are needed as a check on strategic analysis
and vice versa. However, the standard discounted cash flow techniques will tend to
understate the option value attached to growing, profitable lines of business. Financial
management theories require extension to deal with real options. Therefore, to bridge the gap
researchers need to: Apply existing theories correctly; extend the theories. It is evident that
~ 139 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
the most promising line of research is to try to use option of theories to model the time-series
interactions between investments. Both sides could make a conscious effort to reconcile
financial and strategic analysis. Although complete reconciliation will rarely be possible, the
attempt should uncover hidden assumptions and bring a generally deeper understanding of
strategic choices.
References
Abate, J. A., Grant, J. L., & Stewart, G. B. (2004). The EVA Style of Investing. The Journal of
Portfolio Management, 30(4), 61-72.
Admati, A. R., & Pfleiderer P. A. (1989). Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume and Price Variability.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 11, 331-346.
Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1998). Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Agyris, C. (1973). Some Limits of Rational Man Organizational Theory. Public Administration
Review, 33, 253-267.
Allen, F., Bernardo, A. E., & Welch, I. (2000). A Theory of Dividends Based on Tax Clienteles.
Journal of Finance, 55, 2499-2536.
Altman, E. I. (1968). Financial Ratios, Discriminate Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate
Bankruptcy. Journal of Finance, 23(4), 589-609.
Altman, E. I. (2000). Predicting Financial Distress of Companies: Revisiting the Z-Score and Zeta®
Models. Stern School of Business, New York University.
Anderson, C. W., & Garcia-Feijoo, L. (2006). Empirical Evidence on Capital Investment, Growth
Options, and Security Returns. The Journal of Finance, 61(1), 171-194.
Angel, J. J. (1997). Tick Size, Share Price and Stock Splits. Journal of Finance, 52, 655- 681.
Arestis, P., Nissanke, M., & Stein, H. (2005). Finance and Development: Institutional and Policy
Alternatives to Financial Liberalization Theory. Eastern Economic Journal, 31(2), 245-263.
Baekaert, G., & Engstrom, E. C. (2009). Inflation and the Stock Market: Understanding the 'Fed
Model'. NBER Working Paper No. w15024. Retrieved Jun 23 017 from
http://ssrn.com/abstract=141358
Baker, H. K., & Powell, G. E. (1993). Further Evidence on Managerial Motives. Quarterly Journal of
Business and Economics, 32, 20-30.
Baker, M., & Wurgler, J. (2002). Market Timing and Capital Structure. Journal of Finance, 57(1), 1-
32.
Ball, R. (2001). The Theory of Stock Market Efficiency: Accomplishments and Limitations. In Chew,
D. H. (Ed.), The New Corporate Finance: Where Theory Meets Practice (20-33). New York:
Irwin.
Ball, R., & Brown, P. (1968). An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Numbers. Journal of
Accounting Research, 6, 159-178.
Bancel, F. & Mittoo, U. (2004). Cross-Country Determinants of Capital Structure Choice: A Survey
of European Firms. Financial Management, 33(4), 103-32.
Barber, B. M., & Odean, T. (2000). Trading is Hazardous to Your Health: The Common Stock
Investment Performance of Individual Investors. Journal of Finance, 773-806.
Benartzi, S., Michaely, R., Thaler, R., & Weld, W. (2005). The Nominal Price Puzzle. Working
Paper, University of Chicago. Retrieved 13 June 2017 from http://ssrn.com/abstract=891213
Benderly, J., & Zwick, B. (1985). Inflation, Real Balances, Output, and Real Stock Returns.
American Economic Review, 75, 1115-23.
~ 140 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
Bhattacharya, S. (1979). Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy, and 'The Bird in the Hand Fallacy'.
Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 259-70.
Black, F., & Scholes, M. (1973). The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. The Journal of
Political Economy, 81(3), 637-654.
Blynski, L., & Faseruk, A. (2006). Comparison of the Effectiveness of Option Price Forecasting:
Black-Scholes vs. Simple and Hybrid Neural Networks. Journal of Financial Management
and Analysis, 19(2), 46-58.
Bodie, Z. (1976). Common Stocks as a Hedge against Inflation. The Journal of Finance, 2(30), 459-
470.
Botha, D (1985). The Effects of Dividend Policy on Changes in Shareholders’ Wealth. Unpublished
Masters’ Dissertation, University of Port Elizabeth, Port Elizabeth.
Brennan, M. J., & Copeland, T. E. (1988). Stock Splits, Stock Prices, and Transaction Costs. Journal
of Financial Economics, 22, 83-101.
