We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as DOCX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 6
Chapter 1 - DEFINITION, SCOPE AND DIVISION OF ECONOMETRICS
DEFINITION, SCOPE AND DIVISION OF ECONOMETRICS
DEFINITION AND SCOPE OF ECONOMETRICS Econometrics deals with the measurement of economic relationships. The term ‘econometrics’ is formed from two words of Greek origin; o íkovou ía (economy), and ué tpov (measure). Econometrics is a combination of economic theory, mathematical economics and statistics, but it is completely distinct from each one of these three branches of science. Experience has shown that each of these three branches of science, that of statistics, economic theory, and mathematics, is a necessary, but not by itself sufficient, condition for a real understanding of the quantitative relations in modern economic life. It is the unification of all three that is powerful. And it is this unification that constitutes econometrics. Thus econometrics may be considered as the integration of economics, mathematics and statistics for the purpose of providing numerical values for the parameters of economic relationships (e.g. elasticity, propensities, and marginal values) and verifying economic theories. The most important characteristic of economic relationships is that they contain a random element, which, however, is ignored by economic theory and mathematical economics which postulate exact relationships between the various economic magnitudes. Econometrics has developed methods for dealing with the random component of economic relationships. For example, economic theory postulates that the demand for commodity depends on its price, on the prices of other commodities, on consumers’ income and on tastes. This is an exact relationship, because it implies that demand completely determined by the above four factors. No other factor, except those explicitly mentioned, influences the demand. In mathematical economics we express the above abstract economic relationships of demand in mathematical terms. Thus we may write the following demand equation Q = b0 + b1p + b2p0 + b3Y + b4t where Q = quantity demanded of a particular commodity P = price of the commodity P0 = prices of other commodities Y = consumers’ income t = taste b0, b1, b2, b3, b4 = coefficients of the demand equation. The above demand equation is exact, because it implies that the only determinants of the quantity demanded are the four factors which appear in the right hand side of the equation. Quantity demanded will change only if some of these factors change. No other factor may have any effect on demand. However, we know that other factors such as invention of a new product, a war, professional changes, institutional changes, changes in law, changes in income distribution, massive population movements, etc., can affect quantity demanded. Furthermore, human behavior is inherently erratic. In econometrics the influence of these ‘other’ factors is taken into account by the introduction into the economic relationships of a random variable, with specific characteristics, which will be discussed in later chapters. In our example the demand function studied with the tools of econometrics would be of the (stochastic) form. Q = b0 + b1p + b2p0 + b3Y + b4t +u where u stands for the random factors which affect the quantity demanded.
It is essential to stress that econometrics presupposes the existence of a body of
economic theory. In testing a theory we start from its mathematical formulation, which constitutes the model or the maintained hypotheses. In our example of the demand function the maintained hypothesis is Q = b0 + b1p + b2p0 + b3Y + b4t +u. The next step is to confront the model with observational data referring to the actual behavior of the economic units – consumers or producers. The aim of this stage is to establish whether the theory is compatible with the facts. If the theory is compatible with the actual data, we accept the theory as valid. If the theory is incompatible with the observed behavior, we either reject the theory or, in the light of the empirical evidence of the data, we may modify it. The procedure to be followed when testing a theory may be schematically presented as in fig. 1.1. Theory
Mathematical expression of theory
Model or maintained hypothesis
Confrontation of model with data
Accept theory if compatible with data
Reject theory if incompatible with
Revise data theory if incompatible with dat
Confrontation with new data
Fig. 1.1 The procedure outlined above is not intended to imply that when testing a theory the researcher should restrict himself only to factors suggested by economic theory. If these factors do not provide a satisfactory explanation of economic behavior, the research worker is certainly entitled to look for other factors. Econometrics and Mathematical Economics Mathematical economics states economic theory in terms of mathematical symbols. There is no essential difference between mathematical economics and economic theory. Both states the same relationships, but while economic theory uses verbal exposition, mathematical economics employs mathematical symbolism. Both express the various economic relationships in an exact form. Neither economic theory nor mathematical economics allows for random elements which might affect the relationship and make it stochastic. Furthermore, they do not provide numerical values for the coefficients of the relationships. Econometrics differs from mathematical economics even though econometrics presupposes the expression of economic relationships in mathematical form. Mathematical economics like economic theory assume that economic relationships are exact. On the contrary, econometrics assumes that relationships are not exact. Econometric methods are designed to take into account random disturbances which create deviation from the exact behavioral patterns suggested by economic theory and mathematical economics. Furthermore, econometric methods provide numerical values of the coefficients of economic phenomena. Econometrics and Statistics Econometrics differs both from mathematical statistics and economic statistics. An economic statistician gathers empirical data, records them, tabulates them or charts them, and then attempts to describe the pattern in their development over time and perhaps detect some relationship between various economic magnitudes. Economic statistics is mainly a descriptive aspect of economics. It does not provide measurement of the parameters of economic relationships. Mathematical (or inferential) statistics deals with methods of measurement, which are developed on the basis of controlled experiments in laboratories. Statistical methods of measurement are not appropriate for economic relationships, which cannot be measured on the basis of evidence provided by controlled experiments, because such experiments cannot be designed for economic phenomena. In physics and