Opportunity Cost Theory
Opportunity Cost Theory
From the above table, it is clear that Portuguese labour is more efficient than English labour in the
production of wine as well as cloth. So Portugal has an absolute advantage in the production of wine and
cloth. The trade between England and Portugal can also be demonstrated by introducing the concept of
opportunity cost. Table 1.6 gives the opportunity costs for producing wine and cloth in the two nations
calculated on the basis of information given in Table 1.5.
In short, any point on the production possibility curve shows the combination of cloth and wine output
when the productive resources are fully employed and allocated between cloth and wine in a certain
production.
Any point above the PA line is beyond reach with the particular quantum of resources. For example, point
N indicates a combination of eight units of cloth and ten units of wine which is impossible to obtain with
the available resources. Again, when eight units of cloth are produced, the remaining resources are
sufficient to produce only four units of wine.
Any point below the production possibility curve represents a combination of cloth and wine when the
available resources are not fully employed. For example, point R represents a combination of five units of
cloth and seven units of wine. When only five units of cloth are produced, the remaining resources if they
are fully employed, can give an output of ten units of wine.
The slope of the production possibility curve (PPC) represents the marginal rate of transformation (MRT)
or the amount of the commodity that the nation must give up in order to get one more unit of the second
commodity.
If the nation faces constant costs or MRT, then its production possibility curve is a straight line as shown in
Figure with slope equal to the constant opportunity costs or MRT and to the relative commodity prices in
the nation.
In many cases, production is subject to the law of increasing opportunity costs or MRT. Under such
conditions, the production possibility curve is concave to the origin as shown in Fig. 1.4 below
Starting with OA output of cloth and zero of wine, if AC unit of cloth is given up, we can produce OW
wine.
But, if we give up further CC1 output of cloth and reduce cloth production to C1 level, the increase in wine
output that can be achieved is WW1 which is less than OW.
The addition to the wine output that can be produced by giving up yet another equivalent amount of
cloth is W1 W2 , which is still lower than WW1 and so on.
Thus, the amount of extra wine we can produce by decreasing production of cloth with a given amount of
resources steadily decreases as we move downward along the PPC.
This implies that opportunity cost of wine in terms of cloth is steadily increasing as we increase the
production of wine and decrease the production of cloth.
Conversely, for every additional unit of cloth, the amount of wine is to be given up. For the subsequent
increases in the cloth output, the amount of wine to be given per unit of cloth increases from W 2 W3 to W1
W2 and from W W1 to WO.
Under increasing costs, a nation will choose a combination of output at which the MRT will equal the
equilibrium relative commodity price in the nation.
The equilibrium relative commodity price in the nation is determined by the supply and demand
conditions in the nation. This is presented in Fig. 1.5.
If PP represents the price ratio in the country, production will be at point F, representing OC 1 cloth and
OW1 wine, because at F, PP, which represents the price ratio, is tangent to the PPC.
When the price ratio is PP, if the country were to produce at some other point, for example A, the
opportunity cost of producing more wine would be lower than its price which implies that producers
could increase their profits by producing more wine.
The profit will be maximum at point F at which the relative prices and opportunity costs are equal.
If the price of cloth increases and P 1 P1 becomes the new price ratio, producers will reallocate resources
to produce more cloth and move to A at which the price line is tangent to the production frontier.
On the other hand, if the cloth price falls and price ratio changes to P 2 P2 , production of wine will be
increased by reducing the output of cloth and a new equilibrium will be established at point S.
Changes in factor supplies will cause a shift in the PPC of a nation, ceteris paribus. An increase in the
factors of production will cause an outward shift and a decrease will cause an inward shift of the
production frontier.
In Fig. 1.6 given below, the X-axis represents labour intensive goods and the Y-axis represents capital
intensive goods. In this figure, AA represents the original PPC.
Supposing that all the factors of production increase in the same proportion, it will cause a shift of the
PPC upward and the new PPC, A1 A1 will be parallel to the old PPC, AA.
If only one of the factors of production increases or if the increase in the factors of production is
disproportionate, the shape of the new PPC will be different from that of the old one.
Assume that in Fig. 1.7, the X-axis represents labour intensive goods and the Y-axis represents capital
intensive goods. If only the supply of labour increases, the PPC will shift from AA to A 2 A2 as shown in Fig.
1.7 implying that the country is now capable of producing a much larger amount of labour intensive
commodities.
Again, if only the supply of capital increases, the PPC will shift from AA to A A as shown in Fig. 1.8 below.
It implies that the country is now capable of producing a much larger amount of capital intensive
commodities.
Technological progress increases the productivity of a nation’s factors of production and has the same
general effect on the production possibilities as an increase in the supply of its factors of production.