Brounen, D., De Jong, A., & Koedijk, K. (2004). Corporate Finance in Europe: Confronting Theory
and Practice. Financial Management, 33(4), 71-101.
Brown, S. (1978). Earning Changes, Stock Prices, and Market Efficiency. The Journal of Finance,
33(1), 17-39.
Brown, G. R. (1991). Property Investment and the Capital Markets. London: Chapman and Hall.
Brunner, K., & Meckling, W. (1977). The Perception of Man and the Conception of Government.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 9(1), 70-85.
Brush, T. H., Bromiley, P., & Hendrickx, M. (2000). The Free Cash Flow Hypothesis for Sales
Growth and Firm Performance. Strategic Management Journal, 21(4), 455-472.
Buono, A. F., & Bowditch, J. L. (1989). The Human Side of Mergers and Acquisitions: Managing
Collisions between People, Cultures, and Organizations. San Francisco, CA, US: Jossey-
Bass.
Chen, S. N., & Dodd, J. (2002). Market Efficiency, CAPM, and Value-Relevance of Earnings and
EVA: A Reply to the Comment by Professor Paulo. Journal of Managerial Issues, 14(4),
507-512.
Chew, D. H. (Ed.). (2001). The New Corporate Finance: Where Theory Meets Practice. New York:
Irwin.
Chodechai, S. (2004). Determinants of Bank Lending in Thailand: An Empirical Examination for the
years 1992 – 1996. Unpublished Thesis, Tatopac University.
Clarkson, M. B. E. (1995). A Stakeholder Framework for Analyzing and Evaluating Corporate Social
Performance. Academy of Management Journal, 20(1), 92-118.
Coase, R. H. (1937). The Nature of the Firm. Readings in Price Theory (New Series, V: 331-351).
Homewood, IL: Irwin.
Cohen, M. H., & Natoli, V. D. (2003). Risk and Utility in Portfolio Optimization. Physica: A
Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 324(1-2), 81-88.
Conroy, R., Harris, R., & Benet, B. (1999). Stock Splits and Information: The Role of Share Price.
Financial Management, 3, 28-40.
Copeland, T. (1979). Liquidity Changes Following Stock Splits. Journal of Finance, 34, 115-141.
Daily, C. M., Dalton, D. R., & Canella, A. A. (2003). Corporate Governance: Decades of Dialogue
and Data. Academy of Management Review, 28(3), 371-382.
Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Toward a Stewardship Theory of
Management. Academy of Management Review, 22, 20-47.
~ 141 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
DeMaestri, E., & Guerrero, F. (2003). The Rationale for Integrating Financial Supervision in Latin
America and the Caribbean. Technical Papers Series, IMF-135. Washington, DC: IFM
Publications.
Dogan, E., & Smyth, R. (2002). Board Remuneration, Company Performance, and Ownership
Concentration: Evidence from Publicly Listed Malaysian Companies. Asian Economic
Bulletin, 19(3), 319-347.
Donaldson, L., & Davis, J. (1991). Stewardship Theory or Agency Theory: CEO Governance and
Shareholder Returns. Academy of Management Review, 20(1), 65.
Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. (1995). The Stakeholder Theory of the Corporation: Concepts,
Evidence, and Implications. Academy of Management Review, 20, 65-91.
Durand, D. (1959). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment:
Comment. American Economic Review, 49(4), 639-655.
Elton, E. J., & Gruber, M. J. (1997). Modern Portfolio Theory: 1950 to Date. Journal of Banking &
Finance 21, 1743-1759.
Emery, G. W. (1984). A Pure Financial Explanation for Trade Credit. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 19, 271-85.
Ennis, R., & Burik, B. (1991). Pension Fund Real Estate Investment under a Simple Equilibrium
Pricing Model. Financial Analysts Journal, 47(3), 20-30.
Fama, E. (1965). The Behavior of Stock Market Prices. Journal of Business, 38, 34-105.
Fama, E. (1970). Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work. Journal of
Finance, 25, 383-417.
Fama, E. (1974). The Empirical Relationship between the Dividend and Investment Decisions of
Firms. American Economic Review, 64, 304-318.
Fama, E. F. (1980). Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88,
288-307.
Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1996). Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies. Journal
of Finance, 51, 55-84.
Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.
Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 3-56.
Fama, E. F., & Schwert, G. (1977). Asset Returns and Inflation. Journal of Financial
Economics, 5(2), 115-146.
Fama, E. F., Fisher, L., Jensen, M. C., & Roll, R. (1969). The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New
Information. International Economic Review, 10(1), 1-21.