some other sciences, the researcher can hold all other conditions constant and change only one element in performing an experiment. He can then record the results of such a change and apply the classical statistical method to deduce the laws governing the phenomenon being investigated. In studying the economic behavior of human beings one cannot change only one factor while keeping all other factors constant. In the real world all variables change continuously and simultaneously, so that controlled experiments are impossible. We cannot change incomes, keeping prices, tastes and other factors constant, because the latter will change as a result of income changes. Econometrics uses statistical methods after adapting them to the problems of economic life. These adopted statistical methods are called econometric methods. In particular, econometric methods are adjusted so that they become appropriate for the measurement of economic relationships which are stochastic, that is, they include random elements. GOALS OF ECONOMETRICS We can distinguish three main goals of econometrics: (1) analysis, i.e. testing of economic theory; (2) policy–making i.e. supplying numerical estimates of the coefficients of economic relationships, which may be then used for decision-making; (3) forecasting, i.e. using the numerical estimates of the coefficients in order to forecast the future values of the economic magnitudes. Of course, these goals are not mutually exclusive. Successful econometric applications should really include some combination of all three aims. Analysis; Testing Economic Theory In the earlier stages of the development of economic theory economists formulated the basic principles of the functioning of the economic system using verbal exposition and applying a deductive procedure. Thus in demand theory it was assumed that the consumer aims at the maximization of his satisfaction (utility) from the expenditure of his income, given the prices of the commodities. Similarly, producers were assumed to be motivated by maximization of their profits. From these assumptions the economists by pure logical reasoning derived some general conclusions (laws) concerning the working processes of the economic system. Economic theories thus developed in an abstract level were not tested against economic reality. Econometrics aims primarily at the verification of economic theories. In this case we say that the purpose of the research is analysis, i.e. obtaining empirical evidence to test the explanatory power of economic theories, to decide how well they explain the observed behavior of the economic units. Today any theory, regardless of its elegance in exposition or its sound logical consistency, cannot be established and generally accepted without some empirical testing. Policy-Making; Obtaining Numerical Estimates of the Coefficients of Economic Relationships for Policy Simulations In many cases we apply the various econometric techniques in order to obtain reliable estimates of the individual coefficients of the economic relationships from which we may evaluate elasticities or other parameters of economic theory (multipliers, technical coefficients of production, marginal costs, marginal revenues, etc.). The knowledge of the numerical value of these coefficients is very important for the decisions of firms as well as for the formulation of the economic policy of the government. It helps to compare the effects of alternative policy decisions. For example, the decision of the government about devaluing the currency will depend on a great extent on the numerical value of the marginal propensity to import, as well as on the numerical value of the price elsticities of exports and imports. If the sum of price elasticities of exports and imports is less than one in absolute value, the devaluation will not help in eliminating the deficit in the balance of payments. Similarly, if the price elasticity of demand for a product is less than one (inelastic demand); it does not pay the manufacturer to decrease its price, because his receipt would be reduced. Such examples show how important is the knowledge of the numerical values of the coefficients of the economic relationships. Econometrics can provide such numerical estimates and has become an essential tool for the formulation of sound economic policies. Forecasting: The Future Values of Economic Magnitudes In formulating policy decisions it is essential to be able to forecast the value of the economic magnitudes. Such forecasts will enable the policy maker to judge whether it is necessary to take any measures in order to influence the relevant economic variables. For example, suppose that the government wants to decide its employment policy. It is necessary to know what is the current situation of employment as well as what the level of employment will be, say, in five years’ time, if no measure whatsoever is taken by the government. With econometric techniques we may obtain such an estimate of the level of employment. If this level is too low, the government will take appropriate measures to avoid its occurrence. Forecasting is becoming increasingly important both for the regulation of developed economies as well as for the planning of the economic development of underdeveloped countries. DIVISION OF ECONOMETRICS Econometrics may be distinguished into two branches, theoretical econometrics and applied econometrics. Theoretical econometrics includes the development of appropriate methods for the measurement of economic relationships. Two features of economic reality render the pure methods of mathematical statistics inappropriate for the measurement of economic phenomena. Firstly, the data which are used for the measurement of economic relationships are observations of actual life and are not derived from controlled experiments. In economic life laboratory experiments are not possible, because most of the economic magnitudes change contemporaneously and each influences and is influenced by all the other magnitudes. Secondly, the economic relationships are not exact, as economic theory and mathematical economics assume them to be. Economic behavior is to a certain extent erratic, being influence by unpredictable events. Econometric methods may be classified into two groups: (1) single-equation techniques, which are methods that are applied to one relationship at a time; and (2) simultaneous-equation techniques, which are methods applied to all the relationships of a model simultaneously. Applied econometrics includes the application of econometric methods to specific branches of economic theory. It examines the problems encountered and the findings of applied research in the fields of demand, supply, production, investment, consumption, and other sectors of economic theory. Applied econometrics involves the application of the tools of theoretical econometrics for the analysis of economic phenomena and forecasting economic behavior.