Fama, E., & French, K. (1992). The Cross-Section of Expected Returns. Journal of Finance, 47, 427-
465.
Feldstein, M. (1980). Inflation and the Stock Market. American Economic Review, 70, 839-847.
Findlay, M., Hamilton, C., Messer, S., & Yormark, J. (1979). Optimal Real-Estate Portfolios.
AREUEA Journal, 7, 298-317.
Fisher, I. (1930). The Theory of Interest. New York: Macmillan.
Freeman, R. E. (1984). Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach. London: Pitman.
Freeman, R. E. (1999). Response: Divergent Stakeholder Theory. Academy of Management Review,
24(2), 233-236.
Fry, M. J. (1997). In Favour of Financial Liberalization. The Economic Journal, 107, 754-770.
Gertler, M., & Grinols, E. L. (1982). Unemployment, Inflation and Common Stock Returns. Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking, 14(2), 216-33.
~ 142 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
Glen, J., & Singh, A. (2005). Corporate Governance, Competition and Finance: Rethinking Lessons
from the Asian Crisis. Eastern Economic Journal, 31(2), 219-243.
Gonzalez, M. (2006). ¿Cuánto se paga por el desempeño? El EVA y la remuneración de los gerentes.
Debates IESA, 11(2), 58-60.
Gordon, J. (1991). European Real Estate’s Place in a Portfolio. Baring Investment Property Bulletin,
3(2), 1-3.
Goslings, J., & Petri, V. (1991). The Role of Real Estate in Efficient Investment Portfolios. Journal of
Property Valuation & Investment, 10, 405-412.
Gwilym, O. (2008). Financial Intermediation. London: University of London International Studies
Publications Office.
Hart, O. (1995). Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structures. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hatfield, G. (2002). R&D in an EVA World. Research Technology Management, 45(1), 41-47.
Jaffe, J. F., & Mandelker, G. (1976). The “Fisher Effect” for Risky Assets: An empirical
investigation. The Journal of Finance, 2(31), 147-458.
Jensen, M. C. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs and Ownership
Structure. Harvard: Harvard Business School.
Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers.
American Economic Review, 76(2), 323- 330.
Jensen, M. C. (1989). Active Investors, LBOs, and the Privatization of Bankruptcy. J. Appl. Corp.
Financ., 2, 35-44.
Jensen, M. C. (1994). Dividends and Earnings Announcements and Stockholders’ Returns: An
Empirical Analysis. Journal of Finance, 36, 1-12.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and
Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360.
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (2001). The Nature of Man. In Chew, D. H. (Ed.), The New Corporate
Finance: Where Theory Meets Practice (4-19). New York: Irwin.
Keynes, J. M. (1930). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. UK: Palgrave
Macmillan Publishers, UK
Kiplangat, A. P., Bitok, J. K., Tenai, J., & Rono, L. (2009). Determinants of Investor Confidence for
Firms Listed at the Nairobi Securities Exchange. Eldoret: Moi University Press.
Lakonishok, J., & Lev, B. (1987). Stock Splits and Stock Dividends: Why, Who and When. Journal
of Finance, 42(4), 913-32.
Lamoureux, C. G., & Poon, P. (1987). The Market Reaction to Stock Splits. Journal of Finance,
42(5), 1347-1370.
Lee, B. (1992). Causal Relations among Stock Returns, Interest Rates, Real Activity, and Inflation.
Journal of Finance, 42(4), 1591-1603.
Lee, C., Lee, A. C., & Lee, J. (Eds.). (2010). Handbook of Quantitative Finance and Risk
Management. San Francisco: San Francisco State University.
Lintner, J. (1965). Security Prices, Risk, and Maximal Gains from Diversification. The Journal of
Finance, 20(4), 578-616.
Longstaff, F. A., & Schwartz, E. S. (1995). A Simple Approach to Valuing Risky Fixed and Floating
Rate Debt. The Journal of Finance, 50(3), 789-819.
Madhavan, A. (2002). Market Microstructure: A Practitioner’s Guide. Financial Analysts Journal,
58(5), 28-45.
~ 143 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
~ 144 ~
The University Journal Volume 1 Issue 2 2018 ISSN: 2519-0997 (Print)
Myers, S. C., & Majluf, N. S. (1984). Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions when Firms
Have Information those Investors do not Have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13(2), 187-
221.
Nelson, C. R. (1976). Inflation and Rates of Return on Common Stocks. The Journal of Finance,
2(31), 471-483.
Nilsen, J. (2002). Trade Credit and the Bank Lending Channel. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 34(1), 227–53.
Ozerol, H. Camgoz, M., & Karan, E. (2011). Determining the Performance of Individual Investors:
The Predictive Role of Demographic Variables and Trading Strategies. International Journal
of Business and Social Science, 2(18), 86-90.
Park, S. (1997). Rationality of Negative Stock-Price Responses to Strong Economic Activity.
Financial Analysts Journal, 53(5), 52-56.
Perrow, C. (1986). Economic Theories of Organization. Theory & Society, 15(1/2), 11-45.
Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1997). Trade Credit: Theories and Evidence. Review of Financial
Studies, 10, 661-92.
Pompion, M. M. (2008). Behavioral Finance and Wealth Management: How to Build Optional
Portfolio that Account for Investor Biases. New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons.
Powell, W. W., & Dimaggio, P. J. (1991). The New Institutionalism in Organization Analysis.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Ram, R., & Spencer, D. E. (1983). Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation, and Money: Comment.
American Economic Review, 73, 463-470.
Reddy, W. (2001). Property Trust Investment for Fiji: Opportunities, Constraints and Viability. A
Paper Presented during the Pacific Rim Estate Society Annual Conference.
Ross, S. (1976). The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing. Journal of Economic Theory, 13,
341–60.
Ross, S. A. (1973). The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal’s Problem. The American
Economic Review, 63(2), 134-139.
Ross, S. A. (1977). The Determination of Financial Structure: The Incentive-Signalling Approach.
The Bell Journal of Economics, 8(1), 23-40.
Rubin, P. H. (1990). Managing Business Transactions, Controlling the Cost of Coordinating,
Communicating, and Decision Making (New Ed). New York: Free Press.
Sahoo, P., Nataraj, G., & Kamaiah, B. (2001). Savings and Economic Growth in India: The Long-Run
Nexus. Savings and Development, 25(1), 67-80.
Schultz, P. (2000). Stock Splits, Tick Size, and Sponsorship. The Journal of Finance, 55(1), 429-450.
Shah, A. K., & Oppenheimer, D. M. (2008). Heuristics Made Easy: An Effort Reduction Framework.
Psychological Bulletin, 134(2), 207-222.
Shapiro, S. P. (2005). Agency Theory. Annual Review of Sociology, 31, 4.1-4.22.
Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of
Risk. Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425–442.
Shaw, E. S. (1973). Financial Deepening in Economic Development. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1991). The Takeover Wave of the 1980’s. Journal of Applied Corporate
Finance, 49-56.
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1997). A Survey of Corporate Governance. Journal of Finance, 52(2),
737-783.
~ 145 ~
Theories in Finance Discipline: A Critique of Literature Review [Warue et al.]
Shrieves, R., & Wachowicz, J. (2001). Free Cash Flow (FCF), Economic Value Added (EVA™), and
Net Present Value (NPV): A Reconciliation of Variations of Discounted-Cash-Flow (DCF)
Valuation. The Engineering Economist, 46, 33-52.
Sproul, M. (1998). The Quantity Theory versus the Real Bills Doctrine in Colonial America. UCLA
Economics Working Papers 775B, UCLA Department of Economics.
Stern, J., Stewart, G. B., & Chew, D. (1995). The EVATM Financial Management System. Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance, 8(2), 32-46.
Stern, S. & Company. (n.d.) Stern Stewart’s Four M’s. Retrieved September 27, 2016 from
http://www.sternstewart.com/evaabout/fourm.php
Stewart, G. B. III. (1991). The Quest for Value. New York: Harper-Collins.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1981). The Allocation Role of the Stock Market: Pareto Optimality and Competition.
Journal of Finance, 235-51.
Sundaram, A. K., & Inkpen, A. C. (2004). The Corporate Objective Revisited. Organization Science,
15(3), 350-363.
Tolbert, P. S., & Zucker, L. G. (1996). Institutionalization of Institutional Theory. In S. Clegg, C.
Hardy and W. Nord (Eds.), Handbook of Organizational Studies. London: Sage.
Versluis, C., & Hillegers, T. (2006). The Impact of Portfolio Re-Financing on Black-Scholes Call
Option Valuation. Applied Financial Economics Letters, 2, 261-263.
Williamson, O. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York, NY: Free Press.
Zajac, E., & Westphal, J. (2004). The Social Construction of Market Value: Institutionalization &
Learning Perspectives on Stock Market Reactions. American Sociological Review, 69(3),
433-457.
~ 146 ~